The effect of dividends on consumption.
Baker, Malcolm ; Nagel, Stefan ; Wurgler, Jeffrey 等
MICROSOFT'S $32 BILLION CASH dividend of December 2004 was the
largest corporate payout ever. Classical models of finance and
consumption-saving decisions predict that this dividend will have little
effect on the consumption of Microsoft investors. Under the assumptions
of Merton Miller and Franco Modigliani, for example, investors can
always reinvest unwanted dividends, or sell shares to create homemade
dividends, and thereby insulate their preferred consumption stream from
corporate dividend policies. (1) Thus, in traditional models, the
division of stock returns into dividends and capital gains is a
financial decision of the firm that has no "real" consequence
for investor consumption patterns.
Yet there are a number of reasons to think that dividend policy,
and dividends more generally, may indeed affect consumption. Most
obviously, the popular advice to "consume income, not
principal" suggests a potentially widespread mental accounting
practice in which investors do not view dividends and capital gains as
fungible, as in the homemade dividends story and traditional theories of
consumption, but rather place them into different mental accounts from
which they have different propensities to consume. (2) This behavior is
also consistent with a belief that dividends, unlike capital gains,
represent permanent income. Less exotic but equally realistic frictions,
such as transaction costs (of making homemade dividends) and taxes, can
also lead an investor to favor consuming dividends before capital
appreciation.
Although the dividends-consumption link is a potentially
fundamental one between corporate finance and the real economy, little
empirical research has pursued the issue. The reason is probably that
the most easily available data on consumption and dividends are
aggregate time-series data, which have several limitations. Among other
challenges, such data require one to identify the effect of a smooth
aggregate dividend series using a small number of data points; they
combine investors and noninvestors; and they face an essentially
prohibitive endogeneity problem: omitted variables such as business
conditions will jointly affect consumption, dividends, and capital
appreciation, making it difficult to establish the causality behind any
observed correlations.
This paper studies the effect of dividends on investor consumption
using two micro data sets that reveal and exploit powerful
cross-sectional variation in dividend receipts and capital gains. The
first is the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX), which is a repeated
cross section with data on expenditure measures and self-reported
dividend income and capital gains (or losses). Our CEX sample includes
several hundred households per year between 1988 and 2001. The second
data set includes the trading records of tens of thousands of households
with accounts at a large discount brokerage from 1991 through 1996. (3)
Although these portfolio data do not contain an explicit expenditure
measure, they complement the CEX by allowing us to accurately measure
net withdrawals from the portfolio, a novel dependent variable in its
own right and a precursor to expenditure. The data set also allows us to
measure the withdrawal rates of different types of dividend income,
including ordinary, special, and mutual fund dividends, which allows for
finer comparisons.
We start with an analysis of the CEX data. Our most basic approach
is to regress consumption on realized dividend income, controlling for
total returns including dividends. The coefficient on dividend income
thus captures differences between the consumption responses to dividends
and to capital gains. We find that the coefficient on realized dividend
income for total consumption expenditure is large, positive, and
significant. This basic result is robust to a variety of control
variables and estimation techniques, including specifications in first
differences. It suggests that, contrary to classical models, the form of
returns does matter for consumption.
We then use the brokerage account data in an effort to test the
mechanism behind this effect; that is, we test whether dividends are
indeed withdrawn from the household portfolio at a higher rate than
capital gains. The data strongly confirm this. On average, investors do
not reinvest ordinary dividends: the propensity to withdraw modest
levels of ordinary dividends is unity. A fraction of mutual fund and
special dividends is also withdrawn. On the other hand, very large
dividends of any type are not fully withdrawn. As in the CEX data, the
effect of capital appreciation on net withdrawals is uniformly smaller
than the effect of dividends.
We conduct a variety of subsample splits and robustness tests on
each data set. The results suggest that the apparent differential effect
of dividend income on net withdrawals and consumption is at least partly
causal; that is, it does not arise only because investors who plan to
consume dividends in the future buy dividend-paying stocks. In
particular, we find that investors tend to withdraw from both
predictable and unpredictable components of dividends. For instance,
investors often withdraw special dividend income, which is unpredictable
by definition.
In sum, although the CEX and the portfolio data involve completely
different households and somewhat different data concepts, they lead to
qualitatively similar results, namely, that investor consumption is
affected by the form of returns, not just the level. What drives this
effect? We first evaluate explanations based on well-understood
frictions such as transaction costs, taxes, and borrowing constraints.
Upon inspection, however, none of these explanations is fully
satisfactory. Borrowing constraints are irrelevant in this setting,
because the substitution of dividends for capital gains has no overall
wealth effect, and homemade dividends can be created by selling shares.
Tax stories are varied, but none seems consistent with key aspects of
the data. Transaction costs cannot account for, for example, the fact
that households with low rates of portfolio turnover withdraw dividends
at rates similar to those of high-turnover households.
Although our findings are surely driven by a combination of
factors, mental accounting seems among the most compelling. The notion
that many investors do not view dividends and capital gains as fungible
seems especially plausible in light of the popular adage to
"consume income, not principal." Mental accounting offers a
natural explanation for both our main findings and certain finer
results. For example, ordinary dividends are more likely to be mentally
accounted for as current income than are large special dividends. Hence,
the mental accounting framework predicts a higher propensity to consume
from ordinary dividends than from large special dividends. This is what
we find in net withdrawals (where we can measure different types of
dividends). Tax and transaction cost explanations, on the other hand, do
not predict this pattern.
This paper builds on earlier work that uses aggregate data. (4)
Some papers have viewed the equality of the propensity to consume from
dividends and corporate retained earnings, not capital appreciation, as
the null hypothesis of interest and found weak evidence that corporate
saving affects consumption. Other papers find little evidence that
capital gains and losses have an effect on aggregate consumption. (5)
Our results also relate to evidence, consistent with the existing
literature on the consumption response to windfalls, that consumers have
a relatively high propensity to consume moderately sized cash windfalls.
(6) It appears that ordinary dividends are treated like moderate-size
windfalls. However, our analysis differs from the existing literature in
that we focus on the relative propensity to consume two forms of income,
dividends and capital gains, holding their sum, total return, constant.
More broadly, this study falls into a growing literature on
"household finance." (7)
At the end of the paper, we briefly consider what our estimates
imply for the response of aggregate consumption to the May 2003 dividend
tax cuts. Alternative scenarios suggest a consumption stimulus in the
range of $8.3 billion to $49.9 billion, which is not insubstantial in
relation to a standard deviation of total personal consumption
expenditure of $66 billion over the preceding five years.
Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey
Our first data set is drawn from the Consumer Expenditure Survey,
obtained from the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social
Research at the University of Michigan. The strength of the CEX is its
detailed data on household consumption and demographics. Its comparative
weakness, for our purpose, is that dividends and portfolio returns are
self-reported and thus likely to be noisy. After introducing the data
and definitions, we describe our empirical methodology and then present
regression estimates of the effects of dividends on consumption.
Data and Definitions
The CEX has been conducted annually by the Bureau of Labor
Statistics since 1980. (8) It is a short panel based on a stratified random sample of the U.S. population. Selected households are
interviewed quarterly for five quarters and are then replaced by new
households. As we discuss more fully below, the information on financial
asset holdings and changes in these holdings over the preceding twelve
months is collected in the fifth interview; data on dividends, interest
received, other income variables, and demographics are collected in the
second and fifth interviews and cover the twelve months before the
interview date. We extract most of the variables from the CEX family
files, but the data on housing and credit are from the detailed
expenditure files.
Basic variables are as follows. We consider both expenditure on
nondurable goods and total expenditure (which includes durables) as
measures of consumption. A priori it is not clear which of the two
consumption measures is likely to be affected more strongly by
dividends. On one hand, nondurables expenditure is less lumpy and could
be adjusted more smoothly in response to changing dividend income than
durables expenditure. On the other hand, durables consumption is more
discretionary than nondurables consumption, and so the household might
have more flexibility to adjust durables consumption when dividend
income changes. We define nondurables consumption, C, as the sum of
food, alcohol, apparel, transportation, entertainment, personal care,
and reading expenditure. (9) We use the total expenditure variable as
provided in the CEX. In both cases we sum consumption over the four
quarters from the second to the fifth interview. Dividends, D, are
defined as (in the words of the survey question) "the amount of
regular income from dividends, royalties, estates, or trusts" over
the past twelve months. We also collect interest, I, received by the
household. We use reported income after taxes, Y, as a proxy for total
income.
Total wealth, W, is the sum of home equity (property values less
outstanding mortgage balances) and financial wealth. Financial wealth is
the sum of balances in checking accounts, savings accounts, savings
bonds, money owed to the household, and "stocks" (which
includes not only holdings of stocks and mutual funds, but also
corporate bonds and government bonds that are not savings bonds), minus
other debt. (10) Before 1988, information on the level of mortgage
balances is lacking from the CEX, so we use the 1988 to 2001 data only.
Also, whereas for financial assets we can measure changes over the
twelve months preceding the fifth interview, for other wealth components
(home equity and "other debt") we can compute only the change
over the nine months between the second and the fifth interviews.
In their fifth interview survey participants are asked about the
amount of securities purchased and sold over the preceding twelve
months. This information allows us to decompose the change in the value
of stock holdings into an active investment or disinvestment component
and a capital gains or losses component. To compute the latter, G, we
need to make an assumption regarding the timing of investment. We assume
that half the reported investment was made at the beginning of the
period and half at the end.
We employ a few filters to screen out unusual observations. We
require that there be only one consumer unit (family) in the household
and that the marital status of the respondent and the size of the family
remain the same from the second to the fifth interview. We delete observations where any wealth component or income is topcoded. (11) We
require that lagged financial wealth be positive and that a nonzero fraction of this wealth be invested in stocks or mutual funds. This last
screen is the most significant: most (roughly 80 percent) of the
households in the sample do not participate in the stock market. We use
the consumer price index (CPI) to deflate all variables to December 2001
dollars.
Summary Statistics
Table 1 presents summary statistics for the CEX data. After
applying the filters, we have 3,106 household-year observations. In this
sample, mean nondurables consumption, reported in the top panel, is
$15,042, and the median is slightly lower. Total expenditure, including
durables, is three to four times as large. The next two panels report
wealth and income measures. Financial wealth is typically around a third
of total wealth. Total income, which includes dividends but not capital
gains, has a mean of $56,566 and again a slightly lower median.
Comparing the first and third panels, one sees that, on average, total
income is slightly higher than total expenditure. For the households in
our sample that hold some stock, average interest income is $1,264 and
average dividends total $935.
As one would expect, the mean capital gain of $363 is relatively
small compared with total income, and its average share in total income
is roughly the same as the average share of interest income. Capital
gains, however, do show significant variation across households. Note
that the extreme values are from wealthy households with a large amount
of financial wealth. What the table does not show is that capital gains
also vary widely across time: virtually all of the largest negative
observations, including the minimum of--$301,407, originate from 2001,
where the measurement period includes the crash in technology stock
prices during 2000 and 2001.
The fourth panel shows that, on average, interest and dividends
account for 4 percent and 2 percent of total income, respectively. The
distribution is skewed, with a median household dividend income of zero.
It is likely that some of the zero-dividend observations in the CEX
result from underreporting of dividends by the interviewees. To ensure
that our results are not driven by the zero-dividend observations, we
include a zero-dividend dummy variable in our regressions.
Empirical Methodology
The null hypothesis of interest is that capital gains and dividends
are fungible, which means that households should react similarly to a
change in wealth whether it comes in the form of a capital gain or in
the form of a dividend. In other words, only the total return should
matter, not the split of that return into dividends and capital gains or
losses.
To test this hypothesis, we run ordinary least squares regressions
with specifications alternatively in levels, first differences, and log
differences. We describe and motivate these in turn. Our basic levels
specification is as follows:
(1) [C.sub.it] = [a.sub.0] + [a'.sub.1][Z.sub.it] +
[a'.sub.2][F.sub.it] + g[R.sub.it] + d[D.sub.it] + [u.sub.it],
where [C.sub.it] is household i's consumption in period t (in
this specification, consumption is summed over the four quarters
preceding the fifth interview); [Z.sub.it] is a vector of household
characteristics; [F.sub.it] is a vector of financial variables that
includes income, lagged wealth, and interactions with [Z.sub.it];
[R.sub.it] is the total dollar return on stocks including dividends; and
[D.sub.it] is total dollar dividend income. In equation 1 the total
stock return is already accounted for with [R.sub.it] and therefore d =
0 under the null. However, if for some reason a household has a higher
propensity to consume from dividends than from capital gains, we expect
d > 0.
The levels specification can be interpreted as an approximation to
the consumption rule used by households. Different consumption models
map income, wealth, and other household characteristics onto consumption
in different ways. (12) We are agnostic as to which consumption model is
most accurate. Our goal is simply to distinguish between models in which
capital gains and dividends are fungible and those in which the effect
of dividends diverges from that of capital gains. We approximate the
consumption rule with a range of variables that may be relevant for
consumption decisions, allowing them to enter linearly, quadratically,
and through interactions to approximate the nonlinear consumption
function. (13) In the end the levels specification boils down to asking
whether two consumers in the same financial situation, with similar
income, similar household characteristics, and similar total return on
financial assets, but different compositions of total returns across
dividends and capital gains, have different consumption.
Household characteristics in [Z.sub.it], include the education of
the household head (dummies for high school and college graduation), the
age of the household head, age of household head squared, family size,
family size squared, and a set of year-month fixed effects to absorb
seasonal variation in consumption as well as variation in macroeconomic factors. (14) Financial variables in [F.sub.it] include variables that
proxy for future income and for current cash on hand, including income
after tax (excluding dividends), (15) lagged total wealth, lagged
financial wealth, the percentage of financial wealth invested in stocks,
and the squares of all these variables. We also allow for interactions
of age and family size with income, lagged wealth, and lagged financial
wealth.
In interpreting an estimate that d > 0, the key question is
whether this set of controls is sufficient or whether some omitted
variable could be positively correlated with dividends, thus biasing
upward the estimate of d. Although all of these controls should do a
reasonable job of approximating households' consumption rule, it is
difficult to fully rule out the possibility of some remaining unobserved
difference between households that hold dividend-paying stocks and those
that hold nonpaying stocks. Moreover, wealth and capital gains in the
CEX survey are inevitably measured with error, and this sort of
measurement error problem causes an upward bias in our dividend
coefficient, to the extent that dividends proxy for mismeasured wealth
changes. To address this omitted variables problem we also run
regressions in first differences, which removes any household fixed
effects that could be correlated with dividend income.
Differencing is also useful for addressing an important endogeneity
concern, namely, that any relationship between dividends and consumption
is not causal but rather reflects the fact that households that expect
to consume might decide ex ante to hold securities that pay the
preferred consumption stream in the form of dividends. (16) While such
an "ex ante effect" would also mean that fungibility does not
hold, in the sense that some consumers anticipate their unwillingness to
consume from principal and adjust their portfolio accordingly, it would
not imply that the composition of returns has an effect on consumption.
However, to the extent that any such ex ante effect is largely a
household fixed effect, with only slow time variation, differencing
should help to eliminate it.
Our basic differences specification is as follows: (17)
(2) [DELTA][C.sub.it] = [b.sub.0] + [b'.sub.1][Z.sub.it] +
[b'.sub.2][DELTA]([Y.sub.it] - [D.sub.it]) + g[R.sub.it] +
d[DELTA][D.sub.it] + [e.sub.it].
Since the CEX offers at most four quarterly consumption
observations per household, we define [DELTA][C.sub.it] as the
difference in consumption between the fifth and the second interview. As
mentioned above, dividends and income in the CEX are measured over
overlapping twelve-month periods leading up to the second and fifth
interviews. We define [DELTA][D.sub.it] and [DELTA]([Y.sub.it] -
[D.sub.it]) as the difference in the reported values. Because of the
imperfect matching of measurement periods between [DELTA][C.sub.it] and
[DELTA][D.sub.it], the d estimate is likely to be biased toward zero.
(The same is true for [b.sub.2].) Inferences about the magnitude of d
will thus be difficult, but a significant positive coefficient will
still be meaningful, as the null is still d = 0. As before, [Z.sub.it]
is a vector of household characteristics and time dummies. In some
specifications we also include the level of second-quarter consumption
as an explanatory variable, because it may pick up some noise that is
introduced through the measurement-period mismatch between
[DELTA][C.sub.it] and the income variables.
Finally, to check whether the results are robust to functional
form, we also try a third set of specifications with the change in the
logarithm of consumption as the dependent variable. There we use an
indicator variable for the sign of dividend growth as our key
explanatory variable, because we lack a clear prediction about how
consumption growth would be affected quantitatively by dividend growth.
For example, a 10 percent increase in dividends would presumably have a
different effect on the percentage growth in consumption when dividends
are a small proportion of total income than when they are a large
proportion. By using an indicator variable, we simply estimate the
average difference in consumption growth between households with
dividend increases and those with dividend decreases. (18)
Effects of Dividends on Household Consumption
Table 2 reports estimates of equation 1. Specifications in the
first four columns use nondurables consumption as the dependent
variable, and the rest use total expenditure. Independent variables in
the first specification include total returns, dividends, and a dummy for zero dividends, plus a large number of controls. We find little
economic impact of total returns on consumption, and no statistically
significant relationship. But dividends are positively related to the
level of consumption, and the effect is statistically significant. A
one-dollar difference between households in dividends received is
associated with a 16-cent difference in nondurables consumption. (19)
The second specification reported in table 2 includes the first
lagged value of dividends, as a first step toward distinguishing between
the "ex ante" (endogenous dividend-consumption clientele) and
"ex post" (causal) effects that d could capture. (As mentioned
previously, our main approach to dealing with this issue is
differencing, results of which follow below.) Specifically, if ex ante
matching of anticipated dividends and consumption were the full story,
then lagged and contemporaneous dividends should have about the same
correlation with current consumption. As it turns out, however, the
effect of current dividends is far stronger than that of lagged
dividends, consistent with a causal effect of dividends on consumption
that goes beyond ex ante matching.
The third and fourth specifications look at the sum of dividends
and interest income, [D.sub.t], + [I.sub.t]. It seems possible that
mental accounting consumers, for example, would treat interest income
and dividend income similarly; likewise, spending from interest income
allows households to skirt the transaction costs of selling bonds in the
same way that spending from dividends avoids the costs of selling stock.
The results provide some support for these analogies, as the effect of
[D.sub.t], + [I.sub.t], on consumption is similar to that of [D.sub.t].
The last four specifications in table 2 use total expenditure as
the dependent variable. The estimated coefficients on [D.sub.t] and
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] are roughly four to five times those in the
regressions with nondurables consumption on the left-hand side. As total
expenditure is proportionally higher than nondurables consumption, on
average these results suggest that dividend income is not used
exclusively for nondurables consumption but rather boosts expenditure of
all types. In all other respects, the results in these specifications
are similar to those for nondurables.
It is interesting that no evidence emerges of a significant effect
of capital gains; indeed, all the point estimates on total returns are
negative. Of course, a low (but positive) propensity to consume capital
gains would not have been surprising. Under the permanent income
hypothesis, for instance, forward-looking consumers spread the
consumption from an unexpected increase in wealth over their lifetime,
so that the coefficient on total returns is predicted to be on the order
of the real interest rate. From this perspective, what is striking about
the results in table 2 is the far higher consumption from the return
component that we label "dividends." The very large effects of
dividends on total expenditure, in particular, strongly suggest that
individuals consume dividends disproportionately in the period in which
they are received.
Table 3 reports estimates of equation 2. The first specification
includes total returns, the change in dividends, and other controls,
including a dummy for zero dividends over the preceding and current
twelve-month periods and, in some specifications, lagged consumption.
Since we are regressing the change in quarterly consumption (from the
second to the fifth interview) on changes in dividends measured over
twelve-month periods (preceding the second and fifth interviews), one
would expect the coefficient estimates on [DELTA][D.sub.t] to be about
one quarter of those on [D.sub.t] in the levels specifications.
The results indicate that multiplying the coefficient estimates on
[DELTA][D.sub.t] by four does yield numbers that are at least of the
same order of magnitude as the estimates in table 2, although somewhat
lower, in particular for the nondurables specifications. The moderate
decrease is consistent with some ex ante effect in the levels estimates,
but it could also reflect the noise introduced through the imperfect
matching of dividends and consumption measurement periods. Consistent
with the latter possibility, controlling for lagged consumption, which
should absorb some of the noise, raises the magnitude of the coefficient
on dividend changes. But for the nondurables specifications overall,
standard errors are large, and the coefficient estimates are at best
marginally significant. For total expenditure, on the other hand, all
coefficient estimates for [DELTA][D.sub.t] and [DELTA][D.sub.t] +
[DELTA][I.sub.t] are statistically significant.
Table 4 presents results of the regressions specified in log
differences. As mentioned above, the analysis here focuses on a dummy
variable for an increase in dividends. Its coefficient measures the
average difference in consumption growth between households with
dividend increases and those without. In all specifications the
coefficient estimates on the [DELTA][D.sub.t] > 0 dummy is positive,
and it is significantly different from zero in all but the first two
nondurables specifications. But even there the point estimate is
economically large: the average household that experiences an increase
in dividend income increases its consumption by 2 percent relative to
the average household that does not.
We also experimented with splitting the sample by age. Dividends
account for a bigger fraction of income in households headed by older
individuals and are larger in absolute terms: the mean dividend income
for households with a household head below age 65 is $614, versus $1,818
for households with a household head of age 65 or older. On one hand,
the consumption effects of dividends could be stronger for older
households, because those households might be more aware of their
dividend income, and that income is more likely to be retirement income.
On the other hand, older households could be less prone to consume from
dividends according to a simple mental accounting rule, because
dividends make up a substantial part of their income and the household
might therefore think more carefully about spending them.
The results are as ambiguous as the theoretical predictions. For
example, rerunning the base case total expenditure regression
(regression 2-5) from table 2, with dividends interacted with a dummy
variable for age greater than 65, yields a negative coefficient on the
interaction term (-0.43) that is on the borderline of statistical
significance (standard error of 0.23). Interacting age with dividends
produces similarly insignificant results. This seems consistent with the
argument that older households' consumption is less sensitive to
dividend income. However, even taking the point estimates at face value,
dividend income has a quantitatively more important effect on dollar
consumption for older households than for younger ones, because the
variation in dividends across older households is so much larger.
As an additional robustness check, we have also removed capital
gains outliers from the regression. In a survey like the CEX, which is
based on self-reported information, the capital gains data are likely to
have substantial measurement error. We want to ensure that the absence
of a capital gains effect on consumption is not caused by a few large
and potentially erroneous outliers. Winsorizing capital gains at their
5th and 95th percentiles, however, results in quantitatively similar
estimates. (20) Perhaps more important, winsorizing the capital gains
data leaves the coefficients on dividends virtually unaffected. Overall,
it seems that the results are not unduly influenced by outliers.
In summary, the best available U.S. micro data on consumption
suggest that controlling for total returns, dividends have a significant
effect on consumption. The relationship is generally robust across
specifications in levels, simple differences, and log differences.
Evidence from Household Portfolios
As already mentioned, a concern with the self-reported CEX data is
that dividends and capital gains are likely to be measured with
substantial error. It is not clear to what extent measurement error
influences the foregoing results. Furthermore, the results would be made
even more persuasive if we could verify the intermediate, mechanical
step between receipt of dividends and consumption expenditure--that
dividends are in fact withdrawn from brokerage accounts, and at a higher
rate than capital gains. Our second micro data set, based on household
portfolios, achieves these objectives and thus complements the CEX data.
Furthermore, it allows us to study net withdrawals from investment
portfolios, an interesting and novel dependent variable in its own
right. (21) Finally, the larger sample size and detail of the portfolio
data allow for certain robustness tests and sample splits that are not
possible in the CEX data.
Data and Definitions
Our household portfolio data set contains monthly position
statements and trading activity for a sample of 78,000 households with
accounts at a large discount brokerage firm. (22) To enter the sample,
households were required to have an open account during 1991. For the
sampled households, position statements and accounts data were gathered
for January 1991 through December 1996. The full data set covers all
accounts, including margin and retirement accounts, opened by each
sampled household at this brokerage. For our sample we exclude margin
accounts, Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs), Keogh accounts, and
accounts that are not joint tenancy or individual accounts. Securities
followed include common stocks, mutual and closed-end funds, American
depository receipts, and warrants and options held in these accounts. We
focus on common stocks and mutual funds, which represent all, or nearly
all, of most households' portfolios.
We use household-month level observations on net withdrawals,
portfolio value, capital gains, and total dividends. Net withdrawals C
(we use C in analogy to our earlier definitions, although, to be
precise, we are not studying consumption but rather net withdrawals in
this data set) are inferred as the starting value of portfolio assets A,
plus capital gains G, plus dividends D, minus the ending value of the
portfolio. That is, for household i,
(3) [C.sub.it] = [A.sub.it] + [G.sub.it] + [D.sub.it] - [A.sub.it],
where the components that can be directly estimated include total
portfolio value, defined as the product of price P and quantity Q held
in investment j and summed across investments,
(4) [A.sub.it] = [summation over j][Q.sub.jt][P.sub.jt];
capital gains,
(5) [G.sub.it] = [summation over
j][Q.sub.jt-1]([P.sub.jt]-[P.sub.jt-1]),
where prices are adjusted for stock splits; and total dividend
income,
(6) [D.sub.it] = [summation over j][Q.sub.jt-1][D.sub.jt],
where [D.sub.jt], is dividends paid per share of investment j.
For simplicity, we suppress the household i subscript on per-share
quantities, prices, and dividends.
To estimate these quantities from the brokerage data, we pool each
household's accounts to obtain positions and trades by
household-month. The brokerage data do not directly identify dividend
income; we match portfolio holdings to the stock file of the Center for
Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) database to measure dividends on
common stocks, and to the CRSP mutual fund file to measure dividends on
mutual funds. For each stock and mutual fund in a household's
portfolio at the beginning of the month, we use the monthly CRSP data on
dividend distributions to calculate the dollar amount of dividends
received during that month. We assume that each household holds until
the end of the month the securities in its portfolio at the beginning of
the month. For common stock dividends, we use CRSP distribution codes
1232, 1212, 1218, 1222, and 1245 to identify ordinary dividends, and
1262 and 1272 to identify special dividends. (23) We then total the
dollar amounts of stock and mutual fund dividends across all stocks and
funds in the portfolio to get a monthly measure of dividends.
The data contain outliers due to account openings and closings that
do not reflect actual consumption and saving decisions. We exclude
household-month observations where we cannot identify a CRSP mutual fund
or common stock match for at least 75 percent of the account value at
month t - 1, and we exclude households where the account value fails
below $10,000, or dividends are missing in any of the months t to t -
11. This leaves 93,312 household-months of data on lagged account value,
dividends, capital gains, and net withdrawals. These data still contain
some outliers; for instance, the minimum value for net withdrawals as a
percentage of lagged account value is -2,807.7, indicating a very large
net inflow of funds in that portfolio. To prevent a few such data points
from driving results, we exclude household-months in which net
withdrawals exceed 50 percent in absolute value. This screen excludes
about 0.96 percent of the sample. (24) The final sample includes 92,412
household-months.
The household portfolio data have fairly clear advantages over the
CEX data, but also some limitations of their own. One is that we usually
do not know how large the accounts we observe figure in the
household's total wealth, although for a fraction of the sample we
do have self-reported data on household net worth. (25) In any case it
is not clear that this should lead to bias as opposed to just adding
noise. Another limitation is that we observe net withdrawals, not
consumption. Although, as mentioned above, this means that the portfolio
data are a useful complement to the CEX, a concern is that dividends and
realized capital gains may be deposited into a cash account that we
cannot observe. If so, and if a portion of these funds is eventually
reinvested and ultimately reappears in the portfolio, we should not be
counting that portion as potential consumption. Therefore an important
part of the analysis below is to examine the extent to which
contemporaneous withdrawals are offset by delayed reinvestment; for
consumption, we care only about long-run withdrawals.
Summary Statistics
The size and composition of the portfolios in the sample are
described in the top panel of table 5. The mean account value is $54,410
and the median is $28,430. On average, common stocks make up 82.7
percent of the total portfolio value, and mutual funds another 13.5
percent.
Changes in portfolio value are reported in the second panel. To
make cross-household comparisons, we scale net withdrawals, capital
gains, and dividend estimates by portfolio value at the end of month t -
1. The mean rate of net withdrawals by household-month in our sample is
low, at less than 0.1 percent, and the median rate is zero. The average
total monthly return is positive, at 1.1 percent. The average dividend
income per month, 0.2 percent of beginning-of-month portfolio value, is
a significant fraction of the average month's total return, but
much less volatile.
The final two panels of table 5 break dividend income down by type
of dividend. Dividend income is positive in just under half of all
household-months. For these observations (bottom panel), an average of
77.9 percent of dividend income is due to ordinary dividends, with
mutual funds accounting for almost all of the remainder. Special
dividends are rare but can be very large when they do occur.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Effects of Dividends and Capital Gains on Net Withdrawals
Figure 1 is a scatterplot of household-month observations of net
withdrawals against contemporaneous total dividends. The figure clearly
shows two modal behaviors with respect to dividend income. The
clustering of points along a line indicating a one-for-one increasing
relationship between net withdrawals and dividends suggests that many
investors follow a "zero (contemporaneous) reinvestment"
policy; the clustering of points along a second line indicating a flat
relationship suggests that many other investors have an "automatic
reinvestment" policy. The many thousands of observations that lie
on neither line suggest a weakly positive relationship more generally.
An analogous scatterplot of net withdrawals as a function of capital
gains (not shown) reveals no visible patterns.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 2 plots median and mean responses to dividend payouts. In
the top left panel, dividend income is broken down into eleven groups,
one for household-months with no dividend income and ten deciles for
those with positive dividends. Within each group we plot median net
withdrawals against median total dividends. The results suggest that the
median household does not immediately reinvest moderate-size dividends:
net withdrawals increase one for one with dividend income over the
bottom several deciles; that is, in this range the first of the two
modal behaviors noted in figure 1 is also the median behavior.
The top right panel of figure 2 depicts the mean responses to
dividend payouts. We show mean net withdrawals for the zero-dividend
group and for the mean level of dividends within each of the ten
positive-dividend deciles. The figure again shows a positive
relationship between dividends and net withdrawals. Note that the mean
behavior is to contemporaneously withdraw most, but not all, of a
relatively large dividend. (This could be consistent with a mental
accounting practice in which the large dividends that result from cash
acquisitions, for example, are treated not like ordinary dividends but
rather as principal to be reinvested.)
The bottom two panels provide an initial look at the effect of
total returns, again at the median and at the mean. The contrast with
the picture for dividends confirms the CEX results: the effect of total
returns appears to be much smaller. The bottom left panel shows that
regardless of the level of total returns, the median contemporaneous net
withdrawal is zero. The bottom right panel shows that, at the mean, very
large total returns engender net withdrawals, and very low total returns
net inflows. There is no clear effect in the intermediate range.
Table 6 reports regression estimates of the effects of
contemporaneous dividends and total returns on the rate of withdrawals.
The first three specifications include linear effects only; we then
confirm the additional structure suggested in the figures using a
piecewise linear specification. Specifically, we allow for a
differential effect when dividends are in the top decile and a
differential effect when total returns (primarily capital gains) are
smaller than 2.5 percent in absolute value. Again suppressing the
household i subscripts,
(7) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
It may be helpful to interpret the coefficients explicitly.
Regression 6-1 indicates that, on average, investors have a propensity
to contemporaneously withdraw dividends of about 0.35. Regression 6-2
shows an average propensity to contemporaneously withdraw total returns
of 0.02. Regression 6-3 shows that, for a given contemporaneous total
return, investors have a 0.35 higher propensity to withdraw from the
dividends component than from the capital gains component. Because the
propensity to withdraw from contemporaneous total returns is almost
zero, this also means that the total propensity to withdraw from
dividends is around 0.35, as in the first regression. Although direct
comparisons are not appropriate, it is interesting that these
coefficients are of the same order of magnitude as the effects of
dividends and capital gains on total consumption that we estimated in
the CEX data (tables 2 and 3). And again, what is most striking is not
that the coefficient on capital gains is so small, but that the
coefficient on dividends is so large.
As an aside, it may seem that the relatively small coefficient on
returns implies that the effect of capital gains on consumption is
negligible, but this is not obvious. In fact, because the range between
the 10th and the 90th percentile is about thirty times bigger for
returns (from -6.13 to 8.28 percent of total assets) than for dividends
(from 0.0 to 0.55; see table 5), the point estimates in table 6 suggest
that the variation in withdrawals caused by dividends and capital gains
may be of roughly similar magnitude. (Of course, we found at best weak
effects of total returns in the CEX, and so, unlike in the case of
dividends, we are unable to find any strong evidence that capital gains
lead to withdrawal-financed consumption.) In any case, given our
particular hypotheses, the appropriate focus is on the relative
magnitude of the dividend and capital gains effects for a given change
in wealth, not on the proportion of withdrawal variance explained by
each effect.
Of the last three regressions in table 6, which estimate piecewise
linear effects, the first indicates a propensity to withdraw
contemporaneous dividends of 0.77 for typical levels of dividend income
and of 0.33 (0.77 - 0.44) for unusually high levels. Regression 6-6
shows that, for small total returns, investors have a propensity to
withdraw from contemporaneous capital gains of -0.03 (0.02 - 0.05; that
is, they do not withdraw at all), whereas the differential propensity to
withdraw contemporaneous dividends stays the same. All of these results
are consistent with figure 2.
Delayed Reinvestment
Although the analysis so far suggests large differences in the
withdrawal behavior of dividends versus capital gains, and hence that
dividends may indeed affect consumption, several questions remain. One
is whether a portion of dividends (and perhaps capital gains), rather
than being withdrawn for consumption, may just have been temporarily
moved to a cash account and later reinvested. To the extent that is the
case, estimates based on contemporaneous effects will overstate the true
potential impact on consumption.
To investigate this effect, we augment our previous model to allow
for up to one year of delays in reinvestment. The resulting model is
unsightly but easy to interpret:
(8) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
In this specification, when the monthly total return is greater
than 2.5 percent in absolute value, the long-run propensity to withdraw
capital gains is ([r.sub.1] + [r.sub.3]). When smaller, the long-run
propensity is ([r.sub.1] + [r.sub.2] + [r.sub.3] + [r.sub.4]). Likewise,
the differential or "extra" long-run propensity to withdraw a
small or medium-size dividend income realization is ([d.sub.1] +
[d.sub.3]), and the differential long-run propensity to withdraw a
top-decile dividend realization is ([d.sub.1] + [d.sub.2] + [d.sub.3] +
[d.sub.4]). Note that in this setup any effect of delayed reinvestment
shows up empirically as a negative estimate for [d.sub.3] and [d.sub.4]
for dividends ([r.sub.3] and [r.sub.4] for capital gains), because
dividends or capital gains that are reinvested will be detected as
reduced net withdrawals as a function of the lagged variable. (26)
Table 7 shows that allowing for the possibility of a full year of
delayed reinvestment does not alter earlier inferences about the effects
of dividends. In the simple linear regressions (7-1 through 7-3), the
contemporaneous coefficients are as before, and the effects of lagged
dividends are nil. The full piecewise linear model (regression 7-6)
shows that the long-run propensity to withdraw small or medium-size
dividends is 0.73 (0.80 - 0.07) greater than that of total returns,
statistically indistinguishable from the 0.77 gap in the short-run
propensities to withdraw that we found in table 6, and thus indicating
little or no reinvestment. On the other hand, the differential long-run
propensity to withdraw very large dividends is still positive, but
considerably smaller, at 0.33 (0.80 - 0.47 - 0.07 + 0.07), which is also
the same as the estimate we obtained without allowing for delayed
reinvestment. Finally, there is little evidence that capital gains
engender reinvestment.
Thus accounting for delays in reinvestment does not change the
conclusion that there is a large difference in the propensities to
withdraw dividends and capital gains. Unless households in this sample
are out of steady state, systematically accumulating cash balances (and
doing so out of dividends, not capital gains), the results are
consistent with the notion that a substantial portion of dividend income
is permanently withdrawn to finance consumption.
Household Characteristics
To check the robustness of our results, we split the sample across
several household and portfolio characteristics (table 8). First, we
split by portfolio size. These accounts are believed to typically
represent a rather small fraction of the household's net worth, but
for about a fifth of the sample we have self-reported data on net worth
and tax rates supplied to the brokerage firm when the account was
opened, so we can test whether the results extend to households for
which the portfolio represents at least half of reported net worth.
Second, we split by net worth itself. Third, we split by marginal income
tax rate, which is obviously also a proxy for income. Fourth, we split
the sample by portfolio turnover.
The results suggest that the higher propensity to withdraw dividend
income is broadly robust across the available household characteristics.
Wealthier households appear more likely to reinvest very large
dividends, but again standard errors are too large to allow any
confident conclusions.
Composition of Dividends
Intuition and mental accounting theories suggest that it may be
inappropriate to treat all types of dividends as equivalent. The
nonlinear effects documented in figure 2 and table 6 may be due to
differences in the treatment of special dividends and ordinary
dividends, for example, and the reinvestment of dividends could also
vary by type.
Figure 3 shows scatterplots of contemporaneous net withdrawals as a
function of dividends of each type. An immediate result is that the
"automatic reinvestment" mode is apparent only in mutual fund
dividends (middle panel), likely reflecting formal elections to
automatically reinvest. In addition, both mutual fund dividend
recipients and many ordinary dividend recipients (top panel) engage in
the "zero reinvestment" mode. Perhaps because large special
dividends are so rare, there is little visually apparent pattern in how
they are withdrawn or reinvested (bottom panel).
Figure 4 depicts median and mean net withdrawals by dividend type.
The median behavior (top left panel) is to withdraw ordinary dividends
dollar for dollar. For mutual fund dividends, the median behavior
(middle left panel) is to withdraw nothing. For special dividends, on
the other hand, the median behavior is to withdraw (bottom left panel).
In means (the three right-hand panels), the patterns are rougher, as
expected, and affected by the fact that the average household is a net
saver into its portfolio over this period. Even in means, however, there
are generally monotonic relationships for dividends of each type,
although very high values of mutual fund dividends do not increase mean
net withdrawals one for one.
These impressions are confirmed formally in table 9.
Households' propensity to contemporaneously withdraw ordinary
dividends (near unity) is 0.80 higher than their propensity to withdraw
capital gains (near zero). Also, reflecting the automatic reinvestment
policy that many mutual fund investors pursue, mutual fund dividends are
withdrawn at a lower rate. The standard errors are too large to allow
finer observations about reinvestment and how behavior changes for
unusually large dividends. Small special dividends are withdrawn at
roughly the same rate as ordinary dividends, whereas the point estimates
suggest that large special dividends are mostly reinvested.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Reverse Causality
Like the CEX results, the above results may be affected by an
endogeneity problem. Some households may have chosen their
ordinary-dividend-paying stocks and, to a lesser extent, their mutual
funds ex ante in anticipation of consuming the dividends. If so, the
evidence presented so far is insufficient to demonstrate that dividends,
particularly ordinary dividends, have a causal effect.
For the ex ante effect to dominate, there would have to be a large
predictable component in dividends such that it is feasible for
households to match desired future consumption with anticipated dividend
streams. Unlike in our CEX analysis, dividends here are scaled by
portfolio value, which already reduces a potential source of
cross-sectional predictability. As it turns out, scaled dividends in
total (the sum of ordinary, mutual fund, and special dividends) are
unpredictable from lagged dividends (that is, almost all variation is
"unexpected"): twelve months of lagged dividends explains only
4 percent of the variation in scaled dividends in the current month.
Hence reverse causality is empirically not a major concern in the
total-dividends results that we reported above, unless we are to believe
that investors are rapidly rebalancing their portfolios in anticipation
of changing consumption needs.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Ordinary dividends on their own (scaled by beginning-of-period
portfolio value), however, are highly predictable, with the
one-year-lagged value explaining 57 percent of the variation in ordinary
dividends, and the one-year- and three-month-lagged values together
explaining 81 percent. Mutual fund dividends are less predictable, with
the one-year-lagged value explaining 43 percent and the
three-month-lagged value (as expected) adding little. Special dividends
are, of course, unpredictable by definition. Therefore, like our results
for total dividends, our results for special dividends are not subject
to reverse causality concerns.
The question in terms of understanding causality is whether this
predictable component in ordinary and mutual fund dividends alone
explains consumption, or whether the unpredictable component also plays
a role. To examine this, our second specification in table 9 includes
the twelve-month lag of dividends as an additional control for the
potential ex ante effect of expected consumption on holdings of
dividend-paying assets. If the ex ante effect is the full story, and it
is largely a household fixed effect with slow time variation, then the
twelve-month lag of dividends and contemporaneous dividends should have
about the same correlation with withdrawals. And if the ex ante effect
is not a complete explanation, then the coefficient on the
contemporaneous dividend should be larger than that on the twelvemonth
lag, since it captures effects on withdrawals related to the dividend
component that is not predictable by [D.sub.t-12].
Consistent with a modest ex ante effect, the coefficient estimate
on [D.sub.t-12] is greater than zero for both ordinary and mutual fund
dividends, although the effects are statistically insignificant. But the
coefficients for the contemporaneous dividend terms remain highly
significant and far larger than the coefficients on the twelve-month
lag. We find similar results for mutual fund dividends.
These results suggest that reverse causality in the form of ex ante
matching of withdrawals and dividends most likely plays a fairly modest
role in the case of ordinary and mutual fund dividends. It plays even
less of a role for our other results, including special dividends and
total dividends. Although one cannot establish causality with complete
confidence, all of the results are consistent with an important element
of causality running from dividends to withdrawals--and, based on our
analysis of the CEX data, to consumption.
Explanations
Our results from two quite different micro data sets suggest that
investors have a higher propensity to consume from dividends than from
capital gains. So far we have focused solely on documenting the basic
facts and their robustness. Now we move on to potential explanations.
Borrowing Constraints
A standard explanation for the high sensitivity of consumption to
current income is borrowing constraints. (27) However, borrowing
constraints by themselves do not predict a different propensity to
consume from dividends than from capital appreciation. The substitution
of dividends for capital gains has no overall wealth effects, and
homemade dividends can always be created by buying and selling shares.
Hence, borrowing constraints are not an important factor.
Transaction Costs
The transaction costs of making homemade dividends are a more
relevant factor a priori. Perhaps households recognize that reinvesting
dividends, especially in the modest amounts that accrue in the smaller
accounts in our sample, would require the purchase of an odd lot of
shares, which carries relatively high transaction costs. To the extent
such costs are substantial, rational households should prefer to consume
from recent dividends rather than from selling shares.
The CEX data allow us to examine a transaction cost explanation in
which the trading costs (and perhaps taxes) of creating extra homemade
dividends constrain consumption. For households where income exceeds
total expenditure, this constraint does not bind: these households could
create homemade dividends at no cost by simply saving less. In
unreported results, we find coefficients of a similar magnitude and
generally lower standard errors (a coefficient of 0.90 with a standard
error of 0.12 in a variation on regression 2-5 in table 2) among
households that save income, casting doubt on this effect as a complete
explanation.
The brokerage data results in table 8 also contain results that
cast doubt on transaction costs as a complete explanation. First, if
households view odd-lot transactions costs as an important
consideration, one might expect a higher propensity to withdraw
dividends in smaller accounts, which face the odd-lot costs more often.
But the propensity to withdraw dividends appears not to depend on the
size of the portfolio. Second, the propensity to withdraw dividends is
similar, if not even higher, for high-turnover households. These
households would be able, if they wished, to reinvest unwanted dividends
at little, if any, marginal cost; in other words, again, the transaction
costs are not binding. (28)
Taxes
Perhaps investors fail to fully reinvest dividends (that is, have a
higher propensity to withdraw them) because they regularly withhold a
portion for federal and state taxes. Of course, taxes can be paid from
any source, and so this story is already founded on mental accounting.
Table 8 shows that high-tax households are more likely than low-tax
households to withdraw dividend income. In fact, the difference between
the two groups is much too large (although standard errors are also
large) to attribute to differential taxation: higher-tax households
withdraw 100 percent of their small and medium-size dividends, far more
than they would need to cover taxes.
Another tax consideration is the higher tax rate on dividend income
than on capital gains that prevailed in our sample period. Perhaps
households made mistakes ex ante in buying the highly taxed
dividend-paying assets, or purchased them at a discount, and ex post,
given their holdings, it makes sense to finance consumption through
dividends rather than capital gains. But, to develop this same idea
further, many households in our sample have individual stocks with
accumulated capital losses at any given time, and so from an ex post tax
perspective these households should consume from realized losses even
before dividends. Yet empirically the evidence indicates that investors
are more likely to sell winners than losers in every month except
December. (29)
Different "Permanence" of Dividends and Capital Gains
The results might yet be reconciled with fully optimizing,
forward-looking behavior if stock returns have permanent and transitory
components. In our regressions we control for total returns, and so
dividends do not add any additional information about the size of wealth
shocks. But if changes in dividends are more strongly correlated with
the permanent component of stock returns than with the transitory
component, changes in dividends could provide some information about the
permanence of wealth shocks. (30) In this case one would expect
dividends to be correlated with consumption even after controlling for
total returns.
At the level of the aggregate market, such an explanation could
have relevance, although it would be difficult to distinguish it from
other explanations such as mental accounting. A large proportion of the
variation in market-level returns appears to be transitory, driven by
temporary movements in discount rates. (31) There is also empirical
support for the idea that aggregate consumption responds more to
permanent than to transitory changes in asset values. (32)
However, our results are driven by cross-sectional, not aggregate
variation in returns and dividends. This is an important difference,
because movements in discount rates are systematic, driven by
macroeconomic variables. As a result, the variation in returns induced
by changes in discount rates is, to a large extent, a common component
across stocks. (33) The time fixed effects in our regressions absorb
aggregate movements in asset values, leaving the market-adjusted and
largely permanent component of returns. Thus differences in the
permanence of dividends and capital gains also cannot explain our
results.
Mental Accounting
Finally, a higher propensity to consume from dividends than from
capital gains is predicted by typical mental accounting theories.
Indeed, Hersh Shefrin and Richard Thaler explicitly describe such a
higher propensity as an important (but as yet untested) prediction of
their mental accounting framework. (34)
In the Shefrin and Thaler model, households place wealth into one
of three mental accounts: current income, current assets, and future
wealth. (35) Shefrin and Thaler argue that the propensity to consume
wealth categorized as current income, such as dividends, is greater than
the propensity to consume wealth categorized as assets, such as capital
and its appreciation. Household behavior in their model is thus
consistent with the popular advice to "spend from income, not from
principal."
Our main results fit well with these predictions. The propensity to
withdraw and consume dividends is indeed far higher for dividends than
for capital gains. Moreover, in the CEX data, the propensity to consume
dividends is similar to the propensity to consume labor income,
consistent with the notion that both are placed in the "current
income" mental account.
In addition, mental accounting seems to offer more natural
explanations for some finer aspects of our results than do the other
theories. For example, it is natural that ordinary dividends and small
special dividends would be categorized as current income to a greater
extent than large special dividends, which, in turn, would be seen as
still more income-like than capital appreciation. Under mental
accounting, one would thus expect a higher propensity to consume
ordinary than large special dividends, and a higher propensity to
consume the latter than capital gains. Table 9 shows precisely this
pattern.
The underlying psychology behind this sort of mental accounting is
an important open question. Self-control and prospect theory are
potential psychological roots. (36) Another, anecdotally plausible
possibility is that although firm-level stock returns and
cross-sectional variation in portfolio performance are largely
permanent, individuals do not view them as such. A quasi-rational rule
of thumb for a passive investor facing perceived stock market mispricing
may then be to consume dividends but not capital gains.
Mental accounting of any type suggests bounded rationality, and so
a natural way to close this discussion is to comment on the welfare
consequences of deviating from fully optimizing behavior in this
setting. We suspect that these consequences are relatively small for two
reasons: dividends make up a small fraction of total portfolio returns,
and more important, they have a much lower standard deviation.
Corporations smooth dividends, adjusting only partially and only to the
permanent component of earnings, as captured by the Lintner dividend
model. This behavior on the corporate side limits the welfare
consequences of an investor rule of thumb to consume from dividends.
The May 2003 Dividend Tax Cut
The Jobs and Growth and Taxpayer Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003
reduced the maximum federal tax rate on dividend income from over 38
percent to 15 percent. After taking into account state income taxes and
their deductibility from federal income tax, the average household
marginal tax rate on dividends fell from 32.1 percent in 2002 to 18.5
percent in 2003. (37)
The tax cuts were designed to stimulate economic growth. Reducing
the double taxation of corporate profits was expected to lower the cost
of capital and thereby spur capital formation and growth, although there
is a debate in the economics literature over whether this view is true.
An alternative view is that retained earnings are the marginal source of
finance for new investment projects. In that case taxes on dividends
would have no effect on real investment. (38)
Our results suggest that the dividend tax cut of 2003 may have had
another, more direct impact on growth through its impact on household
consumption, just as the Microsoft dividend might have had a measurable
impact on consumer spending. An interesting exercise then is to use our
estimates from (pre-2003) micro data to assess how much the increase in
after-tax dividend income may have increased aggregate consumption.
An important preliminary note is that taxes are not withheld when
dividends are paid, and so the May 2003 tax cut did not have a direct
effect on the cash flows occurring on the date when the dividends are
paid. Our estimates are based on how individuals' consumption
reacts at that point. So, for our estimates to be valid measures of the
propensity to consume from after-tax dividend income, we need to assume
that individuals' monthly withdrawal behavior fully reflects the
relevant taxes that are to be paid when the tax year ends. For this
exercise, we will assume that our estimated marginal propensities to
consume before-tax dividends in tables 2 and 6 come from a constant
marginal propensity to consume (MPC) after-tax dividends, or
(9) [MPC.sub.pre-tax,t] = [MPC.sub.after-tax] x (1 -
[[tau].sub.t]),
where [tau] is the tax rate.
A second caveat is that our estimates come from a representative
sample of U.S. households. Dividends are paid disproportionately to the
highest-income households, which are perhaps more sophisticated in their
financial planning and less likely to use mental accounting rules of
thumb. In this regard it is a useful feature of our CEX analysis that
the variables are defined in dollars, which implies that the regressions
put more weight on households with higher income and higher dividends.
Moreover, the sample is restricted to stockholders. This ensures that
our results are driven by households with substantial income.
Nevertheless, it is possible that we still are not capturing the
behavior of the richest households. For now we will assume that our
estimates apply, but we interpret them as upper-bound impacts.
We first consider a scenario in which the dividend tax cut has no
effect on the supply of dividends by corporations. In this case the
impact on consumption is simply the change in the before-tax MPC times
dividends D. Rearranging equation 9 yields
(10) [(MPC.sub.pre-tax,2003] - [MPC.sub.pre-tax,2002]) x D = (1 -
[[tau].sub.2003]/1 - [[tau].sub.2002] - 1) x [MPC.sub.pre-tax,2002] x D.
According to the IRS Statistics of Income, individuals reported
dividend income of $103 billion in 2002. With a fall in the dividend
income tax rate from 32.1 percent to 18.5 percent and an initial
before-tax MPC of 0.4--a number that appears to be around the middle of
our baseline estimates--we obtain $8.3 billion as the estimated effect
on aggregate consumption. Table 3 points to a before-tax MPC somewhat
lower than 0.4, whereas table 2 suggests a value above 0.7. At this high
end, where the after-tax MPC is essentially 1.0, the estimated effect
for 2003 is $14.0 billion.
A second scenario is that the dividend tax cut, by reducing the
relative tax disadvantage on dividend income, may have increased the
supply of dividends. Raj Chetty and Emmanuel Saez suggest that the tax
cut caused an increase in dividend payouts. (39) In fact, they find that
a sample of firms with limited tax incentives--the largest shareholder
is not taxable--did not increase the rate at which they initiated
dividends, for example, and thus they attribute the entire change to tax
effects. On the other hand, Alon Brav and coauthors surveyed hundreds of
financial executives in the wake of the tax cut and found that they only
occasionally cite the tax cut as a motivator of payout decisions. (40)
Stock market sentiment may also have affected dividend behavior during
this period, as some firms initiated or increased dividends in an
attempt to distance themselves from the nondividend-paying "new
economy" firms that had crashed in 2000 and 2001. (41) In any case,
suppose for the sake of argument that the entirety of the observed
change in dividends from 2002 to 2003, from $103 billion to $115
billion, was due to the tax cut. Recall that the before-tax MPC rises as
the tax rate falls, from 0.4 to 0.48:
(11) [(MPC.sub.pre-tax,2003] = [MPC.sub.pre-tax,2002]) x = (1 -
[[tau].sub.2003]/1 - [[tau].sub.2002].
Applying this estimate to the before-tax increase in dividends, the
supply channel adds another $5.8 billion to the effect on consumption,
for a total effect of $14.1 billion. At the higher MPC estimate, the
total effect is $23.8 billion.
Dividends in the Statistics of Income continued to increase in
2004, to $147 billion, including the large Microsoft payout; hence this
calculation might still underestimate the effect for subsequent years.
Let us suppose the tax cut took two years to have its full effect, and
therefore take the rise from the 2002 to the 2004 value as the supply
increase. Then the estimates of total consumption effects in the
previous paragraph rise to $29.4 billion and $49.9 billion,
respectively.
To gain some perspective on these estimated changes in consumption,
which range from $8.3 billion to $49.9 billion, consider that total
personal consumption expenditure in 2003 was $7.7 trillion, and that the
average increase in total personal consumption over the previous five
years was $365 billion, with a standard deviation of $66 billion.
Against this standard deviation, effects on the order of those estimated
above do not seem trivial.
Conclusion
How investors consume from dividends versus capital gains is
important to a range of questions in corporate finance, macroeconomics,
behavioral economics, and tax policy. Classical theories suggest that
investor consumption patterns are independent of how returns are split
into dividends and capital gains, whereas mental accounting and various
economic frictions motivate an alternative hypothesis that investors are
relatively more likely to consume dividends. The contribution of this
study is to exploit the cross-sectional variation in two household-level
data sets in order to document the effect of dividends on consumption.
The main finding is that consumption indeed responds much more
strongly to returns in the form of dividends than to returns in the form
of capital gains. Data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey show a
strong relationship between household consumption and dividends, after
controlling for total returns (which include dividends). A sample of
household portfolio data also shows that dividends are much more likely
than capital gains to generate withdrawals from investment accounts,
thus illustrating the mechanical process of translating dividend income
into consumption. We stress that the interesting result is not that the
propensity to consume capital gains is rather low--indeed, it should he
low for forward-looking consumers acting according to the permanent
income hypothesis--but that the propensity to consume dividends is so
high. A review of alternative explanations suggests that the results may
in part reflect mental accounting processes of the sort summed up in the
adage, "consume income, not principal."
Comments and Discussion
James Poterba: This paper by Malcolm Baker, Stefan Nagel, and
Jeffrey Wurgler asks whether the division of corporate earnings between
retentions and payouts affects consumer spending. The authors bring
novel insight and a creative empirical strategy to bear on a question
that has a long pedigree in empirical macroeconomics. Early attempts to
model aggregate consumption related consumer spending to disposable
income and household wealth. Estimates of the marginal propensity to
consume out of income were typically an order of magnitude greater than
estimates of the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth. Taken at
face value, such estimates implied that if a firm reduced its retained
earnings by a dollar, thereby reducing its share price, and paid a
dollar of dividends, consumer spending would rise by the difference
between the marginal propensity to consume out of disposable income and
the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth. Some researchers
argued that, to avoid this stark result, consumption should depend on
corporate retained earnings as well as disposable income. This
suggestion led to an empirical debate about whether consumers
"pierce the corporate veil" and recognize the firm's
underlying earnings, or fail to do this and instead consume at different
rates out of different components of corporate earnings.
In contemporary textbook models of consumer behavior, current
household spending depends on the present discounted value of current
and future labor earnings and on current financial assets. In the
absence of taxes and other institutional rigidities, a dividend payment,
as opposed to a capital gain, should not change a household's net
financial assets and therefore should not affect consumer spending. Yet
the possibility remains that different ways of transmitting earnings to
shareholders have different effects on consumption. Various models in
behavioral economics can justify such an outcome. This paper offers
intriguing evidence in support of these models.
In linking this paper and its findings to the debate concerning the
corporate veil, it is important to recognize that even if one does not
reject the null hypothesis that consumers have equal propensities to
consume from dividends and other components of equity returns, the
corporate payout decision may still affect consumption. To illustrate
this possibility, assume that a project generates a dollar of after-tax
corporate profits for an equity-financed firm. The firm could distribute
the dollar as a dividend payment, or it could retain the dollar. In the
latter case the firm's share price would be higher, by dV, than if
the earnings were distributed to the shareholders. The change in
consumption spending from the dividend payout would be [MPC.sub.div],
and the change in the retained earnings case would be [MPC.sub.cg]dV.
Even if [MPC.sub.div] = [MPC.sub.cg], which is the proposition that the
authors study, it is still possible that distributing earnings could
affect consumption if dV is not equal to unity. Tax considerations could
break this equality, for example if retained earnings may be distributed
in the future by repurchasing shares and therefore face a lower tax
burden than dividend payments. Corporate governance factors may also
come into play. If a dollar of retained earnings may be reinvested by
the management team at a rate of return below that demanded by the
marketplace, but not low enough to warrant shareholders incurring the
costs of removing the managers, then dV may be less than 1.
Previous researchers have found it difficult to distinguish the
consumption impact of dividends from that of accruing capital gains,
because there are few exogenous shocks to corporate distribution policy
that cannot be plausibly linked in other ways to consumer spending. This
paper presents two ingenious tests of whether households consume at
different rates from dividend income and from accruing capital gains. By
presenting empirical findings suggesting that dividends increase
consumption more than do accrued capital gains of equal value, this
paper suggests that policies that encourage firms to distribute earnings
may increase aggregate consumer spending.
The identification problem confronting earlier studies is easily
summarized. In time-series data, most of the variation in the mix
between dividends and retained earnings is due to shocks to corporate
earnings. Such shocks may affect consumer spending through their
informational effect on future earnings prospects, as well as through
coincident changes in dividends or retentions. One strategy for avoiding
this endogeneity, which Ii exploited in a previous study of the
corporate veil, (1) is to use changes in the relative tax treatment of
dividend income and of capital gains as an instrumental variable for
corporate payout.
This paper takes a different tack. It exploits cross-sectional
differences in the dividend payments received by different households.
The authors control for the total return earned by different investors
and study how the composition of this return between dividends and
capital gains affects consumer spending. This approach avoids
time-series endogeneity, but it brings with it a new set of concerns
about the factors that determine cross-sectional differences in
portfolio dividend yields. The authors recognize the potential for
omitted variables to contaminate their cross-sectional inferences, and
they control for many household-specific attributes that may lead to
differences in both consumption behavior and dividend receipts. The
identification hinges on whether one believes that even after
controlling for many household attributes, there may still be some
omitted variables that affect both the choice of portfolio dividend
yield and consumption outlays. To completely explain the results, such
an omitted variable would need to move in tandem with both dividends and
consumer spending, since the paper's key empirical findings emerge
when the household data are differenced. An example illustrates the
potential problem. Household-level empirical work on portfolio structure
has shown that a household's marginal tax rate is correlated with
the dividend yield of its stock portfolio. If the marginal tax rate is
also correlated with a household's consumption spending, the
possibility of a spurious relationship arises. If household tax rates
change over time, thereby inducing changes in both portfolio dividend
yield and consumer spending, then even differencing may not solve the
problem.
The paper begins with an analysis of Consumer Expenditure Survey
(CEX) data. A key limitation of these data is the topcoding of income
components, including dividends. The topcoding limits information on the
behavior of the high-income, high-net-worth investors who hold most of
the corporate stock outside of retirement accounts and pension plans.
The authors omit from their sample all survey respondents who have a
topcoded entry. This restriction to lower-income households may limit
the extent to which the empirical findings can be used to describe the
impact of changing payout patterns. My table 1 presents information on
the concentration of dividend income on individual income tax returns
filed in 2004. Just over half of all dividends are received by taxpayers
with adjusted gross income of more than $200,000--a group that includes
fewer than 8 percent of all taxpayers with dividend income, and about 2
percent of all taxpayers. Data from the Survey of Consumer Finances suggest that households in the top decile of the wealth distribution
receive roughly 90 percent of all dividends. In contrast, the
highest-income respondent in the CEX has an annual income of just over
$300,000, and the mean annual consumption expenditure is approximately
$60,000. This underscores the absence of households in the top strata of
income and wealth.
The reason topcoding and the absence of high-income households are
concerns is that the behavior of these households may differ from that
of lower-income households. Their consumption decisions, in particular,
may be less sensitive to cash flow considerations. This possibility
suggests the need for caution in using the coefficient estimates in the
current study to estimate how broad changes in corporate dividend
payouts may affect consumer spending.
Another concern with the CEX is that the measure of accrued capital
gains is very noisy. There are two sources of measurement error in the
equity capital gains data. The first is that financial asset values are
self-reported. If households do not know the current value of their
stock portfolios at the time of the survey, this will translate into
noisy data. The second problem, which may be even more important, is
that when households sell stock between two survey dates, there is no
record of the timing of the sale. This requires assuming an arbitrary
time pattern for such sales, inducing further measurement error. If
capital gains are measured with substantial error, while cash dividend
income is measured precisely, standard errors-in-variables arguments
will lead to an estimate of the marginal propensity to consume from
capital gains that is biased toward zero. Such a bias could explain the
paper's empirical results in both the level and difference
specifications.
The second part of the paper focuses on withdrawals from brokerage
accounts. This component of the paper is particularly innovative, and
evidence on whether investors withdraw dividends from their accounts or
reinvest them is of independent interest. The authors note that
withdrawals are not the same as consumption, and that message bears
emphasis. The CEX-based project uses a measure of consumption as the
dependent variable. The brokerage account-based project implicitly
assumes that withdrawals are consumed--an assumption that may not be
valid for all households. The findings on withdrawal patterns are
nevertheless intriguing. The data suggest that relatively few investors
reinvest dividend payments. This is particularly true for ordinary
dividends; large special dividends do appear to be reinvested.
A key limitation of this study, and of other studies that have used
information provided by financial institutions, is the restriction to
information from a single brokerage firm. If investors hold assets at
multiple firms, cross-firm reinvestment decisions will look like
withdrawal or consumption decisions from the vantage point of a single
firm. This is a concern but it may not be a serious empirical
limitation. In the 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances, 87 percent of
households with a brokerage account have only one. Investors with
multiple brokerage accounts are likely to account for a disproportionate share of total dividend income and total stock ownership, but, at least
for middle-income households, using data from a single brokerage firm is
likely to provide valuable insights.
A more subtle concern involves the timing of reinvestment
decisions, even decisions with respect to the same brokerage account. An
investor who receives a dividend check, deposits it in a money market
account or checking account that is not visible to the brokerage firm,
and then decides after some time to purchase additional shares of stock
will appear to have consumed the dividend if the reinvestment does not
happen within the same month as the dividend payment. If dividends are
uniformly distributed throughout each month, that leaves on average only
two weeks for the investor to make the reinvestment decision before the
end-of-month cutoff. The authors recognize this potential problem and
note that they can reduce it by widening the time interval over which
they measure dividend income and withdrawals. They painstakingly track
net account inflows and withdrawals as a function of lagged dividend
payments; this offers another way of attacking the measurement interval
problem.
One concern about the brokerage account data used in this study is
whether they are representative of the broader population of U.S.
households. Different broker types may attract different types of
clients. A discount broker, for example, is likely to attract investors
who are more inclined to trade than the population at large, whereas a
full-service broker may attract clients who view themselves as needing
disproportionate levels of advice and assistance in making financial
decisions. It is not clear how best to control for any differences
between these groups, or between them and investors more generally.
The paper concludes with an interesting analysis of how changes in
the relative tax burden on dividends and capital gains in 2003 may have
affected consumer spending. Three potential effects of the Jobs and
Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA) warrant
consideration. First, the tax reform reduced the average tax burden on
dividends paid to U.S. investors, thereby increasing the disposable
income of these taxpayers. This might increase consumer spending.
Second, JGTRRA reduced the tax penalty for paying dividends relative to
retained earnings, thereby increasing the incentive for firms to pay
dividends. Several studies suggest that this led to an increase in
dividend payments. (2) If the marginal propensity to consume from
dividends is greater than that from retention-induced capital gains,
this effect would also support higher consumption. In light of the
empirical evidence in this study, higher dividend payouts might increase
consumer spending. Finally, the tax change may have provided new
incentives for investment in the corporate sector. The caution here
arises from the temporary nature of the dividend tax cut. A permanent
cut in the dividend tax would reduce the burden on payouts from new
corporate sector investments, making it more attractive for firms to
issue new shares and use the proceeds to undertake new investments. The
temporary nature of the tax cut undermines this incentive, since
relatively few projects would be expected to generate returns before the
expiration of the dividend tax relief. The magnitude of the investment
incentives associated with the dividend tax change is unclear, as is the
corresponding countervailing force that might dampen the other
pro-consumption effects of JGTRRA. If investors expected the dividend
tax relief to be permanent--and much of the rhetoric at the time of
JGTRRA's passage suggested that this might be the case--then the
investment effects associated with the tax change could weaken or
reverse the pro-consumption effects described above.
Let me close with two observations about the research
opportunities, and needs, associated with the 2003 change in tax rates.
First, on the opportunities, this paper does not exploit JGTRRA as a
source of variation that could be used to study the extent to which
consumer spending responds to dividend income. Consider the impact of
the Microsoft special dividend of December 2004, which the authors cite.
This was a $32 billion extraordinary payout that occurred after JGTRRA
reduced marginal dividend tax rates. This dividend provides an ideal
experiment--or would if only one could isolate and study the behavior of
Microsoft shareholders. It represented a transfer of $32 billion in cash
from the firm to its shareholders, and if it were possible to compare
Microsoft shareholders, who received dividend income and a concomitant reduction in the value of their equity portfolio, with other
shareholders who did not have Microsoft stock in their portfolios, it
might be possible to test the authors' hypothesis in a particularly
powerful fashion.
Second, this paper's central theme highlights an important
problem in studying how taxes affect portfolio behavior, and it suggests
a need for further post-JGTRRA research. If changes in tax policy, or in
other components of the economic environment, lead firms to distribute a
greater fraction of their earnings as dividends, this may lead to
changes in investors' portfolio choices. The set of investors who
hold dividend-paying stocks may differ before and after a substantial
tax reform. This adds a new complication to analyzing the consumption
effects of a tax change like JGTRRA. If the tax change induces a shift
in the investor clienteles who hold different types of stock, then
evidence on how dividend income affected the investors who held
dividend-paying stocks before the reform may not carry over to the
postreform environment. The extent to which portfolio clienteles shift
in response to tax changes is likely to depend on the magnitude of the
tax reform and on the distribution of households by marginal tax rate
and wealth. Only by studying the consumption behavior of stockholders
after the reform can one determine whether the prereform patterns
continue to hold.
(1.) Poterba (1987).
(2.) See, in particular, Cherty and Saez (2005).
Table 1. Distribution of Taxable Dividends by Household Income, 2004
Taxpayers reporting
dividends
Dividends reported
Percent
of all Percent
taxpayers of all
Adjusted gross income reporting Billions of dividends
(thousands of dollars) Millions dividends dollars reported
< 10 3.55 11.6 5.8 3.9
10-50 9.91 32.3 19.0 13.0
50-100 9.41 30.7 22.6 15.4
100-200 5.41 17.6 23.8 16.2
200-500 1.80 5.9 20.3 13.8
500-1,000 0.38 1.2 11.3 7.7
1,000 0.22 0.7 44.1 30.0
All households 30.69 100.0 146.8 100.0
Source: U.S. Treasury Department, Statistics of Income: Individual
Income Tax Returns, table 1.4.
Joel Slemrod: This paper by Malcolm Baker, Stefan Nagel, and
Jeffrey Wurgler is an ambitious and thought-provoking take on a
fascinating question--in short, it is a discussant's dream. It
challenges the Modigliani-Miller view that, taxes aside, because
dividend payments "just" move money from one pocket of
shareholders to another, they do not affect consumption. The authors
offer an alternative hypothesis based on mental accounts, in which
dividends move money from one mental account to another, namely, the
shareholder's pocket, from which the shareholder is more likely to
spend. The plausibility of this story depends on the context. For
example, it is less plausible if the business transferring funds to its
owners is a ma-and-pa grocery store, a small partnership, or even a
closely held corporation; it is more plausible--and certainly plausible
enough to take seriously--with respect to public corporations.
To investigate this hypothesis empirically, the authors examine two
kinds of data. The first consists of data from a discount brokerage,
which the authors use to examine whether dividend payments trigger
withdrawals from individual (actual, not mental) accounts. This is an
interesting question, but, as the authors admit, withdrawals from a
discount brokerage account are not acts of consumption. Yet neither are
they, as the authors assert, "precursors" to consumption.
Withdrawals are neither necessary nor sufficient indicators of
consumption unless an individual maintains no other brokerage account
and indeed no other financial account--no checking account, no credit
card account, no mortgage, and so on. The authors claim that this
disjunction between account withdrawals and consumption adds noise but
not bias to their estimates. I would say it threatens the interpretation
of the estimated coefficients as informing us about consumption.
What factors, including dividends, affect withdrawals from such a
brokerage
account is an interesting question for household finance in and of
itself. The answer presumably depends on such questions as who invests
in discount brokerages and what other accounts they have. Answering
these questions would contribute to the theory and evidence for account
choices and account shifting. In the same way that the connection
between portfolio choice and consumption has been worked out, the
connection between account choice and consumption needs to be clarified.
The authors' second data source is the Consumer Expenditure
Survey (CEX). The CEX data are not perfect, but unlike the brokerage
account data, they do purport to measure consumer expenditure directly,
and the issues of measurement error in these data have been widely
recognized and studied. Some of these issues are particularly relevant
to the question at hand. One is the topcoding of the data, and a second
is that the CEX data do not oversample high-income people, who hold a
disproportionate amount of stock held outside of institutions. For these
reasons one might worry that any behavioral response of the usable CEX
sample is not representative of aggregate dollar-weighted stock
ownership. That the stockholders in the sample are not high rollers becomes clear when one notes that the median value of dividends and
accrued gains in the sample is zero and that the mean annual capital
gain is $363 (with a huge dispersion). This will be a problem if, for
example, Bill Gates does not keep the same kind of mental accounts as
the average stockholder, a plausible notion if there are fixed costs to
constructing "better" mental accounts.
Perhaps the most troublesome issue in this analysis is the fact
that capital gains are probably subject to much greater measurement
error than dividend receipts. This will bias the outcome toward finding
that dividends matter for consumption and capital gains do not matter,
not only for consumption but for anything. Perhaps the Survey of
Consumer Finances (or other sources with better capital gains measures)
can give a sense of the size of the measurement error problem as well as
the induced bias.
To be sure of the causal relationships, it would be helpful to have
panel data that span a longer period. In their absence one wonders to
what extent the authors' results are driven by heterogeneity--do
those people who choose high-dividend stocks also behave differently in
managing their accounts? For example, do they also move money in and out
of their brokerage accounts more frequently? However, if the observed
correlations were due to (persistent) heterogeneity of this type, one
would expect that lagged dividends would explain such behavior as well
as current dividends, but the authors show that they do not, and that is
reassuring, as is the fact that the results survive first-differencing.
The tax system is one source of exogenous cross-sectional
variation, in part because the federal income tax has graduated rates.
If dividends are taxed more heavily than capital gains at the individual
level, the income tax system should induce a clientele effect so that,
other things equal, highly taxed individuals do not hold
high-dividend-paying stocks. One might be initially optimistic that the
variation in the marginal tax rate across people provides an instrument
with which to examine the effect of dividends on consumption. But, alas,
the marginal tax rate is highly correlated with income, and so it would
be difficult to separate the effect of receiving dividends from the
effect of income itself. Note, however, that although highly taxed
individuals normally would be unhappy about higher dividends, they also
would benefit most from a temporary cut in the dividend tax, which may
be part of what the 2003 tax change, discussed below, was perceived by
many to be.
The authors want to make assertions about the aggregate consumption
impact of dividend changes. To make such statements with the data they
have, one would need to know why dividends, or after-tax dividends,
change over time for different shareholders. It could be that higher
dividends are a signal of improved company prospects, in which case
there would be both a dividend effect and a wealth effect. If instead
changes in dividends reflect a changed payout policy, then higher
dividends would imply lower expected capital gains, with no first-order
wealth effect.
What if a change in dividends results from a tax policy change, one
that either changes the incentive to pay out a given amount of after-tax
earnings, or changes the amount of after-tax earnings itself, or both?
The tax issues are tricky and are controversial among public finance
economists, with the varying theories loosely classified as either
"new view" or "old view." What is distinctive about
the new view is that it implies that a permanent dividend tax cut will
not change the payout behavior of mature firms (those whose earnings
exceed good investment opportunities). In this case the dividend tax cut
represents a windfall gain to shareholders (and, presumably, a windfall loss to other taxpayers). In general, the fact that a dividend tax cut
should have different effects on different companies may help to
identify the effect of a tax change, the payout responses to it, and
shareholders' responses to both. To the extent that a dividend tax
cut is perceived as temporary, this is a good time to get money out of a
corporation.
The paper gives little attention to the authors' preferred
explanation of their findings, namely, mental accounts. The behavior the
authors identify does seem to follow the maxim about consuming income
but not principal. But is it a rule of thumb that economizes on
cognitive capital and transaction costs, one that works well in most
situations but may work poorly in unusual circumstances? Is the goal
also to smooth saving, rather than consumption, so that unexpected
income can be spent but spending can be cut back in bad times?
Individuals' reliance on mental accounting is certainly
heterogeneous. Who, then, is likely to use it--does it relate to
one's sophistication in dealing with financial issues? Does it
relate to wealth, as seems plausible if there are fixed costs to be
saved by using simple rules of thumb? What might cause users of mental
accounting to abandon their rule of thumb? One possibility is special
dividends. Another is windows of time created by temporary, or possibly
temporary, tax changes. Prominent news stories about corporations
reacting to a tax change might be noticed by some taxpayers, who react
by altering their usual mental accounting.
Once we are in the realm of behavioral economics, how far do we
need to expand it? One might, for example, also consider the cognitive
process of corporate officers. Surveys suggest they do not act as if
they solve either the new view or the old view problem, but themselves
use rules of thumb as well. (1) How shareholders react to dividends
induced by tax changes also overlaps with the nascent field of
behavioral public finance. (2) Note that the response of cognitively
constrained individual shareholders to corporate behavior is in some
ways similar to the response to government behavior: both corporate and
government policies may move taxpayer "money" from one pocket,
or mental account, to another. This raises a large set of interesting
questions, including whether people have particular cognitive issues
with respect to tax cuts. Do taxpayers have the cognitive sophistication
to be Ricardian, or is this a particularly difficult cognitive problem
whose solution involves rules of thumb and mental accounts? These issues
arise in trying to understand taxpayer responses to anticipated tax
refunds or occasional tax "rebates."
The paper ends by relating the authors' research program to
the U.S. experience in 2003, when the tax on dividends was cut
substantially. I would like to see the authors clarify the prediction of
mental accounting with respect to exogenous changes in payouts. Do their
findings imply that a permanently increased dividend payout ratio would
induce shareholders to consume more forever? This seems implausible and
would indeed be impossible in a life-cycle model (unless bequests
decline), because lifetime income has not risen. Or would it increase
consumption only until shareholders figure out that their mental
accounting is not performing well in this scenario and they readjust
their rule of thumb?
As my remarks suggest, although I found this paper ambitious and
thought-provoking, I am not persuaded that the empirical
analyses-especially the analysis of the brokerage accounts--shed much
light on the determinants of consumption, at either the individual or
the aggregate level. But I am quite sure that this research has enriched
the conversation about this and other important questions of
macroeconomics and public economics.
(1.) Brav and others (2007).
(2.) See McCaffery and Slemrod (2006).
General discussion: William Gale drew parallels between the current
paper and a 1987 paper by Yves Balcer and Kenneth Judd in the Journal of
Finance, which examined the life-cycle accrual of capital gains,
deriving formally that the marginal propensity to consume out of capital
gains should, for tax reasons, be different from the marginal propensity
to consume out of dividends. The taxation of realized capital gains
provides an incentive to defer these gains for as long as possible in
order to lower the effective tax rate on them. William Brainard agreed,
commenting that the current tax treatment and the fact that increases in
dividends are more permanent than capital gains are both nonbehavioral
explanations of the authors' results.
Richard Cooper noted that trust funds are often an important source
of income to shareholders and that, at least under New York State law,
trust funds may pay out only dividends and not capital gains. Therefore
the authors' results may reflect not mental accounting, but rather
a legal doctrine that draws a sharp distinction between dividends and
gains and treats only the former as income.
Benjamin Friedman noted that although only a fraction of gains are
realized in any given year, and when they occur they usually reflect a
decision on the part of the shareholder, shareholders occasionally
realize gains inadvertently because shares are taken over by some other
entity. He would find it informative to know how stockholders respond to
the receipt of proceeds from such takeovers and whether their behavior
is in line with the authors' estimate of the response to ordinary
dividends.
We thank Yakov Amihud, John Campbell, Alok Kumar. Erik Hurst,
Martin Lettau, James Poterba, Enrichetta Ravina, Hersh Shefrin, Joel
Slemrod, Nicholas Souleles, and seminar participants at the American
Finance Association 2007 Mectings in Chicago and at Babson College. the
University of British Columbia, the Brookings Institution, the
University of Colorado, HEC, INSEAD. Imperial College (University of
London), the National Bureau of Economic Research Working Group on
Behavioral Finance, the New York University Stern School of Business,
the Stanford Graduate School of Business, and the University of Southern
California for helpful comments. We thank Terrance Odean for providing
data. Malcolm Baker gratefully acknowledges financial support from the
Division of Research of the Harvard Business School.
References
Angeletos, George-Marios, and others. 2001. "The Hyperbolic Consumption Model: Calibration, Simulation, and Empirical
Evaluation." Journal of Economic Perspectives 15, no. 3: 47-68.
Auerbach, Alan J., and Kevin A. Hassett. 2006. "Dividend Taxes
and Firm Valuation: New Evidence." American Economic Review 96, no.
2: 119-23.
Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2004a. "A Catering Theory
of Dividends." Journal of Finance 59, no. 3: 1125-65.
--. 2004b. "Appearing and Disappearing Dividends: The Link to
Catering Incentives." Journal of Financial Economics 73, no. 2:
271-88.
Barber, Brad M., and Terrance Odean. 2000. "Trading Is
Hazardous to Your Wealth: The Common Stock Investment Performance of
Individual Investors." Journal of Finance 55, no. 2: 773-806.
Bodkin, Ronald G. 1959. "Windfall Income and
Consumption." American Economic Review 49, no. 4: 602-14.
Brav, Alon, and others. 2007. "Managerial Response to the May
2003 Dividend Tax Cut." Duke University.
Campbell, John Y. 2006. "Household Finance." Journal of
Finance 61, no. 4: 1553-1604.
Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller. 1988. "The
Dividend-Price Ratio and Expectations of Future Dividends and Discount
Factors." Review of Financial Studies 1, no. 3: 195-228.
Carroll, Christopher D. 1994. "How Does Future Income Affect
Current Consumption?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, no.
1:111-47.
--. 1997. "Buffer-Stock Saving and the Life-Cycle/Permanent
Income Hypothesis." Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, no. 1:
1-55.
Case, Karl E., John M. Quigley, and Robert J. Shiller. 2005.
"Comparing Wealth Effects: The Stock Market versus the Housing
Market." Advances in Macroeconomics 5, no. 1: 1-32.
Chetty, Raj, and Emmanuel Saez. 2005. "Dividend Taxes and
Corporate Behavior: Evidence from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, no. 3: 791-833.
Choi, James L., and others. 2006. "Consumption-Wealth
Comovement of the Wrong Sign." Yale University, Harvard University,
and University of Pennsylvania.
Cohen, Randolph B., Christopher K. Polk, and Tuomo Vuolteenaho.
2006. "The Price is (Almost) Right." Harvard University.
DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and Douglas J. Skinner. 2000.
"Special Dividends and the Evolution of Dividend Signaling."
Journal of Financial Economics 57, no. 3: 309-54.
Deaton, Angus. 1991. "Saving and Liquidity Constraints."
Econometrica 59, no. 5: 1221-48.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1988. "Permanent and
Temporary Components of Stock Prices." Journal of Political Economy
96, no. 2: 246-73.
Feldstein, Martin S. 1973. "Tax Incentives, Corporate Saving,
and Capital Accumulation in the United States." Journal of Public
Economics 2, no. 2: 159-71.
Feldstein, Martin S., and George Fane. 1973. "Taxes, Corporate
Dividend Policy and Personal Savings: The British Postwar Experience." Review of Economics and Statistics 55, no. 4: 399-411.
Graham, John R., and Alok Kumar. 2006. "Do Dividend Clienteles
Exist? Evidence on Dividend Preferences of Retail Investors."
Journal of Finance 61, no. 3: 1305-36.
Hayashi, Fumio. 1985. "The Effect of Liquidity Constraints on
Consumption: A Cross-Sectional Analysis." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 100, no. 1: 183-206.
Johnson, David S., Jonathan A. Parker, and Nicholas S. Souleles.
2006. "Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of
2001." American Economic Review 96, no. 5: 1589-1610.
Kreinin, Mordechai E. 1961. "Windfall Income and Consumption:
Additional Evidence." American Economic Review 51, no. 3: 388-90.
Lettau, Martin, and Sydney Ludvigson. 2004. "Understanding
Trend and Cycle in Asset Values: Reevaluating the Wealth Effect on
Consumption." American Economic Review 94, no. 1: 279-99.
McCaffery, Edward J., and Joel Slemrod, eds. 2006. Behavioral
Public Finance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Miller, Merton H., and Franco Modigliani. 1961. "Dividend
Policy, Growth, and the Valuation of Shares." Journal of Business
34, no. 4: 411-33.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. "A Simple,
Positive Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix." Econometrica 55, no. 3: 703-08.
Odean, Terrance. 1998. "Are Investors Reluctant to Realize
their Losses?" Journal of Finance 53, no. 5: 1775-98.
--. 1999. "Do Investors Trade Too Much?" American
Economic Review 89, no. 5: 1279-98.
Parker, Jonathan A. 1999a. "The Reaction of Household
Consumption to Predictable Changes in Social Security Taxes."
American Economic Review 89, no. 4: 959-73.
--. 1999b. "The Consumption Function Re-Estimated."
Princeton University.
--. 2001. "The Consumption Risk of the Stock Market."
BPEA, no. 2: 279-333.
Peek, Joe. 1983. "Capital Gains and Personal Saving
Behavior." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 15, no. 1: 1-23.
Poterba, James M. 1987. "Tax Policy and Corporate
Saving." BPEA, no. 2: 455-503.
--. 2000. "Stock Market Wealth and Consumption." Journal
of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 2: 99-118.
--. 2004. "Taxation and Corporate Payout Policy."
American Economic Review 94, no. 2: 171-75.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1988. "Mean
Reversion in Stock Prices: Evidence and Implications." Journal of
Financial Economics 22, no. 1: 27-59.
Rantapuska, Elias H. 2005. "Do Investors Reinvest Dividends
and Tender Offer Proceeds?" Helsinki School of Economics
Shefrin, Hersh M., and Meir Statman. 1984. "Explaining
Investor Preference for Cash Dividends." Journal of Financial
Economics 13, no. 2: 253-82.
Shefrin, Hersh M., and Richard H. Thaler. 1988. "The
Behavioral Life-Cycle Hypothesis." Economic Inquiry 26, no. 4:
609-43.
Souleles, Nicholas S. 1999. "The Response of Household
Consumption to Income Tax Refunds." American Economic Review 89,
no. 4: 947-58.
--. 2002. "Consumer Response to the Reagan Tax Cuts."
Journal of Public Economics 85, no. 1: 99-120.
Stephens, Melvin, Jr. 2003. "'3rd of tha Month': Do
Social Security Recipients Smooth Consumption between Checks?"
American Economic Review 93, no. 1: 406-22.
Summers, Lawrence, and Chris Carroll. 1987. "Why Is U.S.
National Saving so Low?" BPEA, no. 2: 607-35.
Thaler, Richard H., and Hersh M. Shefrin. 1981. "An Economic
Theory of Self-Control." Journal of Political Economy 89, no. 2:
392-406.
Vuolteenaho, Tuomo. 2002. "What Drives Firm-Level Stock
Returns?" Journal of Finance 57, no. 1: 233-64.
Wilcox, David W. 1989. "Social Security Benefits, Consumption
Expenditures, and the Life Cycle Hypothesis." Journal of Political
Economy 97, no. 2: 288-304.
MALCOLM BAKER
Harvard University
STEFAN NAGEL
Stanford University
JEFFREY WURGLER
New York University
(1.) Miller and Modigliani (1961).
(2.) Mental accounting behavior of this sort is discussed in detail
in Thaler and Shefrin (1981), Shefrin and Statman (1984), and Shefrin
and Thaler (1988).
(3.) This data set was introduced by Barber and Odean (2000).
(4.) See Feldstein (1973), Feldstein and Fane (1973), Peek (1983),
Summers and Carroll (1987), Poterba (1987), and Poterba (2000).
(5.) To our knowledge, the only paper to use micro data in this
context is a contemporaneous paper by Rantapuska (2005). He analyzes
Finnish investor registry data and finds that there is little
reinvestment within two weeks after receipts of dividends or tender
offer proceeds. His results are broadly consistent with and
complementary to ours, but there are some important differences. In
particular, the CEX data allow us to look at actual consumption, not
just reinvestment. Moreover, reinvestment may occur over horizons much
longer than two weeks, an issue that our brokerage account data allow us
to investigate. Finally, automatic reinvestment plans are absent in
Finland but common in the United States, so the effect of dividends on
consumption and reinvestment could be quite different in any case.
(6.) For instance, Souleles (1999) finds that consumption responds
to federal income tax refunds whether or not the household faces
borrowing constraints, and Souleles (2002) documents that consumption
responds to preannounced tax cuts. Related studies in this vein include
Bodkin (1959), Kreinin (1961), Wilcox (1989), Parker (1999a), Stephens
(2003), and Johnson. Parker, and Souleles (2006).
(7.) See Campbell (2006).
(8.) We use the average estimates in the interview survey of the
CEX, not the more detailed records from the diary survey.
(9.) This definition follows Parker (2001).
(10.) The surveys do not ask respondents to include retirement
assets, but they also do not ask explicitly to exclude them, so it is
unclear whether some respondents include them.
(11.) To preserve the anonymity of respondents, the CEX
administrators reset observations above certain thresholds on wealth,
income, and some other variables to a cutoff threshold value. Before
1995 the topcoding level was $100,000 for many items in the survey.
However, since the topcoding threshold applies to single items, the
total value of variables such as income after tax, for example, which is
calculated as the sum of many single items, can be much larger than
$100,000. After 1995, the topcoding thresholds were raised.
(12.) Under the basic form of the permanent income hypothesis,
permanent income determines consumption, and so the right-hand-side
variables in equation 1 matter to the extent that they are correlated
with permanent income. In models of buffer-stock saving with impatience,
such as those of Deaton (1991) and Carroll (1997), consumption depends
on cash on hand (liquid wealth plus current income) relative to its
target level.
(13.) This approach follows Hayashi (1985), Carroll (1994), and
Parker (1999b).
(14.) The quarterly interviews are conducted for overlapping ends
of quarters, and so we need year-month fixed effects, not simply
year-quarter fixed effects.
(15.) The income variable does not include capital gains (realized
or unrealized), so we only need to subtract dividends. In specifications
where dividends plus interest is the explanatory variable, we subtract
dividends and interest.
(16.) See Graham and Kumar (2006) and references therein for clear
evidence of dividend clienteles. Graham and Kumar show that the
allocation to and trades of dividend-paying stocks depend on investor
characteristics.
(17.) This is not an exact difference of the specification in
equation 1. We have only a single observation per household of lagged
wealth, lagged financial wealth, and capital gains, and so we are not
able to compute first differences. The most notable issue is that we do
not first-difference returns. Including R, instead of [DELTA]R, in the
regression means that we are leaving a -[R.sub.t-1] term in the residual
as an omitted variable. Fortunately, this should have little effect on
our test, as the change in dividends from t - 1 to t is not likely to be
highly correlated with [R.sub.t-1]. To the extent that there is some
correlation, high [R.sub.t-1] should forecast higher dividend changes
from t - 1 to t as firms' dividend policy responds with a lag to
unexpected increases in profits. As a result, the -[R.sub.t-1] term m
the residual is negatively correlated with dividend changes, and hence
this should lead to a downward bias on the dividend change coefficient.
This effect would bias the test against our hypothesis.
(18.) See Johnson, Parker, and Souleles (2006) for a similar dummy
variable approach to analyze the effect of tax rebates on log
consumption.
(19.) Dividends in our data are measured before tax. Our
regressions therefore show the relationship between before-tax dividends
and consumption. If one were to use after-tax dividends, the fraction
that goes into consumption would exceed 16 cents of every dollar. At the
same time, however, it is also not clear how households treat taxes on
dividends in a mental accounting framework. Since taxes on dividends are
not withheld, the before-tax dividend cash flow and the tax payment
occur at different points in time. To what extent households
"integrate" the before-tax dividend cash flow with the
subsequent tax payment, and to what extent it is more appropriate to
view them instead as separate income streams with possibly different
effects on consumption, are interesting questions. Unfortunately, we
cannot answer them with the data at hand. Our focus instead is on
documenting that dividends have an independent effect on consumption,
and showing that before-tax dividends affect consumption is sufficient
for that purpose. The 0.16 unit consumption effect of 1 unit of
dividends could in principle be compared with the coefficient on labor
income. However, in our specifications we see income and wealth
variables merely as controls for all the potential determinants of
households' consumption rule that could be correlated with
dividends. We would prefer not to claim that we have a complete and
correct model that would deliver the marginal propensity to consume out
of income. Nonetheless, for the interested reader, the total effect of
current and lagged income is 0.18 in regressions 2-1 and 2-2, 0.71 in
regression 2-5, and 0.70 in regression 2-6. So the effect of after-tax
labor income is in the same range as that of before-tax dividends.
(20.) Winsorizing replaces all observations in the tails of the
distribution (in this case the top and bottom 5 percent) with the
observed values at the 5th and the 95th percentiles, respectively. In
the base case nondurables regression (regression 2-1) in table 2, the
coefficient on the total return drops to -0.02 with a standard error of
0.02. In the base case total expenditure regression (regression 2-5) in
table 2, the coefficient rises to 0.01 with a standard error of 0.04.
(21.) In a paper that is similar in spirit, Choi and others (2006)
use shifts in savings into 401(k) plans to identify changes in
consumption.
(22.) See Barber and Odean (2000) for more details about the data
set.
(23.) This method follows DeAngelo, DeAngelo, and Skinner (2000).
(24.) The results below are robust to choosing different cutoffs.
For example, they are quantitatively similar when 5 percent or 0.5
percent of the most extreme observations are eliminated. But some
deletion of outliers is necessary: the most extreme single observation
would otherwise account for about one-third of the sum of squared net
withdrawals (even though there are close to 100,000 observations in
total), making any regression analysis practically meaningless.
(25.) Data from the Survey of Consumer Finances for 1992 and 1995
show that 87 percent and 89 percent, respectively, of U.S. households
with a brokerage account have only one brokerage account. This suggests
that our brokerage account data often capture at least the entire wealth
these investors have invested in brokerage accounts.
(26.) In principle, one could also include individual lags of
[D.sub.t] and [R.sub.t] instead of the summation terms, and then sum the
estimated coefficients on the individual lags to calculate the total
effect of delayed reinvestment. The approaches are equivalent when
[D.sub.t] and [R.sub.t] and their lags, respectively, are uncorrelated.
In our data these correlations are low, so both approaches lead to
similar results. For simplicity, we report results from the summed lags
approach.
(27.) A closely related, but behavioral, explanation for the high
propensity to consume current income is hyperbolic discounting as in
Angeletos and others (2001).
(28.) See Odean (1999) and Barber and Odean (2000) for more general
arguments that investors trade too much and fail to properly consider
transaction costs.
(29.) See Odean (1998).
(30.) Note that the issue of permanence of wealth shocks correlated
with dividends is unrelated to the issue of whether companies set
dividends equal to the permanent component of earnings. It is perfectly
possible for a company's earnings to have a strongly transitory
component while its stock returns are entirely permanent, and vice
versa. The relevant issue here is the permanence of stock returns, not
of earnings.
(31.) See Poterba and Summers (1988), Fama and French (1988), and
Campbell and Shiller (1988).
(32.) See Lettau and Ludvigson (2004).
(33.) Vuolteenaho (2002) and Cohen, Polk, and Vuolteenaho (2006)
find that only a small fraction of individual variation in stock returns
around the market return is transitory.
(34.) See Shefrin and Thaler (1988).
(35.) See also Shefrin and Statman (1984).
(36.) See Shefrin and Statman (1984).
(37.) These numbers are from Poterba (2004).
(38.) See Auerbach and Hassett (2006) for a discussion of the two
views on the investment effect of dividend taxes and of the evidence in
the context of the 2003 tax cuts.
(39.) See Chetty and Saez (2005) and Poterba (2004).
(40.) See Brav and others (2007).
(41.) Baker and Wurgler (2004a, 2004b) study how investor sentiment
affects dividend payment.
Table 1. Annual Summary Statistics for the Sample Drawn from the
Consumer Expenditure Survey, 1988-2001 (a)
Dollars except where stated otherwise
No. of
Variable observations Mean
Consumption
Nondurables (b) 3,106 15,042
Total 3,106 48,076
Wealth (c)
Financial 3,106 67,700
Total (d) 3,106 161,822
Income
Total ([Y.sub.t]) (c) 3,106 56,566
Interest ([I.sub.t]) 2,869 1,264
Dividends ([D.sub.t]) 3,106 935
Other 2,869 54,128
Capital gains ([G.sub.t]) (f) 3,106 363
Income components as percent
of total income
Interest 2,869 4.2
Dividends 3,106 2.1
Other 2,869 89.3
Capital gains 3,106 4.4
Controls
Share of financial wealth 3,106 56.19
invested in stock (percent)
Age of household head (years) 3,106 52
Family size 3,106 2
Percentile
Variable 50th 5th 95th
Consumption
Nondurables (b) 13,698 4,463 30,003
Total 44,582 15,549 91,892
Wealth (c)
Financial 38,701 2,928 222,207
Total (d) 127,276 10,943 428,919
Income
Total ([Y.sub.t]) (c) 52,316 12,282 115,505
Interest ([I.sub.t]) 145 0 6,383
Dividends ([D.sub.t]) 0 0 4,751
Other 50,526 10,192 112,245
Capital gains ([G.sub.t]) (f) 0 -16,014 18,988
Income components as percent
of total income
Interest 0.2 0.0 19.1
Dividends 0.0 0.0 12.0
Other 97.5 45.3 122.2
Capital gains 0.0 -27.3 38.2
Controls
Share of financial wealth 60.26 3.76 97.94
invested in stock (percent)
Age of household head (years) 49 30 80
Family size 2 1 5
Variable Minimum Maximum
Consumption
Nondurables (b) 1,347 78,548
Total 4,955 201,559
Wealth (c]
Financial 14 984,165
Total (d) 190 1,199,269
Income
Total ([Y.sub.t]) (c] 49 303,793
Interest ([I.sub.t]) 0 86,391
Dividends ([D.sub.t]) 0 144,658
Other -13,823 302,238
Capital gains ([G.sub.t]) (f) -301,407 181,503
Income components as percent
of total income
Interest -137.1 2,086.4
Dividends -36.4 236.7
Other -13,249.2 3,996.0
Capital gains -5,216.1 13,397.0
Controls
Share of financial wealth 0.05 100.00
invested in stock (percent)
Age of household head (years) 21 93
Family size 1 11
Source: Consumer Expenditure Survey and authors' calculations.
(a.) Sample is limited to households with the following
characteristics: household has nonzero financial wealth invested in
stocks: data on income and consumption am not missing; household
consists of only one consumer unit (family): marital status of the
respondent and family size remain unchanged from the second to the
fifth interview: none of the wealth components are topcoded. All
variables are converted to December 2001 dollars using the Consumer
price index as the deflator. All means, percentiles, and minimum and
maximum values refer to the distribution of households with respect to
the indicated variable.
(b.) Sum of food. alcohol, apparel, transportation, entertainment.
personal care, and reading expenditure over the four quarters from a
household's second to fifth interview.
(c.) Both wealth variables are lagged one period.
(d.) Sum of home equity and financial wealth. which is the sum of
checking and savings accounts balances, holdings of savings bonds,
money owed to the household. and stock holdings (stocks plus
mutual funds plus small positions in corporate and government bonds
other than savings bonds) minus other debts.
(e.) After-tax income over the preceding four quarter, as reported by
households in their firth interview. It includes income from dividends
(defined as dividends, royalties, and income from estates or
trusts) and interest income, but not capital gains.
(f.) Difference between the change in reported stock holdings over
four quarters and the reported net investment in stocks during the
same period.
Table 2. Regressions of Consumption on Dividends, Total Returns, and
Other Sources of Income Using Consumer Expenditure Survey Data in
Levels (a)
Dependent variable
Nondurables expenditure (b)
Independent variable 2-1 2-2 2-3 2-4
Total return on stocks ([R.sub.t] -0.01 -0.01
= [G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t]) (0.01) (0.01)
Dividends ([D.sub.t]) 0.16 0.16
(0.04) (0.05)
Dividends lagged one period 0.01
([D.sub.t-1]) (0.04)
Dummy variable equaling 1 if -694 -688
[D.sub.t] = [D.sub.t-1] = 0 (249) (253)
Total return ([R.sub.t] = -0.01 -0.01
[G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] + (0.01) (0.01)
[I.sub.t])
Dividends and interest ([D.sub.t] 0.13 0.12
+ [I.sub.t]) (0.04) (0.04)
Dividends and interest lagged one 0.03
period ([D.sub.t-1] + (0.03)
[I.sub.t-1])
Dummy variable equaling 1 if -595 -566
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (267) (268)
[D.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t-1] = 0
No. of observations 2,796 2,796 2,410 2,410
[R.sup.2] 0.52 0.52 0.52 0.52
Dependent variable
Total expenditure
Independent variable 2-5 2-6 2-7 2-8
Total return on stocks ([R.sub.t] -0.01 -0.01
= [G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t]) (0.02) (0.02)
Dividends ([D.sub.t]) 0.75 0.72
(0.14) (0.14)
Dividends lagged one period 0.14
([D.sub.t-1]) (0.11)
Dummy variable equaling 1 if -915 -772
[D.sub.t] = [D.sub.t-1] = 0 (639) (641)
Total return ([R.sub.t] = -0.02 -0.02
[G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] + (0.02) (0.02)
[I.sub.t])
Dividends and interest ([D.sub.t] 0.58 0.56
+ [I.sub.t]) (0.13) (0.13)
Dividends and interest lagged one 0.06
period ([D.sub.t-1] + (0.09)
[I.sub.t-1])
Dummy variable equaling 1 if -980 -922
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (684) (687)
[D.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t-1] = 0
No. of observations 2,796 2,796 2,410 2,410
[R.sup.2] 0.63 0.63 0.64 0.64
Source: Authors' regressions using Consumer Expenditure Survey data.
(a.) Consumption, total returns, dividends, and interest income are for
the four quarters from the household's second to its fifth interview.
Lagged variables cover the four quarters ending with the second
interview. All regressions include year-month fixed effects. Household
controls (family size, high school education of respondent. college
education of respondent. age of respondent). income and wealth controls
(income, lagged income, financial wealth, total wealth, and percent of
financial wealth in stocks, with all wealth variables for the period
ending four quarters before the fifth interview), and variables
interacting household controls with other household controls (high
school education x age, college education x age, family size x age,
age squared, family size squared) and with income and wealth variables
(financial wealth x age, income x family size. total wealth x family
size, income squared, total wealth squared, financial wealth squared,
and percentage of financial wealth in stocks squared). Numbers in
parentheses are heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. All
variables in dollars are deflated by the consumer price index.
(b.) Defined as in table 1.
Table 3. Regressions of Consumption on Dividends, Total Returns, and
Other Sources of Income Using Consumer Expenditure Survey Data in
First Differences (a)
Change in nondurables expenditure (b)
Independent variable 3-1 3-2 3-3 3-4
Total return on stocks -0.003 -0.002
([R.sub.t] = [G.sub.t] + (0.003) (0.003)
[D.sub.t]) (c)
Change in dividends ([DELTA] 0.017 0.005
[D.sub.t]) (d) (0.009) (0.010)
Dummy variable = 1 when -279 -127
[D.sub.t] = [D.sub.t-1] = 0 -92 -110
Change in income less dividends -0.001 0.000
([DELTA][[Y.sub.t] - (0.003) (0.004)
[D.sub.t]]) (d)
Total return ([R.sub.t] = -0.004 -0.004
[G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] + (0.003) (0.004)
[I.sub.t])
Change in dividends plus change 0.009 0.007
in interest ([DELTA] (0.008) (0.008)
[D.sub.t] + [DELTA]
[I.sub.t]) (d)
Dummy variable = 1 when -268 -78
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (105) (127)
[D.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t-1] = 0
Change in income less dividends -0.002 0.000
and interest ([DELTA] (0.004) (0.004)
[Y.sub.t] - [D.sub.t] -
[I.sub.t]]) (d)
Consumption lagged one period -0.678 -0.703
([C.sub.t-1]) (0.047) (0.049)
No. of observations 2,796 2,796 2,410 2,410
[R.sup.2] 0.38 0.06 0.39 0.06
Change in total expenditure
Independent variable 3-5 3-6 3-7 3-8
Total return on stocks 0.006 0.004
([R.sub.t] = [G.sub.t] + (0.008) (0.008)
[D.sub.t]) (c)
Change in dividends ([DELTA] 0.093 0.057
[D.sub.t]) (d) (0.029) (0.028)
Dummy variable = 1 when -850 -833
[D.sub.t] = [D.sub.t-1] = 0 -256 -255
Change in income less dividends 0.025 0.034
([DELTA][[Y.sub.t] - (0.007) (0.008)
[D.sub.t]]) (d)
Total return ([R.sub.t] = 0.003 0.002
[G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] + (0.009) (0.009)
[I.sub.t])
Change in dividends plus change 0.056 0.056
in interest ([DELTA] (0.028) (0.028)
[D.sub.t] + [DELTA]
[I.sub.t]) (d)
Dummy variable = 1 when 0 -732
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (0) (277)
[D.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t-1] = 0
Change in income less dividends 0.028 0.039
and interest ([DELTA] (0.008) (0.010)
[Y.sub.t] - [D.sub.t] -
[I.sub.t]]) (d)
Consumption lagged one period -0.621 -0.627
([C.sub.t-1]) (0.041) (0.045)
No. of observations 2.796 2,796 2,410 2,410
[R.sup.2] 0.37 0.07 0.39 0.08
Source: Authors' regressions using Consumer Expenditure Survey data.
(a.) The dependent (consumption) variables are defined as the
difference between quarterly consumption in the fifth (and last)
interview and that in the second interview three quarters earlier. All
regressions include year-month fixed effects and household controls
(family size and high school education. college education, and age of
respondent) and the following interactions: high school education x
age, college education x age, family size x age, age squared, and
family size squared. Numbers in parentheses are
heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. All variables in
dollars are deflated by the consumer price index.
(b.) Consumer nondurables expenditure is defined as in table 1.
(c.) Total returns are measured over the four quarters before a
household's fifth interview.
(d.) Difference between annual income items reported at the fifth
interview and the second interview three quarters earlier. This
variable is only an approximation of the first difference because
income in measured after tax whereas dicidcnds ire measured before tax.
Table 4. Regressions of Consumption on Dividends, Total Returns, and
Other Sources of Income Using Consumer Expenditure Survey Data in Log
Differences (a)
Dependent variable
Changes in nondurables
expenditure (b)
Independent variable 4-1 4-2 4-3 4-4
Log (1 + [G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t]] -0.034 -0.013
/[FW.sub.t-1] (c) (0.025) (0.029)
Dummy variable = 1 when [DELTA] 0.026 0.020
[D.sub.t] > 0 (0.026) (0.029)
Dummy variable = 1 when -0.035 0.002
[D.sub.t] = [D.sub.t-1] = 0 (0.022) (0.025)
Change in log of income less 0.010 0.020
dividends ([DELTA] log (0.012) (0.014)
[[Y.sub.t] - [D.sub.t]]) (d)
Log (1 + [G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] -0.031 -0.003
+ [I.sub.t]/[FW.sub.t-1]) (0.027) (0.032)
Dummy variable = 1 when [DELTA] 0.036 0.042
[D.sub.t] + [DELTA][I.sub. (0.018) (0.021)
[tau]] > 0
Dummy variable = 1 when -0.036 0.007
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (0.020) (0.022)
[D.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t-1] = 0
Change in log of income less 0.009 0.022
dividends and interest (0.013) (0.015)
([DELTA] log [Y.sub.t] -
[D.sub.t] - [I.sub.t]]) (d)
Log of consumption lagged one -0.441 -0.451
period ([C.sub.t-1]) (0.021) (0.023)
No. of observations 2,764 2,764 2,369 2,369
[R.sup.2] 0.26 0.06 0.27 0.08
Dependent variable
Change in total expenditure
Independent variable 4-5 4-6 4-7 4-8
Log (1 + [G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t]] 0.011 -0.002
/[FW.sub.t-1] (c) (0.030) (0.034)
Dummy variable = 1 when [DELTA] 0.074 0.083
[D.sub.t] > 0 (0.024) (0.028)
Dummy variable = 1 when -0.017 0.017
[D.sub.t] = [D.sub.t-1] = 0 (0.021) (0.025)
Change in log of income less 0.035 0.047
dividends ([DELTA] log (0.012) (0.014)
[[Y.sub.t] - [D.sub.t]]) (d)
Log (1 + [G.sub.t] + [D.sub.t] 0.010 0.003
+ [I.sub.t]/[FW.sub.t-1]) (0.033) (0.038)
Dummy variable = 1 when [DELTA] 0.029 0.047
[D.sub.t] + [DELTA][I.sub. (0.017) (0.019)
[tau]] > 0
Dummy variable = 1 when -0.040 -0.003
[D.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] = (0.018) (0.020)
[D.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t-1] = 0
Change in log of income less 0.035 0.049
dividends and interest (0.014) (0.016)
([DELTA] log [Y.sub.t] -
[D.sub.t] - [I.sub.t]]) (d)
Log of consumption lagged one -0.456 -0.440
period ([C.sub.t-1]) (0.021) (0.023)
No. of observations 2,764 2,764 2,369 2,369
[R.sup.2] 0.29 0.07 0.28 0.08
Source: Authors' regressions using Consumer Expenditure Survey data.
(a.) The dependent (consumption) variables are defined as the
difference between the logarithm of quarterly consumption in the fifth
land last) interview and that in the second interview three quarters
earlier. All regressions include year-month fixed effects. Household
controls (family size and high school education. college education, and
age of respondent), and the following interactions: high school
education x age, college education x age, family size x age, age
squared. and family size squared. Numbers on parentheses are
heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. All variables in dollars
are deflated by the consumer price index.
(b.) Consumer nondurables expenditure is defined as in table 1.
(c.) Total returns (G + D) are measured over the four quarters prior
to a household's fifth interview. FW is financial wealth, defined as
in table 1, note d.
(d.) Difference between annual income items reported of the fifth
interview and the second interview three quarters earlier.
Table 5. Summary Statistics for the Sample Drawn from the Brokerage
Portfolio Data, 1991-96 (a)
Percent of assets in previous period except where stated otherwise
No. of
Variable observations Mean
Portfolio composition
Assets in previous period 92,412 54.41
(thousands of dollars)
Common stocks 92,412 82.69
Mutual funds 92,412 13.49
Other assets 92,412 3.82
Withdrawals, dividends, and total returns
Withdrawals (C] (b) 92,412 0.06
Dividends (D) (c] 92,412 0.20
Returns (R] (d) 92,412 1.11
Dividends bY type, all households (e)
Ordinary 92,412 0.12
Mutual fund 92,412 0.07
Special 92,412 0.01
Dividends by type as percent of total current-period dividends (f)
Ordinary 44,509 77.92
Mutual fund 44,509 21.79
Special 44,509 0.30
Percentile
Variable 50th 10th 90th
Portfolio composition
Assets in previous period 28.43 13.85 99.78
(thousands of dollars)
Common stocks 0.00 0.00 100.00
Mutual funds 0.00 0.00 0.00
Other assets 0.00 0.00 15.48
Withdrawals, dividends, and total returns
Withdrawals (C] (b) 0.00 -0.7 0.99
Dividends (D) (c] 0.00 0.00 0.55
Returns (R] (d) 1.06 -6.13 8.28
Dividends bY type, all households (e)
Ordinary 0.00 0.00 0.43
Mutual fund 0.00 0.00 0.07
Special 0.00 0.00 0.00
Dividends by type as percent of total current-period dividends (f)
Ordinary 100.00 0.00 100.00
Mutual fund 0.00 0.00 100.00
Special 0.00 0.00 0.00
Variable Minimum Maximum
Portfolio composition
Assets in previous period 10.00 5,018.89
(thousands of dollars)
Common stocks 0.00 100.00
Mutual funds 0.00 100.00
Other assets 0.00 25.00
Withdrawals, dividends, and total returns
Withdrawals (C] (b) -50.00 50.00
Dividends (D) (c] 0.00 102.39
Returns (R] (d) -73.96 153.47
Dividends bY type, all households (e)
Ordinary 0.00 2.96
Mutual fund 0.00 29.91
Special 0.00 102.39
Dividends by type as percent of total current-period dividends (f)
Ordinary 0.00 100.00
Mutual fund 0.00 100.00
Special 0.00 100.00
Source: Barber and Odean (2000) and authors' calculations.
(a.) Observations are excluded when a CRSP mutual fund or common stock
match cannot be identified for more than 75 percent of household
account value in the period preceding the returns calculations: when
the account value falls below $10,000. or dividends are missing in any
of the months t to t - 11; for margin accounts: for accounts that are
not joint tenancy or individual accounts: and when the absolute value
of consumption exceeds 50 percent of assets. All means, percentiles,
and minimum and maximum values refer to the distribution of households
with respect to the indicated variable.
(b.) Monthly withdrawals are estimated as the household's account value
in the previous period (aggregating across all eligible accounts held
by the household) less the account value in the current period plus
dividends and capital gains earned on the previous-month account
holdings.
(c.) Dividends are calculated from CRSP and the CRSP mutual fund
database on common stock and mutual fund account holdings at the end
of the previous month.
(d.) Dividends plus capital gains, the latter defined as capital
appreciation as taken From CRSP and the CRSP mutual fund database on
previous-month common stock and mutual fund account holdings.
(e.) Ordinary and special dividends are identified from CRSP
(distribution codes 1232. 1212, 1218. 1222. and 1245 for ordinary, and
1262 and 1272 for special dividends). Mutual fund dividends are
identified from the CSRP mutual fund database,
(f.) Distribution includes only those households receiving dividends.
Table 6. Simple Regresions of Net Brokerage Withrawals on Dividends
and Total Returns (a)
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as share of
previous-period assets and
regressions are
Linear
Independent variable 6-l 6-2 6-3
Intercept -0.01 0.04 -0.03
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Dividends as share 0.35 0.35
of previous-period (0.09) (0.09)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] dummy = 1 if
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets (R,/A,_,)
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy 1 if
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025
[R.sup.2] 0.0025 0.0005 0.0029
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as share of
previous-period assets and
regressions are
Piecewise linear
Independent variable 6-4 6-5 6-6
Intercept -0.06 0.04 -0.07
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Dividends as share 0.77 0.77
of previous-period (0.09) (0.09)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] dummy = 1 if -0.44 -0.44
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile (0.11) (0.11)
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets (R,/A,_,)
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy 1 if -0.03 -0.05
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025 (0.02) (0.02)
[R.sup.2] 0.0027 0.0005 0.0032
Source: Authors' regressions using data from Barber and Odean (2000).
(a.) All data are in percent. All regressions include an intercept
(not reported). Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are in
parentheses. The sample in each regression consists of 92.412
observations.
Table 7. Regressions of Net Brokerage Withdrawals on Dividends and
Total Returns Controlling for Effect of Delayed Reinvestment (a)
Dependent variable is
net withdrawals as share
of previous-period
assets and
regressions are
Linear
Independent variable 7-1 7-2 7-3
Dividends as share 0.35 0.35
of previous-period (0.09) (0.09)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1)
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile
Average of 11 monthly 0.01 0.01
lags of dividends/assets (0.10) (0.10)
(1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11]
[D.sub.t-s]/[A.sub.t-1])
1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11]
[D.sub.t-s]/[A.sub.t-1]) x
dummy = 1 [D.sub.t-s]/[A.sub.t-1]
> 90th percentile
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets ([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025
1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11] 0.00 0.00
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] (0.01) (0.01)
1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11] x dummy = 1
if |[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025
[R.sup.2] 0.0025 0.0005 0.0029
Dependent variable is
net withdrawals as share
of previous-period
assets and
regressions are
Piecewise linear
Independent variable 7-4 7-5 7-6
Dividends as share 0.81 0.80
of previous-period (0.10) (0.10)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1)
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.48 -0.47
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile (0.12) (0.12)
Average of 11 monthly -0.16 -0.07
lags of dividends/assets (0.17) (0.18)
(1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11] 0.14 0.07
[D.sub.t-s]/[A.sub.t-1])
1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11]
[D.sub.t-s]/[A.sub.t-1]) x
dummy = 1 [D.sub.t-s]/[A.sub.t-1] (0.18) (0.18)
> 90th percentile
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets ([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.03 -0.04
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025 (0.02) (0.02)
1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11] 0.00 0.00
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] (0.01) (0.01)
1/11 [[summation].sub.s=1 to 11] x dummy = 1 0.03 -0.06
if |[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025 (0.06) (0.06)
[R.sup.2] 0.0027 0.0005 0.0032
Source: Authors' regressions using data from Barber and Odean (2000).
(a.) All data are in percent. All regressions include an intercept
(not reported). Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are in
parentheses. Data on household net worth and tax rate are self-reported
and were supplied to the brokerage firm at the time the account
was opened. The sample in each regression consists of 92,412
observations.
Table 8. Split-Sample Regressions of Net Brokerage Withdrawals on
Dividends and Total Returns (a)
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as share of
previous-period assets and
sample is split according to
Household portfolio value
>Half
net
Independent variable <Median >Median worth
Dividends as share of previous- 0.77 0.80 0.84
period assets ([D.sub.t]/ (0.12) (0.13) (0.43)
[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy -0.43 -0.48 -0.54
= 1 if [D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] (0.15) (0.16) (0.44)
> 90th percentile
Total returns as share of 0.02 0.02 0.01
previous-period assets (0.00) (0.00) (0.01)
([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy 0.00 -0.08 -0.02
= 1 if |[R.sub.t]/ (0.03) (0.03) (0.08)
[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025
No. of observations 45,092 47,320 6,240
[R.sup.2] 0.0042 0.0026 0.0012
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as share of
previous-period assets and
sample is split according to
Household Household
net worth tax rate
Independent variable <Median >Median <Median >Median
Dividends as share of previous- 0.67 0.81 0.44 1.00
period assets ([D.sub.t]/ (0.32) (0.36) (0.29) (0.40)
[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy -0.16 -0.72 -0.32 -0.57
= 1 if [D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] (0.32) (0.36) (0.30) (0.41)
> 90th percentile
Total returns as share of 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.00
previous-period assets (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy -0.07 -0.01 -0.07 -0.01
= 1 if |[R.sub.t]/ (0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.08)
[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025
No. of observations 11,947 7,973 11,768 8,152
[R.sup.2] 0.0035 0.0010 0.0021 0.0026
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as share of
previous-period assets and
sample is split according to
Household portfolio
turnover
Independent variable <Median >Median
Dividends as share of previous- 0.75 0.89
period assets ([D.sub.t]/ (0.07) (0.19)
[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy -0.45 -0.52
= 1 if [D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] (0.11) (0.21)
> 90th percentile
Total returns as share of 0.01 0.03
previous-period assets (0.00) (0.01)
([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy -0.02 -0.07
= 1 if |[R.sub.t]/ (0.02) (0.04)
[A.sub.t-1]| < 0.025
No. of observations 48,353 44,059
[R.sup.2] 0.0062 0.0029
Source: Authors' regressions using data from Barber and Odean (2000).
(a.) All data are in percent. All regressions include an intercept
(not reported). Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are in
parentheses.
Table 9. Regressions of Net Brokerage Withdrawals on Dividends of
Different Types and Total Returns (a)
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as shareof
previous-period assets and
dividends are
Independent variable Ordinary
Dividends as share 0.82 0.71
of previous-period (0.11) (0.13)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if 0.16 0.16
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile (0.12) (0.12)
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets ([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.02 -0.02
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| <0.025 (0.02) (0.02)
Ratio of 12-month lag 0.13
of dividends to total (0.09)
assets ([D.sub.t-12]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.2] 0.0023 0.0023
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as shareof
previous-period assets and
dividends are
Independent variable Mutual fund
Dividends as share 0.40 0.35
of previous-period (0.12) (0.14)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.26 -0.23
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile (0.13) (0.13)
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets ([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.04 -0.04
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| <0.025 (0.02) (0.02)
Ratio of 12-month lag 0.05
of dividends to total (0.06)
assets ([D.sub.t-12]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.2] 0.0007 0.0007
Dependent variable is net
withdrawals as shareof
previous-period assets and
dividends are
Special
Independent variable and other
Dividends as share 0.75 0.75
of previous-period (0.13) (0.13)
assets ([D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.46 -0.46
[D.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] > 90th percentile (0.19) (0.19)
Total returns as share 0.02 0.02
of previous-period (0.00) (0.00)
assets ([R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1] x dummy = 1 if -0.03 -0.03
|[R.sub.t]/[A.sub.t-1]| <0.025 (0.02) (0.02)
Ratio of 12-month lag -0.08
of dividends to total (0.04)
assets ([D.sub.t-12]/[A.sub.t-1])
[R.sub.2] 0.0021 0.0022
Source: Authors' regressions using data from Barber and Odean (2000).
(a.) All data are in percent. All regressions include an intercept
(not reported). Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are in
parentheses. The sample in each regression consists of 92,412
observations.