Comments and discussion.
Glaeser, Edward L. ; Gottlieb. Joshua D.
COMMENT BY ROBERT E. HALL The issues addressed in this paper by
Edward Glaeser and Joshua Gottlieb will be coming into focus in the
United States in the rest of this century as the country adapts to
rising energy prices, including the appropriate carbon tax. The economic
geography of the United States features extremely low residential
densities made possible by universal automobile travel over good roads.
People here live in free-standing houses surrounded by lawns, a style of
living almost unknown in the rest of the world apart from our close
cousins, Canada and Australia. On the other hand, the United States lags
far behind many East Asian and European countries in residential
broadband deployment because our dwellings are so far apart.
The economic logic of raising residential density seems powerful,
but so far none of the policies discouraging higher density have
changed. California puts heavy taxes on cars and gives heavy subsidies
to mass transit, but almost nobody uses mass transit, because it does
not pass near where they live. Sixty-passenger diesel buses rumble up
and down Silicon Valley's El Camino, seldom carrying more than
three passengers. And it is utterly unlawful to develop new land for
housing or replace a single-family house with anything other than a new
single-family house. Restrictions on land use condemn us to driving cars
at a time when any reasonable society would shrink car travel
substantially.
Glaeser and Gottlieb's interesting and wide-ranging paper
touches on a number of the research issues underlying the response to
higher energy prices and many other policies that involve economic
geography. The authors take the standard economist's position that
the primary case for government intervention is the correction of an
externality. They find little support for the view that taxes and
subsidies that vary by location alter the distribution of income or that
they would be desirable if they did. They believe that an attack on
income inequality through policies with direct effects on the income
distribution would generally be better than the more roundabout approach
of subsidizing the locations where the poor live. This conclusion is
unlikely to be controversial at meetings of the Brookings Panel.
One might think that geographic policy faces the classic issue:
Build on strength, or focus on improving the weak places? The paper
takes the resolutely middle-of-the-road stand that policy should do
neither. Policy should strive to do good for its own sake, not to alter
the geographic distribution of economic activity.
The paper's concern with geographic policy gives it something
of a European flavor. Such policy is not on the agenda in the United
States. In Europe, government puts substantial resources into
subsidizing poorer areas, such as eastern Germany and southern Italy.
Poor Portugal lost its EU subsidy when the European Union incorporated
some of the countries of eastern Europe. I am not aware of any important
policy push toward regional subsidies in the United States. We let our
airlines sink or swim on their own, more or less--three sank in the week
before this Brookings Panel meeting. There is no chance that Alitalia
would still be flying if it were a U.S. airline. We tend to take the
same tough-love attitude toward poorer regions. The authors set forth a
good case for tough love toward cities like Detroit: no need to
subsidize new housing there; Detroit already has plenty of cheap
housing.
The paper pushes the point that it is not enough to identify
spatial externalities to rationalize government intervention. To justify
an intervention that moves people, say, from Boston to Philadelphia, one
needs to show that the social gain per person moved is greater in
Philadelphia than the loss in Boston. I concur with the authors that the
earlier evidence in favor of agglomeration externalities is fairly
compelling. Much of the interesting new empirical work in the paper
shows that the marginal effects of pro-agglomeration policies are
roughly the same across cities. The authors find no good evidence that
moving people from city to city generates any net agglomeration
economies.
The paper confirms earlier estimates of positive agglomeration
effects. Using historical population as an instrument, equation 2-5 of
their table 2 provides an instrumental variables estimate of the
structural response-([omega] - [alpha][gamma])/(1 - [alpha] +
[alpha][gamma]) in their notation--of 0.089, a large effect by the
standards of this literature. The authors back away from this finding,
however, saying, "... historical instruments of this kind do not
naturally solve the identification problem in a spatial model...."
Their main concern is that using historical population as an instrument
may be invalid, because it is correlated with current productivity
differences. They quite properly dismiss the ordinary least squares
results in table 2 because the identification assumption that current
population is uncorrelated with productivity seems obviously false. One
wonders why the pages of the Brookings Papers need to be cluttered with
OLS results that the authors believe are invalid.
I am puzzled by some features of table 3. The basic idea is that
the growth in income per capita has a structural coefficient of ([omega]
- [alpha][gamma])/(1 - [alpha] + [alpha][gamma]) on population growth.
Here co is the elasticity of agglomeration productivity with respect to
population, 1 - [alpha] is the elasticity of output with respect to
labor input, and [gamma] is the factor share of fixed capital. The
estimated value in equation 3-2 is 0.004. Thus, if 1 - [alpha] = 0.66
and [alpha][gamma] = 0.04, values the authors suggest, then the implied
value of the agglomeration coefficient co is 0.04, somewhat above the
finding of the earlier literature. But the implied value of [gamma] is a
staggering 0.12. What is the basis for making fixed capital so
important? Without fixed capital, that is, with [alpha][gamma] = 0, the
implied value of co is 0.003, which is contrary to the entire theme of
the paper that agglomeration is important. The authors defend their
implicit assumption about the share of fixed capital by identifying it
with nonresidential buildings. But buildings, although fixed in space,
are not a fixed quantity over time, but instead are producible. In
studying spatial equilibrium, I believe that one should take a long-run
view, so that the durability of buildings is not a good argument in
favor of the assumption that they are fixed. If fixed capital is limited
to land (which is not really fixed either when production competes with
housing in a city), the usual view is that its share is only a few
percentage points. Thus table 3 seems to undermine the main idea of the
paper that agglomeration itself is an important fact.
The authors go on to test whether the agglomeration effect differs
by city size. They approach this issue by measuring the extra effect of
population growth in larger places. Table 3 reports the results. It goes
without saying that regression 3-1 should have been removed from the
table, as neither the authors nor any reader is interested in OLS
results when the right-hand variables are plainly endogenous.
The third coefficient in equation 3-3 in table 3 finds that the
wage-population growth slope was lower in 2000 in larger places. The
t-statistic on this effect is 1.2, indicating moderately persuasive
evidence of smaller agglomeration effects in areas with higher
population. Nonetheless, the authors remain agnostic about the variation
in agglomeration effects between small and large places. Given that the
most important theme of the paper is that differences in marginal
agglomeration effects are the primary rationalization for policies with
spatial effects, I think this equation deserves a lot more attention. On
its face, it contradicts the authors' general skepticism about
disparities in marginal effects.
Table 4 investigates the relationship between city size and some of
the adverse consequences of size. In this table the odd-numbered
equations look for differences between large and small places, and the
even-numbered equations look for differences based on centralization.
Positive values of the coefficients in the second row indicate a
nonlinearity that could be exploited by moving people from bigger to
smaller cities. All of the size coefficients are essentially zero,
suggesting the lack of any exploitable differences by city size. The
coefficient in the fourth row measures the difference in the marginal
effect of population in more centralized cities. Here the results are
mixed. Congestion is more sensitive to population in more centralized
cities, but pollution and murders are less sensitive. Sampling variation
obscures any definite conclusion as well.
Although the authors are careful about endogenous fight-hand
variables in most of the empirical work in the paper, they drop that
concern in table 4, where all estimation is by OLS. For congestion and
air quality, the direction of the bias seems obviously downward. If a
city has a geography that results in naturally high congestion--for
example, if it surrounds a bay, so that traffic concentrates on the
edges of the bay and along the few bridges that cross it--congestion
will be high and population low. This implies a negative correlation between the disturbance in the regression and the right-hand variable,
population, and a consequent downward bias. The same argument applies to
air pollution, as some cities are in basins that collect polluted air.
Los Angeles is smaller than it would be if the air circulated more
effectively. Because nothing rules out nonlinear effects from
endogeneity bias, the results on nonlinearity in table 4 are less than
conclusive.
The authors might make the same point about city-size policy as
they do about income redistribution: direct policies are surely better
for dealing with congestion, pollution, and crime. Notwithstanding the
recent setback in New York City, congestion taxation is making steady
advances around the world. Progress in controlling air pollution in
developed countries has been astronomical, and even China is beginning
to take the issue seriously. Crime rates for less serious crimes have
proven remarkably responsive to simple changes in law enforcement: the
United States and Western Europe have switched places over the past few
decades, as burglary and mugging have declined here and exploded in
Europe.
The first part of the section of the paper titled "U.S.
Policies toward Places" deals with transportation and presents
moderately persuasive evidence that canals, railroads, highways, and
airports shape urban growth. The paper does not delve into evidence on
the marginal effects of transport subsidies on different places. The
authors conclude, "current spending does not appear to be targeting
the high-income, high-density areas where the agglomeration effects are
likely to be strongest." I don't see where the empirical work
supports this conclusion. The authors' observation that it may be
desirable to subsidize transportation in poor areas for its direct
effect does not involve agglomeration effects.
The section of the paper on housing policy argues that policy has
not made the mistake of trying to attract people to particular places by
subsidizing housing there, but rather has made the huge mistake of
constraining density and thus grossly failing to achieve the social
optimum where land prices are maximal. As I noted at the beginning,
these policies may need to relent in the face of high and rising fuel
prices, especially when the appropriate carbon tax is included in fuel
prices.
COMMENT BY
PAUL ROMER Economists do not quite know what to make of the yin and
yang of cities. More than 150 years ago, Frederic Bastiat famously captured the invisible-hand yin:
On coming to Paris for a visit, I said to myself: Here are a
million human beings who would all die in a few days if supplies of
all sorts did not flow into this great metropolis. It staggers the
imagination to try to comprehend the vast multiplicity of objects
that must pass through its gates tomorrow.... What, then, is the
resourceful and secret power that governs the amazing regularity of
such complicated movements? ... That power is an absolute
principle, the principle of free exchange. (1)
So cities are the perfect illustration of the miracle of the
market, right?
Not exactly. Turns out that economists can't capture what goes
on in a city with the model of competitive equilibrium that is supposed
to capture the invisible hand. Cities are dense with goods and services that are characterized by inherent nonconvexities and therefore cannot
be provided competitively: water, sewerage, garbage collection, electric
power, communications, roads, parks, police protection. More
fundamentally, in a model of perfect competition, cities should not even
exist. If production technologies exhibited the kind of convexity required to show that one can use the price system to achieve an
efficient outcome with prices, there would be no reason to pile up so
much economic activity on so little land.
Like their colleagues who have had to confront fundamental
nonconvexities in international trade and economic growth, economists
working on cities have invoked both the Marshallian extension of the
competitive equilibrium model based on external increasing returns, and
the more recent extension based on monopolistic competition. With these
extensions, they can build models in which people are willing to pay
high prices for the chance to be around lots of other people. But these
extensions get one only partway toward a model that can capture the
variety of outcomes in different cities. In the universe of interactions
that take place in dense urban environments, the missing markets far
outnumber the ones that are present. As a result, the nonmarket
mechanisms that city governments use to control public health, crime,
traffic, air pollution, noise, sight lines, visual clutter, and the
activities permitted in any specific location make a world of difference
to the quality of city life. Someone comparing life in Lagos today with
life in Paris in 1845 might reasonably conclude that successful cities
tell us more about some miracle of good governance than about the
miracle of the market.
Getting the right perspective on cities would not matter much if
cities themselves did not matter, but of course they do. Half of the
people on earth now live in cities. Most of the other half live in
grinding poverty. Despite the romance of the rural that infiltrates many
discussions of development, it seems likely that this second half will
escape from poverty only when most of them can find places to live and
work in cities. So even before taking account of population growth,
either the world will need a lot more cities, or the existing ones will
have to get a lot bigger. It is a pressing priority to understand the
appropriate roles for markets and governments in carrying out this
expansion.
In a rich country like the United States, the structural
transformation that moves most people into cities is largely complete,
but the United States will experience significant population growth in
the coming century, and so Americans, too, have to think about the
processes that will determine where the growth in urban population will
take place. Moreover, although the United States does not face the same
challenge in reducing poverty that remains in much of the world, income
inequality driven by the interaction between skill and technology will
likely be a growing policy concern. The facts that Edward Glaeser and
Joshua Gottlieb cite at the beginning of their paper suggest that there
may be an important interaction between urbanization on the one side and
skills and technology on the other. Moreover, whatever that connection
was in the past, it may now be changing.
So the issues that Glaeser and Gottlieb touch on in this paper are
among the most challenging for economists and the most important for
policymakers. The common thread in my comments will be that economists
can provide the most help to policymakers by focusing more on
understanding the fundamental issues and less on trying to do their job
of designing or advocating specific policies.
This paper has two conceptually distinct parts: a summary of key
facts about urban areas in the United States, and an analysis of various
U.S. federal policies toward cities and regions. The bulk of the paper
is devoted to this second part. Here it seems to me the authors are
overly constrained by the requirement (whether self-imposed or
externally imposed) that they speak directly to the wisdom of specific
federal policies. This part is rich with detail but can be boiled down
to a simple summary message: In formulating policy toward cities,
economists should focus on the yin and ignore the yang. The authors
conclude that there is little evidence to support the expansion or
continuation of any of the active government policies they consider. The
only positive role they can find is for the feds to suppress an active
policy (land use restrictions) implemented by some local governments. If
one takes the "do no harm" view seriously, telling government
to do nothing may be safe advice, but the contrast between Lagos and
Paris suggests that policy errors of omission can be as harmful as those
of commission.
There are at least three ways to interpret the conclusion that
emerges from this paper--that no policy is good policy. The first is
that market mechanisms are all it takes to achieve an efficient outcome,
so there is no room for government policy in the development and
operation of cities. The second is that government matters, but that in
the United States policy has already been optimized, so that no further
policies are needed (other than perhaps to drop some old bad ideas). The
third is that government policy matters a lot and is far from being
optimal, but the required policies are best implemented at the local
level, and so the federal government, which seems to be the audience for
the advice offered here, had best stay out of the way.
The first of these positions, that government services do not
matter, seems intellectually indefensible to me. I suspect that the
authors would agree, and if so, it might be worth saying so explicitly,
because the paper is simply silent on this point. The second seems
unlikely to me, but because I am not a specialist, I am not sure how
much evidence one could marshal to undermine it. But as for the third
position, if the quality of governance explains part of the difference
between Paris in 1845 and Lagos today, might it not explain part of the
difference between Pine Bluff, Arkansas, and Sioux Falls, South Dakota?
Or between New York in 1970 and New York today?
My hunch is that there is, in fact, a lot of variation in the
quality of governance between different cities in the United States,
just as there is in the quality of management between firms. Economists
might be no better at prescribing what managers of city and state
governments should do than at prescribing what managers of firms should
do, but it does not follow that the quality of governance is irrelevant.
Nor does it follow that economists have nothing useful to say.
For example, if there is variation in the quality of city
governance, then the mobility of people has added significance that is
captured neither in the model nor in the verbal analysis. But allowing
for mobility of people clearly cannot solve all the problems associated
with bad city governance. People can move but most physical capital
cannot. In principle, one might want to consider mechanisms that could
do for the enormous amount of capital that can be trapped in a badly run
city what a private equity takeover or a bankruptcy can do for capital
trapped in a badly managed firm.
The paper is strongest when it develops or deepens a robust
abstract insight. A good example is what the authors call the concept of
spatial equilibrium, which is based on the observation that people can
freely move between cities. As the authors observe, this fact has deep
implications for how one looks at, for example, the difference in
average income between Brownsville and Bridgeport. It does not make
sense to try to help people living in Brownsville by making Brownsville
more like Bridgeport. For someone living in Brownsville, if moving to
Bridgeport will not make her better off, moving Bridgeport to her will
not help either. This insight is important and not obvious. The paper
makes a good start at driving this point home.
There is room to contribute other robust general insights like this
one in a model that is more flexible than the one presented in the
paper. To illustrate what this model might look like and the kind of
results it might generate, consider two cities on two islands, one
larger in area than the other. Workers consume land and a single
produced good. Firms produce output using land and labor. To simplify
the analysis of migration between the two islands, assume that all land
is owned by absentee landlords.
Next, consider adding in two types of agglomeration effects.
Suppose first that productivity in a city is an increasing function of
its population, precisely as in the paper's model. In addition,
assume that the utility that a consumer can achieve per unit of
expenditure is also an increasing function of the number of people who
live in the city. The assumption about productivity is easy to
rationalize using a variety-in-production model. In just the same way,
the assumption about additional utility from being around others can be
captured in a variety-in-consumption model.
It seems clear that the following results should hold in this
two-island model:
1. If there is any agglomeration effect in production or
consumption, population density will be higher on the larger of the two
islands.
2. As a special case, suppose that agglomeration effects are
present in production but not in consumption. Assume as well that land
is used only in production. Because of the agglomeration effect, total
factor productivity will be higher on the larger island. However, wages
and the marginal productivity of labor will be equal between the two
cities. Firms producing on the larger island will face a higher cost of
land and use less land per worker.
3. Continue to suppose that there are no agglomeration benefits in
consumption, only in production. Now, in contrast to case 2, assume that
land is used only in consumption. Then wages and labor productivity will
be higher on the larger island. Land will be more expensive there, and
land consumed per person will be lower.
4. Now reverse the assumption about agglomeration benefits. Suppose
that there are no agglomeration benefits in production but there are
agglomeration benefits in consumption. Continue to assume that land is
used only in consumption. Then wages will be the same in the two cities,
but housing will be more expensive on the larger island. Workers there
will consume less land and (depending on the elasticity of demand for
land) may have more or less income to spend on other goods. They will
derive more utility from each unit of spending on produced goods.
Because the situation outlined in case 4 does not arise in the
model considered in the paper, it is worth pausing briefly to evaluate
its plausibility. One implication of this case is that because of the
broader variety of consumption activities that the larger island offers,
someone who is wealthy and who does not work might choose to live there
even though the price of land is higher. This sounds like the behavior
one observes in at least some cities, but under model 3, the one assumed
in the paper in which the only benefits from density come via
production, someone who did not work would never choose to live in the
larger and denser city.
The richer class of models outlined here offers several insights
that differ slightly from the analysis in the paper. First, in the
section on basic facts about cities, the paper's discussion of
agglomeration effects seems to suggest that these effects are present
only if wages are higher in more dense or more populous locations. The
broader class of models outlined here suggests that agglomeration
effects are present any time population density is higher in one place
than in another. In effect, once there are cities, some kind of
agglomeration effect must be operating. Given this, all that the
analysis of cross-sectional differences in wages can do is provide a
window into the form that these agglomeration effects take. In cases 2
and 4, wages are the same across cities. In case 2, firms trade higher
total factor productivity against higher costs of land. In case 4,
consumers pay higher prices for housing to access better consumption
opportunities.
A blended version of cases 2 and 4 is particularly interesting
because of the key fact cited in the early section of the paper: people
who move between cities in the United States do not experience an
immediate increase in their wage on moving to a bigger city. Taking
these cases and this fact at face value, one has to recognize that the
apparent correlation between city size or density and wages may have
nothing to do with agglomeration effects. Instead it may simply reflect
differences in the characteristics of the workers in different
cities--differences that are not adequately captured even with the
standard individual variables in a wage regression.
Other basic facts cited in the early part of the paper also suggest
that worker heterogeneity and positive assortment of worker types across
cities are a crucial part of the observed variation across cities, one
that may be becoming more firmly entrenched over time. Skilled cities
are becoming even more skilled. Interestingly, they no longer seem to be
the fastest-growing cities. It is as if they are limiting population
growth and swapping lower-skilled for higher-skilled residents. In a
development that may be related, in the 1980s and 1990s, incomes in
different cities stopped converging.
All of these facts call for a model with at least two types of
workers. To see what this might look like, suppress for the moment the
questions addressed in cases 2 through 4 above. That is, set aside the
issue of precisely where the agglomeration effects show up (in
production or in consumption) and where a higher cost of land pinches as
cities get more dense (on the production side or the consumption side).
Instead, consider a very reduced form model in which utility is linear
in a general-purpose form of consumption good that is produced from
land, low-skilled labor, high-skilled labor, and roads. Roads are
provided by the local government and are available at no charge to all
city residents. Here roads are a stand-in for any of the many different
services provided by local governments. In this simple model it is
easiest to take the stock of roads as given by history and set aside the
question of how inputs provided by the government are financed and
produced.
In this reduced-form equilibrium, the stock of land, skilled and
unskilled labor, and roads produce total output Y. Skilled and unskilled
labor are paid returns that may be greater than or less than their
marginal product in producing 11. Agglomeration effects will tend to
make the private return to an additional worker less than the social
return. By itself, unpriced access to a congestible good like a road
will tend to make the private return to a worker who comes to this town
greater than the social return.
Imagine that the positive agglomeration effects are larger for
high-skilled than for low-skilled workers. (This, too, could easily be
captured in a variety model where skilled workers are the inputs needed
in the fixed-cost process that creates new goods.) Assume that the
congestion costs from more users of roads are the same for all workers.
If the congestion effects are large enough, the net social return to an
additional low-skilled worker could be lower than the private return. At
the same time, because the high-skilled workers generate agglomeration
effects, the social return to an additional high-skilled worker is
higher than the private return. If the stock of roads cannot be changed,
cities in this kind of environment might maximize income for those who
remain by limiting increases in the total population, particularly if in
so doing they screen out low-skilled workers and allow in the
high-skilled workers. Better still, they could induce the low-skilled
workers already present to leave as high-skilled workers enter.
The point here is that there may be important links among (i) the
clustering by ability that may be behind the higher wages observed in
bigger and denser cities, (ii) the tendency for skilled cities to become
more skilled yet, recently, to grow more slowly, and (iii) intentional
growth-limiting policies. Because of these links, flexible theories that
let us understand cities more completely and that have a chance at
capturing all of the disparate trends outlined in the early part of the
paper might offer a better basis for thinking seriously about the
reasons behind growth limitations and what their aggregate effects might
be.
The paper's discussion of growth limitations turns on the
observation that the same home would sell for only a slightly higher
price if it were moved to a town with regulations that increase the
minimum lot size, resulting in a lower population density. The
coefficient estimate that the authors report for the effect of density
on housing prices suggests that cutting the average lot size in half and
doubling the number of houses would reduce the price per house by only
about 10 percent. This certainly does seem to suggest that towns are not
maximizing the value of their land.
But a closer look shows that the regressions that find this
surprisingly small effect of density on house price also show that,
holding density constant, each additional regulatory barrier to new
construction increases home prices by about 7 percent. (2) This suggests
that the barriers are acting through channels other than density.
Moreover, the descriptive data show that lower density is associated
with a higher percentage of white residents, a lower percentage of
residents who are foreign-born, and a higher percentage of residents
with a B.A. degree. It therefore seems possible that lot size
restrictions are part of a larger package of policies that may actually
be adjusting the skill mix in ways that increase the number of
high-skilled workers and decrease the number of low-skilled workers.
Without a full model, one cannot say whether decentralized decisions by individual cities about the mix of residents by skill type
will be efficiency enhancing or not, even if they do increase the local
value of land. Nor can one say what effects such policies might have on
overall inequality. Because there are many possible models, and the
evidence will probably not narrow them down to just one, any
investigation of these issues will probably not lead to precise policy
recommendations. Nevertheless, the facts from the first section of the
paper about the evolving skill mix across cities, and the changing
relationship between skill on the one side and population growth and
convergence in income on the other, strike me as the most provocative
part of the paper. I think the authors could usefully have devoted less
attention to the analysis of specific policies and instead have given us
a richer set of models that could help us better understand what these
facts are telling us about cities, governments, and markets.
(1.) Frederic Bastiat, Economic Sophisms, edited and translated by
Arthur Goddard (Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: Foundation for Economic
Education, 1996), sect. I, ch. 18, para. 12.
www.econlib.org/library/Bastiat/basSoph.html.
(2.) E. L. Glaeser and B. A. Ward, "The Causes and
Consequences of Land Use Regulation: Evidence from Greater Boston,"
Journal of Urban Economics (forthcoming)
GENERAL DISCUSSION Lawrence Summers remarked that some of the
paper's conclusions would be shocking to any local politician
actually engaged in place-making policies. In particular, most would be
surprised to hear that investment in urban renewal has no impact except
to create capital gains for homeowners. Benjamin Friedman compared the
notion that place-making policies have zero impact to the Malthusian
model, which worked under a certain set of conditions but not when those
conditions changed. Local politicians may want to know how to
discriminate between circumstances in which place-making policies are
effectual and those in which they are not. Edward Glaeser replied that
his model differs from the Malthusian model in that local investment
positively affects the welfare of the whole society, even if utility is
equilibrated over space; one party does not gain at the expense of
another. For example, if an investment in Baltimore makes Baltimore more
productive, the spatial model predicts that utility outside Baltimore
will eventually equal that in Baltimore, but the utility of all will be
higher. Summers suggested that the authors defend the idea that utility
is really the same in all areas, as this is highly counterintuitive to
most people.
Robert Gordon observed that the pattern of growth and decline of
American cities seems to suggest convergence across regions in terms of
income per capita relative to the U.S. average, with a few exceptions.
For example, metro-area relative income per capita in the former
Confederate states has risen in the last forty years, while that in old
Midwestern industrial cities such as Detroit and Cleveland has declined.
Urban growth seems consistently driven by desirability of location only
in coastal cities, such as San Francisco, Seattle, and the Northeastern
cities. To explain low urban density in the United States, Gordon cited
four factors that date back to the 1940s: the tax deductibility of
mortgage interest, zoning regulations that preclude small suburban lot
sizes, the starvation of mass transit, and the subsidization of
interstate highways. On this point Lawrence Katz suggested that
increasing urban density may not be optimal from a global health
perspective, even though it may be optimal from a global pollution
perspective.
Katz noted further that the paper focused on static, long-run
equilibrium issues. He would have liked to see more discussion of how
policies might reduce barriers to migration when people are hit with
negative shocks or find better opportunities elsewhere.
Rebecca Blank observed that most place-making policies focus on
creating spillovers among neighborhoods within a particular
municipality, not on allocating investment among different regions of
the country. She suggested that the paper could address more local,
intracity concerns.
Gary Becker expressed surprise at the emphasis on the wage effects
of migration. He noted that the impact on real wages of nominal wage
versus land price changes is sensitive to how production and consumption
processes are modeled. Thus, it is difficult to determine how much
regional growth or decline is reflected in movement in wages and how
much in changes in land prices.
Martin Baily observed that land use policies have a large impact on
productivity growth. Changing industry composition is an important
factor in productivity growth, and countries that heavily regulate land
use make such change more difficult. In the case of declining areas, it
seems clear that whatever equilibrium was once in place has changed, and
it may not make sense to preserve places that have lost their economic
base. Still, individuals and families in these places can incur major
losses (if housing prices decline, for example), and one could make a
case for helping them. One way might be to facilitate their relocation
to a different city.
APPENDIX A
Proofs of Propositions
The core equations state that demand equals supply for the
nontraded good (housing), which means that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], where [L.sub.H] is labor in the housing sector
and [L.sub.p] is labor in the traded sector. The two wage equations
imply that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Together
these equations imply that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII].
Solving for traded capital gives us that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], or
(A1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The price solves [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] or
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], where
[Q.sub.W,1], [Q.sub.W], [Q.sub.P,1], and [Q.sub.P] are constants.
Finally, to solve for overall population, we use [U.bar] =
[[theta].sub.i] [N.sup.-[sigma].sub.i] (1 - [t.sub.i])
[W.sub.i][P.sup.-[beta].sub.i], which delivers the result that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Equations 2 through 4 in the text then follow.
Proof of Proposition 1: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII]
(A2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [N.sub.T] is aggregate population in all regions.
We use the formulation above where both wages and prices can be
thought of as a function of population and exogenous parameters, but not
of the tax rate or the amenity level. The derivative with respect to
[N.sub.i] is [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], which
can also be written as k[U.sub.i] - [[lambda].sub.N], where k is a
constant and [U.sub.i] is total utility, which will be equal everywhere
in a spatial equilibrium. As such, the decentralized equilibrium is
location equilibrium, despite the existence of agglomeration economies
and congestion effects in amenities.
As shown in equation 2, population is an increasing function of
[[theta].sub.i](1 - [t.sub.i]), so any choice of [t.sub.i] that
maximizes [[theta].sub.i](1 - [t.sub.i]) will also maximize population.
Wages (equation 3) are a monotonically decreasing function of
[[theta].sub.i](1 - [t.sub.i]), so maximizing wages per capita will end
up minimizing utility. Equation 4 reveals that house prices are
increasing in [[theta].sub.i](1 - [t.sub.i]) as long as [omegas](1 -
[mu] + [mu][eta]) + [mu][eta](1 - [alpha]) - [alpha][gamma](1 - [mu])
> 0 and decreasing in [[theta].sub.i](1 - [t.sub.i]) if the reverse
inequality holds.
Proof of Proposition 2: (a) Social welfare maximization can be
written as maximizing the Lagrangian, where [H.sub.i] now stands for
housing consumption per capita and T is total taxes:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is constant
over space in the competitive equilibrium, then the competitive
equilibrium is equivalent to the first three first-order conditions. If
[U.sub.Y][[Y.sub.i], [H.sub.i], [[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])] is not
constant over space, then the competitive equilibrium cannot be a social
optimum.
The fourth condition can be rewritten as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
If [N.sub.i] [[theta]'.sub.i]([N.sub.i])
[U.sub.[theta]][[Y.sub.i]i, [H.sub.i], [[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])] +
[U.sub.Y][[Y.sub.i], [H.sub.i], [[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])]
[A'.sub.i] ([N.sub.i]) [F'.sub.i]([N.sub.i] - [L.sub.i]) is
constant across space, then this condition will also be implied by the
competitive equilibrium, since U[[Y.sub.i], [H.sub.i],
[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])] is constant across space and so is unearned
income, which equals [A.sub.i] ([N.sub.i]) [F'.sub.i]([N.sub.i] -
[L.sub.i]) - [Y.sub.i] [U.sub.H]/[U.sub.Y] [H.sub.i].
If [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is not
constant, then the competitive equilibrium cannot satisfy this condition
when U[[Y.sub.i], [H.sub.i], [[theta].suib.i]([N.sub.i])] is constant
across space.
(b) Moving someone from area j to area i represents setting
[N.sub.i] = [N.sub.i,C] + [epsilon] and [N.sub.j] = [N.sub.j,C] -
[epsilon], where [N.sub.i,C] and [N.sub.j,C] are the competitive
population allocations. To determine the value of this change, we take
the derivative of social welfare with respect to [epsilon] and evaluate
it at [epsilon] = 0. Total social welfare can be written as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where total unearned income is [[summation].sub.i]
[N.sub.i][Z.sub.i] = [summation][[A.sub.i]
([N.sub.i])[F.sub.i]([N.sub.i] - [L.sub.i]) + [P.sub.i][G.sub.i]
([L.sub.i]) - [N.sub.i][W.sub.i] - T, or total revenue minus labor costs
minus taxes.
If the marginal utility of income is constant across space, then
this derivative equals [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII].
If the marginal utility of income is not constant across space, but
if unearned income from an area goes entirely to the residents of that
area, then the condition becomes
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Both of these are equivalent to the expression given in the text.
Proof of Proposition 3: We can write social welfare maximization as
the maximization of a social planner's Lagrangian:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
This yields a first-order condition for transportation spending of
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In a competitive equilibrium, total social welfare can be written
as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] again.
The derivative of this with respect to transport spending is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The added benefit of transport spending is positive if and only if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Proof of Proposition 4: Social welfare can be written as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
First-order conditions are [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
For these conditions to be satisfied in a competitive equilibrium,
where net unearned income is constant across space,
[U.sub.Y]([Y.sup.k.sub.i], [[theta].sup.k.sub.i]) and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] must be
constant across space.
Starting with a competitive equilibrium where the marginal utility
of income is constant across space, welfare can be improved by moving
type k individuals from city j to city i if and only if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
APPENDIX B
Data Description
Census aggregated data are taken from the compilation provided by
the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research, under
record number 2896. This compilation includes Census county data from
1790 to 2000, including data from various issues of the Census's
City and County Data Book.
To analyze the metropolitan-area level data, we aggregate the
county data according to metropolitan statistical area (MSA) definitions
released by the Office of Management and Budget. Each figure or table
specifies the definition used for that particular application. We use
different definitions for different purposes in order to be consistent
with data from other sources used in a particular figure or table.
A word of caution is in order regarding some aggregate numbers
computed from these data. In order to use a consistent set of MSA
definitions for each purpose, we need median family income and median
house value data at various MSA definitions; these medians are only
presented under certain definitions. We therefore estimate the median by
averaging the component counties' median values, weighting by
families in the case of family income and by housing units in the case
of house values. The resulting numbers are not equal to the true median
for the metropolitan area, but they should be a close enough
approximation for our purposes.
We obtained the Census Bureau's 5 percent Public Use Microdata
Sample (PUMS) of the 2000 Census from the Integrated Public Use
Microdata Series (IPUMS) service of the Minnesota Population Center. The
sole geographical identifier included in the PUMS is a Public Use
Microdata Area (PUMA), which IPUMS links to an MSA where appropriate.
(In particular, IPUMS uses the 1999 MSA definitions, using primary
rather than consolidated MSAs where applicable.) This identification is
imperfect because the Census does not ensure that each PUMA is contained
within a county, so PUMAs do not necessarily map onto MSAs. Nonetheless
it is the best that can be done to link the Census microdata to other
geographical data.
When running wage regressions on the individual-level data, we
include only prime-age men (defined as those 25 to 55 years old) in
order to avoid picking up differing labor force participation rates. We
exclude anyone who reports not having a full-time job or whose annual
earnings are below half of the annual minimum wage. We include dummy controls for each individual's age (grouped by decade: 20s, 30s,
40s, or 50s) and educational attainment (high school dropout, high
school graduate, or college graduate), and in the repeated panel
regressions (table 3) we allow the coefficient on each dummy variable to
change across Census years.
When we use industry-level data in conjunction with Census industry
categorization, it is necessary to match the different industry
classification systems used in the different datasets. Census industry
codes for manufacturing industries, on the 1990 basis, are matched to
Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes using appendix A to
Census Technical Paper No. 65, which is available online at
www.census.gov/hhes/www/ioindex/ tp65_report.html. Since there is not an
exact one-to-one relationship between Census industry codes and SIC
codes, the concordance is necessarily imperfect; we select one SIC code
if multiple ones are given, and we use data from the SIC code given even
when informed that the Census industry code matches only part of the SIC
category. A given Census industry code can be matched with a two-digit,
three-digit, or four-digit SIC code, so our resulting dataset uses a
mixture of levels of detail. These SIC data are in turn matched to
exporting data from the International Trade Administration, available
online at ita.doc.gov/td/industry/otea/industry_sector/tables.htm.
Table B1. Additional Regressions (a)
Dependent variable
Log
Log wage Log
Independent variable wage residual population
Human capital predicted by 2.32 0.28 9.36
industrial distribution (b) (0.33) (0.21) (2.06)
Constant 9.20 -0.17 10.0
(0.10) (0.07) (0.6)
No. of observations 285 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.15 0.01 0.07
Human capital predicted by 2.39 -0.45 -0.55
industrial distribution (b) (0.59) (0.37) (3.62)
Predicted human capital x -0.01 0.15 2.06
above median subsample (0.10) (0.06) (0.62)
Constant 9.18 (0.03) 11.5
(0.16) (0.10) (0.4)
No. of observations 285 285 290
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.15 0.02 0.10
Exporting predicted by 0.35 0.16 1.48
industrial distribution (c) (0.24) (0.14) (1.43)
Constant 9.85 -0.11 12.7
(0.05) (0.03) (0.30)
No. of observations 285 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.01 0.005 0.004
Exporting predicted by 0.27 -0.06 -5.18
industrial distribution (c) (0.47) (0.28) (2.74)
Predicted exporting x 0.03 0.10 2.99
above-median subsample (0.18) (0.11) (1.05)
Constant 9.86 -0.08 13.60
(0.07) (0.04) (0.40)
No. of observations 285 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.01 0.01 0.03
Wage premium predicted 1.71 -0.44 -31.3
by industrial distribution (d) (3.76) (2.23) (22.30)
Constant 9.92 -0.08 12.9
(0.01) (0.01) (0.06)
No. of observations 285 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0007 0.0001 0.007
Wage premium predicted -2.1 -3.16 -60.3
by industrial distribution (d) (13.2) (7.83) (78.2)
Predicted wage premium x 4.3 3.03 32.3
above-median subsample (14.0) (8.35) (83.4)
Constant 9.92 -0.082 12.9
(0.01) (0.007) (0.1)
No. of observations 285 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.001 0.0006 0.007
Dependent variable
Population Income
growth, growth,
Independent variable 1990s 1990s
Human capital predicted by 0.23 0.02
industrial distribution (b) (0.20) (0.11)
Constant 0.06 0.41
(0.06) (0.03)
No. of observations 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.005 0.0001
Human capital predicted by -0.12 0.29
industrial distribution (b) (0.35) (0.20)
Predicted human capital x 0.07 -0.056
above median subsample (0.06) (0.034)
Constant 0.16 0.34
(0.10) (0.06)
No. of observations 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.01 0.01
Exporting predicted by -0.31 0.03
industrial distribution (c) (0.13) (0.08)
Constant 0.19 0.41
(0.03) (0.01)
No. of observations 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.02 0.0004
Exporting predicted by -0.38 0.18
industrial distribution (c) (0.26) (0.15)
Predicted exporting x 0.03 -0.07
above-median subsample (0.10) (0.05)
Constant 0.20 0.39
(0.04) (0.02)
No. of observations 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.02 0.01
Wage premium predicted 0.5 -1.21
by industrial distribution (d) (2.11) (1.18)
Constant 0.13 0.417
(0.01) (0.003)
No. of observations 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0002 0.004
Wage premium predicted 2.91 3.37
by industrial distribution (d) (7.41) (4.12)
Predicted wage premium x -2.68 -5.09
above-median subsample (7.89) (4.39)
Constant 0.13 0.418
(0.01) (0.003)
No. of observations 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0006 0.008
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) Units of observation are MSAs according to the 1999 definitions,
using primary rather than consolidated MSAs where applicable. Data
for the dependent variables are from the U.S. Census Bureau as
described in this appendix.
(b.) Calculated from the Census Public Use Microdata Sample (PUMS) as
described in this appendix. The percent of workers with a college
degree is first calculated for each industry code as defined by the
Census Bureau. These numbers are then averaged for each metropolitan
area, weighting by the distribution of industry employment in the
metropolitan area from the 1980 PUMS.
(c.) Calculated using data from the International Trade Administration
as described in this appendix as the value of an industry's exports
divided by the total value of its shipments. The industry-level export
fraction is averaged for each metropolitan area, weighting by the
distribution of industry employment in the metropolitan area from the
1980 PUMS.
(d.) Calculated from the PUMS as described in this appendix. A wage
premium is first calculated for each industry code, as defined by
the Census, as the industry fixed effect in a wage regression
containing controls for individual age, sex, and education. These
industry wage premiums are then averaged for each metropolitan
area, weighting by the distribution of industry employment in
the metropolitan area from the 1980 PUMS.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We are grateful to Robert Hall, Patrick Kline, Paul
Romer, and Clifford Winston for insightful comments and suggestions, and
to Charlie Redlick and Kristina Tobio for research assistance. Edward
Glaeser thanks the Taubman Center for State and Local Government for
financial support.
References
Acemoglu, Daron, and Joshua Angrist. 2001. "How Large Are
Human-Capital Externalities? Evidence from Compulsory Schooling
Laws." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000: 9-59.
Achenbach, Joel. 2004. The Grand Idea: George Washington's
Potomac and the Race to the West. Simon and Schuster.
Alonso, William. 1964. Location and Land Use: Toward a General
Theory of Land Rent. Harvard University Press.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1991. "Convergence
across States and Regions." BPEA, no. 1: 107-58.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel. 2007. "Did Highways Cause
Suburbanization?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, no. 2:
775-805.
Bergstrom, Theodore. 1986. "Soldiers of Fortune." In
Equilibrium Analysis: Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, edited by
Walter P. Heller, Ross Star,
David J. Starrett, and Kenneth J. Arrow. Cambridge University
Press.
Bernstein, Peter. 2005. Wedding of the Waters: The Erie Canal and
the Making of a Great Nation. W. W. Norton.
Berry, Christopher R., and Edward L. Glaeser. 2005. "The
Divergence of Human Capital Levels across Cities." Papers in
Regional Science 84, no. 3: 407-44.
Bewley, Truman F. 1981. "A Critique of Tiebout's Theory
of Local Public Expenditures." Econometrica 49, no. 3:713-40.
Black, Sandra E. 1999. "Do Better Schools Matter? Parental
Valuation of Elementary Educations." Quarterly Journal of Economics
114, no. 2: 577-99.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Lawrence F. Katz. 1992. "Regional
Evolutions." BPEA, no. 1: 1-61.
Brueckner, Jan K. 1983. "Property Value Maximization and
Public-Sector Efficiency." Journal of Urban Economics 14, no. 1:
1-15.
Bureau of Transportation Statistics. 1996. Airport Activity
Statistics of Certificated Route Air Carriers 1995. Washington.
Busso, Matias, and Patrick Kline. 2008. "Do Local Economic
Development Programs Work? Evidence from the Federal Empowerment Zone
Program." Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 1638. Cowles
Foundation, Yale University.
Caudill, Harry. 1963. Night Comes to the Cumberlands: A Biography
of a Depressed Area. Little, Brown.
Ciccone, Antonio, and Robert E. Hall. 1996. "Productivity and
the Density of Economic Activity." American Economic Review 86, no.
1: 54-70.
Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Gilles Duranton, and Laurent Gobillon.
2008. "Spatial Wage Disparities: Sorting Matters!" Journal of
Urban Economics 63, no. 2: 723-42.
Craig, Lee A., Raymond B. Palmquist, and Thomas Weiss. 1998.
"Transportation Improvements and Land Values in the Antebellum
United States: A Hedonic Approach." Journal of Real Estate Finance
and Economics 16, no. 2: 173-89.
Duranton, Gilles, and Matthew Turner. 2007. "Urban Growth and
Transportation." Working Paper 305. University of Toronto.
Ellison, Glenn, and Edward L. Glaeser. 1999. "The Geographic
Concentration of Industry: Does Natural Advantage Explain
Agglomeration?" American Economic Review 89, no. 2:311-16.
Erickson, Rodney A., and Paul M. Syms. 1986. "The Effects of
Enterprise Zones on Local Property Markets." Regional Studies 20,
no. 1: 1-14.
George, Henry. [1879] 1975. Progress and Poverty: An Inquiry into
the Cause of Industrial Depressions and of Increase of Want with
Increase of Wealth: The Remedy. New York: Robert Schalkenbach
Foundation.
Gilbert, Neil, and Harry Specht. 1974. "Picking
Winners--Federal Discretion and Local Experience as Bases for Planning
Grant Allocation." Public Administration Review 34, no. 6: 565-74.
Glaeser, E. L. 1998. "Should Transfer Payments Be Indexed to
Local Price Levels?" Regional Science and Urban Economics 28, no.
1: 1-20.
--. 2005. "Urban Colossus: Why Is New York America's
Largest City?" Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy
Review 11, no. 2: 7-24.
--. 2008. "The Economic Approach to Cities." Harvard
Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper 2149. Harvard
University.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joshua D. Gottlieb. 2006. "Urban
Resurgence and the Consumer City." Urban Studies 43, no. 8:
1275-99.
--. 2008. "The Economics of Cities." Harvard University.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joseph Gyourko. 2005. "Urban Decline
and Durable Housing." Journal of Political Economy 113, no. 2:
345-75.
Glaeser, Edward L., Joseph Gyourko, and Raven E. Saks. 2005.
"Why Have Housing Prices Gone Up?" American Economic Review
95, no. 2: 329-33.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Matthew Kahn. 2004. "Sprawl and Urban
Growth." In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 4:
Cities and Geography, edited by J. Vernon Henderson and Jacques Thisse.
New York: North Holland.
--. 2008. "The Greenness of Cities: Carbon Dioxide Emissions
and Urban Development." Working Paper 14238. Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Glaeser, Edward L., Hedi D. Kallal, Jose A. Scheinkman, and Andrei
Shleifer. 1992. "Growth in Cities." Journal of Political
Economy 100, no. 6:1126-52.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Janet E. Kohlhase. 2004. "Cities,
Regions and the Decline of Transport Costs." Papers in Regional
Science 83, no. 1: 197-228.
Glaeser, Edward L., and David C. Mare. 2001. "Cities and
Skills." Journal of Labor Economics 19, no. 2:316-42.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto. 2007. "Did the
Death of Distance Hurt Detroit and Help New York?" Working Paper
13710. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Bruce Sacerdote. 1999. "Why Is There
More Crime in Cities?" Journal of Political Economy 107, no, 2,
part 2: 225-58.
Glaeser Edward L., and Albert Saiz. 2004. "The Rise of the
Skilled City." Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs, pp.
47-94.
Glaeser. Edward L., Albert Saiz, and Jed Kolko. 2001.
"Consumer City." Journal of Economic Geography 1, no. 1:
27-50.
Glaeser. Edward L., and Raven Saks. 2006. "Corruption in
America." Journal of Public Economics 90, no. 6-7: 1053-72.
Glaeser Edward L., and Jesse M. Shapiro. 2003. "Urban Growth
in the 1990s: Is City Living Back?" Journal of Regional Science 43,
no. 1: 139-65.
Glaeser Edward L., and Kristina Tobio. 2008. "The Rise of the
Sunbelt." Southern Economic Journal 74, no. 3: 610-43.
Glaeser Edward L., and Bryce A. Ward. Forthcoming. "The Causes
and Consequences of Land Use Regulation: Evidence from Greater
Boston." Journal of Urban Economics.
Green, Richard K. 2007. "Airports and Economic
Development." Real Estate Economics 35, no. 1:91-112.
Gyourko, Joseph E., Albert Saiz, and Anita A. Summers. 2007.
"A New Measure of the Local Regulatory Environment for Housing
Markets: The Wharton Residential Land Use Regulatory Index."
Wharton Real Estate Center Working Paper 558. University of
Pennsylvania.
Gyourko, Joseph, and Joseph Tracy. 1989. "The Importance of
Local Fiscal Conditions in Analyzing Local Labor Markets." Journal
of Political Economy 97, no. 5: 1208-31.
Haines, Michael R., and Robert A. Margo. 2006. "Railroads and
Local Economic Development: The United States in the 1850s."
Working Paper W12381. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Isserman, Andrew, and Terance Rephann. 1995. "The
Economic-Effects of the Appalachian-Regional-Commission--An
Empirical-Assessment of 26 Years of Regional-Development Planning."
Journal of the American Planning Association 61, no. 3: 345-64.
Kahn, Matthew E. 2003. "The Geography of US Pollution
Intensive Trade: Evidence from 1958 to 1994." Regional Science and
Urban Economics 33, no. 4: 383-400.
Katz, Lawrence, and Kenneth T. Rosen. 1987. "The
Interjurisdictional Effects of Growth Controls on Housing Prices."
Journal of Law and Economics 30, no. 1: 149-60.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1988. "On the Mechanics of
Economic-Development." Journal of Monetary Economics 22, no. 1:
3-42.
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.
Moretti, Enrico. 2004. "Estimating the Social Return to Higher
Education: Evidence from Longitudinal and Repeated Cross-Sectional
Data." Journal of Econometrics 121, no. 1-2: 175-212.
Papke, Leslie E. 1994. "Tax Policy and
Urban-Development-Evidence from the Indiana Enterprise Zone
Program." Journal of Public Economics 54, no. 1: 37-49.
Rauch, James E. 1993. "Productivity Gains from Geographic
Concentration of Human Capital: Evidence from the Cities." Journal
of Urban Economics 34, no. 3: 380-400.
Rappaport, Jordan, and Jeffrey D. Sachs. 2003. "The United
States as a Coastal Nation." Journal of Economic Growth 8, no. 1:
5-46.
Roback, Jennifer. 1982. "Wages, Rents, and the Quality of
Life." Journal of Political Economy 90, no. 6: 1257-78.
Romer, Paul M. 1986. "Increasing Returns and Long Run
Growth." Journal of Political Economy 94, no. 5: 1002-37.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1979. "Wage-Based Indexes of Urban Quality of
Life." In Current Issues in Urban Economics, edited by Peter
Mieszkowski and Mahlon Straszheim. Johns Hopkins University Press.
Schwartz, Amy E., Ingrid G. Ellen, Ioan Voicu, and Michael H.
Schill. 2005. "The External Effects of Place-Based Subsidized
Housing." NYU Law and Economics Research Paper 05-05. New York
University.
Schwarz, John E., and Thomas J. Volgy. 1988. "Experiments in
Employment-A British Cure." Harvard Business Review (March/April):
104-12.
Shapiro, Jesse M. 2006. "Smart Cities: Quality of Life,
Productivity, and the Growth Effects of Human Capital." Review of
Economics and Statistics 88, no. 2: 324-35.
Simon, Curtis J., and Clark Nardinelli. 1996. "The Talk of the
Town: Human Capital, Information, and the Growth of English Cities, 1861
to 1961." Explorations in Economic History 33, no. 3: 384-413.
Staples, John H. 1970. "Urban Renewal--Comparative Study of
Twenty-Two Cities, 1950-1960." Western Political Quarterly 23, no.
2: 294-304.
Tym, Roger. 1984. "Finance and Affordability." In
Low-Income Housing in the Developing World: The Role of Sites and
Services and Settlements Upgrading, edited by Geoffrey K. Payne. Wiley.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2004. Federal Aid to States for Fiscal Year
2003. Washington.
Von Hoffman, Alexander. 2000. "A Study in Contradictions: The
Origins and Legacy of the Housing Act of 1949." Housing Policy
Debate 11, no. 2: 299-326.
Warner, John C. 1978. "Unfulfilled Long-Term Interest-Rate
Expectations and Changes in Business Fixed Investment." American
Economic Review 68, no. 3: 339-47.
EDWARD L. GLAESER
Harvard University
JOSHUA D. GOTTLIEB
Harvard University
(1.) Haines and Margo (2006); Duranton and Turner (2007).
(2.) Busso and Kline (2008).
(3.) Alonso (1964); Rosen (1979); Roback (1982).
(4.) Some places, such as Sioux Falls, South Dakota, and Charlotte,
North Carolina, have GMP per capita far above their income per capita,
presumably reflecting relatively high levels of physical capital.
(5.) This exercise was done using 2000 Census microdata. Our
individual-level controls are age, race, educational attainment, and
speaking a language other than English at home.
(6.) The NAR figures for inexpensive areas are considerably higher,
since those data only look at recent home sales, which skew the sample
toward newer, higher-quality homes. Using NAR data, it is the Rustbelt,
not Texas, that has the cheapest homes: Decatur, Illinois, Saginaw,
Michigan, and Youngstown, Ohio, are the three cheapest metropolitan
areas according to the NAR, with median sales prices below $90,000.
(7.) Glaeser and Gottlieb (2008).
(8.) Including Roback (1982), Gyourko and Tracy (1989), and Black
(1999),
(9.) Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991).
(10.) Glaeser and Gottlieb (2008).
(11.) All of our metropolitan areas have at least 60 respondents to
the happiness question over the period, and 95 percent have at least
100.
(12.) Blanchard and Katz (1992).
(13.) Bewley (1981).
(14.) For simplicity we assume that this is true for the rentier class as well.
(15.) The decentralized equilibrium is, however, not a Pareto
optimum. There would still be gains from redistributing income across
space, holding populations constant.
(16.) George (1879).
(17.) See, for example, Brueckner (1983).
(18.) This is a spatial version of the Bergstrom (1986) problem,
where wages for the volunteer army equate total utility levels but not
marginal utility levels. Glaeser (1998) examines this issue in the
context of indexing transfers for local price levels.
(19.) This failure of the decentralized equilibrium is not an
artifact of assuming a utilitarian social welfare planner. The
decentralized equilibrium will not generally maximize any weighted
average of individual utility levels. If the planner puts a larger
weight on people in areas where the marginal utility of income is high,
then the spatial equilibrium will generically be suboptimal, because the
utility of those people is the same as the utility of people in areas
where the marginal utility of income is low.
(20.) This argument for redistribution appears in many situations
where the market equilibrium equates total utilities, rather than the
marginal utility of income; the same argument can be used to justify
transfers to high-amenity occupations that pay lower wages, at least if
those amenities are not a complement to earnings. However, as Oliver
Hart emphasized in his comment on Bergstrom (1986), this problem can be
solved privately with cash lotteries that occur before choosing
occupations or locations.
(21.) Ellison and Glaeser (1999).
(22.) Ellison and Glaeser (1999).
(23.) Ciccone and Hall (1996).
(24.) Glaeser and Mare (2001).
(25.) Combes, Duranton, and Gobillon (2008).
(26.) Ciccone and Hall (1996).
(27.) Glaeser and Tobio (2008).
(28.) The index was developed by Gyourko, Saiz, and Summers (2007)
based on a survey of local zoning authorities nationwide.
(29.) Glaeser and Kahn (2004).
(30.) Glaeser and Kahn (2004).
(31.) Kahn (2003).
(32.) Glaeser and Sacerdote (1999).
(33.) Glaeser and Gottlieb (2006).
(34.) Achenbach (2004).
(35.) Bernstein (2005).
(36.) Glaeser (2005). An easier case can be made that
Chicago's success depended on artificial waterways. Its growth was
set off by a boom anticipating the completion of the Illinois and
Michigan Canal, which connected the Great Lakes to the Mississippi. With
that canal, the city of Chicago became the linchpin of a system of
waterborne transportation that stretched from New York to New Orleans.
(37.) Haines and Margo (2006).
(38.) Craig, Palmquist, and Weiss (1998). The data were kindly
provided by Robert Margo.
(39.) Glaeser and Saks (2006).
(40.) Warner (1978).
(41.) Baum-Snow (2007).
(42.) Duranton and Turner (2007).
(43.) Glaeser and Kohlhase (2004).
(44.) Glaeser and Ponzetto (2007).
(45.) Green (2007).
(46.) Glaeser, Saiz, and Kolko (2001).
(47.) Glaeser and Shapiro (2003).
(48.) The full environmental calculus is quite complex and involves
the trade-off between more air pollution in densely settled areas and
less pollution per square mile over a larger area.
(49.) Caudill (1963).
(50.) Isserman and Rephann (1995).
(51.) Isserman and Rephann (1995).
(52.) Papke (1994)
(53.) Tym (1984).
(54.) Schwarz and Volgy (1988)
(55.) Erickson and Syms (1986).
(56.) Papke (1994).
(57.) Busso and Kline (2008).
(58.) Von Hoffman (2000).
(59.) Von Hoffman (2000).
(60.) Schwartz and others (2005).
(61.) Glaeser, Gyourko, and Saks (2005).
(62.) Glaeser and Gyourko (2005).
(63.) Staples (1970).
(64.) Gilbert and Specht (1974, p. 565).
(65.) Glaeser and Ward (forthcoming); Glaeser, Gyourko, and Saks
(2005).
(66.) Glaeser and Ward (forthcoming).
(67.) Glaeser and Ward (forthcoming).
(68.) Katz and Rosen (1987).
(69.) Brueckner (1983).
(70.) Why do communities fail to maximize land value? The Coase
theorem, after all, suggests that side deals between property owners
should lead to maximizing joint wealth. One answer is that property
rights are murky and that the democratic process is not geared toward
such side payments. In many cases the right of an owner to build is the
outcome of a complicated regulatory process that cannot be predicted in
advance. In other cases explicit legal impediments prevent such side
deals. Since each new development creates a windfall for one owner and a
host of inconveniences for everyone else, one can understand why
democratic decisionmaking would lead to many restrictions on building.
(71.) Glaeser and Kahn (2008).
(72.) Glaeser (2008) provides a more detailed plan of this kind.
(73.) Lawrence Summers emphasized this point to us.
(74.) Marshall (1890, Book 2, ch. 10).
(75.) Lucas (1988); Romer (1986).
(76.) Rauch (1993).
(77.) Glaeser and others (1992).
(78.) Shapiro (2006).
(79.) Berry and Glaeser (2005).
(80.) Glaeser and Kahn (2004).
(81.) Following Rauch (1993).
(82.) As in Moretti (2004).
(83.) Simon and Nardinelli (1996).
(84.) Glaeser and Saiz (2004); Shapiro (2006).
(85.) Berry and Glaeser (2005).
(86.) Acemoglu and Angrist (2001).
(87.) Moretti (2004).
(88.) We also examined the share of the industry's goods that
are exported and the average wage residual in the industry. Both of
these variables were suggested by Lawrence Summers. We do not find a
significant tendency of wages to be higher in areas surrounded by such
industries, nor do we find any significant nonlinearities in the impact
of these variables on wages or population growth.
(89.) Glaeser and others (1992).
Table 1. U.S. Metropolitan Statistical Areas Ranked on Selected
Indicators (a)
Indicator Top, five MSAs Average value
Gross metropolitan Bridgeport, CT $74,285
product per Charlotte, NC $68,406
capita, 2004 San Jose, CA $68,311
Washington, DC $62,251
Sioux Falls, SD $59,003
Median family San Jose, CA $81,053
income, 2000 Bethesda, MD $81,000
Bridgeport, CT $77,690
Nassau-Suffolk, NY $76,595
San Francisco, CA $75,416
Share of adult Boulder, CO 52.4%
population with Bethesda, MD 50.2%
a college degree, Ann Arbor, MI 48.1%
2000 (b) San Francisco, CA 43.6%
Cambridge, MA 43.6%
Median house San Jose, CA $441,900
price, 2000 San Francisco, CA $440,500
Santa Cruz, CA $377,500
New York, NY $362,500
Honolulu, HI $309,000
Indicator Bottom five MSAs Average value
Gross metropolitan Brownsville, TX $16,025
product per McAllen, TX $16,149
capita, 2004 Lake Havasu City, AZ $17,126
Cumberland, MD $18,302
Prescott, AZ $18,482
Median family McAllen, TX $26,009
income, 2000 Brownsville, TX $27,853
Laredo, TX $29,394
El Paso, TX $33,410
Las Cruces, NM $33,576
Share of adult Dalton, GA 9.0%
population with Lake Havasu City, AZ 9.9%
a college degree, El Centro, CA 10.3%
2000 (b) Hanford, CA 10.4%
Merced, CA 11.0%
Median house Odessa, TX $47,700
price, 2000 McAllen, TX $52,400
Brownsville, TX $53,000
Danville, IL $56,000
Pine Bluff, AR $56,200
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; U.S. Census Bureau.
(a.) Units of observation are metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs)
under the 2006 definitions, using metropolitan divisions where
applicable. All dollars are current (2000 or 2004) dollars.
(b.) Among MSAs with at least 100,000 population.
Table 2. Regressions of Wages on Metropolitan-Area Population
and Density (a)
Regression
Independent variable 2-1 2-2 2-3
Log of population in 2000 0.041 0.023
(0.009) (0.010)
Log of population in 2000, 0.076
below-median subsample (0.029)
Log of population in 2000, 0.038
above-median subsample (0.012)
Log of population density, 0.029
2000 (0.015)
Log of density in 2000,
below-median subsample
Log of density in 2000,
above-median subsample
No. of observations 1,591,140 1,591,140 1,591,140
No. of MSAs 283 283 283
[R.sup.2] 0.22 0.22 0.22
Regression
Independent variable 2-4 2-5 (b)
Log of population in 2000 0.089
(0.037)
Log of population in 2000, 0.057
below-median subsample (0.029)
Log of population in 2000, 0.020
above-median subsample (0.013)
Log of population density,
2000
Log of density in 2000, 0.041
below-median subsample (0.017)
Log of density in 2000, 0.027
above-median subsample (0.020)
No. of observations 1,591,140 1,282,116
No. of MSAs 283 210
[R.sup.2] 0.22
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) The dependent variable is the logarithm of the individual
wage. The regression method is ordinary least squares except where
noted otherwise. Only fully employed men aged 25 to 55 are included
in the sample. All regressions include individual controls for age
and education. Individual-level wage data are from the U.S. Census
Public Use Microdata Sample, as described in appendix B.
Metropolitan-area covariates are from the U.S. Census Bureau as
described in appendix A. Units of observation are metropolitan
statistical areas (MSAs) presented under the 1999 definitions,
using primary rather than consolidated MSAs where applicable and
New England county metropolitan areas where applicable. Standard
errors (in parentheses) are clustered by MSA.
(b.) Instrumental variables regression using the logarithm of
population in 1850 to instrument for log of population in 2000.
Table 3. Instrumental Variables Regressions Testing for Agglomeration
Effects (a)
Regression
Independent variable 3-1 (b) 3-2 3-3
Population growth in 1990s x 0.200 0.004 0.166
year 2000 dummy (0.044) (0.098) (0.088)
Above-median population dummy x 0.006
year 2000 dummy (0.017)
Population growth in 1990s x -0.165
above-median population (0.133)
dummy x year 2000 dummy
Above-median centralization
dummy x year 2000 dummy
Population growth in 1990s x
above-median centralization
dummy x year 2000 dummy
Dummy for bottom quartile of
MSA population growth, 1970-90
x year 2000 dummy
Log of population in 2000 x
dummy for bottom quartile of MSA
population growth, 1970-90 x
year 2000 dummy
No. of observations 2,950,850 2,950,850 2,950,850
No. of MSAs 287 287 287
Regression
Independent variable 3-4 3-5
Population growth in 1990s x -0.020 -0.099
year 2000 dummy (0.121) (0.141)
Above-median population dummy x
year 2000 dummy
Population growth in 1990s x
above-median population
dummy x year 2000 dummy
Above-median centralization -0.038
dummy x year 2000 dummy (0.022)
Population growth in 1990s x 0.216
above-median centralization
dummy x year 2000 dummy (0.163)
Dummy for bottom quartile of -0.057
MSA population growth, 1970-90 (0.026)
x year 2000 dummy
Log of population in 2000 x 0.398
dummy for bottom quartile of MSA
population growth, 1970-90 x (0.252)
year 2000 dummy
No. of observations 2,490,733 2,950,850
No. of MSAs 229 287
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) The dependent variable is the logarithm of the individual wage
for employed men aged 25 to 55. Regressions are instrumental
variables regressions except where noted otherwise. Instruments are
mean January temperature, mean July temperature, and precipitation,
from the 1994 City and County Data Book. Individual data are from
the 1990 and 2000 Census Public Use Microdata Sample, as described
in appendix B. Population data are from the Census. Units of
observation are metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) under the
1999 definitions, using primary rather than consolidated MSAs where
applicable and New England county metropolitan areas where
applicable. All regressions include individual controls for sex,
age, and education and MSA and year fixed effects. Standard errors
(in parentheses) are clustered by MSA.
(b.) Regression is by the ordinary least squares method.
(c.) Centralization is defined as the fraction of MSA employment
located within five miles of the central business district, from
Glaeser and Kahn (2004).
Table 4. Regressions of Urban Disamenity Measures on Metropolitan-Area
Population and Centralization Measures (a)
Dependent variable
Log of concentration
Log of average of TSP-10
communte (minutes) particulates (b)
Independent variable 4-1 4-2 4-3 4-4
Log of population in 2000 0.12 0.057 0.142 0.145
(0.012) (0.016) (0.056) (0.079)
Log of population x -0.003 0.001
population above (0.002) (0.012)
median in 2000
Centralization (d) -0.874 2.065
(0.420) (2.134)
Log of population in 0.052 -0.222
2000 x centralization (0.033) (0.156)
Constant 1.65 2.531 1.945 2.284
(0.137) (0.210) (0.657) (1.134)
No. of observations 318 248 40 37
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.48 0.56 0.36 0.52
Dependent variable
Log of murder rate Log of real wage (c)
Independent variable 4-5 4-6 4-7 4-8
Log of population in 2000 0.222 0.485 0.028 0.037
(0.146) (0.234) (0.015) (0.024)
Log of population x 0.004 0.000
population above (0.018) (0.003)
median in 2000
Centralization (d) 4.305 0.974
(5.476) (0.611)
Log of population in -0.309 -0.089
2000 x centralization (0.442) (0.048)
Constant -1.371 -4.947 8.363 8.336
(1.733) (3.025) (0.184) (0.330)
No. of observations 153 126 220 186
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.07 0.09 0.05 0.06
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) Population, income, and commute time data are from the U.S.
Census Bureau, as described in appendix B. Murder rate is from the
Federal Bureau of Investigation Uniform Crime Reports, and TSP-10
data are from the Environmental Protection Agency. Units of
observation are metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) under the
1999 definitions, using primary rather than consolidated MSAs
where applicable and New England county metropolitan areas where
applicable. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.
(b.) Total suspended particulates of less than 10 microns diameter,
a standard measure of atmospheric pollution.
(c.) Computed by adjusting the average nominal wage for the cost of
living index from the American Chamber of Commerce Research
Association.
(d.) Percent of employment within 5 miles of the central business
district, from Glaeser and Kahn (2004).
Table 5. Historical Regressions of Population and Income Growth
on Metropolitan-Area Transportation Measures and Controls (a)
Dependent variable
Population Population
growth, growth,
1850-60 1850-1900
Independent variable 5-1 5-2
Log of initial population -0.335 -0.629
(0.011) (0.017)
Distance in miles to ocean or 0.04 0.037
Gulf of Mexico (0.003) (0.005)
Dummy for county accessible by 0.144 0.203
rail in 1850 (0.023) (0.036)
Congregationalists per capita 0.925 0.96
in 1850 (0.181) (0.286)
Log of new miles of highway,
1960-90
Dummy for top-50 airport
Percent of population with
college degree in 1990
Constant 3.154 6.431
(0.100) (0.158)
Unit of observation Counties Counties
No. of observations 1,517 1,517
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.53 0.57
Dependent variable
Population Income per
growth, capita growth,
1960-90 1960-90
Independent variable 5-3 5-4
Log of initial population -0.101 -0.038
(0.023) (0.010)
Distance in miles to ocean or -0.021 -0.013
Gulf of Mexico (0.004) (0.002)
Dummy for county accessible by
rail in 1850
Congregationalists per capita
in 1850
Log of new miles of highway, 0.111 0.039
1960-90 (0.026) (0.009)
Dummy for top-50 airport
Percent of population with
college degree in 1990
Constant 1.309 2.412
(0.245) (0.109)
Unit of observation MSAS MSAS
No. of observations 20-5 205
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.15 0.22
Dependent variable
Population Income per
growth, capita growth,
1990-2000 1990-2000
Independent variable 5-5 5-6
Log of initial population -0.007 -0.02
(0.007) (0.004)
Distance in miles to ocean or
Gulf of Mexico
Dummy for county accessible by
rail in 1850
Congregationalists per capita
in 1850
Log of new miles of highway,
1960-90
Dummy for top-50 airport 0.046 0.025
(0.021) (0.011)
Percent of population with 0.337 0.097
college degree in 1990 (0.088) (0.047)
Constant 0.136 0.65
(0.086) (0.046)
Unit of observation MSAS MSAs
No. of observations 318 318
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.07 0.1
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) Metropolitan statistical areas (MSAS) are under the 1999
definitions, using primary rather than consolidated MSAS where
applicable and New England county metropolitan areas where
applicable. Population, income, and Congregationalists data are
from the U.S. Census Bureau, as described in appendix B. Data on
proximity to rail transportation are from Craig, Palmquist, and
Weiss (1998). Distance to ocean or Gulf is from Rappaport and Sachs
(2003) and is the distance from the closest county in the MSA.
Highway data are from Baum-Snow (2007). Airport data are from
Bureau of Transportation Statistics (1996). Standard errors are in
parentheses.
Table 6. Correlations of Federal Transportation Spending with
State Size (d)
Correlation Correlation
Correlation with log of with log of
with log of population income
Spending measure population density per capita
Log of highway spending -0.54 -0.32 -0.18
per capita, including
trust fund (b)
Log of highway spending -0.48 -0.49 -0.39
per capita, excluding
trust fund
Log of air travel spending -0.34 -0.79 -0.45
per capita
Log of railroad spending -0.50 -0.18 -0.14
per capita
Log of public transit 0.11 0.46 0.53
spending per capita
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) Each cell reports the correlation coefficient between the
indicated transportation spending measure and the indicated state
characteristic. Transportation spending data are from U.S. Census
Bureau (2004). Population data are from the U.S. Census Bureau as
described in appendix B. Land area is from Rappaport and Sachs
(2003).
(b.) Includes contributions by the states to the national
transportation trust fund.
Table 7. Regressions Estimating Impact of the Appalachian Regional
Commission (a)
Dependent variable
Growth in income
Population growth per capita
Independent variable 1970-80 1970-2000 1970-80 1970-2000
Dummy for county in ARC 0.037 -0.002 0.004 -0.029
coverage area (0.008) (0.020) (0.005) (0.008)
Log of initial population -0.018 -0.036
(0.004) (0.010)
Log of initial income -0.323 -0.406
per capita (0.011) (0.016)
Constant 0.299 0.637 3.418 5.172
(0.038) (0.099) (0.082) (0.123)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.051 0.015 0.512 0.420
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) Units of observation (N = 898) are counties. Income and
population data are from the U.S. Census Bureau, as described in
appendix B. Standard errors are in parentheses.
Table 8. Regressions Estimating Impact of Urban Renewal (a)
Dependent variable
Growth from 1960 to 1970
In income
Independent variable In population per capita
Urban renewal spending 0.0022 0.0004
per capita (dollars) (0.0014) (0.0006)
Dummy for Model Cities
participant
Log of initial population -0.027
(0.051)
Log of initial income -0.459
per capita (0.152)
Constant 0.054 5.92
(0.768) (1.17)
No. of observations 21 21
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.20 0.45
Dependent variable
Growth from 1970 to 2000
In income
Independent variable In population per capita
Urban renewal spending
per capita (dollars)
Dummy for Model Cities -0.051 0.023
participant (0.063) (0.016)
Log of initial population -0.053
(0.021)
Log of initial income -0.177
per capita (0.035)
Constant 1.06 3.34
(0.26) (0.28)
No. of observations 318 318
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.04 0.07
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) Units of observation are metropolitan statistical areas under
the 1999 definitions (primary rather than consolidated MSAs where
applicable, New England county metropolitan areas where
applicable). Income and population data are from the U.S. Census
Bureau, as described in appendix B. Urban renewal spending per
capita is from Staples (1970).
Table 9. Regressions of Wages on Metropolitan-Area Human Capital
and Industrial Structure (a)
Regression
Independent variable 9-1 9-2
Percent of population with 0.814
college degree (0.024)
Percent with college degree, 0.638
below-median subsample (0.072)
Percent with college degree, 0.862
above-median subsample (0.031)
Percent employment in top quartile
of human capital
Percent employment in top quartile,
below-median subsample
Percent employment in top quartile,
above-median subsample
Herfindahl index for MSA
Herfindahl index for MSA and sector
No. of observations 3,789,707 3,789,707
No. of MSAs 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.31 0.31
Regression
Independent variable 9-3 9-4
Percent of population with
college degree
Percent with college degree,
below-median subsample
Percent with college degree,
above-median subsample
Percent employment in top quartile 0.671
of human capital (0.027)
Percent employment in top quartile, 0.035
below-median subsample (0.070)
Percent employment in top quartile, 0.946
above-median subsample (0.034)
Herfindahl index for MSA
Herfindahl index for MSA and sector
No. of observations 3,789,707 3,789,707
No. of MSAs 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.31 0.31
Regression
Independent variable 9-5 9-6 (b)
Percent of population with 0.792
college degree (0.024)
Percent with college degree,
below-median subsample
Percent with college degree,
above-median subsample
Percent employment in top quartile
of human capital
Percent employment in top quartile,
below-median subsample
Percent employment in top quartile,
above-median subsample
Herfindahl index for MSA -1.011
(0.243)
Herfindahl index for MSA and sector -0.087
(0.001)
No. of observations 3,789,707 3,789,707
No. of MSAs 285 285
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.31 0.32
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) The dependent variable is the logarithm of the individual
wage; the sample includes fully employed men aged 25 to 55 only.
Individual-level data are from the 1990 and 2000 Census Public Use
Microdata Sample, as described in appendix B. All regressions
include individual controls for sex, age, and education and
industry fixed effects (but not MSA fixed effects except where
noted otherwise). Data on industry concentration and human capital
by industry are calculated from the microdata. Metropolitan-area
education data are from the U.S. Census Bureau as described in
appendix B. City characteristics are at the level of MSAs under the
1999 definitions, using primary rather than consolidated MSAs where
applicable and New England county metropolitan areas where
applicable. Standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered by MSA
and industry.
(b.) Regression includes MSA fixed effects.