The economics of place-making policies.
Glaeser, Edward L. ; Gottlieb. Joshua D.
ABSTRACT Should the national government undertake policies aimed at
strengthening the economies of particular localities or regions?
Agglomeration economies and human capital spillovers suggest that such
policies could enhance welfare. However, the mere existence of
agglomeration externalities does not indicate which places should be
subsidized. Without a better understanding of nonlinearities in these
externalities, any government spatial policy is as likely to reduce as
to increase welfare. Transportation spending has historically done much
to make or break particular places, but current transportation spending
subsidizes low-income, low-density places where agglomeration effects
are likely to be weakest. Most large-scale place-oriented policies have
had little discernable impact. Some targeted policies such as
Empowerment Zones seem to have an effect but are expensive relative to
their achievements. The greatest promise for a national place-based
policy lies in impeding the tendency of highly productive areas to
restrict their own growth through restrictions on land use.
**********
Three empirical regularities are at the heart of urban economics.
First, output appears to be subject to agglomeration economies, whereby
people become more productive when they work in densely populated areas
surrounded by other people. Second, there appear to be human capital
spillovers, whereby concentrations of educated people increase both the
level and the growth rate of productivity. Finally, the urban system
appears to be roughly described by a spatial equilibrium, where high
wages are offset by high prices, and high real wages by negative
amenities. Do these three regularities provide insights for
policymakers, at either the local or the national level?
The concept of spatial equilibrium, presented in the first section
of this paper, generally throws cold water on interventions that direct
resources toward particular geographic areas. If high prices and low
amenities offset high wages in a spatial equilibrium, there is nothing
particularly equitable about taking money from rich places and giving it
to poor places. Subsidies to poor places will be offset by higher
prices, and the primary real effect will be to move people into
economically unproductive areas. The spatial equilibrium concept thus
suggests that the case for national policy that favors specific places
must depend more on efficiency--internalizing externalities--than on
equity.
The second section of the paper formalizes this theory and
discusses its implications for optimal spatial policy. The model allows
for agglomeration economies, which imply that productivity rises with
the population or the population density of an area. Two types of
evidence support the existence of those externalities: the concentration
of economic activity in dense clusters and the robust connection between
density and productivity. In principle, omitted exogenous differences in
local productivity could explain both facts, but there is little
evidence that any such differences are large.
At the local policy level, agglomeration economies provide a
further justification for local leaders to seek to maximize population
growth. At the national policy level, the existence of agglomeration
economies and congestion disamenities makes it unlikely that a centrally
unencumbered spatial equilibrium will be socially optimal. However, the
mere existence of agglomeration economies does not tell us which areas
should be subsidized. The spatial equilibrium model suggests that
resources should be pushed to areas that are more productive and where
the elasticity of productivity with respect to agglomeration is higher.
Empirically, however, economists have little idea where that is the
case. Given the difficulty even of identifying the magnitude of
agglomeration economies, it should not be surprising that we cannot
convincingly estimate nonlinearities in those economies.
The spatial equilibrium model suggests that agglomeration economies
are best identified through shocks to amenities or housing supply. For
that reason, in the paper's third section we use the connection
between climate and population growth to estimate the impact of
population on productivity. We find little evidence to suggest that
agglomeration economies are larger for smaller than for bigger cities,
or for more compact than for less compact cities. We also find little
evidence that the negative impact of population due to urban
disamenities differs across types of cities. If anything, there seems to
be a more positive link between population and amenities in more compact
urban areas.
The fourth section discusses the historical record of place-making
policies in the United States. From the Erie Canal to the Interstate
Highway System, government-sponsored transportation infrastructure has
long influenced the growth of particular places. We review the evidence
showing a strong connection between access to railroads and growth in
the nineteenth century, and between highways and urban growth in the
twentieth century. (1) We argue that the place-making effects of
transportation infrastructure do not imply that one should judge
transportation spending on the basis of its ability to change the
distribution of population across space. Since we lack confidence about
which places should be subsidized, a simple model suggests that social
welfare is maximized by choosing transport spending to maximize its
direct benefits, not according to its ability to enhance one place or
another. Current federal subsidies to transportation favor low-income,
low-density states, which are unlikely to have particularly large
agglomeration effects.
The Appalachian Regional Commission (ARC), created in the 1960s, is
the largest example, in terms of total spending, of unambiguous American
regional policy. Using transportation subsidies and other forms of
spending, the U.S. government has tried to boost the fortunes of
Appalachia. There is little robust evidence suggesting that this
spending has been effective. Given that the program involved a modest
amount of money spread over a vast geographic area, this is
unsurprising. No regional policies that direct relatively small amounts
of money at big places can be properly judged, since too many other
forces influence these areas' outcomes.
The ability to measure impact is one of the appeals of highly
targeted interventions, such as the Empowerment Zones established in the
1990s, that direct significant resources at small areas. Matias Busso
and Patrick Kline find that Empowerment Zones did boost local
employment, but at a high cost: the program spent more than $100,000 for
each new job that can be attributed to an Empowerment Zone. (2)
Moreover, just as the spatial equilibrium model suggests, housing prices
rose in these zones, possibly more than offsetting any benefits to
renters who were employed there before the policy.
The paper's fifth section turns to the national housing
policies, such as urban renewal, that were seen as a tool for urban
revitalization in the middle decades of the twentieth century. One
rationale for these policies is that dilapidated housing creates
negative externalities. The case against them is that declining areas
already have an abundance of housing supply relative to demand, so that
it makes little sense to build more housing. Empirically, we find little
evidence that either urban renewal or the subsequent Model Cities
Program had any discernable effects on urban prosperity.
Indeed, it might make more sense to focus on building in areas that
are more, rather than less, productive. Given the huge wage gaps that
exist across space, it may be better strategy to enable more people to
move from Brownsville to Bridgeport than to try to turn Brownsville into
a thriving, finance-based community. If the most productive areas of the
country have restricted construction through extensive land use
controls, and these controls are not justified on the basis of other
externalities, then it may be welfare enhancing for the federal
government to adopt policies that could reduce the barriers to building
in these areas.
The sixth section of the paper turns to human capital spillovers,
which occur when productivity is a function of other area
residents' skills in the area. The existence of human capital
spillovers suggests that local leaders trying to improve area incomes or
increase area population should focus on policies that attract or train
more skilled residents. Like agglomeration economies, human capital
spillovers mean that a decentralized equilibrium is unlikely to be
optimal. For example, some education subsidies are likely to enhance
welfare. Determining the correct national policy toward places, however,
requires not only identifying the average effect of human capital
externalities or industrial spillovers, but also knowing where these
effects are larger.
There is little clear evidence that human capital spillovers or
industrial spillovers differ between smaller or larger, or more or less
dense, cities. If anything, the impact of skilled workers and industries
seems to be convex, suggesting possible returns from pushing skilled
workers into already skilled areas. Of course, any tendency to
artificially subsidize those areas with high human capital would seem
inequitable. The recent tendency of skilled people to move to places
where skills are already abundant seems to be progressing without
government aid. If anything, these results bolster the case for working
against land use restrictions that stymie growth in areas with high
human capital.
The Spatial Equilibrium
The economic approach to urban policy begins with a model that has
three equilibrium conditions. The urban model makes the standard
assumption that firms are maximizing profits and hence hiring workers to
the point where wages equal the marginal product of labor. The model
also assumes that the construction sector is in equilibrium, which means
that housing prices equal the cost of producing a house, including land
and legal costs. Finally, and most important, the model assumes that
migration is cheap enough to make consumers indifferent between
locations. High wages in an area are offset by high prices; low real
wages are offset by high amenities. For more than forty years this
spatial equilibrium assumption has helped economists make sense of
housing prices within cities and the distribution of prices and wages
across cities. (3)
The assumption of low-cost migration between places implies only
that expected lifetime utility levels should be constant across space.
In practice, economists typically assume that enough migration occurs at
every point in time to ensure that period-by-period utility flows are
also constant across space. This assumption is standard, if extreme, and
we will use it here. The indirect utility function for an individual in
location i can be written as V [[W.sub.i], [P.sub.i.sup.j],
[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])], where [W.sub.i] refers to labor income in
area i, [P.sub.i.sup.j] is a vector of prices of city-specific nontraded
goods (especially housing), and [[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i]) describes the
quality of life in the area, which may be decreasing in population, N,
because of congestion externalities. Traded goods prices and unearned
income may also enter into welfare, but since these are constant over
space, we suppress them. A variable [X.sub.i] that influences wages must
have an offsetting impact on either prices or amenities that satisfies
d[W.sub.i]/d[X.sub.i] + [summation over (j)] ([V.sub.P]/[V.sub.W]
d[P.sub.i.sup.j]/d[X.sub.i]) + [V.sub.[theta]]/[V.sub.W]
d[[theta].sub.i]/d[X.sub.i] = 0. If amenities are fixed, if the only
nontraded good is housing, and if everyone consumes exactly one unit of
housing, then d[W.sub.i]/d[X.sub.i] = d[P.sub.i.sup.j]/d[X.sub.i]. Any
wage increase is exactly offset by a price increase.
The spatial equilibrium assumption has significant implications for
urban policy. If individuals are more or less indifferent to location,
then there is no natural redistributive reason to channel government
support to poor places. The logic of the spatial equilibrium insists
that the residents of those places are not particularly distressed, at
least holding human capital constant, because low housing prices have
already compensated them for low incomes. Moreover, the
equilibrium's logic also suggests that governmental attempts to
improve incomes in poor places will themselves create an equal and
offsetting impact on housing prices. If the spatial equilibrium
assumption holds, then property owners, not the truly disadvantaged,
will be the main beneficiaries of aid to poor places.
How strong is the evidence supporting the spatial equilibrium
assumption? The striking disparities in income and productivity across
American regions might seem to be prima facie evidence against it. Table
1 presents some figures for the U.S. metropolitan areas with the highest
and lowest values of several relevant characteristics. The top panel
lists the top and bottom five metropolitan areas ranked by gross
metropolitan product (GMP) per capita. These figures are produced by the
Bureau of Economic Analysis; they are meant to be comparable to gross
national product in that they attempt to measure an area's entire
output. (The figures are based on the output of the people who work in
the area, not of the people who live there.) By this measure Bridgeport,
Connecticut (which includes Greenwich), Charlotte, North Carolina, and
San Jose, California, are the most productive places in the United
States, with GMP per capita in the range of $60,000 to $75,000 in 2005.
The five least productive places all have GMP figures less than
one-third of the low end of that range: GMP per capita in Brownsville,
Texas, America's least productive metropolitan area, was about
$16,000 in 2005. The relationship between income per capita and GMP,
shown in figure 1, is very tight, with a correlation coefficient of 75
percent. (4)
The next panel of table 1 shows the disparity in family income
between the five richest and the five poorest metropolitan areas. The
five poorest areas have median family incomes less than half those in
the five richest.
For these remarkable income differences to be compatible with the
spatial equilibrium model, high prices or low amenities must offset
higher incomes in the richest areas. The strongest piece of evidence
supporting this view is that there are no legal or technological
barriers preventing any American from moving from one metropolitan area
to another, and indeed mobility across areas is enormous. Forty-six
percent of Americans changed their place of residence between 1995 and
2000, half of them to a different metropolitan area. Critics of the
spatial equilibrium assumption can argue, however, that moving
costs--both financial and psychological--are often quite high. The
existence of these costs leads us to examine other evidence on the
existence of a spatial equilibrium.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
One reason spatial income differences may not reflect differences
in welfare for similarly skilled people is that people in different
places do not have similar human capital endowments. The third panel of
table 1 shows the differences across metropolitan areas in the share of
the adult population with a college degree. Bethesda, Maryland, is one
of the richest urban areas in the country, and more than half of its
adults have college degrees. By contrast, fewer than one in ten adults
in the least educated metropolitan areas have college degrees. The
poorest metropolitan areas also have more non-native English speakers
and more residents who speak English poorly or not at all. For example,
more than three-quarters of the residents of McAllen, Texas, speak a
language other than English at home.
One simple exercise is to compare the standard deviation of wages
across metropolitan areas before and after controlling for observable
individual-level human capital variables, such as years of schooling.
The standard deviation of mean wages across metropolitan areas drops by
26 percent when we control for individual characteristics, suggesting
that differences in human capital account for about half of the variance
in metropolitan-area wage levels. (5) There are also important
differences in unobserved human capital, which may themselves be a
product of the differing experiences and role models across particular
locales.
Even after accounting for differences in human capital, however,
large differences in earnings remain across metropolitan areas. For the
spatial equilibrium model to be correct, these differences must be
offset by variation in the cost of living and amenities. The bottom
panel of table 1 shows the disparities in housing prices across areas
using Census data on housing prices. In the five most expensive areas,
three of which are in California, the value of the median house was
$309,000 or more in the 2000 census. According to National Association
of Realtors (NAR) data on recent housing sales, the average sales prices
for San Jose and San Francisco were $852,000 and $825,000, respectively,
in the third quarter of 2007. Meanwhile prices below $60,000 are the
norm in the five cheapest metropolitan areas. These places are again
primarily in Texas, although Danville, Illinois, and Pine Bluff,
Arkansas, are also among the least expensive areas. (6)
High incomes and high prices go together across metropolitan areas.
Regressing the logarithm of income on the logarithm of housing prices
across areas yields a coefficient of 0.33, which is reassuringly close
to the share of housing in average expenditure. (7) Figure 2 shows a
strong relationship (the correlation is 70 percent) between income per
capita and house prices across metropolitan areas. For every extra
dollar of income, prices increase by nearly ten dollars. This
relationship means that higher housing costs exactly offset higher
incomes if each extra dollar of housing cost is associated with l0 cents
of annual expenses in interest payments, local taxes, and maintenance,
net of any capital gains associated with living in the house. This
figure does not seem unreasonable for many areas of the country.
Even though higher housing costs absorb much of the added income in
high-wage places, they are only one of the costs of moving into a
high-income area--many other goods are also more expensive. The American
Chamber of Commerce Research Association (ACCRA) has assembled cost
indices on a full range of commodities across metropolitan areas. Figure
3 shows the relationship between the logarithm of the ACCRA price index
and the logarithm of income per capita, both as of 2000. The correlation
between these variables is 54 percent, and as the ACCRA index goes up by
0.1 log point, personal income rises by 0.08 log point. Higher prices
are offset by higher incomes, just as the spatial equilibrium model
predicts.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Of course, there is still plenty of heterogeneity in real incomes
across space. The spatial equilibrium model implies that lower real
incomes must be offset by higher amenities. One of these is a pleasant
climate. Figure 4 shows the relationship between average January
temperature and real wages in 2000: warmer places pay less, just as the
spatial equilibrium model suggests. A large literature shows that real
incomes are lower where amenities are high. (8)
If it is much better to live in a high-income place, then one would
expect population to be flowing toward richer areas. However, figure 5
shows a lack of any relationship across metropolitan areas between
population growth from 1980 to 2000 and income per capita in 1980.
People are not moving disproportionately to higher-income areas. The
stability of the spatial equilibrium model is also supported by the
relatively weak convergence of incomes across metropolitan areas in
recent decades. If higher incomes in some areas represented some
disequilibrium phenomenon, one would expect firms to abandon those areas
and workers to gravitate toward them. Both forces would tend to make
incomes converge. (9) But as we have documented elsewhere, the 1980s saw
essentially no convergence, and in the 1990s convergence was much weaker
than in the 1970s. (10)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
One final piece of evidence comes from happiness surveys. We reject
the view that responses to questions about happiness are a direct
reflection of consumer welfare--we see no particular reason why utility
maximization should be associated with any particular emotional state,
even one as desirable as happiness. Still, a strong tendency of people
who live in poor areas to report lower levels of happiness would be seen
as a challenge to the spatial equilibrium approach. Using the General
Social Survey between 1972 and 2006, we form self-reported happiness
measures at the metropolitan-area level using the fraction of
respondents who report being happy. (11) Figure 6 shows no relationship
between self-reported happiness and income per capita--people do not
seem any less happy in places that are poorer.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
These facts certainly do not prove that the spatial equilibrium
assumption holds. Given that amenities are part of any region's
appeal and that it is impossible to know how much people value those
amenities, it is effectively impossible to prove that welfare levels are
equalized across space. A better way to describe the evidence is to say
that many empirical facts are compatible with the spatial equilibrium
assumption, and few, if any, would cause us to reject the assumption. Of
course, we accept that welfare might not be equalized in the short run.
A negative shock to an area's productivity will lead to a reduction
in income that is not immediately capitalized into housing costs. (12)
Moreover, when such capitalization does occur, homeowners will face a
real decline in wealth in response to the area's economic troubles.
The spatial equilibrium assumption is best understood as a
characterization of the medium and long runs, not year-to-year variation
in regional well-being.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Economic Policy and Urban Theory
We will now fully specify a model to guide both our empirical work
and our policy discussion. For our empirical work, we will assume that
production and utility functions are Cobb-Douglas. But since these forms
generate policy prescriptions that do not hold generically, we will have
to move to a somewhat more general formulation when we discuss the
implications for national policy.
We assume that individuals have Cobb-Douglas utility with a
multiplicative amenity factor. We assume that they face a proportional
tax rate of [t.sub.i], so that the indirect utility function can be
written as [U.sub.i] = [[theta].sub.i[([N.sub.i])(1 [t.sub.i])
[W.sub.i][[PI].sub.j][([P.sup.j.sub.i]).sup.-[[beta].sub.j]. The spatial
equilibrium assumption is that utility in each area is equal to a
reservation utility [U.bar], which implies
(1) log([W.sub.i]) = log([U.bar]) -
[[summation].sub.j][[beta].sub.j] log([P.sup.j.sub.i]) - log(1 -
[t.sub.i]) - log[[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])].
With a slight abuse of notation, we assume that
[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i]) = [[theta].sub.i][N.sup.-[sigma].sub.i], to
capture possible congestion externalities. On the production side, we
restrict the model to two goods: one traded good that has a fixed price
of one, and one nontraded good with an endogenously determined price of
[P.sub.i]. The share of spending on the nontraded good is denoted
[beta], so overall utility is [[theta].sub.i][N.sup.-[sigma].sub.i](1 -
[t.sub.i])[W.sub.i] [P.sup.-[beta].sub.i].
The traded sector is characterized by free entry of firms that
produce traded goods according to a constant-returns-to-scale production
function [A.sub.i]([N.sub.i])[F.sub.i]([L.sub.i], [K.sub.T,i],
[K.sub.N,i]). We let [A.sub.i]([N.sub.i]) =
[a.sub.i][N.sup.[omega].sub.i], which is meant to capture the level of
productivity in the area, which may be increasing in the total number of
people working in the area. L represents labor, [K.sub.T] a vector of
traded capital inputs, and [K.sub.N] a vector of nontraded capital
inputs. A fixed supply of nontraded capital implies that a production
function that displays constant returns to scale at the firm level will
display diminishing returns at the area level--at least if agglomeration
economies are not too strong. If the production function is written as
[F.sub.i]([L.sub.i], [K.sub.T,i], [K.sub.N,i]) =
[a.sub.i][N.sup.[omega].sub.i][K.sup.[alpha][gamma].sub.N,i]
[K.sup.[alpha](1 - [gamma]).sub.T,i][L.sup.1[alpha].sub.i], and if
nontraded capital in the area is fixed (denoted [[bar.K].sub.N,i]), then
labor demand in the area can be written
[Q.sub.w][([a.sub.i][N.sup.[omega].sub.i]
[K.sup.[alpha][gamma].sub.N,i][W.sup.[alpha] - 1 [alpha]
[gamma].sub.i]).sup.1/[alpha][gamma]], where [Q.sub.w] is constant
across areas.
We assume a housing sector characterized by free entry of firms
with access to a production technology [H.sub.i]G(L, [K.sub.T],
[K.sub.N]). [H.sub.i] represents factors that impact the ability to
deliver housing cheaply, and G(., ., .) is a constant-returns-to-scale
production function. The housing production function is
[H.sub.i][[bar.Z].sup.[mu][eta].sub.N,i] [K.sup.[mu](1 -
[eta]).sub.T][L.sup.1 - [mu]], where [[bar.Z].sub.N,i] represents the
nontraded input into housing (land), which we assume is different from
the nontraded input into the traded goods sector. To account for the
returns to nontraded capital inputs (land), we assume they go to
rentiers who also live in the area. They have the same Cobb-Douglas
utility functions as workers but do not work or noticeably affect
aggregate population. Instead they are a wealthy but small portion of
the population; because of their wealth they contribute to demand for
the nontraded good, but because of their negligible number they do not
add to area population. Thus, [N.sub.i] equals only the sum of labor
used in the two sectors. The government also spends a share [beta] of
its revenue on the nontraded good.
We now define our equilibrium concept:
Definition: In a competitive equilibrium, wages equal the marginal
product of labor in both sectors, individuals optimally choose housing
consumption, and utility levels are constant across space.
The spatial equilibrium condition, labor demand, and equilibrium in
the housing sector produce solutions for population, wages, and prices:
(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [[kappa].sub.N], [[kappa].sub.w], and [[kappa].sub.p] depend
on the tax rate and constants, and [bar.[omega]] = ([sigma] +
[beta][mu][eta])(1 - [alpha] + [alpha][gamma]) + ([alpha][gamma] -
[omega])[1 - [beta](1 - [mu + [mu][eta])]. This system of equations will
guide our discussion of the empirical work on agglomeration economies.
These equations show that an exogenous increase in area-level
productivity or amenities will impact population, wages, and prices. In
urban research all three outcomes must be used to understand the impact
of an intervention.
The most natural social welfare function is
[[summation].sub.i][N.sub.i] [[theta].sub.i](1
-[t.sub.i])[W.sub.i][P.sup.[beta].sub.i], which equals the (fixed) total
population times individual utility (which will be constant across
people). We also include the welfare received by rentiers; if total
rentier income is [Y.sub.i, and the size of this group is fixed
exogenously, then the additive utility function that includes rentiers
can be written as [[summation].sub.i][[theta].sub.i](1 -
[t.sub.i])([N.sub.i][W.sub.i] + [Y.sub.i])[P.sup.-[beta].sub.i].
Our first policy question concerns the optimal local tax level to
fund local amenities. We assume that local amenities are a function of
local spending and population, so that [[theta].sub.i] =
[g.sub.i]([t.sub.i] [W.sub.i][N.sub.i], [N.sub.i]). These amenities
could include public safety, parks, and schools. Following Truman
Bewley, (13) two assumptions are typical in the literature. Amenities
may be a pure public good, meaning that there is no depreciation with
population size and [theta] = [g.sub.i]([t.sub.i][W.sub.i][N.sub.i]), or
a pure public service, which means that output is neutral with respect
to population and [[theta].sub.i] = [g.sub.i]([t.sub.i] [W.sub.i]). We
assume the latter so that amenities are a function of individual taxes.
(14)
Proposition 1: The allocation of people across space in a
decentralized equilibrium maximizes social welfare. If an
individual's amenity level [[theta].sub.i] is a function of that
individual's tax payments, then the area-specific tax that
maximizes the sum of utility levels across areas is also the tax that
maximizes utility within each area when holding population constant. A
local government that seeks to maximize population will choose tax rates
that maximize the sum of total utility levels, whereas a local
government that seeks to maximize wages per capita will minimize social
welfare. Housing prices should be maximized if agglomeration economies
are sufficiently large or house production is sufficiently capital
intensive, and minimized otherwise.
In this model, agglomeration economies do not change the optimal
policies for local governments. Maximizing population was desirable even
without agglomeration economies; the existence of such economies only
provides another reason for its desirability. The result that population
maximization is optimal is not general, however. In some cases local
governments must decide between actions that improve the welfare of
existing citizens and actions that attract more citizens. Restrictions
on land use development are a pertinent example of a policy that reduces
area population growth but may increase the quality of life for existing
residents. When a conflict arises between attracting more people and
caring for current residents, agglomeration economies will tend to
strengthen the case for policies that attract new residents.
Despite the existence of externalities, our assumptions about
functional forms imply that there are no welfare gains from reallocating
people across space. (15) The key to this result is that our functional
forms imply that the elasticity of welfare with respect to population is
constant. To address spatial issues more generally, we will need a more
general formulation for agglomeration economies.
This observation notwithstanding, Proposition 1 does not rule out a
role for government. Indeed, by assumption the government provides the
amenity level, so there is an inherent role for government spending. The
proposition does imply, however, that decisionmaking about optimal
spending can ignore population responses and simply maximize the welfare
of the current population. A decentralized decisionmaking process, where
individual areas choose tax and amenity levels to maximize the welfare
of their citizens, will yield a Pareto optimal population distribution.
This result depends on the functional form that guarantees a constant
elasticity of well-being with respect to population.
The proposition also hints at some of the key results from urban
public finance. When localities maximize population or property values,
they will also be maximizing utility and choosing an optimal tax level.
If they try to maximize income per capita, however, they will actually
be minimizing social welfare. In other settings, of course, maximizing
population does not yield socially beneficial results. For example, if
one area suffers a negative externality from congestion and another area
has no such congestion, it will not maximize social welfare for the
congestion-prone area to try to maximize population. A distinguished
literature, following Henry George, (16) shows that choosing policy to
maximize local land values is usually the most reliable way to achieve a
Pareto optimum. (17)
To derive more general results about the location of people across
space, we move to a more general model and ignore the role of government
in creating local public goods. We will also suppress the terms for
capital and write output of nontraded goods in an area as
[A.sub.i]([N.sub.i])[F.sub.i] ([N.sub.i] - [L.sub.i]), which represents
total output of nontraded goods minus the costs of traded capital,
assuming that traded capital is chosen optimally. Likewise, we write
production of housing as [G.sub.i]([L.sub.i]), which again is meant to
be net of traded capital. Utility is U[[Y.sub.i], [H.sub.i],
[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])], where [Y.sub.i] is net income, which may
include rental income, minus housing costs. The next proposition then
follows:
Proposition 2: (a) A competitive equilibrium where net unearned
income is constant across space is a social optimum if and only if
U[Yi,[[theta].sub.i] ([N.sub.i])] and
[N.sub.i][[theta]'.sub.i]([N.sub.i])[U.sub.[theta],i] +
[U.sub.Y][A'.sub.i]([N.sub.i])F([N.sub.i] - [L.sub.i]) are constant
across space, where [U.sub.[theta],i] is the marginal utility of
amenities in location i.
(b) If either all unearned income from an area goes to the
residents of that area, or the marginal utility of income is constant
across space, then moving individuals from area j to area i will
increase total welfare relative to the competitive equilibrium if and
only if
[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i])[U.sub.[theta],i]
[N.sub.i][[theta]'.sub.i] ([N.sub.i])/[[theta].sub.i]([N.sub.i]) +
[U.sub.Y,i] [N.sub.i][A'.sub.i] ([N.sub.i])/[A.sub.i]([N.sub.i])
[A.sub.i]([N.sub.i])[F.sub.i]([N.sub.i] [L.sub.i])/[N.sub.i] is greater
than
[[theta].sub.j]([N.sub.j])[U.sub.[theta],j]
[N.sub.j][[theta]'.sub.j] ([N.sub.j])/[[theta].sub.j]([N.sub.j]) +
[U.sub.Y,j] [N.sub.j][A'.sub.j] ([N.sub.j])/[A.sub.j]([N.sub.j])
[A.sub.j]([N.sub.j])[F.sub.j]([N.sub.j] [L.sub.j])/[N.sub.j].
Part (a) of Proposition 2 reveals two reasons why a spatial
equilibrium may not be a social optimum. First, a spatial equilibrium
equates total utility levels across space, not marginal utilities of
income. (18) Thus a planner could increase welfare by transferring money
to areas where the marginal utility from traded-goods consumption is
high, and holding population levels constant. (19) Since everyone is
identical ex ante, there is no natural means of placing different social
welfare weights on different individuals to eliminate the gains from
redistribution that come from different marginal utilities of income.
The Cobb-Douglas utility functions discussed above imply that the
marginal utility of income equals total utility (which is constant
across space) divided by income. In this case redistributing income to
poor places is attractive--if population can be held fixed--not because
poorer places have lower welfare but because they have a higher marginal
utility from spending. This result would disappear if poor places had
amenities that were substitutes for rather than complements to cash.
(20)
The second reason for government intervention arises if [N.sub.i]
[[theta]'.sub.i]([N.sub.i])[U.sub.[theta],i] +
[U.sub.Y][A'.sub.i]([N.sub.i]) F([N.sub.i] - [L.sub.i] is not
constant across space. In the absence of congestion and agglomeration
economies, the competitive equilibrium is a social optimum.
Alternatively, if the sum of agglomeration plus congestion effects were
(somewhat magically) the same everywhere, the decentralized equilibrium
would be a social optimum. These unusual circumstances were satisfied
under the functional forms described above, which reflect a constant
elasticity of amenities and agglomeration with respect to population.
Those conditions, and the assumption about the functional form of the
utility function, ensured that welfare could not be improved by moving
population around.
Another way to understand the benefits from subsidizing places is
to consider moving people from one region to another, as discussed in
part (b) of Proposition 2. Gains can accrue from reallocating people to
an area if either the amenity elasticity is lower there or the
agglomeration economies are higher. The condition on agglomeration
economies multiplies the agglomeration elasticity
[N.sub.i][N'.sub.i]([N.sub.i])/[A.sub.i] ([N.sub.i]) by [U.sub.Y,i]
[A.sub.i]([N.sub.i])[F.sub.i](N.sub.i - [L.sub.i]/ [N.sub.i]; in words,
it is the product of the marginal utility of income and output per
capita in the nontraded sector. This second term implies that it is
desirable to move people to richer areas if the marginal utility of
income is constant across space. We will focus on the differences in
agglomeration elasticities in the next section.
Agglomeration Economies
Two important facts support the existence of agglomeration
economies: the spatial concentration of economic activity, and the
tendency of densely populated areas to be richer and more productive.
The majority of the world now lives in cities, and hundreds of millions
of people crowd into a small set of particularly large megacities.
Industries are also often spatially concentrated. (21) In principle, the
concentration of people in cities and of industries in clusters could
simply reflect exogenous differences in productivity. This view may well
be accurate for the nineteenth century, when, for example, hundreds of
thousands came to New York to enjoy the productive advantages created by
its natural harbor. In the twenty-first century, however, it is hard to
think of any comparable exogenous advantages that could explain massive
urban agglomerations. Glenn Ellison and Glaeser find that a large
battery of local characteristics can explain less than one-fifth of the
concentration of manufacturing industries across space. (22) Since so
much clustering occurs without an obvious exogenous cause, urban
economists have tended to interpret it as the result of endogenous gains
from co-location, which are referred to as agglomeration economies.
The belief in agglomeration economies is also bolstered by the
robust correlations between income or productivity and urban density.
Figure 7 shows the relationship between the logarithm of GMP per capita
and the logarithm of metropolitan-area population. City size explains
one-quarter of the variation in GMP per capita (that is, the correlation
is 0.50), and the elasticity of productivity with respect to city size
is 0.13.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Because GMP data have been available for only a few years, earlier
researchers looked at either metropolitan-area income or state-level
productivity measures. Antonio Ciccone and Robert Hall show the
remarkably strong correlation between state productivity and the degree
to which the population within a state is concentrated in a small number
of dense counties. (23) Glaeser and David Mare show that the urban wage
premium does not seem to reflect differential selection of more-skilled
people into big cities. (24) They do find, however, that recent migrants
to cities experience only a small portion of the urban wage premium
immediately, instead reaping most of the gains through faster wage
growth. The steep age-earnings profile in cities suggests that cities
may speed the pace of human capital accumulation.
The great challenge facing research on the connection between city
size and income is that this connection may reflect the tendency of
people to move to already-productive areas, rather than any sort of
agglomeration economy. Ciccone and Hall address this reverse causality issue by turning to historical variables, such as nineteenth-century
population and railroad density. Pierre Philippe Combes, Gilles
Duranton, and Laurent Gobillon pursue a similar exercise using French
data. (25) Using these variables as instruments for density, these
authors continue to find a strong connection between density and
economic productivity. However, as we will discuss later, historical
instruments of this kind do not naturally solve the identification
problem in a spatial model such as the one described above.
Since the public policy implications of agglomeration economies
depend on the size and nature of those economies, table 2 reproduces
these standard approaches to measuring agglomeration using
individual-level data from the 2000 Census. We run the regressions using
only prime-working-age men (those between the ages of 25 and 55) to
avoid capturing variation from differences in labor force participation,
but similar results obtain when we include all employed adults.
Regression 2-1 in table 2 shows the basic correlation between the
logarithm of population in a metropolitan area and the logarithm of
wages, holding individual-level controls constant. The measured
elasticity is 0.041, meaning that as population doubles, income
increases by a little more than 2.8 percent. If population is
exogenously distributed, then the Cobb-Douglas functional forms above
imply that the measured elasticity of wages with respect to area
population equals [omega] + [alpha][gamma]/1 - [alpha] + [alpha][gamma];
thus if labor's share in output is two-thirds, then the
agglomeration parameter [omega] equals 1.041 times [alpha][gamma], the
share of nontraded capital in production, plus 0.027.
Regression 2-2 in table 2 examines whether the elasticity of wages
with respect to population differs between big and small cities. It is
specified as a piecewise linear regression with a break at the median
population across our sample of metropolitan areas, thus allowing the
impact of area population to be bigger or smaller for larger areas. The
estimated elasticity is higher for smaller cities (0.076 versus 0.038),
but the difference is not statistically significant.
Some agglomeration theories focus on area size, others on
population density. Regression 2-3 includes both population and density
as independent variables. The coefficients on the two variables are
similar, at 0.023 and 0.029, respectively. Regression 2-4 is a piecewise
linear regression for both density and population. Again the estimated
coefficient on population is stronger for smaller cities. However, the
estimated coefficient on density is stronger for areas with more people
per acre, but the difference in the density coefficients is not
statistically significant.
Regression 2-5 follows Ciccone and Hall and uses historical
data--population of the metropolitan area in 1850--to instrument for
current population. (26) We have data for only 210 metropolitan areas
from this period, so our sample size shrinks. The estimated coefficient
on population in this regression is actually higher than that in
regression 2-1, which suggests that the population-income relationship
does not reflect the impact of recent population movement to more
productive areas.
The model clarifies what we need to assume for instrumental
variables regressions such as this one to be interpreted as estimates of
agglomeration economies. If historical population affects wages by
raising productivity, perhaps because it is associated with investment
in nontraded infrastructure, then the estimated coefficient will equal
[alpha] - [micro][eta][beta]/1 - [beta](1 - [mu] + [micro][eta], which
is also what ordinary least squares would estimate if cross-city
variation came from heterogeneity in productivity. These parameters do
not tell us anything about agglomeration economies, but instead provide
us with information about decreasing returns in the housing sector. If,
however, historical population acts through housing supply or amenities,
then the estimated instrumental variables coefficient will equal [omega]
- [alpha][gamma]/1 - [alpha] + [alpha][gamma] which can be transformed
to get an estimate of agglomeration economies. This would also be the
ordinary least squares coefficient if the exogenous spatial variation
came entirely from amenities or housing supply.
Table 2 raises two challenges for economic policy. First, these
simple correlations between income and area population may not be
instructive about agglomeration economies, since they could result from
omitted productivity. Second, even the ordinary least squares
relationships fail to find a clear difference in agglomeration economies
between bigger and smaller areas or between more and less dense areas.
Since the rationale for agglomeration-based spatial interventions
requires agglomeration elasticities to be different in different types
of areas, we next look for this effect using more complex estimation
techniques. But uncovering differences in elasticities that are not
visible using ordinary least squares is a tall order.
Estimating Agglomeration
The urban model presented in equations 2 through 4 implies that
agglomeration economies can be estimated if we have exogenous sources of
variation that impact amenities or housing supply, but not productivity.
If agglomeration economies exist, then the extra population brought in
by amenities should raise productivity. The mean temperature of an area
is certainly an amenity: people prefer milder climates. We therefore use
climate data to see whether places that attract more people because of
their climate also see an increase in wages.
January temperature and precipitation are both relatively reliable
predictors of urban growth in postwar America. Regressing the change in
population between 1970 and 2000 on these two variables yields the
following equation:
(5) log ([population.sub.2000]/[population.sub.1970]) = 0.0603 +
(0.0549)
0.0166
(0.0012) temperature
0.0068 precipitation
(0.0011)
The adjusted [R.sup.2] is 0.39 and there are 316 observations;
standard errors are in parentheses. One interpretation of these
correlations is that they reflect the interaction between climate and
new technologies, such as air conditioning, that make warm places
relatively more appealing. Glaeser and Kristina Tobio argue that warm
areas tend also to have had more-permissive land use regulations. (27)
An alternative approach might therefore be to use the Wharton Land Use
Index, which measures the restrictiveness of the building environment,
to capture variation related to housing supply. (28) In both cases
identification hinges critically on these variables being orthogonal to
changes in productivity at the local level, except insofar as the
productivity changes are due to agglomeration economies. We cannot be
sure that this is the case, but given the absence of other alternatives
we will use variation in climate as our instrument.
Using the model above, we assume that our climate-based instruments
predict changes in the housing supply and amenity variables,
log[([H.sub.i] [[bar.Z].sup.[micro][eta].sub.N,i]).sup.[beta] +
log([[theta].sub.i]), but not changes in the productivity variable
log([a.sub.i][[bar.K].sup.[alpha][gamma].sub.N,i]). In this case the
univariate regression of wage growth on population growth will estimate
[omega] - [alpha][gamma]/1 - [alpha] + [alpha][gamma]. By examining the
interaction of this treatment effect with other area-level
characteristics, we can determine whether co appears to be higher in
some places than in others. This procedure also requires [alpha] and
[gamma] to be constant across space.
Taking the logarithm of our baseline wage equation (equation A1 in
appendix A) yields the following relationship between the wage of person
j and the size of metropolitan area i, where the person lives:
(6) log([W.sub.j]) = ([b.sub.0] +
[b.sub.1][X.sub.i])log([N.sub.i,t]) + [sigma][Z.sub.j] + [[zeta].sub.i]
+ [[epsilon.sub.j].
The vector [Z.sub.j] represents individual characteristics, such as
age and education, and [sigma] the vector of coefficients on Z at time
t. Each metropolitan area has a fixed effect, [[zeta].sub.i], due to
nontraded capital and MSA-specific noise, and the error term
[[epsilon].sub.j] represents the effect of any unobservable individual
characteristics as well as noise in setting the wage. Population size
[N.sub.i.t] impacts the wage through the coefficient [b.sub.0] +
[b.sub.1][X.sub.i] which equals [omega] - [alpha][gamma]/1 - [alpha] +
[alpha][gamma]. The possibility that these coefficients might be
different for different types of cities is captured by the term
[b.sub.1][X.sub.i] which allows city-level characteristics, [X.sub.i],
to impact the agglomeration economy. This procedure requires [b.sub.0]
and [b.sub.1] to be constant across space. If we also assume them to be
constant over time, then we can write
(7) log([W.sub.j]) = ([b.sub.0] + [b.sub.1][X.sub.i])log([N.sub.i,t
+ 1]) + ([sigma] + [tau])[Z.sub.j] + [[zeta].sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.j],
where [tau] augments [sigma] because we allow the effect of
individual characteristics to change over time. We can rewrite equation
7 to show an explicit dependence on population growth:
(7') [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In equation 7' the MSA-level fixed effect becomes [[mu].sub.i]
= ([b.sub.0] + [b.sub.0] + [b.sub.1][X.sub.i]) log([N.sub.i,t]) +
[[zeta].sub.i]. This is also the estimated MSA-level fixed effect in
equation 6, so we can write
(6') log ([W.sub.j]) = [sigma][Z.sub.j] + [[mu].sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.j].
We will estimate [b.sub.0] and [b.sub.1] by pooling equations
6' and 7' together for Census years 1990 and 2000. We can thus
run
(8) log([W.sub.j]) = ([b.sub.0] +
[b.sub.1][X.sub.j])log([N.sub.i,2000 / [N.sub.i,1990])[I.sub.2000] +
[sigma][Z.sub.j] + [tau][Z.sub.j] [I.sub.2000] + [[mu].sub.i] +
[[epsilon].sub.j],
where [I.sub.2000] is a dummy variable equal to one for
observations in 2000.
We first estimate equation 8 as an ordinary least squares
regression, omitting any interactions with population growth. Results
are presented as regression 3-1 in table 3, and the sample again
includes only prime-working-age men. The coefficient on population
growth is strongly positive, indicating that expanding cities are also
getting more productive. In regression 3-2 we attempt to identify the
effect by using January temperature, July temperature, and precipitation
as instruments for population growth between 1990 and 2000. If [b.sub.1]
= 0, this should yield an unbiased estimate of [b.sub.0] = [omega] -
[alpha][gamma]/1 - [alpha] [alpha][gamma]. The coefficient drops to
0.004, implying that a doubling in population is associated with a 0.3
percent increase in wages. But this coefficient does not mean that
agglomeration economies are absent. The theory predicts that wages will
only increase with population ([b.sub.0] > 0) if population is a
larger input into production than fixed capital. If [b.sub.0] = 0, then
[omega] = [alpha][gamma]; that is, extra population is just as valuable
as extra fixed capital, and increasing prices absorb all of the gains
from agglomeration.
We have little empirical guidance on the amount of nontraded
capital in the production function. Eventually, all capital may be
endogenous, but over the course of a decade or two, much capital is
relatively fixed. The user cost of commercial real estate provides one
possible source of information on the fraction of fixed capital in the
economy's aggregate production function. If this real estate is
worth the $5.3 trillion claimed by Standard and Poor's (2007), then
assuming the same 10 percent user cost as for residential real estate
gives a contribution of $530 billion to U.S. GDP, or about 4 percent.
Assuming [alpha] to be one-third, fixed capital would thus represent
[gamma] = 0.12, or 12 percent of all capital.
The coefficient of 0.004 estimated in regression 3-2 gives a point
estimate indicating that agglomeration is only slightly more important
than fixed capital, although the large standard errors make the true
agglomeration effect hard to estimate. The 95 percent confidence
interval on our estimate ranges from -0.19 to 0.2; with [alpha][gamma] =
0.04 (12 percent of one-third), the former implies that co = -0.09 and
the latter yields co = 0.18. A higher value of y would push both of
these estimates upward, and a lower value would reduce them.
The main implication of the model was that policy should subsidize
places where the elasticity of productivity with respect to population
is higher than elsewhere. One significant question is whether
agglomeration economies are greater for larger or smaller cities, and
table 2 suggested the latter. To test this hypothesis, regressions 3-3
through 3-5 interact the log of population in 2000 with various
variables [X.sub.i] intended to capture larger, denser, and declining
cities, respectively. We now instrument for population growth with the
weather variables as well as the weather variables interacted with
[X.sub.i].
We first explore whether adding people has more of an effect on the
productivity of larger places. Regression 3-3 thus uses a dummy variable
indicating whether an MSA's population was above the sample median
in 1990 for [X.sub.i]. A positive coefficient 5 on the interaction
between this dummy and population growth would imply that adding
population is in fact more valuable for the productivity of larger
places, but we find no significant evidence for any such interaction.
The impact of population on productivity seems to be the same for both
smaller and larger metropolitan areas.
Another possibility is that growing population has more of a
positive effect in areas that are more geographically compact, with a
dense urban core. To test this hypothesis, regression 3-4 uses a measure
of centralization--the share of employment in the area that lies within
five miles of the central business district--as the interaction
variable. These data are based on zip code employment data described by
Glaeser and Matthew Kahn. (29) The data would ideally come from before
1990 but are available only from 1998. In this regression the
coefficient [delta] is small and statistically insignificant. We cannot
conclude that density increases productivity more in faster-growing
cities than in others.
Regression 3-5 examines whether agglomeration economies seem to be
greater in places that were previously in relative decline. We let
[X.sub.i] an indicator variable that takes a value of one if the area
was in the bottom quartile of population growth (that is, had population
growth of 7.08 percent or less) between 1970 and 1990. This regression
shows that having been in relative decline reduces productivity, but
this effect is dampened slightly for larger cities. This result suggests
that population increases may be most advantageous in areas that have
already been in decline.
This analysis does not offer a compelling answer as to where
agglomeration economies are strongest. We look for differences based on
size, compactness, and past decline and are unable to uncover convincing
differences. If anything, the table suggests that agglomeration effects
are stronger in smaller metropolitan areas, more centralized metropolitan areas, and metropolitan areas that have been in decline.
However, all of these measured effects are statistically insignificant
and not robust. Until further research yields more precise estimates,
these results suggest the difficulty of establishing any clear gains to
subsidizing one region or another.
Congestion Externalities
We now turn to the impact that metropolitan-area size has on
amenities. We will first look at the connection between area population
and three direct measures of urban disamenities: commute times,
pollution, and crime. We will then consider real wages. In all of these
cases we remain concerned that the disamenity is itself influencing
urban population. However, since the costs of these disamenities are
arguably minor relative to overall income, we are more comfortable
looking at the ordinary least squares coefficients. Since the case for
national spatial policies depends on different effects of population on
amenities across different cities, our focus will be on whether the
slope of population is different for cities that are larger or more
centralized.
Regression 4-1 in table 4 examines the connection between average
commute time and population. The basic elasticity is 0.12, meaning that
as city size doubles, the average commute increases by 8.7 percent, or
about two minutes. We also investigate whether this coefficient is
larger for cities above the median population in our sample. The
interaction is tiny in both economic and statistical terms. In fact, the
interaction is sufficiently precisely estimated that we can reject the
hypothesis that the elasticity of commute times with respect to
population increases or decreases by any significant amount for larger
cities.
Regression 4-2 in table 4 considers the interaction between area
population and centralization, again using Glaeser and Kahn's data
on the share of employment within five miles of the city center. (30) In
this case we find a marginally significant interaction. Increasing
population has a bigger effect on commute times in denser cities than in
cities where the population is more dispersed.
Regression 4-3 looks at the atmospheric concentration of TSP-10
particulates, one of the key measures of air quality at the
metropolitan-area level. (31) The elasticity of this variable with
respect to city size is 0.142, which is statistically significant:
bigger cities have slightly worse air. However, we do not find a larger
slope for bigger cities. Regression 4-4 adds a variable interacting city
size with centralization. We find that city population has a weaker
effect on pollution in more centralized places, perhaps because people
there are more likely to use public transportation.
Regression 4-5 focuses on crime, another disamenity generally
associated with urban size. Glaeser and Bruce Sacerdote provide evidence
that although some of this connection reflects the sorting of
crime-prone individuals into urban areas, it partly also reflects the
tendency of big cities to increase the supply of potential victims and
make arrest and conviction more difficult. (32) This regression finds
only a weak connection between murder and city size, although this has
declined substantially over time. (33) Regression 4-6 finds no
significant association between murder rates and centralization.
Regression 4-2 suggested that increasing population in centralized
places has a more unfavorable impact on commute times, and regression
4-4 suggested that increasing population in centralized places has a
small negative impact on pollution. The overall lesson for spatial
policy is therefore unclear. We attempt to get around this by looking at
real wages, which provide a measure of overall amenities. Since
population is more likely to respond to the entire basket of amenities
than to these individual disamenities, we are more concerned with
problems of reverse causality in this regression.
Regression 4-7 investigates the elasticity of real wages with
respect to area population. Neither the raw effect nor the interaction
with population above the median is statistically significant. The
failure to find a robust relationship confirms the spatial equilibrium
assumption that agglomeration economies offer no free lunch: high
nominal wages are offset by higher prices. The absence of a clear
interaction means that there does not appear to be an amenity-based
rationale for pushing population toward bigger or smaller cities.
Regression 4-8 finds a statistically significant negative
interaction between area population and area centralization. Interpreted
literally, this result implies that any negative effects of population
on amenities are minimized in more centralized locales. In principle,
this finding seems to suggest that pushing population toward more
compact and less sprawling places might be welfare-enhancing.
Despite this finding, we have little confidence that either
agglomeration or congestion externalities differ significantly across
smaller or larger, or denser or less dense, cities. This does not
reassure us that the current situation is a Pareto optimum, but it does
suggest that it is not obvious which way government policy should
deviate from the status quo. For us, this degree of ignorance suggests
that explicit spatial policies are as likely to do harm as good.
U.S. Policies toward Places
In this section we turn to a brief empirical evaluation of three
major types of policies related to urban growth. The first is
transportation policy. America's most significant place-making
policies have been improvements in transportation. Railroads in the
nineteenth century and highways in the twentieth both had major impacts
on the growth of different areas. Nonetheless, there is little evidence
to suggest that the place-making capacities of transportation are
actually working in a desirable ways As a result, transportation should
be judged on its ability to reduce transport costs and not on its
ability to remake the urban landscape. The second type of policy
consists of large-scale interventions that had the direct goal of
strengthening particular places. In the twentieth century, such
interventions included urban renewal and the Appalachian Regional
Commission. We find no clear effects of these policies, but this is
unsurprising, because they involved small amounts of money relative to
the sizes of the areas involved. The third type of policy is typified by
the enterprise zones of the 1980s and 1990s, which provided much greater
resources to much smaller areas. These policies do seem to have had an
impact, but the costs per new job are extremely high.
Transportation and Place Making
American governments have been in the business of subsidizing
transportation since the dawn of the Republic. Even before the
Revolution, George Washington had contemplated a canal that would
connect the Potomac River to the Ohio River valley and the western
states. (34) After the Revolution, Washington's enormous prestige
enabled him to get the support of the Maryland and Virginia legislatures
to charter the Potomac Company. Washington served as its president. The
states invested in the company, granted it a perpetual monopoly on water
traffic along the Potomac, and gave it considerable powers to acquire
land. Even with this support, the Potomac Canal was unable to fulfill
its mission, and it collapsed in the mid-1820s. Construction along the
route turned out to be enormously difficult, and the limited willingness
of credit markets in 1800 to trust private companies with vast sums made
it hard for any firm to raise sufficient finances to pay for such an
expensive undertaking. The Potomac Company was not a complete failure,
but it did not produce America's great waterway to the west.
That waterway would be created by an even more extensive
governmental investment in transportation infrastructure. It seemed
obvious to DeWitt Clinton, New York City's mayor during most of
1803-15, that connecting the country' s greatest seaport with the
Great Lakes would yield enormous returns. (35) Clinton became one of the
canal's greatest proponents, and when he was elected governor of
New York State in 1817, he quickly began construction. To many
contemporary observers, a New York canal looked no wiser than one in
Virginia, and the idea was dubbed "Clinton's Folly." Yet
with massive government spending and prodigious feats of engineering,
Clinton managed to construct a canal that connected the Hudson River to
Lake Erie.
The Erie Canal was an enormous success by any measure. Its toll
revenues readily covered its costs, and, like the earlier success of the
Bridgewater Canal in Manchester, England, it set off a national craze
for canal building that changed the face of America. In 1816 it cost 30
cents to move a ton of goods a mile by wagon overland. At that price,
moving goods fifteen miles overland cost the same as moving them across
the Atlantic. The canal reduced the cost of transport by more than
two-thirds, to less than 10 cents per ton-mile.
Urban economics certainly suggests that transportation
infrastructure could have a major impact on urban growth. Some forms of
transportation, like a port or a rail yard, significantly increase the
productivity of adjacent land and therefore attract new businesses.
Others, however, like the highway system, reduce the gains from
clustering and hence disperse population. It is hard to accurately
estimate the impact of the canals of the early nineteenth century on the
economic development of different urban areas. It is occasionally
claimed that the Erie Canal was critical to New York City's rise,
but New York was already America's largest port before the canal,
and Glaeser shows that it did not accelerate the city's growth.
(36)
However, the growth of Syracuse, Rochester, Buffalo, and other
cities of upstate New York was at least temporally connected with the
canal. These cities are all close to the canal and grew as mercantile cities exploiting that proximity. Yet although individual histories
certainly attest to the importance of canals in promoting urban growth,
it is hard to tease out the impact of the Erie Canal statistically. For
example, a regression of the logarithm of population growth for New York
State counties between 1820 and 1840 on the logarithm of initial
population and a dummy variable indicating whether the county contains
or abuts the canal yields the following estimates:
(9) log([population.sub.1840]/[population.sub.1820])
= -3.4 - 0.08
(0.7)-(0.12) * Erie Canal
+ 0.28
(0.07) * log ([population.sub.1820])
The counties along the Erie Canal saw remarkable growth during this
period, but there was remarkable growth everywhere--especially in those
places that started at higher densities. The canal was surely important
for the development of many places, but this regression raises questions
about how to appropriately estimate its impact on regional growth.
By contrast, the growth of the railroads tends to be quite closely
connected with different forms of local development. Michael Haines and
Robert Margo show that areas that added rail transportation in the 1850s
were much more likely to urbanize. (37) Although it would be hard to
claim any sort of causality from such regressions, the correlations are
striking.
Table 5 reports population growth regressions for the
nineteenth-century United States using rail data from Lee Craig, Raymond
Palmquist, and Thomas Weiss. (38) We construct a dummy variable
indicating whether a county was accessible by rail in 1850 and then look
at population growth both in the 1850s and for the rest of the century.
Regression 5-1 looks at population growth in the 1850s and access to
rail in 1850. We control for the logarithm of initial population,
proximity to the ocean, and, as a proxy for human capital, the presence
of Congregationalists in 1850. (39) There is a strong positive
relationship between access to rail in 1850 and population growth in the
ensuing decade: on average, those counties with access grew by more than
14 percent more than those without. Regression 5-2 looks at population
growth over the entire 1850-1900 period and again finds a strong
positive effect of rail access in 1850 on subsequent growth.
The Craig, Palmquist, and Weiss data also provide information on
access to waterways in 1850, but for a smaller set of counties. We also
find a significant effect for this variable for the 1850s: counties with
access to water grew by 0.12 log point more, on average, than counties
without access (results not reported).
It is easy to argue with these regressions. After all, rail yards
were not randomly strewn throughout the United States, but rather were
located in places considered to have the brightest economic future.
Still, plenty of supporting evidence suggests that railroads were
important for urban success. After all, civic boosters worked extremely
hard to get rail lines to come through their towns. This would hardly
have made sense if rail were not expected to have an impact. Moreover,
case studies of most large American cities that grew rapidly in the
nineteenth century, from Boston to Los Angeles, argue that rail played
an important role in that growth.
In the nineteenth century, population growth accompanied rail
access, and railroads seem to have particularly encouraged the growth of
big cities. Initially, people and firms clustered around rail yards, as
exemplified by Chicago's stockyards, to save transport costs.
Later, intraurban railroads enabled cities to expand by facilitating
commuting from "streetcar suburbs." (40) In the twentieth
century, further declines in transportation costs accelerated the
process of urban decentralization. Nathaniel Baum-Snow compellingly
shows that suburbanization proceeded more rapidly in those cities that
had more highway development. (41) He addresses the problems of reverse
causality using an early highway plan developed for national security
purposes.
Highway development also seems to have been strongly associated
with the growth of metropolitan areas as a whole. Gilles Duranton and
Matthew Turner show a striking connection between highways and urban
growth in the United States over the last thirty years. (42) They use a
number of different instruments, including the security-based highway
plan used by Baum-Snow, to handle the issue of reverse causality. The
raw correlations are impressive.
Regressions 5-3 and 5-4 in table 5 follow Duranton and Turner in
reporting correlations between population and income growth,
respectively, from 1960 to 1990 and highway mileage built during the
same era. The first of these regressions shows the relationship between
population growth and highway construction, controlling for initial
population, proximity to the coast, and initial share of the population
with a college degree. The elasticity of population growth with respect
to new highway mileage is 0.11, and the coefficient has a t statistic of
4.3. Regression 5-4 reports the elasticity of growth in income per
capita with respect to the same variables from 1960 to 1990. In this
case the elasticity is 0.039 and the t statistic is again over 4. The
extent to which we can be sure that highways were causing growth, rather
than vice versa, depends on the validity of the instruments of Baum-Snow
and Duranton and Turner, such as the initial highway plan based on
national security needs. Yet it is certainly true that highways and
growth move together quite closely.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
More generally, the decline in transportation costs has been
associated with a host of changes in urban form. Figure 8 documents the
90 percent reduction in the cost of moving a ton of goods one mile by
rail, and figure 9 the parallel explosion of highway transport. These
two developments mean that whereas it was enormously costly to move
goods over space in 1900, transporting goods had become almost free 100
years later. Glaeser and Janet Kohlhase argue that this change has led
to the rise of consumer cities, which are located in places where people
want to live, rather than producer cities, which are located in places
where firms have innate productive advantages due to waterways or coal
mines. (43) That paper also argues that the decline of transportation
costs helps explain the exodus of manufacturing from urban areas and the
decline of manufacturing cities. Glaeser and Giacomo Ponzetto go a step
further and argue that declining transport costs may have contributed to
the decline of goods-producing cities like Detroit but boosted the
growth of idea-producing cities like Boston and New York. (44) Their
argument is that globalization has increased the returns to skill and
that workers become skilled by locating around skilled people in cities
that are rich in human capital.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Richard Green argues that airports have played the same role in
promoting urban growth in the last fifteen years that railroads and
highways did in the past. (45) His principal piece of evidence is that
places that have more airline boardings per capita have grown faster.
Although this fact could represent the positive impact of access to
airports, it could also reflect consumer amenities: places that are
attractive for people to visit should also be attractive places for
people to live. (46) One way to check whether the connection between
airplane boardings and growth reflects access or consumer amenities is
to replace the number of boardings per capita with an indicator variable
for whether a metropolitan area has a major airport. We constructed a
dummy variable for having a major airport, with "major"
defined as one of the fifty airports in the country with the most
flights per day. Regressions 5-5 and 5-6 in table 5 show that having a
major airport did have a positive but modest effect on population and
income growth in the 1990s.
Although new transport technologies such as airports still seem to
matter for urban growth, there is little evidence to suggest that
investments in older technologies such as rail have any impact on urban
success today. For example, Glaeser and Jesse Shapiro find that places
with more public transit usage grew less in the 1990s than those with
less usage. (47) This certainly casts some doubt on the view of public
transportation advocates that new rail systems have the same potential
to foster growth in the twenty-first century that they had in the
nineteenth.
There is no question that new transportation infrastructure has
been able to reduce the cost of moving people across space. This
suggests that local leaders who lobby for new forms of transportation
spending are not being foolish. However, it is less clear how
transportation's ability to make places should influence the
evaluation of national transportation projects. We turn to that issue
next.
Place and the Evaluation of Transportation Investment
When discussing the benefits of transportation investments, it is
typical for public officials to emphasize the ways in which a new
highway or rail line could turn their area around economically. The
previous discussion has suggested that these advocates have been right
in some cases. Yet the ability of transportation to make or break cities
does not necessarily change the rules by which transportation investment
should be evaluated. Transportation infrastructure can be seen both as
nontraded productive capital and as a consumer amenity that enters
directly into the utility function. In that case:
Proposition 3: In a social optimum, the social benefits of
transportation spending within an area,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
equal to the marginal cost of that spending. In a competitive
equilibrium, where marginal utility of income is constant across space,
the social benefit of transport spending in area i exceeds
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
This proposition implies that at the social optimum, transportation
spending should be evaluated according to its direct effect on consumer
welfare and firm productivity, not according to its place-making
potential. This result reflects the fact that in a social optimum,
population is directly optimized across space. In a competitive
equilibrium there can be place-making benefits from transportation, but
these benefits result only if the externalities are higher in particular
locales. Unsurprisingly, the ability of transportation to move people
across space has value only if moving people across space is desirable.
The previous section gave only a little guidance about where those
externalities might be higher. There may be productivity gains from
moving people to richer areas, and the negative externalities of
population growth might be lower in places that are already denser, but
these effects are weak. They do, however, provide a benchmark for
thinking about current transportation spending. Should transportation be
subsidized disproportionately in rich, dense areas?
Table 6 reports, for several different modes of transport, the
correlations between transport spending per capita and measures of
agglomeration--population size and population density--and income.
Highways are the dominant recipient of federal aid to transportation.
The table shows federal transfers for highways both with and without the
gasoline tax payments that the states make to the national
transportation trust fund. The results suggest that the United States
subsidizes long-distance transportation in lower-density and
lower-income places, which is exactly the opposite of the model's
predictions. Transportation policy seems to be working against, rather
than toward, taking advantage of agglomeration economies. Environmental
externalities probably also push toward higher-density development that
involves driving over shorter distances. (48)
Of course, if the direct benefits from transportation spending are
greater in poorer, low-density areas, then current spending patterns
make sense. Indeed, the major point of this section is that
transportation needs to be evaluated according to its impact on travel
costs, and nothing we have said suggests that the current distribution
of highway spending fails to meet this criterion. However, if one
includes the place-making effects of transportation when evaluating its
benefits, then current spending does not appear to be targeting the
high-income, high-density areas where the agglomeration effects are
likely to be strongest.
Urban Renewal, the Appalachian Regional Commission, and Empowerment
Zones
Americans have rarely embraced a wholesale regional policy
dedicated toward reinvigorating declining regions. Despite regular calls
from mayors and even promises from presidential candidates, only in a
few instances has the U.S. government explicitly embraced policies meant
to turn around declining areas. In this the United States stands in
stark contrast to many European countries, which have regularly invested
heavily in their poorer regions since before the formation of the
European Union. For example, Italy has a long-standing policy of using
tax incentives to encourage investment in its south. Such policies have
been a particularly important activity for the European Union, which has
regularly redistributed funds from wealthy areas to poor ones.
The supporters of place-based policies have generally argued for
such policies on the basis of two related arguments. The first is purely
egalitarian: place-based support for poor places may create more
economic opportunity for poorer people. The second invokes some market
failure that is causing a particular place to underperform. For example,
it is sometimes alleged that the need for coordinated investments makes
it impossible for private firms on their own to turn a declining area
around. In the framework of the model, this can be understood as
claiming that agglomeration economies are particularly strong for such
places. Yet our empirical work in the previous section found little
evidence to support that claim.
Against these arguments, economists argue that place-based policies
are unlikely to be of material help to poor people. Place-based policies
that aim to turn a declining region around are often thought to be
futile, since the forces of urban change are quite powerful. Place-based
policies that throw enough resources at a small enough community may
indeed be able to improve the quality of that place, but it is not
obvious that the poorer residents of that community will benefit. Some
community-based policies may just lead employers to come to the area and
hire new migrants. Others may make the community a more attractive place
for outsiders to live and thus increase rental costs for longer-term
residents. In general, the spatial equilibrium model leads economists to
think that place-based improvements increase the value of property,
which may be a good thing for local homeowners and landlords, but may
not be so desirable for renters.
Finally, economists have voiced a basic skepticism about the desire
to induce poor people to stay in poor areas. Place-based policies may
boost a poor area, but they may also discourage poor people from leaving
that area for areas where opportunities may be greater. The rationale
for spending federal dollars to try to encourage less advantaged people
to stay in economically weak places is itself extremely weak. For
example, it is not clear why the federal government spent over $100
billion after Hurricane Katrina to bring people back to New Orleans, a
city that was hardly a beacon of economic opportunity before the storm.
In U.S. history the major instances of regional policy have been
the Appalachian Regional Commission (ARC), which targeted development of
a large area in the eastern United States; the enterprise zones and
Empowerment Zones of the 1980s and 1990s, which offered tax breaks to
firms locating in poorer communities; and policies aimed at urban
renewal. The last class of policies was primarily oriented toward
housing and construction, and so we will consider them in the next
section. We turn first to the ARC.
The Appalachian Experience
In 1963 Harry Caudill published Night Comes to the Cumberlands,
which described the rural poverty of the Cumberland Plateau of eastern
Kentucky. (49) Caudill's book brought national attention to
Appalachia and suggested that the region's problems were the fault
of northern coal investors who had taken the wealth out of the ground
and then invested their returns elsewhere. Needless to say, this
argument works better as rhetoric than as sound economic analysis--the
policy implications of the spatial equilibrium model are not changed if
rentiers live outside the regions where they receive their rents.
Even before Caudill's book, the governors of several
Appalachian states had started a coordinated effort to obtain federal
assistance, and President John Kennedy responded in 1963 by forming the
Appalachian Regional Commission. The ARC was originally founded to seek
legislation to provide assistance for the region. In 1965 Congress
turned the ARC into a federal agency that would distribute funds among
the Appalachian counties, to be used for a variety of local projects
intended to enhance economic vitality. Transportation accounted for a
particularly large share of this funding, so the ARC should be seen as a
hybrid between a pure transportation program and a local economic
development program.
The political definition of Appalachia was county-based, and the
area covered by the ARC stretched from Mississippi to New York. The
inclusion of so many states helped to create a legislative coalition for
the policy, but it inevitably meant that funding per acre was modest. In
the first thirty years after it was founded, the ARC disbursed $13
billion. (50) Today the ARC receives much less funding, about $90
million a year.
Did the billions spent on the ARC have a demonstrable effect on
Appalachian success? Andrew Isserman and Terance Rephann address this
question by comparing income and population growth for a matched sample
of Appalachian and non-Appalachian counties. (51) They use a matching
algorithm to connect counties that were in the Appalachian region with
other areas. The study specifically excluded counties that were close to
Appalachia as possible matches because of fears of contamination from
the ARC. As a result, Allegheny County, Pennsylvania, was matched with
Erie County, New York, which contains Buffalo, and Catoosa County,
Georgia, was matched with Warren County, in southwestern Ohio. Comparing
the growth experiences of the two samples, the authors find that income
in the Appalachian counties grew by 5 percent more than in their
comparison counties between 1969 and 1991, and income per capita 17
percent more. Their bottom line is quite remarkable: they find that $13
billion in Appalachian expenditure yielded $8.4 billion of income in one
year alone. This appears to be a quite positive demonstration of the
efficacy of regional policy.
Since Isserman and Rephann's methods are sufficiently
different from those used in most economic analyses, we repeat their
exercise using a more standard regression methodology. Our approach is
to include all counties in any state that was partly included in the
ARC, except those counties within 90 kilometers (56 miles) of the coast.
We then use a dummy variable to identify those counties covered by the
ARC. We are thus comparing Appalachian counties with reasonably
comparable counties in the same region. We examine both income growth
and population growth. We include only the initial values as controls,
but the results are not sensitive to including other controls.
Table 7 presents our results. The first regression finds that
between 1970 and 1980, being part of the ARC coverage area was
associated with 0.037 log point faster population growth--evidence of a
treatment effect on population during this first decade. Between 1970
and 2000, however (the second regression), the dummy variable for
location in the ARC area has a coefficient of -0.002, which is small and
statistically insignificant. The remaining two regressions report the
relationship between inclusion in the ARC and growth in income per
capita. We find an insignificant positive effect in the 1970s, which
turns negative over the longer period. One possible interpretation of
these results is that although the ARC was able to boost population
growth slightly during the period in which it was best funded, the
effect soon disappeared.
Given that Issermann and Rephann found quite different results, we
do not claim to have proved that the ARC had no effect. Indeed, the
standard errors on our coefficients are sufficiently large that we
cannot rule out large positive effects of the program, at least relative
to its modest cost. A more supportable conclusion is that it is unlikely
that the effects of a $13 billion program spread over a giant swath of
America over three decades can be accurately evaluated. Far too many
things were affecting regional growth at the same time for a relatively
modest government program to have had clear positive effects. Powerful
economic forces are driving people to the Sunbelt and to coastal cities.
Current spending on the ARC is no more than the cost of a few large
Manhattan buildings. Could such a program really have changed the course
of a region considerably larger than California? The ARC may or may not
be cost effective, but there is little chance that its effectiveness
will ever be evident in the data.
Enterprise and Empowerment Zones
We now turn to a much more targeted approach: enterprise zones. As
Leslie Papke summarizes, enterprise zones were pioneered in the United
Kingdom by Margaret Thatcher's government in 1981. (52) There were
originally eleven such zones, but the number later increased to
twenty-five. The British zones were particularly oriented toward
industrial development. Firms that located in the zones were exempted
from local property taxes and could deduct all spending on industrial
buildings from corporate income tax. This tax relief was accompanied by
significant public sector investment in the area.
Although plenty of economic activity occurred in the enterprise
zones, evaluations of the zones were largely negative. Roger Tym
suggests that most of the jobs in these zones did not represent new
activity but simply a reallocation within the metropolitan area. (53)
John Schwarz and Thomas Volgy estimate a cost per job created of $67,000
during the 1980s, which would be more than $125,000 in 2007 dollars.
(54) Rodney Erickson and Paul Syms find a moderate increase in land
prices within the enterprise zones. (55)
In the United States the enterprise zone experience begins with
state enterprise zones in the 1980s. Papke reports that thirty-seven
states had created such zones by the early 1990s. (56) Unlike the
British zones, the American enterprise zones were particularly oriented
toward revitalization of urban neighborhoods and were, in some sense,
the descendants of the urban renewal projects described below. The zones
were often quite small--the median zone had 4,500 residents--and they
were quite poor.
Papke's own evaluation focused on the Indiana enterprise zone
system, which exempted businesses in the zones from property taxes and
taxes on income from inside the zone. There was also a tax credit for
hiring workers who lived within the zone and an income tax credit for
zone residents. Despite these considerable tax incentives, and despite
an increase in business inventories within the zones, Papke finds that
the zones actually lost population and income relative to nonzone areas.
Certainly, this should not be interpreted as a true negative treatment
effect of zones, but rather as evidence that the Indiana zones were
relatively ineffective.
In the 1990s the federal government began its own system of areas
called Empowerment Zones, administered by the Department of Housing and
Urban Development (HUD). There were six original Empowerment Zones; two
more were added later. Firms in the zones received employment tax
credits and regulatory waivers. There were also block grants and
spending on infrastructure. The overall cost of the program was slightly
more than $3 billion. (57)
Busso and Kline undertake a particularly careful analysis of the
federal zones' impact. They compare the zones with similar areas
chosen from among communities that also applied to HUD to receive
Empowerment Zone support. Busso and Kline use a propensity score method
to match these communities appropriately and find strong positive
results. Although the populations of the zones did not increase, the
poverty rate fell by an average of 5 percentage points and the
unemployment rate by an average of 4 percentage points in these
communities relative to comparable outside areas. Housing prices
increased by 0.22 log point and rents by 0.077 log point. There was no
appreciable increase in earnings.
On one level these results seem much more promising than
Papke's findings, but there are still reasons to be skeptical.
First, the authors estimate that a program costing more than $3 billion
created 27,000 jobs between 1995 and 2000. This comes to more than
$100,000 per job in current dollars, which seems an expensive way to
boost employment. The figure of 27,000 jobs refers to the employment
increase in 2000. If 27,000 extra jobs were created in every year, then
each job-year would have cost $20,000. The $3 billion figure includes
substantial private money, however, so it is not clear whether this
should be counted as an actual cost. The answer depends on whether this
money reaped private returns and whether it was induced by other federal
programs, such as the Community Reinvestment Act. Nevertheless, the true
cost per year is probably below the $100,000 number.
For already-employed workers in Empowerment Zones who were renters,
earnings did not increase, but rents did. Perhaps other amenities rose
in the Empowerment Zones, but for this group the zones represent a pure
financial loss.
Busso and Kline themselves suggest that the program generated a
$1.1 billion increase in output and a $1.2 billion increase in the value
of homes and rental properties. These two estimates should not be added,
since the housing values are presumably capturing the value of having
access to a more successful labor market. Indeed, one view is that the
closeness of these figures reflects the fact that both are capturing the
same gains. However, in the case of housing values these gains would
omit benefits to previous residents who are not changing their behavior
due to the program. Nevertheless, these gains do seem to be
substantially less than the cost of the program.
Overall, the evidence on enterprise zones is hardly overwhelming.
The British evidence shows positive effects, but the price per job
created is extremely high. The Indiana evidence shows essentially no
effects on key social outcomes. The evidence on federal Empowerment
Zones shows significant employment gains from the programs, but the
price per job is again extremely high. It is hard to see an empirical
case for zone-based policy.
It is harder still to evaluate more amorphous government policies
such as those embodied in the Community Reinvestment Act of 1977 (CRA).
This act required financial institutions to invest in businesses in poor
areas as well as rich areas and to make credit available to poorer
people. It can be argued that economic efficiency would be better served
by allowing banks to focus on lending to firms that are most likely to
be most productive rather than firms that have a particular geographic
locale. However, one could also argue that the CRA served equity
purposes and had only a small negative effect on overall financial
efficiency. Without more thorough evaluation--and it would be hard to
imagine how to produce such an evaluation--it is difficult to come to
any strong conclusions about the CRA.
An alternative way of understanding enterprise zones and certain
other place-based policies is as a means of reducing taxes on nontraded
business inputs such as real estate. Optimal taxation theory suggests
that it makes sense to have lower tax rates in areas where these inputs
are more elastic. Enterprise zones can be justified if the supply of the
nontraded output is more elastic in depressed areas. However, we know of
no evidence that this is the case.
Another interpretation of enterprise zones is as an indirect means
of freeing local businesses from paying for social services for poor
residents of their community. If one thinks of those social services as
a national responsibility whose costs must be borne by someone, then
making the residents of one community pay disproportionately for those
services will be distortionary. These taxes will induce lower input
demand in that area, which will lead to too little production there
relative to the first-best outcome. A similar conclusion results if one
taxes the rich in a community to pay for services to the poor in that
community. Such a policy will lead the rich to live elsewhere, which is
also a distortion relative to the first-best. Reducing the added
governmental costs of locating near poor people may reduce the
tax-created distortions that induce firms and people to leave poor
places.
To sum up, the combination of theory and evidence leads us to be
suspicious of local economic policies that are meant to increase
production in a particular area, whether that area is depressed or
booming. Empirically, these policies seem to be either extremely
expensive or ineffective. Theoretically, the case for these policies
depends either on extra agglomeration economies in depressed areas or on
a particularly high elasticity of demand for inputs in those areas.
These conditions may exist, or they may not. There is, however, a case
for reconsidering policies that require local businesses and workers to
pay for social services for the local poor in a way that essentially
amounts to redistribution.