How much do we understand about the modern recession?
Hall, Robert E.
MODERN RECESSIONS HIT THE U.S. economy in 1990-91 and in 2001. A
modern recession is one occurring in an economy with well-executed
monetary policy and a small fraction of the labor force on the factory
floor. I review the facts about modern recessions and compare them with
earlier recessions, with primary emphasis on the labor market. The facts
are perplexing: employment falls in modern recessions at least as far as
in past recessions, without identifiable driving forces.
Economists' understanding of the modern causeless recession is at
an early stage, but progress has occurred and the future of this area of
research seems promising.
Facts about Modern and Earlier Recessions
The first important fact about modern recessions is that they are
about as severe when measured in employment losses as earlier ones,
leaving aside the Great Depression. Figure 1 shows deviations of total
employment from its trend since 1948, and table 1 shows the percentage
decline in employment associated with each of the ten recessions of the
past sixty years. (The identification of recessions follows the standard
chronology as determined by the National Bureau of Economic Research
Business Cycle Dating Committee, but the dates are for the peaks and
troughs in detrended employment, not the National Bureau's dates
for peaks and troughs in economic activity.) The two modern recessions
rank second and sixth in employment decline. Plainly the "Great
Moderation"--the broad reduction in economic volatility of the last
couple of decades--is a feature not of employment, but rather of output.
One of the important features of the modern recession is that
productivity does not decline as it did in earlier ones.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The Great Moderation definitely applies to GDP, whose volatility
has fallen by half in the past two decades compared with the two
preceding decades. By some measures, such as the standard deviation of
year-to-year changes in employment, the volatility of employment also
has declined, but not as much. But the key fact is that modern
recessions have involved lengthy periods of below-trend employment
growth, and so a metric that captures these lengthy periods, such as
that in table 1, reveals that employment volatility has not declined at
all. Of course, this statement is based on a sample size of two. The
next recession could easily have a small and brief decline in
employment.
The second important fact is that the decline in employment and
rise in unemployment associated with a modern recession occur without
any important increase in job loss. Figure 2 shows the layoff rate
reported by employers in the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
(JOLTS), which began in December 2000, just in time to catch the 2001
recession. Apart from a spike at 9/11, layoffs remained quite constant
until they began to decline moderately in late 2005. This picture of the
2001 recession is confirmed by a long time series constructed by Robert
Shimer for the exit rate from employment, that is, the rate of departure
from employment into unemployment or out of the labor force (figure 3).
Shimer's series actually declines fairly steadily over the entire
period since the early 1980s, with no visible reversal during the 2001
recession. This illustrates the third important fact: unemployment rises
in a modern recession because new jobs are hard to find, not because
workers have lost jobs. In a recession, the flow of workers out of jobs
remains about the same, and so does the flow of workers back into jobs.
But a much larger pool of unemployed develops because jobs are hard to
find. The rate at which the unemployed find jobs falls in the same
proportion that the stock of unemployed rises, resulting in a constant
flow from unemployment into new jobs.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 3 shows that earlier recessions did generate spikes of job
loss. In those recessions, unemployment rose both because workers lost
jobs more frequently and because the unemployed found it harder to land
new jobs. The spikes of job loss were brief, so that unemployment
rebounded more rapidly in the earlier recessions than in the modern
ones. Layoffs in durables manufacturing were an important factor in
these spikes.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Figure 4 shows the job-finding rate for the unemployed, also
calculated by Shimer. In the 1990-91 and 2001 recessions, the same
dramatic fall in the monthly likelihood of finding new work occurred as
in the recessions of earlier decades.
Another dimension of the softening of the labor market in
recessions is in the recruiting efforts of employers, as measured by
help-wanted advertising. Figure 5 shows that help-wanted ads collapse in
every recession, but did so especially sharply in the two modern
recessions. The 2001 recession, although not severe by the standard of
employment decline, saw the largest fall ever in help-wanted ads. The
decline may have been exaggerated by a shift toward Internet recruiting,
as the further decline during the recovery suggests. The Conference
Board, which collects these data, has recently begun to gather data on
online job listings but has not yet produced a combined index.
In the modern recession, as in earlier ones, all sectors of the
labor market slacken at the same time. Figure 6 illustrates this fact in
terms of job openings recorded in JOLTS for the 2001 recession. Each of
the seven major sectors-even including government--was recruiting to
fill far fewer positions at the trough of the recession than at the
previous peak. The softening of the labor market was economy-wide, not
restricted to recession-prone sectors such as durables. Katharine
Abraham and Lawrence Katz were the first to recognize the significance
of this feature of the economy, (1) which rules out theories of
recession that rest on reallocation from shrinking to expanding sectors.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
If unemployment in a recession were the natural, efficient result
of reallocation of workers from shrinking to growing sectors, the
growing sectors would be seen opening their doors wide to absorb the
flow of workers leaving the shrinking sectors. Vacancies would be high
in the growing sectors and low in the shrinking ones. Figure 6 refutes
that view for the most recent recession. Some common force was making
all sectors cut back their recruiting. Later I will discuss the idea
that sticky prices and wages could explain these facts. I find that they
could, but that the traditional way of thinking about stickiness is
theoretically unsatisfying and is in the process of being replaced by a
new line of thought.
Driving Forces
What exogenous forces cause recessions? Three forces are prominent
in the accounts of the various schools of macroeconomic thought:
productivity, government purchases, and monetary shocks.
I have shown elsewhere that the appropriate measure of productivity
from the perspective of the labor market is the average product of
labor, which moves in proportion to the marginal product of labor under
constant returns to scale. (2) Figure 7 plots detrended productivity
since 1948. It shows that although productivity did decline in earlier
recessions, the two modern recessions occurred without any contribution
from that source. Given that finding, it is unnecessary to enter the
debate over whether the earlier productivity declines were the cause or
the effect of the recessions that accompanied them.
Figure 8 shows detrended government purchases. The 1990-91
recession occurred during a period of unusually rapid decline in these
purchases--as did the 1970-71 recession. But purchases rose slightly
more than normal in 2001. Fluctuations in government purchases do not
seem to play much of a role in the story of recessions.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The two modern recessions occurred in the setting of fully modern
monetary policymaking. In that setting the central bank responds to
outside influences, with the objective of keeping inflation low in the
longer run and offsetting booms and recessions in the shorter
run--monetary policy is not a source of disturbances to the economy.
Figure 9, which plots the interest rate on federal funds since 1954,
illustrates the change in monetary policymaking that separated the last
of the earlier recessions, in 1981-82, from the two modern recessions.
Here the most noticeable change is the huge reduction in the volatility
of the funds rate. But timing differences are important as well. Under
modern policy the Federal Reserve cuts the rate aggressively as soon as
a recession is apparent. Under the old policy the Federal Reserve not
only caused the recession by raising the rate to extreme levels, but
held it high during the recession. This behavior was most prominent in
the 1973-75 and 1981-82 recessions. Although monetary policy can be a
causal factor in recessions, and apparently was in the 1980s and before,
it is hard to see how monetary policy could have caused either of the
modern recessions.
John Cochrane argued similarly long before the second modern
recession. He assigned virtually all responsibility for recessions to
what one might call "mystery shocks," after reviewing the
standard candidates. (3) Sometimes the mystery shocks have names. For
example, many observers blame the 1990-91 recession on the savings and
loan crisis, and the 2001 recession on the collapse of technology
spending when the technology bubble broke in 2000.
The primary defect with this class of explanations is their failure
to explain the Abraham-Katz phenomenon. If housing fell in 1990-91
because of financial constraints stemming from the savings and loan failures, but all other sectors were unaffected, it is hard to see why
all the other sectors' labor markets turned so slack. The focus of
the technology sector collapse was even narrower. Why didn't the
winning sectors expand to absorb the workers released by the single
losing sector in each of the two modern recessions ?
A traditional answer to this question is that the wage-price system
fails to send the right signals to consumers, workers, and firms to
expand the unaffected sectors. One view is that real wages are sticky
and thus remain too high to yield firms in the other sectors high enough
profits to expand. Another is that prices are sticky and remain too high
to result in full employment because the central bank keeps the interest
rate too high for any expansion to occur. Recent models combine both
views. The recent paper by Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and
Charles Evans is a leading example of modern research in this vein. (4)
Sticky wages and prices are not a full explanation, however,
because they lack a deep rationalization. A sticky wage that keeps
employment below a mutually desirable level creates an opportunity for a
worker and an employer to make a Pareto improvement for themselves by
adjusting employment upward. What happens to the wage is immaterial
here--what matters is the increase in employment. The same holds when a
sticky price keeps the quantity of goods traded below its efficient
level. The traditional sticky-price literature has not come to grips
with the obvious tools that employers, workers, sellers, and customers
possess to overcome inefficiently low employment or sales. The
literature lacks a coherent theory of disequilibrium. Departures from
equilibrium are an assertion, not a derived conclusion from
fundamentals. Traditional sticky-wage and sticky-price theory has a
strong descriptive claim but not a strong theoretical underpinning.
The Modern Economics of Job Creation
The 1994 paper by Dale Mortensen and Christopher Pissarides is the
canon of the modern theory of job creation in a frictional labor market.
(5) Pissarides later provided a more complete book-length treatment of
the subject, before the recent explosion of new thinking. (6) The
Mortensen-Pissarides paper brought unemployment back into formal
macroeconomics. The labor market in their model describes unemployment
in a way that rings true. People grope around trying to find jobs that
fit, and the process takes time and information flows are limited. The
model improves on traditional sticky-wage treatments of the labor market
by invoking a full equilibrium, devoid of any opportunities for
bilateral Pareto improvements by a worker-employer pair.
The Mortensen-Pissarides model also fits the facts about modern
fluctuations, in the sense that it focuses mainly on job creation rather
than job loss. The incentive for job creation is the margin between the
productivity of a new worker and the wage to be paid to that worker,
both as present values over the duration of the worker's employment
with the firm. Employers expend recruiting resources--running ads,
paying posting fees at Monster.com, interviewing applicants, and the
like--up to the point that the resources needed to add one worker to the
payroll absorb the entire present value of the productivity-wage margin.
The model describes an equilibrium in the market for new hires.
The model also describes an equilibrium with respect to the
termination of employment. Workers do not lose jobs because their wages
are too high. They lose or leave jobs only if their opportunity cost in
the market at large exceeds their productivity in their current job.
This equilibrium property is probably the most important difference
between the modern macroeconomic view of unemployment, as embodied in
the Mortensen-Pissarides model, and traditional thinking. The older view
had workers resisting wage cuts that would have saved their jobs. Jobs
are automatically saved in the Mortensen-Pissarides model exactly when
they are worth saving--job separations are efficient.
In October 1969--the month, it so happens, that I was recruited as
a member of the Brookings Panel--the paper by Robert Lucas and Leonard
Rapping appeared that launched the equilibrium school of employment
fluctuations. (7) Although the proposition that markets achieve
equilibrium-in the sense that pairs of actual or potential transactors
cannot alter the terms of their transaction to their mutual
advantage--is virtually the defining concept of economic science, the
Lucas-Rapping story, that movements in employment are along a labor
supply curve and that unemployment can be lumped with leisure, was at
best at the borderline of plausibility. The enhancement of the story in
the real business cycle model and its progeny never persuaded even the
more sympathetic of its critics (such as me). The essential problem was
that every version of the equilibrium story invoked a far higher
elasticity of labor supply than could ever be found in the micro data.
The Mortensen-Pissarides model, in contrast, holds out the
tantalizing possibility of an equilibrium theory without excessively
elastic labor supply. The question that we have been wrestling with
since 2002, when Shimer first circulated his paper that would later
appear in the American Economic Review, (8) is whether some variant of
the model can generate cyclical fluctuations of the magnitude found in
the U.S. economy. Shimer showed that the original Mortensen-Pissarides
model could not come close. Dozens of subsequent papers have introduced
alterations in the model to boost its response to the driving forces so
as to generate realistic unemployment volatility.
Mortensen and Pissarides followed John Nash in taking the division
of the surplus as a fixed parameter. That assumption turned out to doom
their model to failure as far as unemployment volatility is concerned.
If one abandons this assumption, their model has the potential to
generate lots of volatility. With realistic choices of its parameters,
it turns out that a relatively small decline in productivity relative to
the wage causes a substantial reduction in recruiting effort, making it
much harder for workers to find jobs. The constant flow of workers into
the pool of unemployed-unchanging over the cycle--requires a much larger
stock of unemployed to generate an equal flow from unemployment to work.
The reluctance of employers to hire any given job seeker is offset by
the greater number of job seekers.
Not surprisingly, a lot of the new research has focused on wage
determination. In a sense, the wage is indeterminate within a specified
range in the Mortensen-Pissarides model. The indeterminacy arises in any
model where potential transactors meet each other at random, in pairs,
rather than gathering in a central market where they can participate in
an auction. An employer and a worker, having met at random, face the
situation described by an Edgeworth box. If a bargain is available that
benefits both sides, there is a contract curve showing the possible
levels of compensation that split the joint surplus. But no fundamental
theory exists to show how the parties make their bargain along the
contract curve.
John Nash tackled this problem in his second-most-famous paper. (9)
Under plausible but not compelling assumptions, the parties pick a
division of the surplus controlled by a parameter reflecting their
relative bargaining powers. Researchers in the Mortensen-Pissarides line
tend, with one interesting exception that I will take up momentarily, to
think of bargaining power as roughly equally divided between worker and
employer.
The choice of the Nash bargain prevents the original
Mortensen-Pissarides model from harnessing this source of unemployment
volatility. It makes the wage so flexible that there is essentially no
movement in the key productivity-wage margin. If productivity falls, so
does the wage, the margin remains the same, and employers recruit with
their usual enthusiasm.
Marcus Hagedorn and Iourii Manovskii spotted a way to overcome the
low unemployment volatility implied by the Mortensen-Pissarides model
with a Nash wage bargain. (10) They assigned low bargaining power to the
worker and at the same time assigned a low desire to work--in other
words, a high opportunity cost of participating in the labor market. The
wage is essentially a weighted average of the opportunity cost and
productivity, with the weight on the latter equal to the worker's
bargaining power, measured as the worker' s share of the total
surplus from the employment relationship. Thus, Hagedorn and
Manovskii's two assumptions imply that the wage is controlled more
by the opportunity cost and less by productivity. So if productivity
falls, the wage does not fall by as much, the incentive to recruit
falls, the labor market softens, and unemployment rises. Hagedorn and
Manovskii's model can match the observed volatility of
unemployment-it delivers a true equilibrium account of cyclical
fluctuations. But attributing a high opportunity cost to participation
in the labor market is just another way of saying that labor supply is
quite elastic. The elasticity of labor supply implicit in their model is
two or three times higher than is found in micro studies.
I have been involved in elaborating a couple of alternative
solutions that avoid excessive labor supply elasticity. My 2005 paper
drops the Nash wage bargain, replacing it with a wage rule that
stabilizes the wage within the bargaining set, that is, along the part
of the contract curve in the Edgeworth box that is within the lens
formed by the indifference curves that pass through the points the
parties could achieve if they did not make a bargain. (11) If the normal
wage is in the middle of the bargaining set, corresponding to equal
sharing of the employment surplus, the model avoids the
Hagedorn-Manovskii implication of a high labor supply elasticity. The
cost is that the wage rule is ad hoc. Although the rule satisfies the
basic property of equilibrium--the solution lies on the contract curve,
inside the Edgeworth lens--the model provides no guidance about where
wage stabilization comes from.
My recent paper with Paul Milgrom offers a less arbitrary theory of
equilibrium sticky wages. (12) We again drop the Nash bargain, this time
in favor of alternating-offer bargaining. We see this as a move toward
realism in how bargaining actually occurs: whereas the Nash bargain just
appears as if by magic, in alternating-offer bargaining one party--we
believe usually the employer--makes an offer and the worker accepts or
makes a counteroffer. The resulting wage bargain is much less sensitive
to the worker's opportunity cost. Although the bargain is still
fairly flexible, it is sufficiently stickier than the Nash bargain to
make the model capable of matching the observed increase in unemployment
in a recession.
Taming the excess flexibility of the wage bargain in the original
Mortensen-Pissarides model strikes me as the most promising way to
generate realistic unemployment volatility. However, some researchers
are exploring modifications of the model in other directions, especially
adding on-the-job search to the story. The project of enhancing the
Mortensen-Pissarides model to account for realistic movements in
unemployment faces a huge unmet challenge, however. We have no idea how
to generate a modern recession from the model. Almost all the recent
work has taken productivity fluctuations as the most promising driving
force. If the wage is sticky but productivity rises and falls, the key
margin will fluctuate properly, and the Mortensen-Pissarides setup gives
a totally convincing account of the results in the labor market and the
economy as a whole. But productivity has not fallen in the two modern
recessions. The recession of 2001 in fact occurred during a burst of
productivity growth so rapid that essentially no decline in output
occurred even as employment fell dramatically. So the next step in this
promising line of work is to figure out how the subtle changes that
occurred in the economy in 1990-91 and 2001 translated into diminished
incentives all across the economy to create jobs.
General Discussion
Benjamin Friedman wondered how economists should judge the role of
monetary policy in causing recessions. When monetary policy responds to
a shock to the economy, that response may trigger another problem to
which monetary policy must then respond. Inflation may ultimately end up
outside the central bank's comfort zone, and monetary policy
tightens in response. Was the resulting recession then
"caused" by monetary policy, or by the original shock, or by
one of the intermediate steps in the chain of events? Friedman gave the
example of the recession of the early 1980s: Paul Volcker did not
deliberately set out to create a recession but was responding to various
events, many of them (like the 1979 increase in oil prices) originating
outside the United States, and this chain of events and responses ended
in recession. Thus, monetary policy is an important but somewhat
ambiguous part of the cyclical story.
William Brainard discussed the complexity of the relationships
between firms and employees. He argued that the models of
employer-employee wage bargaining in the paper, which assume a single
employer and a representative employee engaging in bargaining, ignore
the differences between the marginal and the average worker in a firm.
This simplification is less of a problem if all workers are represented
by a completely centralized union, but this is usually not the case.
Brainard suggested that the model's assumption was artificial and
ignored the constraints imposed by within-firm labor markets.
William Nordhaus said that he would have liked rigid wages and
prices to be addressed more in the paper, particularly to explain the
moderate decline in the layoff rate since 2005. Another possible
explanation for this decline may be the "Europeanization" of
some American institutions: it is becoming increasingly difficult to lay
off workers. Nordhaus also wondered why employment has not become less
volatile given the striking decline in output volatility.
Arithmetically, these phenomena are reconciled by a decline in the
cyclicality of productivity, but that decline suggests a reduction in
labor market rigidities that appears inconsistent with the declining
layoff rate in recent years.
Lawrence Summers noted that the recessions preceding World War II
were "modem recessions" by Robert Hall's definition,
because they were not caused by inflation prompting the Federal Reserve
to tighten monetary policy. "Modern" recessions seem to be
caused by a more widespread and unquantifiable loss of confidence, which
Robert Shiller has written about elsewhere. Summers suggested that
modern and traditional recessions may have different implications for
productivity, which might be a useful way of categorizing them.
References
Abraham, Katharine G., and Lawrence F. Katz. 1986. "Cyclical
Unemployment: Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate Disturbances?" Journal
of Political Economy 94, no. 3 (part 1, June): 507-22.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans.
2005. "Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to
Monetary Policy." Journal of Political Economy 113, no. 1
(February): 1-45.
Cochrane, John H. 1994. "Shocks." Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy 41 (December): 295-364.
Hagedorn, Marcus, and Iourii Manovskii. Forthcoming. "The
Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies
Revisited." American Economic Review.
Hall, Robert E. 2005. "Employment Fluctuations with
Equilibrium Wage Stickiness." American Economic Review 95, no. 1
(March): 50-65. --. 2007. "Sources and Mechanisms of Cyclical
Fluctuations in the Labor
Market." Department of Economics, Stanford University (June).
Hall, Robert E., and Paul R. Milgrom. Forthcoming. "The
Limited Influence of Unemployment on the Wage Bargain." American
Economic Review.
Lucas, Robert E., and Leonard A. Rapping. 1969. "Real Wages,
Employment, and Inflation." Journal of Political Economy 77, no. 5
(September/October): 721-54.
Mortensen, Dale T., and Christopher A. Pissarides. 1994. "Job
Creation and Job Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment." Review
of Economic Studies 61: 397-415.
Nash, John. 1953. "Two-Person Cooperative Games."
Econometrica 21: 128-40.
Pissarides, Christopher A. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory,
2nd ed. MIT Press.
Shimer, Robert. 2005. "The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium
Unemployment and Vacancies." American Economic Review 95, no. 1:
25-49.
--. 2007. "Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment."
Working Paper 13421. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research (September).
(1.) Abraham and Katz (1986).
(2.) Hall (2007).
(3.) Cochrane (1994).
(4.) Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005).
(5.) Mortensen and Pissarides (1994).
(6.) Pissarides (2000).
(7.) Lucas and Rapping (1969).
(8.) Shimer (2005).
(9.) Nash (1953).
(10.) Hagedorn and Manovskii (forthcoming).
(11.) Hall (2005).
(12.) Hall and Milgrom (forthcoming).
ROBERT E. HALL
Stanford University
Table 1. Employment Declines Associated
with Post-World War 11 Recessions *
Previous
peak in Trough in Decline in
detrended detrended employment
employment employment (percent)
1981:4 1983:1 5.74
1990:1# 1993:1# 5.04#
1973:11 1975:6 4.38
1960:6 1963:2 3.02
1969:8 1971:6 2.99
2001:1# 2003:9# 2.61#
1979:2 1980:8 2.58
1953:3 1954:7 2.21
1957:7 1958:7 2.15
1948:6 1949:10 2.13
Source: Author's calculations from data in figure I.
(a.) Recessions are those identified by the National
Bureau of Economic Research's Business Cycle Dating
Committee. Number following colon indicates month.
Shading indicates modern recessions. See figure I
for an explanation of the detrending method.
Note: Modern recessions is indicated with #.