In honor of William Brainard and George Perry.
Hall, Robert E.
THE BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECONOMIC ACTIVITY is a unique and amazing
institution, created by three visionaries, two of whom we thank and
appreciate in this volume, George Perry and William Brainard. We should
not, however, forget the founding contributions of Arthur Okun, who died
in 1980, even though many readers know them only from the classic
Brookings Papers of the 1970s, still full of wisdom.
The Brookings Papers was much more unique at its inception in 1970
than it is today, because it has inspired imitation and because Okun and
Perry were the first to understand the value of a field-oriented,
ongoing, academic conference series. In the 1960s there were no
conference series in economic specialties. One went to the annual
American Economic Association meetings and the Econometric Society meetings and to department seminars, but nothing else. How did we
survive? The fixtures of the macroeconomics conference circuit all
started later: the Carnegie-Rochester series in 1973; the National
Bureau of Economic Research's economic fluctuations program and its
International Seminar on Macroeconomics and Summer Institute in 1978;
the NBER Macroeconomics Annual in 1986 (a self-conscious copy of the
Brookings Papers, I can say from firsthand knowledge); and the Minnesota
Workshop in Macroeconomic Theory in 1990.
The world was different in 1970, when the Brookings Panel first
met. The Brookings special room rate at the Dupont Plaza for the first
meeting was $14 a night. Central cities, including the Dupont Circle area of Washington, seemed doomed. For the first decade of the
Panel's existence, we would not have dreamed of crossing the center
of the circle after 6 p.m., and we could have bought a spectacular house
in Kalorama for $25,000.
I think some people feel that the Brookings Papers missed something
in that two prominent developments in macroeconomics over the period of
its existence--the rational expectations revolution and the simple
general-equilibrium real business cycle model--did not figure
prominently in the Panel's discussions. Or, to be more candid, they
were more often criticized than advanced at the Panel. With respect to
rational expectations, the editors did try to bring it within the
Panel's ambit. Thomas Sargent, a leading proponent, was a member of
the Panel in 1973 and wrote a significant Brookings Paper, (1) and
Rudiger Dornbusch, who in 1976 became an instant star when he explained
that rational expectations resulted in the overshooting of exchange
rates, (2) was active here for many years. It did not take long for the
Panel to follow the macroeconomics profession in absorbing rational
expectations into its daily thinking.
The Brookings Papers' hostility to the real business cycle
model and its many progeny, the dynamic stochastic general-equilibrium
models, is easier to explain and reflects well on the editors. When the
panel was launched, big econometric models reigned over macroeconomics.
The Brookings Institution had lent its name to a huge effort to produce
one such model. But a strict founding principle of the Brookings Panel
was no big models, and it would be hard to exaggerate how important this
was for the intellectual contribution of the Brookings Papers. Big
models were a dead end. I do not personally think that the smaller
general-equilibrium models are a dead end, but it was an easy and
understandable transition from hostility to the big models to hostility
to the smaller ones when they sprang up from Minnesota. From the start
the Brookings Papers was about sectors, equations, and phenomena, and
not about general equilibrium. I think this was and is a great strength.
In preparing these remarks, I went through the tables of contents
of the Brookings Papers for its entire history--three issues a year in
the first few years and two issues a year ever since, not counting the
splinter publication, the Brookings Papers on Microeconomic Activity,
which ran from 1989 to 1998. The two main conclusions I reach from my
survey are the following: first, that the Brookings Papers has published
a considerable number of papers that changed the direction of thinking
in many different branches of macroeconomics; and second, that the
Brookings Papers remains unique in its ability to recruit top people in
the field to write original scholarly papers about current macroeconomic
events.
Let me take you on a quick tour of some of the Brookings
Papers' hits. This tour will not be very systematic and certainly
not fair. I made a list of the papers that I thought, using lots of
hindsight, had the greatest merit, and then I looked at the citation
counts for those papers in Google Scholar. I am not a great believer in
citation counts, but it seemed the best way to avoid further
contaminating the process with my own prejudices.
The process found twenty-nine papers with more than 200 cites each.
The two earliest included Lawrence Summers as either co-author or
author: the 1979 paper by Kim Clark and Summers on unemployment and the
1981 paper by Summers alone on the q theory of investment. (3) Both are
squarely in the Brookings Papers mode--one about a current phenomenon
and the other about an equation.
The first paper on my list to break 300 citations was the one by
Laurence Ball, Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer on new Keynesian
economics, in 1988. (4) That paper perhaps came dangerously close to a
general-equilibrium approach, but it was simple and informative.
The Brookings Papers' first megahit, and a foundational work
on the investment equation, was the paper by Steven Fazzari, Glenn
Hubbard, and Bruce Petersen, also in 1988, with 1,543 cites and still
counting. (5) The panel' s devotion to sectors and equations really
paid off here.
Olivier Blanchard and Peter Diamond scored well twice with key
papers on labor dynamics, once in 1989 and again in 1990. (6) Blanchard
teamed up with Lawrence Katz in 1992 to write a blockbuster on
adjustment across regional labor markets, (7) exposing some puzzles that
are still under active discussion.
Robert Barro--hardly the prototypical Brookings Papers
contributor--co-wrote a paper with Xavier Sala-i-Martin in 1991 on the
topic of growth convergence between developed and developing economies.
(8) This was a hot area in macroeconomics at that time.
The tradition of actually paying attention to current events had a
dramatic payoff for the Brookings Papers after the fall of the Soviet
Union. The most heavily cited paper on my list, by Jeffrey Sachs and
Andrew Warner on economic reform and integration, appeared in the
twenty-fifth anniversary volume in 1995, (9) following an influential
Brookings Paper by Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny
about privatization in Russia, published in 1993. (10) When attention
shifted to financial crises later in the 1990s, so did the Panel, with
heavily cited papers by Sachs, Aaron Tornell, and Andres Velasco and
later by Steven Radelet and Sachs. (11)
Inflation and productivity, two phenomena of constant and intense
interest to the panel, were the subject of papers too numerous to list.
Notwithstanding that the price level has risen by a factor of 5 since
the Panel's first meeting, by far the most frequently cited paper
on the subject was that by George Akerlof, William Dickens, and Perry on
the macroeconomics of low inflation. (12)
The editors of the Brookings Papers--Perry and Brainard since
1980--have an enormous amount to be proud of. They brought together a
diverse group of macroeconomists, got them to think about current events
when the existing payoffs to academics favored longer-run thinking, and
got them to focus on phenomena, puzzles, sectors, and equations rather
than dissipating their resources on general-equilibrium models, big or
little. The result was some of the most important and lasting papers in
macroeconomics and in international economics. Truly a job well done.
References
Akerlof, George A., William T. Dickens, and George L. Perry. 1996.
"The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation." BPEA, no. 1: 1-59.
Ball, Laurence, N. Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer. 1988. "The
New Keynesian Economics and the Output-Inflation Trade-off." BPEA,
no. 1: 1-65.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1991. "Convergence
across States and Regions." BPEA, no. 1: 107-58.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Peter Diamond. 1989. "The
Beveridge Curve." BPEA, no. 1: 1-60.
--. 1990. "The Cyclical Behavior of the Gross Flows of U.S.
Workers." BPEA, no. 2: 85-143.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Lawrence Katz. 1992. "Regional
Evolutions." BPEA, no. 1: 1-60.
Boycko, Maxim, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1993.
"Privatizing Russia." BPEA, no, 1: 139-92.
Clark, Kim B., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1979. "Labor Market Dynamics and Unemployment: A Reconsideration." BPEA, no. 1:13-60.
Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976. "Expectations and Exchange Rate
Dynamics." Journal of Political Economy 84, no. 6:1161-76.
Fazzari, Steven M., R. Glenn Hubbard, and Bruce C. Petersen. 1988.
"Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment." BPEA, no. 2:
141-95.
Radelet, Steven, and Jeffrey D. Sachs. 1998. "The East-Asian
Financial Crisis: Diagnosis, Remedies, Prospects." BPEA, no. 1:
1-90.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew Warner. 1995. "Economic Reform
and the Process of Global Integration." BPEA, no. 1: 1-95.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., Aaron Tornell, and Andres Velasco. 1996.
"Financial Crises in. Emerging Markets: The Lessons from
1995." BPEA, no. 1: 147-215.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1973. "Rational Expectations, the Real Rate
of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemployment." BPEA, no. 2:
429-72.
Summers, Lawrence H. 1981. "Taxation and Corporate Investment:
A q-Theory Approach." BPEA, no. 1: 67-127.
(1.) Sargent (1973).
(2.) Dornbusch (1976).
(3.) Clark and Summers (1979); Summers (1981).
(4.) Ball, Mankiw, and Romer (1988).
(5.) Fazzari, Hubbard, and Petersen (1988).
(6.) Blanchard and Diamond (1989, 1990).
(7.) Blanchard and Katz (1992).
(8.) Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991).
(9.) Sachs and Warner (1995).
(10.) Boycko, Shleifer, and Vishny (1993).
(11.) Sachs, Tornell, and Velasco (1996); Radelet and Sachs (1998).
(12.) Akerlof, Dickens, and Perry (1996).
ROBERT E. HALL
Stanford University