Trade and wages, reconsidered.
Krugman, Paul R.
ABSTRACT Standard economic analysis predicts that increased U.S.
trade with unskilled labor-abundant countries should reduce the relative
wages of U.S. unskilled labor, but empirical studies in the 1990s found
only a modest effect. Has the situation changed in this decade, given
the surge in imports from very low wage countries? In fact, most of this
increase has been in skill-intensive goods such as computers, so that
one would expect little additional impact on U.S. relative wages.
However, developing countries appear to be specializing in unskilled
labor-intensive niches within these industries. If so, the effect on
wage inequality could still be significant. The paper develops a model
and a numerical example showing that when developing countries can take
over the unskilled labor-intensive portions of vertically specialized
industries, the consequences can closely resemble the textbook effect.
But determining the actual impact will require more finely disaggregated factor content data than are currently available.
**********
There has been a great transformation in the nature of world trade
over the past three decades. Before the late 1970s, developing countries
overwhelmingly exported primary products rather than manufactured goods;
one relic of that era is that people still sometimes refer to wealthy
nations as "industrial countries," when in fact industry
currently accounts for almost twice as large a share of GDP in China as
in the United States. Since then, however, developing countries have
increasingly become major exporters of manufactured goods, and latterly
of selected services as well.
From the beginning of this transformation it was apparent to
international economists that the new pattern of trade might pose
problems for low-wage workers in wealthy nations. Standard textbook
analysis says that to the extent that trade is driven by international
differences in factor abundance, the classic analysis of Wolfgang
Stolper and Paul Samuelson, which shows that trade can have very strong
effects on income distribution, should apply. (1) In particular, if
trade with unskilled labor-abundant countries leads to a reduction in
the relative price of unskilled labor-intensive goods, this should,
other things equal, reduce the real wages of less educated workers, both
relative to other workers and in absolute terms. And in the 1980s, as
the United States began to experience a marked rise in inequality,
including a growing gap in wages between skilled and unskilled workers,
it was natural to think that growing imports of unskilled
labor-intensive goods from low-wage countries might be a major culprit.
But is the effect of trade on wages quantitatively important? A
number of studies conducted during the 1990s concluded that the effects
of North-South trade on inequality were modest. Table 1 summarizes
several well-known estimates, together with one crucial aspect of each:
the date of the latest data incorporated in the estimate.
For a variety of reasons, possibly including a reduction in
concerns about wages during the economic boom of the later 1990s, the
focus of discussion in international economics then shifted away from
the distributional effects of trade in manufactured goods with
developing countries. When concerns about trade began to make headlines
again, they tended to focus on the new and novel aspects of trade--in
particular the phenomenon of services outsourcing, which Alan Blinder,
in a much-quoted popular article, (2) went so far as to call part of a
new Industrial Revolution.
Until recently, however, surprisingly little attention was given to
how increasingly out of date the data are behind the reassuring
consensus that trade has only modest effects on income distribution. Yet
the problem is obvious and was in fact noted by Federal Reserve chairman
Ben Bernanke last year: "Unfortunately, much of the available
empirical research on the influence of trade on earnings inequality
dates from the 1980s and 1990s and thus does not address later
developments." (3) And there have been a lot of later developments.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 shows U.S. imports of manufactured goods as a percentage
of GDP since 1989, split between imports from developing countries and
imports from developed countries. (4) It turns out that developing
country imports have roughly doubled as a share of the U.S. economy
since the studies that concluded that the effect of trade on income
inequality was modest. This seems, at first glance, to suggest that
estimates of this effect should be scaled up accordingly. Josh Bivens
has done just that with the simple model I offered in my 1995 Brookings
Paper, concluding that the distributional effects of trade are now much
larger. (5)
There is another aspect to the change in trade: the developing
countries that account for most of the expansion in trade since the
early 1990s have substantially lower average wages, relative to wages in
developed countries, than the developing countries that were the main
focus of concern in the original literature. In particular, China's
average hourly compensation in manufacturing is estimated by the Bureau
of Labor Statistics (BLS) to be only 3 percent of the U.S. level at the
current exchange rate. (6) Again, this shift to lower-wage sources of
imports seems to suggest that the distributional effects of trade may
well be considerably larger now than they were in the early 1990s.
But should one jump to the conclusion that although the effects of
trade on distribution were not serious then, they are now? It turns out
that there is a problem: although the aggregate picture suggests that
the distributional effects of trade should have gotten substantially
larger, detailed calculations of the factor content of trade--which
played a key role in some earlier analyses--do not seem to support that
conclusion. This result, in turn, rests on what appears in the data to
be a marked increase in the sophistication of the goods the United
States imports from developing countries--in particular, a sharp
increase in imports of computers and electronic products compared with
traditional unskilled labor--intensive goods such as apparel.
Robert Lawrence, in a recent study that shares the same motivation
as this paper, essentially concludes from the evidence on factor content
and the apparently rising sophistication of developing country imports
that the rapid growth of these imports has not, in fact, been a source
of rising inequality. (7) But this conclusion is, in my view, too quick
to dismiss what seems like an important paradox. On one side, the United
States and other developed countries have seen a surge in imports from
countries that are substantially poorer and more abundant in unskilled
labor than the developing country exporters that created so much anxiety
a dozen years ago. On the other side, the United States seems to be
importing goods that are more skilled labor intensive and less unskilled
labor intensive than before. As I will show, the most important source
of this paradox lies in the information technology sector: for the most
part there remains a clear tendency for developing countries to export
unskilled labor--intensive products, but the large exports of computers
and electronics from the developing world stand out as a clear anomaly.
One possible resolution of this seeming paradox is to argue that
the data on which factor content estimates are based suffer from severe
aggregation problems--that developing countries are specializing in
unskilled labor intensive niches within otherwise skilled
labor--intensive sectors, especially in computers and electronics. I
will make that case later in the paper, while admitting that the
evidence is fragmentary. If this is the correct interpretation, however,
the effect of rapid trade growth on wage inequality may indeed have been
significant.
Just to be clear: even if growing trade has in fact had significant
distributional effects, that is a long way from saying that calls for
import protection are justified. First of all, although supporting the
real wages of less educated U.S. workers should be a goal of policy, it
is not the goal: for example, sustaining a world trading system that
permits development by very poor countries is also an important policy
consideration. Second, as generations of economists have argued, the
first-best response to the adverse distributional effects of trade is to
compensate the losers, rather than to restrict trade. Yet whether trade
is, in fact, having significant distributional effects, rather than
being an all-round good thing, clearly matters.
The remainder of this paper is in four parts. The first part offers
an overview of the changes in U.S. trade with developing countries, in a
way that sets the stage for the later puzzle. The second part describes
the theoretical basis for analyzing the distributional effects of trade,
and then shows how calculations at the aggregate level and factor
content analysis yield divergent conclusions. The third part turns to
the case for aggregation problems and the implications of vertical
specialization within industries. The final part considers the
implications both for further research and for policy.
The Changing Pattern of Trade
Figure 1 showed the dramatic rise in U.S. imports of manufactured
goods from developing countries since 1989. One qualification that needs
to be made right away is that to some extent this rise reflects the
movement of the United States into massive trade deficit. The
theoretical analysis later in this paper suggests that the average of
imports and exports may be a better guide to the likely distributional
effects than imports alone. Figure 2 shows this average as a percentage
of GDP for U.S. trade in manufactured goods with developing and
developed countries; the rise in developing country trade is slightly
less dramatic, but still impressive. Figure 2 also shows that 2006
marked a watershed: in that year, for the first time, the United States
began doing more total trade in manufactured goods with developing
countries than with other developed countries.
This rapid growth in U.S. trade with developing countries mainly
took the form of increased trade with countries that were only minor
players in the early 1990s. At the time of the earlier literature on
trade and income distribution, North-South trade in manufactures still,
to a large extent, involved the original four Asian "tigers":
Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan. Since then, however,
growth in U.S. trade with developing countries has principally involved
China, Mexico, and some smaller players. Figure 3 is an area chart of
U.S. manufactured imports from developing countries, again as a
percentage of GDP; it shows a modest relative decline for the original
tigers and a large rise for Mexico and especially China.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
This changing direction of North-South trade has one immediate
implication: the countries where growth in trade is occurring today have
even lower average wages than those where the growth was occurring in
the early 1990s. Thus, the aspect of this trade that initially attracted
so much (often hostile) attention has, from the critics'
perspective, only gotten worse. In 1990, according to BLS estimates,
average hourly compensation in manufacturing in the four tigers was 25
percent of the U.S. level, and by 1995 that figure had risen to 39
percent. But as of 2005 the BLS estimated that hourly compensation in
Mexico was only 11 percent of the U.S. level, and in China, as already
mentioned, it was slightly more than 3 percent.
As a result, one trend often cited in the early 1990s as a reason
to discount fears about the effect of trade on wages--the rise in the
average wage of U.S. trading partners relative to the U.S. level--has
gone into reverse. Table 2 lists the top ten U.S. trading partners and
the average hourly compensation of manufacturing workers in those
countries, weighted by the value of bilateral trade and expressed as a
percentage of the U.S. level, since 1975. This measure did indeed rise
from 1975 to 1990, reflecting rising relative wages both in developed
country trading partners and in the original Asian tiger economies.
Since 1990, however, the rapidly rising weight of China and, to a lesser
extent, Mexico has driven the index down by approximately 20 percent.
(8)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
What accounts for the rapid growth of manufactured imports from
these new players? China's economy, at least, has grown very
rapidly, and one might imagine that the growth of China's exports
simply reflects that. Simple gravity models, in which trade between any
pair of countries reflects the product of their GDPs, adjusted for the
distance between them, generally work quite well and have become a
standard tool for interpreting the overall pattern of trade. Such a
model would lead one to expect U.S. imports from China as a percentage
of GDP to have risen, other things equal, in proportion to the ratio of
Chinese to U.S. GDP.
In fact, however, U.S. imports from China have risen much more
rapidly than the growth of the Chinese economy, on its own, would have
led one to expect. Table 3 compares the growth in Chinese and Mexican
GDP with growth in imports from each country, both as a percentage of
U.S. GDP. Chinese GDP, at market exchange rates, has tripled relative to
U.S. GDP, but U.S. imports of manufactured goods from China have
increased almost eightfold as a percentage of GDP. Mexico's GDP as
a percentage of U.S. GDP has risen about 40 percent, but Mexico's
manufactured exports to the United States have tripled relative to U.S.
GDP.
The obvious explanation of this "excess growth" in
manufactured exports is that it reflects reduced barriers to trade,
which have led to greater international specialization and hence greater
trade. In the case of Mexico, it is natural to suppose that NAFTA has
played an important role, although much of the growth in Mexican exports
may also reflect two other factors: the delayed effects of Mexico's
dramatic unilateral liberalization of trade between 1985 and 1988, and
the weak peso that followed the 1994-95 financial crisis.
In the case of China, there is no comparable break in policy.
However, work by David Hummels, Jun Ishii, and Kei-Mu Yi suggests that
even modest declines in trade costs can lead to large increases in the
volume of trade by encouraging vertical specialization--the breakup of
the production process into geographically separate stages. (9) Thus
rapid growth in Chinese exports might reflect declines in the cost of
international communication and shipping.
One piece of evidence that may support the view that rapid growth
in imports from developing countries reflects declining trade costs,
both explicit and implicit, is the changing composition of these
imports. A quick way to see the extent of this change in composition is
to rely on a distinction introduced by Jason Faberman. (10) In analyzing
job losses and gains, Faberman distinguishes a group of
"trade-sensitive" industries (at the NAICS three-digit level)
with very large import shares that also corresponds quite well to goods
traditionally exported by developing countries. Figure 4 shows the
long-term trend in U.S. imports of manufactured goods from developing
countries as a percentage of GDP, divided between
"trade-sensitive" and other goods. Even in 1989, it turns out,
traditional developing country manufactured exports accounted for less
than half of all U.S. imports from developing countries. More to the
point, however, the bulk of the growth in imports since then has come
from nontraditional sectors.
What are these nontraditional goods? Figure 5 shows the change over
the same period in imports from developing countries as a percentage of
U.S. GDP by three-digit NAICS sector, from largest to smallest. What is
striking here, of course, is the extraordinary growth in imports of
computers and electronics.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Modeling the Effects of Trade on Income Distribution
There have been two major waves of innovation in international
trade theory over the roughly thirty years since developing country
exports of manufactured goods began to be a significant concern: the
increasing-returns, imperfect-competition revolution of the 1980s, and
the more recent focus on interfirm differences in productivity and
propensity to export within industries. It is not clear, however, how to
apply the insights of either set of ideas to the question of the
distributional effects of developing country exports. As a result, most
analysis of this issue continues to rely on the simple factor
proportions model assuming perfect competition.
The first key insight from this model is the Stolper-Samuelson
relationship between goods prices and factor prices. Consider a world in
which there are two factors of production, skilled labor and unskilled
labor, and two goods produced competitively under constant returns to
scale, a skilled labor-intensive good X and an unskilled
labor--intensive good Y. Assume that workers move freely between firms
and industries, so that all workers of each type receive the same wage.
Finally, assume provisionally that an economy produces both goods. Then
there is a one-to-one relationship between the relative prices P of the
two goods and the relative wages w of the two types of labor. Letting a
"hat" represent proportional rates of change, where
[[theta].sub.SX] and [[theta].sub.SY] are the shares of skilled labor in
the production cost of X and Y, respectively.
[[??].sub.X] - [[??].sub.Y] = ([[theta].sub.SX] - [[theta].sub.SY])
([[??].sub.S] - [[??].sub.U]),
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figure 6 completes the story. The left panel shows the relationship
between relative goods prices and relative factor prices. The right
panel shows the relationship between factor prices and the ratio of
skilled to unskilled labor used in production. In each industry a rise
in the relative wage of skilled workers leads to a fall in the ratio of
skilled to unskilled workers. This is one way to see the logic behind
the Stolper-Samuelson result. As long as the country continues to
produce both goods, a rise in the relative price of the skilled
labor-intensive good must lead to a rise in the relative wages of
skilled workers. This implies a fall in the ratio of skilled to
unskilled workers in both industries--and hence a fall in the marginal
productivity of unskilled workers in terms of both goods. And that, in
turn, means that the real wage of unskilled workers unambiguously falls.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
One more point about this analysis is worth noting: the
Stolper-Samuelson process involves a complex reshuffling of resources
between industries. Consider what happens, according to this model, if
the relative price of X rises. Production within each industry becomes
less skill intensive, yet total employment of both factors remains
unchanged because the industrial mix of production shifts toward
skill-intensive industries. This is not a process one should expect to
play out in full in the short run; the moral I would take from this is
that the Stolper-Samuelson theorem should not be taken too seriously
when interpreting data over short periods, say, five years.
But the focus of this paper is on a somewhat longer period--the
years since the early 1990s, whose data were the basis for the
relatively benign estimates of the effect of trade on wages that still
dominate discussion. Are the data since then consistent with a strong
Stolper-Samuelson effect? At first glance, the answer appears to be yes.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Consider first how prices have changed. The BLS publishes price
indices of manufactured imports from developing and developed countries.
If it is assumed that developing countries mainly export unskilled
labor--intensive goods to the United States whereas developed countries
export skilled labor--intensive goods (an assumption to be confirmed,
with a major asterisk--the case of computers and electronics--in the
next section), the ratio of these prices should offer a measure of the
relative price of unskilled labor--intensive goods. Figure 7 shows the
logarithm of this ratio, normalized so that 1995 = 0. There indeed seems
to have been a substantial decline in the relative price of unskilled
labor--intensive goods since the mid- 1990s.
Consider next changes in relative wages. Figure 8 shows two widely
used indicators of wage differentials: the 90-50 ratio of hourly wages
and the college-noncollege ratio. Both are shown for men only, to
abstract from changes in sex differentials; both are also expressed in
logarithms, normalized so that 1995 = 0. Both measures have risen
substantially since 1995.
Lawrence, however, reaches a different conclusion, arguing that
trends in relative wages are not consistent with a trade-driven story.
(11) This difference in interpretation arises, I believe, from two
factors. First, Lawrence uses earnings data aggregated across sexes,
which do not show as strong a rise in inequality as the male-only data.
(Goldin and Katz, using fixed weights by sex and age, find a continuing
rise in both college-noncollege and 90-50 inequality. (12)) Second, he
focuses primarily on the period since 2000 rather than the longer
stretch since the mid-1990s.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
I would argue that this short-term focus is problematic in two
respects. First, on general principles it is not clear what one learns
from very short term movements in relative wages. As argued above, the
adjustment implied by the Stolper-Samuelson theorem involves a complex
reallocation of resources across industries, making it unsuitable for
short-term analysis. Second, and more specifically, the period since
1995 includes a major boom-bust cycle in high-technology industries. The
technology bubble of the late 1990s probably elevated the education
premium, and the subsequent bust caused that premium to deflate. As a
result, inferences from the movement in inequality during the first few
years after the technology bust should be taken with a grain of salt.
Perhaps the more general point is that Stolper-Samuelson is a ceteris
paribus proposition and as such cannot be refuted--or, to be sure,
confirmed--from the movement of relative wages alone.
That said, the combination of the price changes shown in figure 7
and the wage changes shown in figure 8 does look reasonably supportive
of the proposition that rapid growth in North-South trade since the
studies of the mid-1990s has made the effects on inequality
substantially larger. There is, however, a big problem with that
conclusion: when one uses the methods I and others applied to the
subject of trade and wages in the 1990s to more recent data, the results
do not, at least on first appearances, fit the story.
There was a fairly heated dispute in the 1990s over the appropriate
way to analyze the effects of North-South trade on wages. Some
economists, notably Edward Leamer, (13) argued that since the
relationship shown in figure 6 is between goods prices and factor
prices, the only legitimate approach is to rely on price information,
rather than on the volume of trade, which is endogenous. Others, myself
included, argued that this represented a confusion between the question
of how best to present models and the question of how to construct the
appropriate thought experiment for analysis: it makes sense to present
Stolper-Samuelson as a goods-price, factor-price relationship, but in
the real world prices are as endogenous as trade volumes. The
appropriate method, I argued, (14) was "but for" analysis:
compare goods and factor prices with an estimate of what they would have
been but for the opportunity to engage in manufactures trade with
developing countries. And this but-for analysis inevitably leans
strongly on calculations involving trade volumes.
Figure 9 illustrates that thought experiment from my 1995 paper. As
in figure 6, I assume that there are two goods, one skilled labor
intensive, one unskilled labor intensive. The curve PPF represents the
production possibilities of the developed world in the aggregate. If it
were not possible to trade skilled labor-intensive goods for unskilled
labor-intensive imports from developing countries--that is, but for the
possibility of North-South trade--equilibrium would be at the autarkic point A. In fact, however, this possibility exists; the opportunities
for trade with newly industrializing economies are represented by the
offer curve NIEO. As a result, equilibrium production is at Q, and
equilibrium consumption is at C, with the line PP representing relative
prices in trade. The relative price of skilled labor--intensive goods is
higher, and that of unskilled labor-intensive goods lower, than would
obtain in the absence of trade. Hence the Stolper-Samuelson effect
applies.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
In the original analysis I created an extremely simple computable
general equilibrium model to calculate a back-of-the-envelope estimate
of this but-for effect. This appears at first sight to be a
significantly different approach from analyses such as that of George
Borjas, Richard Freeman, and Lawrence Katz, (15) who instead try to
calculate the factor content of trade--the factors of production
embodied in imports and exports. However, in my later work, (16) it
became apparent that the factor content approach, interpreted carefully,
is fully consistent with an analysis based on trade flows and their
effect on relative prices.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Figure 10 shows how this reconciliation can be carried out. Imagine
holding goods prices constant while altering the economy's factor
endowment, subtracting skilled labor while adding unskilled labor. This
would have the effect of shifting the production possibility frontier
inward at the lower right, but upward at the upper left, as illustrated
by the shift from the production possibility frontier [PPF.sub.1] to
[PPF.sub.2]. Production would also shift, at constant goods prices,
toward less output of the skilled labor-intensive good and more of the
unskilled labor-intensive good. More specifically, suppose that at the
initial factor prices the value of factors added is equal to the value
of factors subtracted. Then production would shift northwest up the
relative price line PP. If the change in factor endowments is
sufficiently large, production will reach point C; that is, production
will match consumption, so that trade is eliminated. And what is this
change in factor endowments? It is precisely equal to the factor content
of the initial volume of trade, as measured using the factor content of
each good's production per dollar of value in the developed economy
(not in the developing economy) under the actual trading regime.
Now, having added the factor content of trade to the developed
economy, thereby eliminating the need for actual trade, imagine a
further thought experiment in which, first, the possibility of trade is
eliminated, and then the change in factor endowments is reversed. This
would shift the production possibility frontier back to [PPF.sub.1], but
because trade is no longer possible, consumption, production, and
relative prices would end up at the original autarky point A.
This may seem rather roundabout, but what it says is the following:
the but-for thought experiment of eliminating North-South trade has the
same effect on wages as another thought experiment that takes a
nontrading economy whose resources include the actual economy's
factor endowment plus the factor content of the actual economy's
trade, and then eliminates that difference in factor endowments. In this
sense, then, the factor content approach, carefully interpreted, is
equivalent to the but-for trade analysis.
There are two advantages to thinking about the issue in terms of
factor content. One is that it simplifies the interpretation of any
structural model. In general, the results of any such model depend on
all the parameters: factor shares in production, goods shares in
spending, and all the relevant elasticities of substitution in both
production and consumption. However, thinking in terms of factor content
makes it clear that these parameters matter only insofar as they affect
one derived number, the aggregate elasticity of substitution between
skilled and unskilled labor. This simplifies sensitivity analysis and in
general helps clarify interpretation. (17)
The other advantage of thinking in terms of factor content is that
it simplifies the task of empirical work--or at least it seemed to do so
in the past. Rather than having to calibrate a full model, the
researcher can simply estimate the factor content of trade, which is
informative in itself, and assess likely impacts by examining the
implications of alternative aggregate elasticities of substitution.
All of this assumes that one can do a reasonably good job of
measuring factor content. Before attempting that, however, it is useful
to extend the analysis to allow for an important feature of U.S. trade,
especially recently: large trade deficits.
Figures 9 and l0 are real-trade theory diagrams, assuming, as must
be the case under standard real-trade models, that trade is balanced.
Clearly that is not a reasonable assumption for the United States today,
which runs large trade deficits financed by capital inflows. (Around
2005 a rough description of the U.S. economy would have been that
Americans made a living selling each other houses, paying for them with
money borrowed from China.) However, it is possible to use the factor
content approach under conditions of trade deficit by making two further
assumptions. The first is that the effects of capital inflows on demand
are equivalent to a transfer payment to domestic households. (That is,
capital inflows are spent in the same way as domestically earned
income.) The second is that all domestic consumers have identical
homothetic preferences, so that the composition of spending does not
depend on who is receiving income.
Under these assumptions the factor content exercise can be
represented by figure 11. Here the economy's actual production and
consumption are once again at Q and C, but this time the value of
consumption at world prices PP exceeds that of production. The
difference is the trade deficit, represented as a transfer of income to
domestic consumers. Again, it is possible to construct a hypothetical
economy that would produce the actual economy's consumption without
the need for trade; this can be done by adding the actual factor content
of trade to the original economy, which shifts the production
possibility frontier from [PPF.sub.1] to [PPF.sub.2]. The effect of
trade on factor prices can then be inferred by subtracting the factor
content of trade out again. Because of the assumption of homothetic
preferences, the effect on relative factor prices depends on the extent
to which the ratio of factors is altered in this exercise. In
particular, even if a country runs so large a trade deficit that it is
implicitly an importer of both skilled and unskilled labor, trade still
raises the skill premium as long as constructing the hypothetical
no-trade economy requires increasing the quantity of unskilled labor by
more, in percentage terms, than the quantity of skilled labor.
And now we get to the fundamental empirical puzzle. In the early to
mid-1990s, factor content exercises indicated a significant, if modest,
move in the expected direction. The most recent estimates, however,
suggest that the dramatic expansion of imports from low-wage countries
since 1990 has not significantly enlarged the factor content of trade.
Table 4 reports estimates of "job displacement" by
education level--another name for factor content--from Lawrence Mishel,
Jared Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto. (18) The estimates were
constructed using changes in the ratios of imports and exports to total
sales within each four-digit NAICS industry to estimate changes in sales
due to trade; these estimates were then run through the input-output
tables to estimate total implied changes in output; finally, estimates
of college- and non-college-educated labor per unit of output from U.S.
data were used to estimate the factor content of the lost output.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
What the estimate shows is that rising trade deficits have made the
United States a consistent importer of goods produced both by highly
educated and by less educated labor--that is, the U.S. picture looks
like figure 11, where factor content arises from a trade deficit as well
as from comparative advantage, rather than figure 10, where the only
effect is from comparative advantage. Nonetheless, before 1989 the
estimated effect of trade was a relative increase in the effective
supply of less educated labor.
Since then, however, the calculations of Mishel, Bernstein, and
Allegretto indicate little net effect of trade on relative effective
factor supplies. The obvious explanation lies in the trends illustrated
in figures 4 and 5: although the traditional manufactured exports of
developing countries to the United States are labor-intensive goods like
apparel, the growth in developing country exports has been concentrated
in nontraditional sectors, especially computers and electronics. As the
next section will show, the apparently strong comparative advantage of
developing countries in these industries seems anomalous--unless the
exports of developing countries are concentrated in unskilled
labor-intensive subsectors within these industries.
Within-Industry Specialization and the Problem of Interpretation
A useful overview of the seemingly anomalous nature of some
developing country exports can be obtained by using a technique
suggested by John Romalis. (19) Romalis provided impressive evidence of
the continuing relevance of Heckscher-Ohlin trade theory based on an
analysis of the sources of U.S. manufactured imports. He showed that the
United States does tend, systematically, to import skilled
labor-intensive goods from developed countries and unskilled
labor-intensive goods from developing countries, although the
relationship is far from perfect. He ascribed the imperfection to the
interaction of product differentiation and transport costs. (20) An
alternative interpretation, of course, is that the evidence is blurred by measurement error.
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Figure 12 is a simple Romalis scatterplot, deliberately conducted
at a relatively high level of aggregation. The data points are
three-digit NAICS industries. The horizontal axis shows skill intensity
as proxied by the share of nonproduction workers in employment. The
vertical axis shows the share of developing countries in U.S. imports
within the given industry. It is immediately apparent that most
industries fall along a downward-sloping "main sequence," in
which developing countries tend to export unskilled labor-intensive
goods, with apparel and other traditional developing country exports at
the upper left.
I have identified the industries that lie clearly off this main
sequence. The industries at the lower left pose little puzzle: the paper
and wood products industries are not very skill-intensive, but U.S.
imports within these industries are, for reasons of resource abundance
and geography, dominated by Canada. (They have lumberjacks, and
that's OK.) But what is one to make of NAICS 334, computer and
electronic products? In U.S. data it ranks as the most skill intensive
of industries, yet it is also an industry in which more than
three-quarters of imports come from developing countries, especially
China.
It seems a foregone conclusion that aggregation is a serious
problem here; why not use more disaggregated data? The answer is that
within the limits of current data, there is little that can be done.
First of all, factor content analyses are limited by the level of
disaggregation of the input-output table, which is at the four-digit
level. A four-digit version of figure 12 would look essentially the
same: all the components of NAICS 334 would remain in the upper right
comer. And even finer levels of disaggregation are of relatively little
help. To see why, consider the five six-digit sectors with the largest
U.S. value added within computers and electronics, which collectively
account for 57 percent of the total:
334413 Semiconductor and related device mfg.
334111 Electronic computer mfg.
33451 l Search, detection, navigation, and guidance instrument mfg.
334220 Radio and TV broadcasting and wireless communications equipment mfg.
334210 Telephone apparatus mfg.
These are not homogeneous sectors. They are, however, globalized
industries, and it is easy to find qualitative information suggesting a
division of labor between skill-intensive operations and less
skill-intensive operations within each industry. Consider the following
four examples.
Computers
There is a clear division between the types of computers produced
in emerging Asia--primarily relatively low-end, standardized
products--and those produced in developed countries. Probably even more
important, computer production involves many stages, which are commonly
split between developed and developing economies in a way clearly
related to skill intensity. This paper was written on a Lenovo notebook
computer. Lenovo, which took over the ThinkPad line from IBM, is
famously a Chinese firm whose headquarters and product planning operations are in North Carolina, and many of whose components are
produced in developed countries. These operations help make the computer
industry look highly skill intensive, if one relies on data from the
U.S. Census of Manufactures; this is not, however, a good representation
of what the industry looks like in China.
The standard caricature of the computer industry is that Japan and
the United States make the innards, and then China adds the plastic
shell. Although the reality is not quite that simple, Judith Dean, K. C.
Fung, and Zhi Wang estimate that imported inputs accounted for 57
percent of the value of Chinese computer exports in 2002. (21)
Similarly, imported inputs accounted for 41 percent of Chinese exports
of electronic devices by value, and for 46 percent for electronic
appliances and 59 percent for communications equipment. And there is
little question that in each case the imported inputs are much more
skill intensive than the Chinese component of the process.
The iPod
Greg Linden, Kenneth Kraemer, and Jason Dedrick have made a widely
publicized effort to figure out "who captures the value" from
the Apple iPod, the enormously popular portable media player. (22) The
study illustrates just how difficult it is to assign value added on the
basis of trade flows.
The iPod is assembled in China, so that iPod imports show up as
imports from China. However, assembly and testing appear to account for
less than 3 percent of an iPod's total input cost. The hard drive,
which accounts for about half the iPod's price, is produced in
China, but a considerable part of the hard drive's value presumably comes from components made elsewhere, (23) so that the Chinese component
is probably quite unskilled labor intensive. The next most valuable
component, the display, is made in Japan; crucial chips are made in the
United States or Taiwan; and so on.
Apple iPod imports are presumably counted under NAICS 334310, audio
and video equipment manufacturing. Yet it is clear from Linden, Kraemer,
and Dedrick's study that trying to estimate the factor content of
these imports using U.S. averages for that sector is wasted effort.
Semiconductors
Semiconductors might seem like a more homogeneous product than
computers or iPods. But even the semiconductor industry is marked by an
international division of labor that places skilled labor-intensive
operations in developed countries and unskilled labor-intensive
operations in developing countries. As in the case of computers, there
is clear horizontal specialization, with developing countries producing
standardized commodity products: the manufacture of "standard"
chips, which are used in many devices, is dominated by emerging Asia,
but much higher-end production remains in developed countries.
There is also extensive vertical specialization. For example,
Intel's manufacturing facilities are of two kinds, because
production takes place in two stages. First, circuits are printed, using
photolithography, on large disks of silicon at wafer fabrication plants,
or "fabs." Then the wafers are sent to assembly and testing
facilities, where, according to an Intel fact sheet, "each wafer is
cut into individual silicon dies, placed within external packages, and
tested for functionality." (24)
Where are these operations located? Intel has wafer fabs in the
United States, Ireland, and Israel. All of its assembly and testing
sites, by contrast, are in developing countries: China, Costa Rica,
Malaysia, and the Philippines, with a new site under construction in
Vietnam. In other words, within microprocessor manufacture, which is
just one piece of the six-digit semiconductor sector, one stage of
production is largely confined to developed economies, whereas another
is largely confined to very low wage countries.
Auto Parts
Figure 5 showed the predominant role of computers and electronics
in the growth of U.S. imports from developing countries. There has also,
however, been significant growth in imports of automotive products,
mainly from Mexico. A look at automotive trade shows the same pattern of
vertical specialization and disintegration as in computers and
electronics, with Mexico taking over labor-intensive niches within the
industry.
Thomas Klier and James Rubenstein, in a survey of the growing trade
in auto parts, describe some key aspects of that trade:
At the least-skilled end was electrical wiring; 80% of wiring
imports originate in Mexico, which emerged as the leading producer
of wiring harnesses in the 1970s. Relatively labor-intensive and
easy to ship, wiring was the first major component to be imported
in large numbers. Imports in chassis, at $15 billion the largest of
the remaining systems, have made the greatest percentage gains
since 1990. The chassis has become the principal "battleground"
system between domestic and imported sources. Engineering advances
have transformed chassis modules from high-cost production items
requiring skilled labor to low-cost "generic" items highly
sensitive to labor cost savings. (25)
All these examples suggest a data problem: numbers showing a rapid
rise in developing country exports, and Chinese exports in particular,
within sectors that are skill intensive in the United States need to be
taken with large doses of salt. As Jianmin Jin puts it, "The kind
of gap seen in the electronic information industry between the rapid
expansion of the scale of the industry coupled with a low value-added
structure is evidence for China's role as an assembly base that is
dependent upon overseas parts, intermediary goods, and capital
goods." (26)
Peter Schott offers additional evidence based on unit values
(import prices divided by import quantity), which are available in
sectors where the goods that the United States imports can be easily
measured in physical units (for example, dozens of shirts, square meters
of carpet, or pounds of chemicals). (27) It turns out that Chinese goods
imported by the United States have substantially lower unit values than
goods within the same industries imported from developed countries; for
example, the shirts that the United States imports from China are
cheaper than shirts imported from Italy. Furthermore, the gap in unit
values has been rising over time, suggesting that the relative
sophistication of Chinese exports within any given industry has been
declining.
Vertical Specialization and Wage Inequality
The broad picture, then, is that the apparent sophistication of
imports from developing countries is in large part a statistical
illusion. Developing countries in general, and China in particular, are
probably specializing in very different niches within industries than
the United States. But how does all of this bear on the question of
whether rising trade with developing countries has led to rising wage
inequality in the United States?
Several recent analyses have argued that such specialization in
effect protects developed country workers from the distributional
effects of trade by placing such countries in a different "cone of
diversification" from developing countries. (28) Figure 13
illustrates the concept of cones of specialization, using a Lerner
diagram. The curves represent unit-value isoquants--combinations of
skilled and unskilled labor inputs that produce an equal value (say,
$100) of good X, Y, or Z at current market prices. The downward-sloping
lines NN and SS represent relative factor prices in developed countries
and developing countries, respectively, and points [E.sub.N] and
[E.sub.S] their aggregate factor endowments.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
As drawn, the figure is consistent with a pattern of specialization
in which both developed and developing countries produce good Z,
developed countries also produce the skilled labor-intensive good X, and
developing countries also produce the unskilled labor-intensive good Y.
Because both types of countries produce Z, the two factor-price lines
represent equal value; in developed countries the cost of producing X is
the same as that of producing an equal value of Z, so both goods can be
produced there; the same is true of Z and Y in developing countries; but
producing a unit of X is more expensive in developing countries than in
developed countries, whereas producing a unit of Z is less expensive.
Each country is able to fully employ all its workers because its
endowment lies in the cone of diversification illustrated in figure 13.
The famous proposition that trade leads to equalization of factor
prices--a proposition closely linked to the Stolper-Samuelson
effect--applies only to countries that lie in the same cone. So the
suggestion that developing and developed countries lie in different
cones may seem to obviate concerns about the distributional effects of
trade. Thus, Schott asserts that
If all countries produce all goods, unskilled workers in the U.S.
can be adversely affected by a drop in the world price of
labor-intensive imports.... Specialization, however, means that
U.S. firms produce a capital-intensive mix of goods and are
therefore not threatened by cheap imports. (29)
Lawrence makes a similar argument. (30) And in fact my 1995 paper
suggested that the prospect of specialization offered one reason to
doubt whether the distributional effects of trade could get much larger
than they were in the early 1990s. (31)
But the evidence on specialization within industries, and on
vertical specialization in particular, calls this interpretation into
doubt. The shock behind rapid growth in developing country exports of
manufactured goods does not appear to be developing country growth
leading to falling prices of traditional exports such as apparel.
Instead what seems to be happening is a breakup of the value chain that
allows developing countries to take over unskilled labor-intensive
portions of skilled labor-intensive industries. And this process can
have consequences that closely resemble the Stolper-Samuelson effect.
This point is difficult to make analytically but comes across
clearly in a numerical example. Assume that there are two final goods, Y
and Z, produced using two factors of production, skilled labor S and
unskilled labor L. There are also two countries, a skilled
labor-abundant North and an unskilled labor-abundant South. Production
of Z is unskilled labor intensive. Production of Y takes place in two
stages: a skilled labor-intensive "component" stage X and an
unskilled labor-intensive "assembly" stage.
Production functions and utility for the final goods are assumed to
be Cobb-Douglas. The assumed parameters and resource endowments are as
follows:
Skilled labor share in X 0.8
Unskilled labor share in X 0.2
X share in Y 0.9
Skilled labor share in Y 0.01
Unskilled labor share in Y 0.09
Skilled labor share in Z 0.27
Unskilled labor share in Z 0.73
Share of Y in spending 0.5
Share of Z in spending 0.5
Skilled labor force in North 1.0
Unskilled labor force in North 1.0
Skilled labor force in South 0.1
Unskilled labor force in South 0.5
The model is initially solved for equilibrium in the developed
North in the absence of trade. I then consider two trade scenarios. Case
I assumes that X and Y must be physically co-located, so that there is
in effect an aggregate XY industry. Case II allows X and Y to be
separated, with unskilled labor-intensive assembly taking place in a
different country from the skilled labor-intensive component production.
Solution of the model requires determining both the pattern of
specialization and relative goods prices. In practice I began by
guessing at the specialization pattern. I then used an initial guess at
factor prices to yield implied goods outputs, used those outputs to
derive goods prices, used those prices to derive a new estimate of
factor prices, and iterated until convergence. The final step was to
confirm that the implied factor prices did in fact support the assumed
pattern of specialization. Given goods prices and factor prices, it was
possible to calculate real wages of skilled and unskilled labor in each
country. In the case in which X and Y had to be co-located, the pattern
of specialization and the associated factor prices were as illustrated
in figure 14. The developing South specialized in the production of
unskilled labor-intensive Z, whereas the North remained unspecialized,
producing both the skilled labor-intensive composite XY and Z. The
relative price of Z was lower in the developed economy than it would
have been in the absence of trade--the standard Stolper-Samuelson
effect. As the first column in table 5 shows, trade raises the real
wages of skilled workers while reducing those of unskilled workers.
But what happens if X and Y can be separated? Then the pattern of
specialization becomes that illustrated in figure 13. Both countries
continue to produce Z; meanwhile the unskilled labor-intensive portion
of XY moves to the developing country while the skilled labor-intensive
portion remains in the developed country.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
Figure 15 schematically illustrates the pattern of trade associated
with each case, with the length of the arrows indicating the value of
exports from each country to the other. When X and Y must be co-located,
North exports Y to South and imports Z. (Think of this as trading
computers for apparel.) When it becomes possible to engage in vertical
specialization, North exports X (for example, computer components) to
South, and imports both Z (apparel) and Y (assembled computers). I have
drawn the figure to suggest a large increase in the volume of trade. In
the numerical example, the share of imports in North's GDP rises
from 13.6 percent to 53.5 percent.
In a qualitative sense the change illustrated in figure 15 seems to
resemble the actual change in North-South trade since the early 1990s,
as documented in this paper. The share of developed country GDP spent on
imports from developing countries rises sharply, because components are
shipped to developing countries for assembly, and the assembled goods
are then exported back to the developed world. If X and Y continue to be
classified as part of the same industry, however, factor content
calculations based on developed country unit input coefficients will not
suggest an increase in effective imports of unskilled labor. And the
measured export mix of developing countries will seem to move upscale,
toward more sophisticated products.
Yet as the second column in table 5 shows, the actual effects on
workers in the developed economy reflect a sort of Stolper-Samuelson
effect: the real wages of skilled workers rise, while those of unskilled
workers fall. Intuitively, the new ability to outsource unskilled
labor-intensive industry segments to the developing world depresses the
demand for less skilled workers, a shock not captured by data that lump
unskilled labor-intensive "assembly" operations together with
skilled labor-intensive "component" manufacture.
However, this example does suggest that the type of calculation
performed by Bivens, (32) in which the distributional effects of trade
are assumed to be essentially proportional to the import share--a
calculation suggested, admittedly, by my own 1995 paper--may exaggerate
the distributional effects of recent trade growth. In this example the
trade share grows fourfold, but the distributional effects do not grow
in proportion. The reason, intuitively, is that much of the content of
the new imports from developing countries is actually skilled
labor-intensive production from developed countries, so that not as much
unskilled labor is displaced as the raw import figures seem to suggest.
If the United States imports computers from China, and China assembles
computers largely from components made in Japan, only the assembly share
of the sales price reflects unskilled labor-intensive imports; the rest
is indirect importing from a country whose factor prices are similar to
U.S. factor prices. Nonetheless, the analysis presented here indicates
that the rapid rise in manufactures imports from developing countries
probably is, indeed, a force for growing inequality, and that factor
content calculations suggesting otherwise are missing the essence of
what is happening.
Implications of the Analysis
The starting point of this paper was the observation that the
consensus that trade has only modest effects on inequality rests on
relatively old data-that there has been a dramatic increase in
manufactured imports from developing countries since the early 1990s.
And it is probably true that this increase has been a force for greater
inequality in the United States and other developed countries.
What really comes through from the analysis here, however, is the
extent to which the changing nature of world trade has outpaced
economists' ability to engage in secure quantitative analysis--even
though this paper sets to one side the growth in services outsourcing,
which has created so much anxiety in recent years. Plain old trade in
physical goods has become remarkably exotic.
In particular, the surge in developing country exports of
manufactures involves a peculiar concentration on apparently
sophisticated products, which seems at first to put worries about
distributional effects to rest. Yet there is good reason to believe that
the apparent sophistication of developing country exports is largely a
statistical illusion, created by the phenomenon of vertical
specialization in a world of low trade costs.
How can the actual effect of rising trade on wages be quantified?
The answer, given the current state of the data, is that it can't.
As I have said, it is likely that the rapid growth of trade since the
early 1990s has had significant distributional effects. Putting numbers
on these effects, however, will require a much better understanding of
the increasingly fine-grained nature of international specialization and
trade.
Comments and Discussion
COMMENT BY ROBERT E. HALL This paper is a much-needed follow-up to
Paul Krugman's 1995 Brookings Paper on the growth of international
trade. (1) A key issue discussed in that paper, and a topic of much
academic research at the time, was the role of increased trade in
driving wage inequality in the United States. The general consensus from
that work was that trade had played a relatively small role in
depressing the relative wages of less skilled workers.
However, one of the most striking changes over the past thirteen
years has been the large increase in U.S. imports from low-wage
developing countries. As Krugman notes, the trade-and-wages research
from the early and mid-1990s has not been updated to take into account
developments such as NAFTA and the emergence of China as a major
exporter. These changes might lead one to assume that the impact of
trade on wages would be significantly greater than it was in studies
that used data primarily from the 1980s. But since the answer is really
not known, the topic is ripe for reconsideration.
Unfortunately, those expecting a definitive answer from
Krugman's paper will be disappointed. As he concludes, "How
can the actual effect of rising trade on wages be quantified? The
answer, given the current state of the data, is that it
can't." Alas, I must agree with Krugman that the question is
going to be very difficult to answer. However, the available evidence
suggests to me that trade is not playing a larger role in driving U.S.
wage inequality today than it was a decade or two ago.
Determining the impact of trade on the wage structure requires data
on wages, data on trade, and a theory linking the two. Each of these
critical components has a problem, which makes finding the trade-wage
relationship very difficult. The first problem is that there are
different, and sometimes conflicting, measures of wage inequality.
Krugman focuses on the college-high school wage premium, which is
frequently studied and has continued to grow over the past decade since
the original trade-and-wages literature began to peter out. (2) The
rising returns to education may be plausibly related to increased trade,
although Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz explain it more on the basis
of a domestic story about the supply and demand for skilled workers. (3)
Yet there are many ways of parsing the wage data. In the 1990s
economists frequently focused on how trade might have contributed to the
increasing wage gap between nonproduction and production workers,
presumably another proxy for white- and blue-collar workers. For
example, Robert Feenstra and Gordon Hanson studied this wage gap closely
and concluded that the outsourcing of production and assembly operations
to developing countries could explain part of the rise. (4)
But as figure 1 shows, this wage gap has been narrowing since about
2000, after most of this research was completed. Because production
outsourcing has most likely continued since 2000, if not accelerated, I
would venture the guess that the Feenstra-Hanson empirical model would
not perform well out of sample; that is, it would probably predict a
further increase in the nonproduction-production wage gap, because
outsourcing has continued since 2000, whereas the wage gap has narrowed.
The simple point is that there are conflicting wage data, and not
all suggest increasing inequality. (5) Until there is clear-cut
agreement on which wage series should command the most attention, no
single cut at the data will be decisive.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The second problem with determining the trade-wages relationship is
that the trade data, as Krugman notes, have become really problematic.
The impact of trade on wages depends upon the factor content of imports.
But the trade data simply record the country from which an imported
product arrives, not necessarily where it was produced or where its
components came from. Since trade in intermediate goods is flourishing,
one cannot simply infer the factor content of a product from its country
of origin.
Krugman mentions the classic case of the Apple iPod: recorded as a
$150 import from China, the iPod embodies just a few dollars of Chinese
labor in assembly and a few more dollars of Chinese labor related to
production of the hard drive. To treat this $150 import from China as an
import of $150 of unskilled labor would grossly exaggerate the low-wage
factor content of the product. Dean, Fung, and Wang conclude that 36
percent of the value of Chinese exports in the aggregate consists of
imported intermediate components, a figure that is much higher in some
sectors such as electronics. (6) This makes it misleading to use the
value of imports to infer something about the factor content of trade.
As a result, as Krugman notes, the impact of imports on the income
distribution is not going to be proportional to the import share.
The final problem in determining the impact of trade on wages is
that one needs a theoretical framework for thinking about the two. When
trade economists think about the issue, the Stolper-Samuelson theorem
immediately comes to mind. Stolper-Samuelson is a magnificent result,
but economists should be somewhat cautious in applying it to the world
today. The flip side of the Stolper-Samuelson result is that the
relative wage of unskilled workers in developing countries should be
increasing, yet the opposite is the case. (7) This suggests that there
is something else going on in the world, or that the strong
Stolper-Samuelson result (based on a simple model with two final goods
and two factors of production) does not capture what a richer version
with internationally mobile capital and trade in intermediate goods
might. Our models are very simple, and the world is a bit more
complicated.
Given the variety of wage data, the problems with the trade data,
and the questions about the theory, does this mean that economists can
say nothing about the issue? Fortunately not. One simple exercise might
put an upper bound on the impact of trade on wages. As noted, one cannot
assume that the impact of imports from low-wage countries on U.S. wages
is proportional to the import share, because those imports use a lot of
components made in high-wage countries. The implication is that using
the import share will result in an exaggerated view of the impact on
wages.
Bivens does this exercise and brings Krugman's 1995 findings
up to date, (8) but the result is surprising: although trade increased
substantially between 1992 and 2005, so did the college-high school wage
gap, and hence the share of that inequality that can be attributed to
trade did not change. By the rough calculation in table 1, trade was
responsible for about 10 percent of wage inequality in the 1979-92
period, and about 10 percent of wage inequality in the 1979-2005
period.(9) And for the reasons already mentioned, the latter is an
overstatement of the impact of trade on wages, so if the impact was
relatively small in the earlier period, it may be even smaller more
recently.
Furthermore, there has been some recent research on the growth of
wage inequality in manufacturing since the earlier literature. Nino
Sitchinava concludes that "the relative contribution of trade is
sensitive to the data and the type of variables used in the
estimation." (10) Using better measures of outsourcing, Sitchinava
finds that two sources of trade tend to work in different directions
with respect to wages: whereas trade in intermediate inputs and final
goods tends to increase wage inequality, trade in service inputs tends
to decrease it. This mutes the effect of trade on overall wage
inequality. As a result, given the increase in services trade, it could
be that trade is less of a factor in driving wage inequality now than it
was in the 1980s.
To conclude on a provocative note: does it matter how much
inequality is being driven by trade? It would certainly matter for our
perception of the world and the demands that might be made to limit
trade. But how much would the policy recommendations of, say, the median
Massachusetts Avenue economist (Brookings Institution, Peterson
Institute for International Economics, Center for Global Development,
Council on Foreign Relations, Johns Hopkins School for Advanced
International Studies, etc.) change depending upon that figure? I
suspect the policy advice would be the same regardless of whether trade
was found to have been responsible for 4 percent or 40 percent of a
given amount of wage inequality. That response would probably be as
follows: inequality may be undesirable, but it should be addressed not
by closing markets through greater protectionism, but by more
progressive income taxation, a stronger social safety net, and more
assistance for displaced workers. Of course, this is just speculation on
my part.
(1.) Paul R. Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and
Consequences," BPEA, no. 1 (Spring 1995): 327-77.
(2.) See David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney,
"Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists,"
Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (2008): 300-23.
(3.) Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz, The Race between
Education and Technology (Harvard University Press, 2008).
(4.) Robert C. Feenstra and Gordon H. Hanson, "The Impact of
Outsourcing and High-Technology Capital on Wages: Estimates for the
U.S., 1979-1990," Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, no. 3 (1999):
907-40.
(5.) For example, much of the recent rise in income inequality has
been driven by the top 1 percent of the distribution, which is
presumably related to financial markets and not international trade.
(6.) Judy Dean, K. C. Fung, and Zhi Wang, "Measuring the
Vertical Specialization in Chinese Trade," USITC Working Paper
(Washington: U.S. International Trade Commission, 2007).
(7.) Pinelopi Goldberg and Nina Pavcnik, "Distributional
Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries," Journal of
Economic Literature 45, no. 1 (2007): 39-82.
(8.) Josh Bivens, "Globalization, American Wages, and
Inequality: Past, Present, and Future," EPI Working Paper 279
(Washington: Economic Policy Institute, 2007).
(9.) This is a very simplistic comparison, but in his comment
Lawrence Katz similarly concludes that the Bivens calculation implies
that trade is responsible for about 15 percent of the increase in
inequality since 1979.
(10.) Nino Sitchinava, "Trade, Technology, and Wage
Inequality: Evidence from U.S. Manufacturing, 1989-2004," working
paper, Department of Economics, University of Oregon (2007). As she
notes, "My preliminary estimation indicates that the standard
measure of foreign outsourcing of intermediate goods, proposed by
[Feenstra and Hanson]... and commonly used in the literature, suffers
from severe measurement errors that prohibit the estimation of the
impact of trade in intermediate inputs on the wage dispersion of the
1990s."
Table 1. Impact of Trade on Wage Inequality Percent
Krugman (1995) Bivens (2007)
Period covered 1979-92 1979-2005
Estimated effect of trade on +4.7 +6.9
skilled-unskilled wage ratio
Change in college-high school +42.5 +65.0
wage ratio (a)
Proportion of change in wage ratio 11 11
due to estimated trade effect
Sources: Paul R. Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and
Consequences," BPEA, no. 2 (Spring 1995): 327-77; Josh Bivens,
"Globalization, American Wages, and Inequality," EPI Working Paper
(Washington: Economic Policy Institute, September 6, 2007);
author's calculations.
(a.) From David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney,
"Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists," Review
of Economics and Statistics 90 (May 2008): 300-23.
COMMENT BY LAWRENCE F. KATZ U.S. wage inequality and educational
wage differentials have expanded dramatically since 1980. Trade with
developing countries has increased rapidly over the same period. Many
commentators, politicians, potential voters, labor leaders, and business
leaders believe there is a strong connection between globalization
(particularly increased imports from and outsourcing to lower-wage
countries), on the one hand, and rising economic inequality and
stagnating living standards for noncollege-educated and other
"middle-class" U.S. workers and their families. But as Paul
Krugman summarizes in table 1 of his engaging paper, most serious
quantitative research using data through the early to mid-1990s found
only small to modest impacts of North-South trade on U.S. wage
inequality and skill differentials.
I am delighted to see Krugman, a major voice for both analytical
rigor and common sense in the trade-and-wages debates of the 1990s,
return to these issues; in particular, I am delighted that his paper
takes into account the large growth in U.S. trade with developing
countries since the mid-1990s and the substantial changes in the nature
of North-South trade. In this comment I will first summarize Krugman's analysis and my interpretation of his framework and
findings. I will then comment on how far his approach based on the
growing vertical fragmentation of international supply chains takes us
toward understanding some of the existing challenges for trade-based
explanations of growing U.S. wage inequality. Finally, I will speculate
on directions for further research to better understand how
globalization is affecting the U.S. labor market.
WHAT KRUGMAN HAS ACCOMPLISHED. Krugman documents that U.S. imports
of manufactured goods from developing countries expanded from under 3
percent of GDP in the early 1990s to around 6 percent in 2006. He also
shows that the developing countries accounting for the bulk of this
expansion (especially China and Mexico) have much lower wages relative
to developed countries than did the main sources of U.S.
"low-wage" imports in the early 1990s. For Krugman these two
factors suggest that growing North-South trade in manufactures should
have substantially larger impacts on U.S. wage inequality today than
past studies found using data covering the U.S. experience of the 1980s
and early 1990s.
Nevertheless, updated micro factor content analyses of the
disaggregated industry composition of U.S. trade in manufactures with
developing countries using data through the mid-2000s continue to imply
only small trade impacts on the U.S. wage structure. (1) Krugman shows
that the reason is the growing apparent sophistication of U.S. imports
from developing countries. The United States increasingly imports goods
from developing countries in skill-intensive sectors such as computers
and electronic products. Even when one disaggregates trade flows to the
four-digit NAICS level, the skill content of U.S. imports from
developing countries looks very similar to the overall skill endowment
of the U.S. workforce, implying little impact of such trade flows on
wage inequality.
The core of Krugman's paper is an attempt to address the
apparent paradox of rising U.S. trade with low-wage countries showing up
in increased U.S. imports of goods in skill-intensive sectors.
Krugman's resolution of this paradox is that the data used in
standard factor content calculations suffer from a severe aggregation
bias, driven by the vertical fragmentation of production through
globalized supply chains in which the unskilled labor-intensive niches
(such as assembly stages) of skilled labor-intensive sectors are shifted
to developing countries. Thus, the apparent sophistication of imports
from developing countries is partly an aggregation illusion, with the
value added from developing countries being in the unskilled
labor-intensive niches (or stages of production) in each (tour-digit
NAICS) industry. He presents some well-known but insightful examples
that illustrate such vertical fragmentation of production by skill
content across countries for computers (Lenovo notebooks), auto parts,
semiconductors, and the iPod. In fact, detailed recent work by Robert
Koopman, Zhi Wang, and Shang-Jin Wei suggests that the foreign content
in China's exports is about 50 percent overall and around 80
percent in sophisticated sectors such as electronic devices. (2) Krugman
suggests that such vertical fragmentation of production means that
growing trade with developing countries may have a larger impact on wage
inequality in developed countries than traditional micro factor content
studies indicate.
Krugman illustrates this possibility through an extension of a
simple Heckscher-Ohlin factor endowment-driven North-South trade model
to incorporate a skilled labor-intensive sector (XY) with two stages of
production (a skilled labor-intensive part X and an unskilled
labor-intensive part Y) and an unskilled labor-intensive sector (Z). My
interpretation of this framework is that in the early stages of the
recent period of globalization (the 1980s to the early 1990s), increased
international integration led to traditional trade flows of skilled
labor-intensive goods (XY) being exported from the North in return for
unskilled labor-intensive traditional imports (Z), such as apparel and
shoes, from the South. The second stage of globalization (from the early
1990s to the present) has involved the vertical fragmentation of skilled
labor-intensive sectors (such as computers), so that XY fragments, with
X being done in the North and Y increasingly being done in the South.
This leads to increased exports from the South to the North that get
classified as sophisticated goods in the XY sector. The new ability of
the North to outsource unskilled labor-intensive industry segments to
the South can have a Stolper-Samuelson-type effect, benefiting skilled
workers and harming unskilled workers in the North, that would not be
fully captured in standard (four-digit NAICS) factor content
calculations because of aggregation bias. Krugman concludes that
"the rapid rise in manufactures imports from developing countries
probably is, indeed, a force for growing inequality," although the
available data are not up to the task of quantifying this effect given
the "increasingly fine-grained nature of international
specialization and trade."
But Krugman's numerical example and intuition suggest that the
distributional impact of increased trade from the vertical fragmentation
of production between North and South is likely to be substantially less
than proportional to the growth in the volume of trade (particularly of
imports from the South as a share of the North's GDP). If this is
the case, then the two existing approaches to estimating trade
impacts--the Krugman 1995 aggregate "but for" analysis in
which the distribution impacts of North-South trade are essentially
proportional to the import share, (3) and the micro factor content
studies, such as those by George Borjas, Richard Freeman, and Katz and
by Robert Lawrence<--can provide upper- and lower-bound estimates of
the impacts of trade on wage inequality in the North.
Josh Bivens's updating of the Krugman 1995 approach to more
recent U.S. data suggests that trade with developing countries served to
expand the wages of skilled relative to unskilled workers (the college
wage premium) by 6.9 percent (log points) in 2006, compared with 4.8
percent (log points) in 1995. (5) This upper-bound estimate suggests
that increased trade with developing countries could explain a
2.1-log-point expansion of the skill premium from 1995 to 2006, or about
30 percent of the 7-log-point increase in the college wage premium from
1995 to 2006 documented by David Autor, Katz, and Melissa Kearney. (6)
The lower-bound estimate by Lawrence using disaggregate skill factor
content analysis suggests that growth in trade with developing countries
over the last decade has had essentially zero impact on the skill
premium. (7) My guesstimate using the developing country import share of
around 2 percent of U.S. GDP in 1979 is that the Krugman-Bivens
upper-bound approach could explain about 4 to 5 log points (or 15 to 19
percent) of the 26-log-point rise in the college wage premium from 1980
to 2006. And the lower-bound micro factor content studies cited by
Krugman in table 1, combined with the new Lawrence estimate, suggest a
lower bound of a 1.5- to 3-log-point impact of trade with developing
countries on the college wage premium from 1980 to 2006, accounting for
6 to 12 percent of its overall rise.
My bottom line is that even taking into account the aggregation
biases in traditional factor content calculations due to the vertical
fragmentation of production, growing trade with developing countries is
still at most a modest contributor to rising U.S. wage inequality since
1980. The skill content impact of growing international trade appears to
be a much smaller contributor to rising U.S. educational wage
differentials than the large slowdown in U.S. skill supply growth after
1980 (from 3.9 percent a year for 1960-80 to 2.3 percent a year for
1980-2005), largely arising from slower growth in educational attainment of successive U.S. birth cohorts. (8)
PUZZLES FOR TRADE-BASED EXPLANATIONS OF RISING U.S. WAGE
INEQUALITY. Several empirical patterns appear difficult to reconcile
with the view that growing international trade is the driving force
behind rising U.S. wage inequality through Stolper-Samuelson effects.
First, the standard Heckscher-Ohlin trade model implies that every U.S.
sector should become less skill intensive as increased international
integration increases the wages of skilled relative to unskilled
workers. In fact, within-sector skill upgrading has been widely
documented in almost all U.S. industries in recent decades. (9)
Krugman's modified model does provide one resolution of this
puzzle, in that the outsourcing of less skilled tasks in each sector
could lead to observed within-sector skill upgrading in traded goods
sectors. But the similar patterns of skill upgrading in largely
nontraded goods and services sectors strongly suggest that skill-biased
technological change has been a stronger force than
Stolper-Samuelson-type effects on U.S. relative skill demands.
On the other hand, Krugman's extension of the standard trade
model does not really help one understand rising wage inequality in the
South with growing trade. (10) Furthermore, it is not clear that one
needs any acceleration in demand for more-skilled workers in the United
States arising from factors related to globalization to explain rising
U.S. skill differentials, given the sharp slowdown in the growth of U.S.
skill supply.
SOME FURTHER ISSUES. Krugman's fascinating paper should
motivate further work toward a better understand of recent changes in
the nature of international trade and supply chains, and how such
changes affect the U.S. labor market. Following the approach of Borjas,
Freeman, and Katz, one might be able to make further progress in micro
factor content studies by using historical information on U.S. factor
ratios by industry, taken from periods before imports from developing
countries surged and international supply chains fragmented. U.S.
domestic skill shares in an industry from twenty years or so ago may
provide a useful upper-bound estimate of the unskilled labor that would
be necessary to replace imports from developing countries within
detailed sectors. Additionally, some updating of the cross-industry
studies that used data through the 1990s (such as that by Autor, Katz,
and Alan Krueger (11)) on the relative importance of trade factors
(import shares and outsourcing measure) versus indicators of techno logical change would also be useful in gaining a better empirical
understanding of how recent globalization is affecting U.S. skill
demands.
Although Krugman takes seriously the increasingly complex nature of
supply chains and international trade flows, he does not show similar
sophistication in this paper in his treatment of labor market data and
wage inequality trends. Krugman's model focuses on a single
unskilled-skilled wage differential, and he plots the college wage
premium and the 90-50 log wage differentials in his figure 8. But U.S.
wage structure trends differ between the early globalization
(traditional trade) era of the 1980s, in which the wage structure
widened in a monotonic fashion, and the last two decades (the vertical
fragmentation era), in which wage inequality continued expanding in the
top half of the distribution but stopped growing in the bottom half.
Furthermore, the returns to education have increasingly convexified
since the late 1980s, with the four-year college premium growing
modestly and the postcollege (graduate) premium continuing to rise
rapidly. Within-group wage inequality has grown rapidly for
college-educated workers and almost stopped growing for
non-college-educated workers. (12)
A key question that future work should address is whether
international trade and outsourcing can help one understand the changing
nature of rising U.S. wage inequality as manifested in the increasing
polarization of U.S. employment into high- and low-wage jobs at the
expense of middle-wage jobs. Models of computerization that take into
account how computers are actually used go some distance toward
understanding these patterns, showing that computers are complementary
to high-skilled workers with abstract skills, substitute for the routine
tasks of middle-skilled workers, and do not substantially affect the
in-person tasks of many lower-skilled workers. (13) My sense is that the
growing vertical fragmentation of production across North and South
emphasized by Krugman is likely to lead increasingly to outsourcing of
many of the tasks of middle-skilled workers (production jobs in the
upper half of the noncollege wage distribution, middle management jobs
in the lower half of the college distribution). Trade models
incorporating more than two skill groups and both within-and
between-group wage inequality will be necessary to make further progress
on these issues.
One also needs to consider how labor market institutions in the
North might mediate the impact of globalization on the wage structure.
If the jobs for less skilled workers in the traded goods sectors that
get displaced by imports tend to be unionized or earn efficiency wage
premiums, then the distributional consequences of increased trade with
developing countries may be larger than suggested by standard models
that assume competitive labor markets. (14) Previous research suggested
that the loss due to trade of jobs paying high economic rents was only a
modest factor in rising U.S. wage inequality through the early 1990s,
(15) but it would be nice to see a further consideration of these
factors using more recent data.
Finally, also missing from Krugman's analysis is the
difference in the consumption baskets of high- and low-skilled workers
(or high- and low-income consumers) arising from nonhomothetic
preferences. Increased imports from developing countries (especially
China) seem to particularly reduce prices for the
"lower-quality" nondurable goods that make up a larger share
of the consumption basket of lower-income U.S. families. (16) Such skill
nonneutralities in the consumption impacts of growing trade with
developing countries imply that the welfare effects of increased trade
for different skill groups may differ from the standard relative wage
impacts.
(1.) Such studies include Robert Z. Lawrence, Blue-Collar Blues: Is
Trade to Blame for Rising US Income Inequality? (Washington: Peterson
Institute for International Economics, 2008), and Lawrence Mishel, Jared
Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto, The State of Working America:
2006/2007 (Cornell University Press and Economics Policy Institute,
2006).
(2.) Robert Koopman, Zhi Wang, and Shang-Jin Wei, "How Much of
Chinese Exports Is Really Made in China? Assessing Domestic Value-Added
When Processing Trade Is Pervasive," Working Paper 14109
(Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, June 2008).
(3.) Paul R. Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and
Consequences," BPEA, no. 1 (Spring 1995): 327-77.
(4.) George J. Borjas, Richard B. Freeman, and Lawrence F. Katz,
"How Much Do Immigration and Trade Affect Labor Market
Outcomes?" BPEA, no. 1 (1997): 1-90; Lawrence, Blue-Collar Blues.
(5.) L. Josh Bivens, "Globalization and American Wages: Today
and Tomorrow," EPI Briefing Paper 196 (Washington: Economic Policy
Institute, October 2007).
(6.) David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney,
"Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists,"
Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (May 2008): 300-23.
(7.) See Lawrence, Blue-Collar Blues.
(8.) Claudia Goldin and Lawrence F. Katz, "Long-Run Changes in
the Wage Structure: Narrowing, Widening, Polarizing," BPEA, no. 2
(2007), 135-65; Goldin and Katz, The Race between Education and
Technology (Harvard University Press, 2008).
(9.) Robert Z. Lawrence and Matthew Slaughter, "International
Trade and American Wages in the 1980s: Giant Sucking Sound or Small
Hiccup?" BPEA: Microeconomics, no. 2 (1993): 161-226; David H.
Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Alan B. Krueger, "Computing Inequality: Have Computers Changed the Labor Market'?"
Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 (November 1998): 1169-1213.
(10.) Pinelopi Goldberg and Nina Pavcnik, "Distributional
Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries," Journal of
Economic Literature 45 (March 2007): 39-82.
(11.) Autor, Katz, and Krueger, "Computing Inequality."
(12.) Autor, Katz, and Kearney, "Trends in U.S. Wage
Inequality"; Goldin and Katz, "Long-Run Changes in the Wage
Structure."
(13.) David H. Autor, Frank Levy, and Richard Muruane, "The
Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical
Investigation," Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (November 2003):
1279-1333; Autor, Katz, and Kearney, "Trends in U.S. Wage
Inequality."
(14.) Lawrence F. Katz and Lawrence H. Summers, "Industry
Rents: Evidence and Implications," BPEA: Microeconomics (1989):
209-90.
(15.) George J. Borjas and Valerie A. Ramey, "Foreign
Competition, Market Power, and Wage Inequality," Quarterly Journal
of Economics 110 (November 1995): 1075-1110.
(16.) Christian Broda and John Romalis, "Inequality and
Prices: Does China Benefit the Poor in America?" (University of
Chicago Graduate School of Business, March 2008).
COMMENT BY ROBERT Z. LAWRENCE At several points in this paper Paul
Krugman is critical of my recent book on the topic of trade and
inequality, (1) so I appreciate the opportunity the editors have given
me to comment on his paper. Independently, Krugman and I both began
studying this question with similar priors, expecting to find that over
the past decade trade had become a much more important contributor to
wage inequality. But we have come out in different places, because we
disagree about how much increased wage inequality there has actually
been and what kinds of models best capture what is happening.
In the 1980s, growing wage inequality was pervasive and obvious.
Although the measures differed in magnitude, evidence of increased wage
inequality emerged whether workers were distinguished by education,
occupation, or experience; whether the data were for women or men; and
whether the focus was on the lower or the upper half of the wage
distribution. The pervasive nature of this rising inequality suggested
that powerful forces were at work and provided support for relatively
straightforward explanations that entailed some amalgam of causes, such
as a shift in social norms, skill-biased technological change (due to
the adoption of computers), immigration, and Stolper-Samuelson effects
associated with expanding trade.
In addition, it was possible to find marked differences, at the
levels of aggregation permitted by the input-output tables, between the
net skill intensity of imports and the skill intensity of goods produced
in the domestic economy. This combination of growing inequality and an
increase in the relative supply of unskilled labor embodied in imports
led naturally to measuring the partial contribution of trade to
increased wage inequality using factor content and "warranted"
price methodologies. It also justified simulations using simple
two-factor models such as that used by Krugman in his earlier Brookings
Paper. (2)
In the 1990s, however, despite the rapid growth of imports from
developing countries, the wage inequality story has become much more
complicated. Krugman leaves the impression that wage inequality has
continued apace and dismisses evidence to the contrary. For example, he
points to an increase in the 90-50 ratio and the rising college premium
for men over the 1990s, and he dismisses the absence of a growing
college premium more recently as a cyclical development. But his use of
data is selective, and he ignores the key point that there is no longer
evidence of growing wage inequality that supports a simple story of
pervasive and growing differences in the rewards to skill.
At least three considerations complicate the current wage picture.
First, since the early 1990s, the wages of the least skilled
Americans--the lowest 10 percent--have more than kept pace with those in
the middle, and high school dropouts have seen faster wage growth than
those who complete high school but do not attend college. This is a
really important development for those concerned about immigration as
well as trade and has led labor economists such as David Autor, Lawrence
Katz, and Melissa Kearney to develop more complicated models of
technological change. (3) Second, since the mid-1990s there has been
almost no increase in the college-high school premium for women.
According to estimates by the Economic Policy Institute (EPI), for
example, the 47.1 percent premium in 2005 was barely above the premium
of 46.7 in 1995. (4) Third, the EPI estimates also show that between
1999 and 2005, even for men, the increase in the college-high school
premium was very small, at only 1.5 percentage points. Similarly,
between December 1999 and December 2006, as measured by the employment
cost index, which includes both wages and benefits, nominal compensation
of workers in white-collar occupations has grown by the exactly the same
amount--25 log points--as for those in blue-collar occupations. Workers
in the category of "executive, administrative, and managerial
occupations," for example, have experienced in relative terms the
same increases in compensation as "machine operators and
handlers." (5) Roughly equal compensation growth is also evident
when compensation is classified by sector (manufacturing versus
services) or by union membership versus nonmembership. (6) All of these
data call into question the idea that inequality has continued to grow
between workers with different levels of skill.
Krugman observes that since there may have been other offsetting
factors, even if there has been no overall increase in wage inequality,
it does not necessarily prove that trade has had no effect. That is
true. Nonetheless, if other factors are improving the relative wages of
unskilled workers, then trade (or immigration) is less of a problem for
them. And the ex post data still warrant the conclusion that any
negative effects from trade have been too small to dominate the outcome.
But it could also be the case that expanding trade with developing
countries does not necessarily lead to increased wage inequality between
skilled and unskilled workers. Indeed, it could be that as the economy
has adjusted to trade with developing countries, the incremental effects
on inequality have diminished. There are several reasons why this might
be so.
The most obvious is complete specialization. A significant share of
American imports today may no longer have domestically produced
counterparts. Even if classified under the same heading, imports could
differ substantially from domestically produced goods, and this could be
true of both intermediate inputs and final goods. This would mean that
although the declining prices of these goods that Krugman points to
yield benefits to buyers, they should not be expected to change relative
wages or even to cause the dislocation of U.S. workers.
To be sure, the proportion of goods that are fully replaced by
imports could increase over time, but as the process advances, the
marginal effects on inequality should be expected to diminish. Given
different factor prices in the United States and the developing world,
it is likely that the first goods to be fully replaced by imports would
be the most unskilled labor intensive. As the process of specialization
expands, however, the goods that are replaced would be increasingly less
intensive in their use of unskilled labor. Since smaller proportions of
unskilled labor would be displaced, the amount of wage inequality caused
for each dollar of additional replacement would decline. Thus,
paradoxically, the further the process of specialization advances, the
smaller its marginal impact on inequality.
Similar arguments could be made in the case of offshoring of
intermediate goods. The model that Krugman develops in the paper
predicts, correctly, that inequality would increase as the adjustment
takes place. But once a particular offshoring process has moved abroad,
one would not expect further increases in U.S. inequality. Again, as
with finished goods, one might expect the most unskilled labor-intensive
processes to have been offshored first and, at the margin, for
offshoring to cause diminishing amounts of inequality.
A second possibility is that there have been "factor intensity
reversals" in what were once relatively unskilled labor-intensive
industries. U.S. firms have increasingly adopted skill-intensive methods
of production and more automation to compete against goods made abroad
with less skilled labor. Indeed, several of the earlier studies of wage
behavior took note of the rising ratio of nonproduction to production
workers throughout U.S. manufacturing, a development that was at odds
with the simple Stolper-Samuelson story. This development would mean
that if imports cause displacement, they do not disproportionately displace unskilled workers.
A third possibility is that the developing countries have upgraded
the skill intensity of their exports. This could occur either because
their workers have become more sophisticated and skilled, or because
some of the goods to which they add unskilled labor contain a
significant amount of value that has been added by skilled labor in
developed countries. Thus, a machine coming from China could be 75
percent Japanese and compete with a machine produced in the United
States with relatively skilled workers.
In sum, U.S. trade today combines these elements in proportions
that are hard to disentangle in a manner that allows for a sufficiently
precise matching of products and the wages earned in producing them. At
relatively high levels of aggregation, the data can be interpreted to
indicate that manufactured imports overall, and even those from
developing countries such as China, are concentrated in U.S.
manufacturing sectors that pay wages significantly higher than the U.S.
average. This evidence, which is compatible with the factor reversals
and upgrading stories, suggests that import displacement does not fall
disproportionately on less skilled workers.
At more disaggregated levels, however, the data suggest that goods
imported from developing countries such as China are associated with
relatively less skilled labor inputs, which would be support for the
traditional story. (7) But there is also evidence, based on unit values,
that suggests that these goods are qualitatively different from those
produced by developed countries such as the United States. This provides
support for the view that some of this trade reflects more complete
specialization, and as such does not result in either wage inequality or
downward pressure on wages generally.
All told, therefore, there is some support for the view that these
mitigating effects are operating, and they give reasons to doubt that
declining import prices or rising import volumes from developing
countries automatically generate increasing wage inequality in the
United States. Moreover, the most striking feature of U.S. wage behavior
since 2000 is not growing inequality but rather that wage gains by both
workers with only a high school diploma and workers with a college
degree have been meager at best.
(1.) Robert Z. Lawrence, Blue-Collar Blues: Is Trade to Blame for
Rising US Income Inequality? (Washington: Peterson Institute for
International Economics, 2008).
(2.) Paul R. Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and
Consequences." BPEA, no. 1 (Spring 1995): 327-77.
(3.) David H. Autor, Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney,
"The Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market." Working Paper
11986 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996).
(4.) See Lawrence Mishel, Jared Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto,
The State of Working America 2006/2007 (Cornell University Press and
Economic Policy Institute, 2007), p. 145. The data used for their figure
3M are available at www.epi.org/content.cfm/datazone_dznational.
(5.) The latter group comprises "machine operators,
assemblers, and inspectors occupations" and "handlers,
equipment cleaners, helpers and laborers occupations."
(6.) See Lawrence, Blue-Collar Blues, pp. 29 and 30.
(7.) See Lawrence, Blue-Collar Blues, p. 40.
GENERAL DISCUSSION Lawrence Katz noted that in micro data using the
employment cost index, inequality has stopped increasing in the bottom
half of the income distribution but continues to grow in the top half.
Incomes in the top 20 percent of the distribution are still rising
relative to everyone else, and those in the middle of the distribution
are not; including benefits in the calculation thus does not change the
result. Alan Krueger observed that since the mid-1990s the bottom decile of the income distribution has done relatively well. He wondered how to
explain this, as one would assume that the price shocks that followed
the currency crises of the 1990s would have disproportionately hurt
those at the bottom. He wondered whether trade simply affects the middle
of the distribution more than the bottom, or whether some other factor
is at play.
Robert Gordon pointed out that changes in U.S. wage inequality are
unlikely to be explained by any one factor alone, especially trade. For
example, much of the increase in inequality is the result of rapid
income growth in the top 1 percent of the distribution. CEOs are now
paid 300 to 400 times what the average production worker is paid, and
this does not seem to be due to trade. Likewise, over the last twenty
years, the average real wage of a major league baseball player has
increased by 9 percent a year, which certainly has nothing to do with
trade. This argues for considering multiple explanations.
Robert Hall found it unsurprising that incomes at the top end of
the distribution are growing so quickly, given the high returns to
intellectual property in today's economy. For example, if the
wholesale price of an iPod is, say, $250, the labor component might well
be only $20, of which only $5 is unskilled. That means the remaining
$230 is a return to intellectual property.
Martin Baily noted that many of the effects under discussion are
very small. For example, services imports from India are 0.05 percent of
GDP. Likewise, the 14 million workers in manufacturing make up a small
fraction of total employment. Listening to media accounts, one might get
the impression that Wal-Mart imports all of its inventory from China. In
fact, the figure was only 10 percent in 2004. It is important to put
these trends in perspective.
Alberto Alesina emphasized the importance of understanding what
share of inequality growth is explained by trade. He rejected the view
that this number is irrelevant because society will choose to
redistribute a certain amount to the poor regardless of the cause of
their poverty. On the contrary, if trade is causing the growth in
inequality, there will be much greater political pressure to restrict
trade than if rising inequality were due to some other cause. From this
political economy perspective, accurately quantifying the effects of
trade on inequality is crucial.
Lawrence Summers wondered whether it would be useful to examine
differences in the effects of trade in different parts of the country.
The fortunes of some regions, particularly the Midwest, seem more
closely linked to international competition than others.
References
Bernanke, Ben. 2007. "Speech before the Greater Omaha Chamber
of Commerce." Washington: Federal Reserve.
Bivens, Josh. 2007. "Globalization, American Wages, and
Inequality: Past, Present, and Future." EPI Working Paper 279.
Washington: Economic Policy Institute.
Blinder, Alan. 2006. "Offshoring: The Next Industrial
Revolution." Foreign Affairs 85, no. 2:113-28.
Borjas, George, Richard B. Freeman, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1997.
"How Much Do Immigration and Trade Affect Labor Market
Outcomes?" BPEA, no. 1: 1-90.
Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2006. "International Comparisons
of Hourly Compensation Costs for Production Workers in
Manufacturing." Washington.
Cline, William. 1997. Trade and Income Distribution. Washington:
Institute for International Economics.
Dean, Judith, K. C. Fung, and Zhi Wang. 2007. "Measuring the
Vertical Specialization in Chinese Trade." USITC Working Paper.
Washington: U.S. International Trade Commission.
Faberman, R. Jason. 2004. "Gross Job Flows over the Last Two
Business Cycles: Not All Recoveries Are Created Equal." BLS Working
Paper 372. Washington: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 2007. "Long-Run Changes
in the Wage Structure." BPEA, no. 2: 135-67.
Gourevitch, Peter, Roger Bohn, and David McKendrick. 2000.
"Globalization of Production: Insights from the Hard Disk Drive
Industry." Worm Development 28, no. 2: 301-17.
Hummels, David, Jun Ishii, and Kei-Mu Yi. 2001. "The Nature
and Growth of Vertical Specialization in World Trade." Journal of
International Economics 54: 75-96.
Jin, Jianmin. 2006. "The Current Status of China's
Electronic Information Industry." Tokyo: Fujitsu Research
Institute.
Klier, Thomas, and James Ruhenstein. 2006. "Competition and
Trade in the U.S. Auto Parts Sector." Fed Letter 222. Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Krugman, Paul R. 1980. "Scale Economies, Product
Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade." American Economic
Review 70, no. 5: 950-59.
--. 1995. "Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences."
BPEA, no. 1 (Spring): 327-77.
--. 1996. "But For, As If, and So What?" Massachusetts
Institute of Technology.
--. 2000. "Technology, Trade, and Factor Prices." Journal
of International Economics 50, no. 1: 51-71.
Lawrence, Robert Z. 1996. Single World, Divided Nations?
International Trade and OECD Labor Markets'. Brookings.
--. 2008. Blue-Collar Blues: Is Trade to Blame for Rising US Income
Inequality? Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Leamer, Edward. 1994. "Trade, Wages, and Revolving Door
Ideas." Working Paper 4716. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Linden, Greg, Kenneth Kraemer, and Jason Dedrick. 2007. "Who
Captures Value in a Global Innovation System? The Case of Apple's
iPod." University of California, Irvine.
Mishel, Lawrence, Jared Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto. 2006. The
State of Working America 2006/2007. Cornell University Press and
Economic Policy Institute.
Romalis, John. 2004. "Factor Proportions and the Structure of
Commodity Trade." American Economic Review 94, no. 1 : 67-97.
Schott, Peter. 2000. "One Size Fits All? Heckscher-Ohlin
Specialization in International Production." Yale University.
--. 2001. "One Size Fits All? Heckscher-Ohlin Specialization
in International Production." Working Paper 8244. Cambridge, Mass.:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
--. 2006. "The Relative Sophistication of Chinese
Exports." Working Paper 12173. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Stolper, Wolfgang, and Paul Samuelson. 1941. "Protection and
Real Wages." Review of Economic Studies 9, no. 1: 58-73.
PAUL R. KRUGMAN
Princeton University
(1.) Stolper and Samuelson (1941).
(2.) Blinder (2006).
(3.) Bernanke (2007).
(4.) Throughout this paper, manufactured goods are defined using
the North American Industry Classification System (NAICS).
"Developed countries" are defined as all members of the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development except Korea,
Mexico, and Turkey; all others are developing countries.
(5.) Bivens (2007); Krugman (1995).
(6.) Bureau of Labor Statistics (2006).
(7.) Lawrence (2008).
(8.) The most commonly used measure of the relative wages of U.S.
trading partners, from the BLS (2006), gives a somewhat different
picture from that in table 2: it shows a more rapid rise between 1975
and 1990, from 62 percent to 80 percent of the U.S. level, and
essentially no change from 1990 to 2005. However, the BLS measure is
fixed-weighted: hourly compensation in each country is weighted by 2004
trade with the United States. As a result, the BLS index does not
reflect the recent shift in U.S. manufactures trade to developing
countries.
(9.) Hummels, Ishii, and Yi (2001).
(10.) Faberman (2004).
(11.) Lawrence (2008).
(12.) Goldin and Katz (2007).
(13.) Leamer (1994).
(14.) Krugman (1995).
(15.) Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997).
(16.) Krugman (1996, 2000).
(17.) Note, however, that the relevant elasticity of substitution
between factors is the one that would prevail in the absence of trade.
So it is somewhat problematic to rely, as for example Borjas, Freeman,
and Katz (1997) do, on estimates of this elasticity from time series
that include a period of significant trade.
(18.) Mishel, Bernstein, and Allegretto (2006).
(19.) Romalis (2004).
(20.) As modeled in Krugman (1980).
(21.) Dean, Fung, and Wang (2007).
(22.) Linden, Kraemer, and Dedrick (2007).
(23.) By the mid-1990s, the assembly of hard disk drives had
already moved overwhelmingly to low-wage countries. Yet the United
States and Japan still accounted for 65 percent of the wages paid by the
industry considered as a whole. See Gourevitch, Bohn, and McKendrick
(2000).
(24.) See "Frequently Asked Questions about Intel
Manufacturing and ProductionRelated Services,"
www.intel.com/pressroom/kits/manufacturing/ manufacturing_qa.htm.
(25.) Klier and Rubenstein (2006, p. 2).
(26.) Jin (2006).
(27.) Schott (2006).
(28.) See, in particular, Schott (2001) and Lawrence (2008).
(29.) Schott (2000).
(30.) Lawrence (2008).
(31.) Krugman (1995).
(32.) Bivens (2007).
Table 1. Selected Estimates of the Effect of Trade on Wages
Effect of trade with
developingO
countries on
skilled-unskilled
wage ratio Date of most
Study (percentage points) recent data
Krugman (1995) 3 1992
Lawrence (1996) 3 1993
Cline (1997) 7 1993
Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997) 1.4 1995
Sources: Literature cited.
Table 2. Average Hourly Compensation in the Top Ten U.S. Trading
Partners, 1975, 1990, and 2005
Average hourly
compensation
(percent of U.S.
Year Top ten trading partners (largest first) average) (a)
1975 Canada, Japan, Germany, United Kingdom, 76
Mexico, France, Italy, Brazil,
the Netherlands, Belgium
1990 Canada, Japan, Mexico, Germany, 81 (b)
United Kingdom, Taiwan, South Korea,
France, Italy, China
2005 Canada, Mexico, China, Japan, Germany, 65 (c)
United Kingdom, South Korea, Taiwan,
France, Malaysia
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (2006); Statistical Abstract of
the United States.
(a.) Averages are weighted by the countries' shares in total U.S.
trade.
(b.) China's hourly compensation is assumed to be 1 percent of the
U.S. level.
(c.) Malaysia's hourly compensation is estimated from United Nations
data.
Table 3. China and Mexico: GDP and Manufactured Exports to the United
States, 1990 and 2006
Percent of U.S. GD Change,
1990-2006
Country and measure 1990 2006 (percent)
China
GDP 6.7 20.0 199
Manufactured exports 0.24 2.13 788
Mexico
GDP 4.6 6.4 39
Manufactured exports 0.37 1.16 214
Sources: U.S. International Trade Commission DataWeb; International
Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook database.
Table 4. College- and Non-College-Educated Workers Displaced by
Trade (a) Percent of all workers displaced
College Non-college
Period graduate (b) graduates
1979-89 12.2 87.8
1989-2000 21.2 78.9
2000-04 21.3 78.7
Memorandum: Shares of 25.6 74.4
total employment, 2000
Source: Mishel, Bernstein, and Allegretto (2006).
(a.) Percentages may not sum to 100 because of rounding.
(b.) Individuals attending four years of college or more.
Table 5. Changes in Real Wages under Industry Co-Location
and Vertical Specialization (a)
Industries Vertical
Percent co-located specialization
Skilled workers +13.4 +15.9
Unskilled workers -11.8 -13.6
Memorandum: Import share 13.6 53.5
in North GDP
Source: Author's calculations using the model described in the text.
(a.) Calculated as described in the text.