Living with global imbalances.
Cooper, Richard N.
OVER THE YEARS, the Brookings Panel has focused overwhelmingly on
the U.S. economy. That emphasis reflected the principal interests of its
founders, Arthur Okun and George Perry. The United States is by far the
largest economy in the world, accounting for a quarter to a third of
global output, so understanding the U.S. economy is important. And this
economy is rich in data. But that still leaves over two-thirds of the
world economy. The Brookings Papers has made excursions into this area
from time to time. At various points Europe, Japan, and most recently
China have been addressed. There was a flurry of interest in the
transition economies some years ago, in the international financial
crises of the mid- to late 1990s, and more rarely in developing
countries more broadly.
The U.S. economy and the economies of the rest of the world
intersect through international transactions. These have received more
attention in the Brookings Papers, although again largely with a U.S.
focus. I will address this intersection with respect to the large global
imbalances that exist today, although I will deviate from the usual
practice here by adopting a rest-of-the-world rather than a U.S.
perspective.
In this brief paper I want to cast doubt on two related
propositions that are widely accepted as truths: that Americans save too
little, and that the U.S. current account deficit is unsustainably
large, risking a disorderly adjustment that would be damaging to the
world economy in the relatively near (but usually unspecified) future.
These remarks should not be treated as new truths, but as plausible
alternative hypotheses about how the world works these days, how we
reached our current circumstances, and what the future may bring.
U.S. National Saving in Perspective
I begin with U.S. saving because I will say less about it. The
question of whether Americans save enough relates to the broader topic
of global imbalances through the national accounts identity linking the
current account deficit to the difference between domestic investment
and national saving. A current account deficit cannot be reduced without
reducing the excess of investment over saving. Few argue that the United
States should invest less (except perhaps in housing during the housing
boom, or in routers and fiberoptic cable in the technology boom), which
implies that if the U.S. current account deficit, around 6 percent of
GDP in recent years, is to be reduced, national saving--the sum of
private and public saving--must be increased. If, as some analysts
suggest, (1) the current account deficit should not exceed 3 percent of
GDP, and if investment is to be protected, then saving must increase by
3 percent of GDP, or from 13 percent of GDP to 16 percent in terms of
2006 shares. I will refer to gross saving and investment throughout, as
is appropriate in a world of rapid technological change.
"Replacement" investment is typically technologically superior
to its predecessor, and in any case a well-run firm will evaluate all
large investments afresh, moving depreciation allowances into new
activities if that is economically appropriate. Thus gross saving can be
considered as available for new allocation.
The U.S. current account deficit has grown over the last decade or
so, from 1.5 percent of GDP in 1995 to 6.1 percent in 2005 and 2006. (2)
Such growth implies a widening gap between saving and investment.
Investment rose in the late 1990s, as did government saving as the
federal budget moved into surplus; meanwhile private saving declined. In
the early 2000s investment declined, but public saving declined even
more, by an extraordinary 6 percent of GDP between 2000 and 2004, as a
result of recession, federal tax cuts in 2001 and 2003, and increased
expenditure for the military, for homeland security, and under other
headings. Private saving recovered somewhat with the growth in corporate
earnings from 2001 to 2005, despite a continued decline in recorded
household saving.
Ratios of U.S. saving and investment to GDP have been below those
in other rich countries and in some poor countries for many years. That
the U.S. economy continues to grow robustly is testimony to the relative
efficiency with which Americans use capital--or perhaps in part to the
inappropriate conventions economists use to measure investment and
saving.
Saving and investment in the national accounts, which were designed
over sixty years ago at the height of the industrial age, are defined
largely in terms of structures and equipment (although computer software
was recently added). This is hardly appropriate for a so-called
knowledge economy. Economists conceive of saving as consumption that is
deferred today for the sake of greater consumption at some time in the
future, perhaps by oneself, perhaps by future generations. On this
definition, several items should be added to "saving" as
currently recorded in the national accounts. Among the obvious ones are
educational expenditure, expenditure on research and development, and
purchases of consumer durables. Another item, not officially included in
GDP, is intangible investment by businesses in training and in company
and product branding. (3) Adding these items to saving and investment
for 2005 raises those quantities from 14 and 20 percent of GDP,
respectively, as defined in the national accounts, to 39 and 44 percent
(after also augmenting GDP by 15 percent to allow for the addition of
intangible investment). These figures do not suggest that Americans are
shorting the future, particularly when allowance is made lot the high
returns to education and to research and development. Recent poll
results notwithstanding, it is extremely improbable that future
Americans will be worse off than the current generation in material
terms. So far as I can tell, the pipeline of prospective innovations is
full; it would take a severe catastrophe for these, and the associated
investment, not to mature into higher income per capita, as they have
steadily done during the past half century. This generation's
biggest legacy to the next is a successful apparatus--both institutions
and incentives--for technical change and innovation.
From the perspective of the household, allowance should also be
made for capital gains on real and financial assets, which can
increasingly be mobilized for reinvestment thanks to innovations in
financial markets such as home equity loans and reverse mortgages, and
for expected legacies. Unlike new investment, these do not add to social
returns in the future (although some part of capital gains on equities
may reflect the intangible investments made by corporations), but they
legitimately count as "saving" from a household's
perspective. And they make a huge difference for total household wealth.
Household net worth rose by 6.5 percent a year over 1990-2005, and by 8
percent in 2005 alone--a year when negative personal rates of saving as
recorded in the national accounts grabbed the financial headlines. Of
course, these are aggregate figures; they do not address the
distribution of saving across households. Doubtless many families would
be well advised to save more in their own interest.
The revised calculations of saving and investment above do not
affect the discrepancy between the two, since saving and investment are
raised by the same amount. I draw attention to them to suggest, rather,
that it will be difficult if not impossible to raise U.S. national
saving further, except through the federal budget. Private saving may
rise of its own accord if house prices decline or stabilize for any
length of time; but households are not likely to be quick to acknowledge
the need to reduce their consumption.
What does all this mean for today's global imbalances? Can a
U.S. current account deficit in excess of $800 billion a year be
sustained? The answer from a technical economic point of view (as
distinguished from psychological or political perspectives, which I do
not address here) is an unambiguous yes. Some argue that the deficit is
large beyond all precedent in this country, veering into the
"danger range" at which some developing countries have run
into payments crises in the past. Some argue that the deficit cannot be
sustained because at some point foreigners will cease to be willing to
invest enough in the United States, or because the United States will
run out of assets attractive to foreigners, or both. Some concede that
the deficit might be sustainable at its current level, but maintain that
it is on a trend that cannot be sustained. Some judge the deficit to be
undesirable even if sustainable, not least on grounds that it permits
higher current consumption but bequeaths greater liabilities to future
generations. Whether it is desirable or not depends, of course, on the
feasible alternatives, not on abstract considerations.
I will try to address quantitatively two questions: whether foreign
saving will be adequate to finance a continuing or even a rising U.S.
current account deficit, and whether U.S. financial claims of adequate
quality will be sufficient to satisfy potential foreign demand for them.
I will also address foreigners' motivation to invest in the United
States.
The U.S. current account deficit (which by definition equals net
foreign investment in the United States, apart from measurement errors)
of $811 billion in 2006 was certainly unprecedentedly large. But in fact
it was smaller than the deficit that would have resulted if world
financial markets were fully globalized, if globalization is taken to
mean that savers around the world allocate their saving according to the
relative sizes of national economies, without any bias toward domestic
investments. Such a "gravity model" approach to world
financial flows, of course, involves a vast simplification, but it is an
informative starting point.
The results of such a calculation are shown in table 1. The U.S.
share of the world economy (at market exchange rates, the relevant
measure for this calculation) was 30 percent in 2000, rose slightly in
2001-02, and then declined to 27.5 percent in 2006. With no home bias,
the rest of the world would have invested these shares of its saving in
the United States. Americans, by the same token, in 2000 would have
invested 70 percent of their saving in the rest of the world, rising to
72.5 percent in 2006. Applying these percentages to actual saving (from
the International Monetary Fund' s World Economic Outlook) in the
rest of the world and the United States, respectively, would have
resulted in net foreign investment of $480 billion in the United States
in 2000, compared with an actual flow of $380 billion. Net foreign
investment in this simple model would have risen to $1.2 trillion in
2006, compared with actual investment of $811 billion. So foreign
investment in the United States can be expected to rise over time until
the slow decline in the U.S. share fully offsets the rise in foreign
saving, or until U.S. saving rises sufficiently sharply to overcome the
annual increases in foreign saving, or until foreign saving falls
sufficiently to close the gap.
This calculation takes gross saving as given, and it ignores the
impact that actual investment opportunities, through such
characteristics as their yield, risk, and liquidity, might have on
decisions about how to allocate saving. In this respect it is similar to
the gravity models of trade, which focus on economic size and distance
and ignore the structure of comparative costs, which are what give rise
to the incentives to trade. I now turn to incentives.
Demography and the Saving-Investment Balance
The net current account surplus of the rest of the world must by
definition equal the U.S. current account deficit, apart from
measurement errors. This surplus implies an excess in the rest of the
world of national saving over domestic investment. Why do such surpluses
occur, especially given that many countries run budget deficits, which
absorb much of the excess private saving? Part of the answer is that a
significant rise in oil prices since 2002 increased government revenue
in the oil-exporting countries in the first instance, producing budget
surpluses. Much of this saving will be transitory as this revenue enters
the domestic income stream, raising private incomes and import demand.
However, a number of oil-exporting countries have now emulated Kuwait
and Norway in setting aside a portion of their large oil earnings,
investing them abroad for the benefit of future generations. Thus
significant saving in these countries may endure for many years.
There are many other reasons for high saving, related, among other
things, to uncertainty and even insecurity about the future (partly due
to memories of past adversity), imperfect arrangements for consumer
credit for large purchases, corporate management incentives to retain
rather than distribute earnings, and so on. But one factor has received
too little attention, and indeed what little notice it has gotten has
been misleading. That is the dramatic demographic transformation that
many countries are going through. Much has been written about the aging
of societies, with appropriate focus on unfunded pension and medical
care commitments by governments. But aging is occurring for two quite
different and mostly unrelated reasons: increasing longevity and
declining natality.
Longevity in the United States rose by 8.2 years over the past half
century, and in Japan it rose by about twice that. When such increases
are not accompanied by a corresponding increase in the average
retirement age, one can expect to see households increase not only their
saving for retirement, but also their precautionary saving, since lives
are not only longer but also uncertain in their length. The standard
model of life-cycle saving behavior, in which dissaving occurs in
one's later years, typically assumes a known, or known expected,
time of death. In reality, there is much uncertainty and, thanks to
steadily advancing medical technology, perhaps even increasing
uncertainty about the time of death. All else equal, this should
increase saving, even into retirement, especially in a context of
growing uncertainty about the financial viability of many public pension
schemes. Americans have heard much about the future problems of their
social security system, but public pension schemes in many other
countries are in even worse shape.
These effects of increasing longevity are important, but the aging
of societies through reduced natality has perhaps an even greater
influence on national saving-investment balances, by reducing
investment. Low natality implies, over time, declining numbers of young
adults, hence fewer new households, hence lower demand for schools,
housing, and all the appurtenances associated with housing, such as
appliances and furniture. Reduced natality also means less new capital
will be required to equip new members of the labor force with the
average share of the productive capital stock. In addition, young adults
today are on average the most highly educated and most flexible members
of the labor force, geographically and occupationally. A decline in
their numbers will thus have a negative impact, ceteris paribus, on
productivity growth in an era of continuous advances in technology and
changes in the composition of demand. Of course, some capital deepening will occur, but that will drive down the domestic return to capital.
Saving rates have dropped in Japan, although less than life-cycle
devotees expected. But investment has dropped even more. Private saving
in Germany has risen, mostly absorbed by a 4-percentage-point increase
in the public deficit between 2000 and 2005, but investment has fallen
sharply. A roughly similar pattern has occurred in the newly rich Asian
economies. In contrast, investment rose in developing Asia, exceeding 40
percent of GDP in China by 2005; but saving rose even more in these
rapidly growing economies.
Population projections in these countries and others are striking.
Most rich countries, along with China, now have a net reproduction ratio
below unity; that is, populations are not reproducing themselves. The
average number of children per woman of childbearing age is around 1.4
in Germany and Japan, and 1.0 in Hong Kong and Singapore (2.1 children
per woman are required to sustain a population in the long run). The
populations of Germany and Japan have already peaked, despite increasing
longevity, and the number of young adults has been declining for some
time, and this will continue.
Among the rich countries, the United States stands out as a strong
exception: although birthrates have declined, they remain above 2 per
woman, and the U.S. population is being augmented by over a million
immigrants a year, who in general are young and over time become well
integrated into the U.S. labor force. Table 2 presents U.S. Census
Bureau projections of the number of young adults (ages 15-29) in each of
the world's largest economies plus four newly rich Asian economies,
whose current account surpluses together (when Germany is augmented by
its two close economic neighbors, the Netherlands and Switzerland) in
2006 equaled 90 percent of the U.S. deficit. (The surpluses of oil
exporters equaled an additional 46 percent of the U.S. deficit. The U.S.
deficit in turn equaled 70 percent of total world deficits.) The numbers
of young adults declined in absolute terms in China, Germany, Japan, and
the four newly rich economies, at a rate of roughly 1 percent a year.
The number of young adults in these countries also declined steeply as a
share of total population. In the United States, in contrast, the number
of young adults is expected to rise slowly over the next two decades,
and the actual increase will probably be even greater because of the
Census Bureau's conservative assumptions regarding immigration.
China, of course, is in different circumstances from Germany,
Japan, and other rich countries. Its rural population, despite having
fallen by 20 percentage points of total population over the past two
decades, remains large, and therefore much further rural-to-urban
migration can be expected. The rapid growth of the urban labor force can
be expected to continue, and with it demand for housing, schools, and
productive capital stock. Moreover, Chinese incomes have grown rapidly,
and this growth can be expected to continue and result in a housing
boom, as people not only change location but also upgrade the quantity
and quality of their living space. China's investment rates are
high. But with income per capita growing at over 7 percent a year, in
the presence of desires for lumpy expenditures and an underdeveloped capital market, Chinese saving rates have increased even as consumption
has grown rapidly. Moreover, many Chinese state-owned enterprises have
been modernized and downsized, improving their earnings, while others
enjoy quasi-monopoly profits. State enterprises in China do not have to
pay dividends to their government owners, and therefore as earnings have
increased, so have recorded corporate savings.
Why Invest in the United States?
Given that a number of the largest and richest countries, as well
as some poor countries such as China, have excess saving, why does so
much of that saving go to the United States rather than to other
countries? After all, under simple neoclassical assumptions, excess
national saving should flow to those regions of the world where the
return to capital is highest, which are assumed to be those where
capital is scarce relative to other factors of production, most notably
labor but including also arable land and specific natural resources.
Part of the answer is that this widely accepted proposition is a
vast generalization, and discerning investors do not invest on the basis
of such generalizations, even if economists are comfortable with or,
indeed, seem to prefer them. Details are all-important. Security of
investment is important, often trumping high yields for many investors,
especially those investing for retirement. Recent experience in
Argentina, Bolivia, Russia, and Venezuela has reminded everyone that
private investment, especially by foreigners, is not always secure.
Also, in the capital-poorest countries, yields are often low because of
strong complementarities between invested private capital and the
institutional setting, the latter interpreted broadly as including but
not limited to public infrastructure.
Despite these shortcomings, much private foreign capital has gone
into developing countries in recent years: over $500 billion (net) in
2005, mostly to East Asia and Central Europe, (4) But this compares with
over $1 trillion in foreign private funds invested in the United States
in 2005, and nearly $1.5 trillion in 2006.
There are several reasons why foreigners might prefer the already
capital-rich United States as a locus for investment. One is simply the
size of the economy, noted above. Another is that property rights are
secure in the United States, and dispute settlement is relatively speedy
and impartial. A third is that the United States continues to be a
dynamic economy, despite its wealth and maturity, partly because of the
demographic features noted above, but also because it is highly
innovative and relatively more flexible than other mature economies (and
even than many immature ones).
U.S. financial markets are even larger relative to the rest of the
world than is its GDP, accounting for over 40 percent of the
world's securities (stocks and bonds). In fact, the U.S. share of
the world's marketable securities is probably more than half if
allowance is made for the fact that many shares of companies in other
countries are unavailable for investment, often because they are in
government hands. Because of its size and institutional arrangements,
many marketable securities are much more liquid in the U.S. market than
is true in other financial markets, increasing their attractiveness to
passive investors. The U.S. market also offers a wide array of financial
assets of differing risk characteristics.
Finally, yields on U.S. debt instruments have recently been higher
than those on similar instruments in many other rich countries, notably
Japan and continental Europe. Yields have been still higher in Britain
and Australia, which share some of the other characteristics of the
United States. It is perhaps not a coincidence that net foreign
investment has also been high in those countries in recent years.
Foreign portfolio investment in the United States is overwhelmingly
denominated in U.S. dollars; indeed, it simply represents purchases of
U.S. domestic instruments by people or institutions who happen to reside
abroad. Most of these investors therefore bear exchange rate risk. Does
this risk not overwhelm the favorable yield differential? Apparently
not. One possible reason is that foreign investors are not conscious of
the exchange rate risk they are running. But this seems extremely
unlikely, given that most of the investors are sophisticated financial
institutions, and that economists have been unsparing in pointing out
the risks, which have thus had more than adequate publicity.
It must be that foreign investors find the characteristics of their
U.S. investments sufficiently attractive to overcome the exchange risks.
They may also discount the risk, perhaps because they see little reason
to expect movements in exchange rates large enough to negate the yield
differential. They may take this view either because they implicitly
accept the structural reasons developed above for believing the large
U.S. current account deficits to be sustainable, or for some other
reason. For example, they may believe that any large exchange rate
movement would be sufficiently damaging to elicit countervailing action
by the monetary authorities in the affected countries. Of course, after
the fact they may be shown to have been wrong in all of these
possibilities.
Much has been made of the fact that some of the financing of the
U.S. current account deficit has come from central bank purchases of
dollar-denominated assets. Is this evidence that something other than
the attractiveness of U.S. yields is driving these flows? Not
necessarily. Arguably, in some of these cases, central banks are simply
acting as financial intermediaries on behalf of their aging publics, who
either choose not to or are not permitted to invest directly abroad. In
any case the inflow of funds to the United States remains overwhelmingly
private in origin (if not always in beneficial ownership): private flows
were over three-fourths of the totals in 2005 and 2006.
How Long Can the United States Provide Assets for Purchase?
What about the outlook for investment opportunities in the United
States? Will foreigners soon acquire so many U.S. assets that their
availability will be exhausted? Not anytime soon. It is useful first to
examine some simple debt dynamics and then look at the relationship of
U.S. external indebtedness to the availability of U.S. assets.
The cumulation of current account deficits affects a country's
net international investment position (NIIP). Let D represent NIIP, Y
output (GDP), r the net return on D, and B the deficit in trade in goods
and services (excluding investment income) plus unilateral transfers.
Then dD = B + rD. Stabilizing D relative to GDP (D/Y) implies that dD/D
equals growth in nominal GDP. If growth in nominal U.S. GDP in the
coming years is assumed to be 5 percent, then a stable D/Y would require
that B/D + r = 0.05.
At the end of 2006, the NIIP of the United States was $2.2
trillion, or 16 percent of U.S. GDP. (5) The current account deficit, as
mentioned before, was around 6 percent. These numbers suggest little
prospect of stabilizing D/Y anytime soon, if ever, even if interest
payments to foreigners are low. It looks as though the U.S. deficit may
not be sustainable, or that it can be sustained only if r is negative.
In fact, to date r has been negative, since recorded earnings on
U.S. investments abroad have continued to exceed foreign earnings on
investments in the United States despite a negative NIIP since the late
1980s. Moreover, total returns on foreign investments substantially
exceed recorded earnings, and the gap favoring the United States has
been even larger, thanks mainly to increases in market values and, to a
much lesser extent, depreciation of the dollar. Thus, although the
cumulative U.S. current account deficit over 1990-2006 was $5.21
trillion, the increase in the net debtor position of the United States,
at $2 trillion, was less than half that. The average annual total return
on U.S. investments abroad since 1990 (including exchange rate effects,
discussed below) was 10.0 percent, compared with a total return of 6.2
percent on foreign investments in the United States. The main reason is
that equity investment, both direct investment and portfolio equity,
makes up a substantially larger share of U.S. claims on the rest of the
world (61 percent) than of foreign investments in the United States (35
percent). Americans act in effect as risk-taking intermediaries in the
world economy, selling fixed-interest claims and investing in equity;
they thus earn an equity premium in the world economy.
In addition, changes in exchange rates affect valuations when U.S.
claims on foreign assets are converted into dollars, in which the U.S.
NIIP is reckoned. Most U.S. assets abroad are denominated in other
currencies, whereas most foreign claims on the United States are
denominated in dollars. When the dollar depreciates against other
currencies, U.S. claims rise in value relative to foreign claims, and
vice versa when the dollar appreciates.
These combined valuation effects can be substantial. In 2005 the
U.S. current account deficit was $755 billion, but the NIIP actually
increased by $200 billion. (Reversals in sign also occurred in 1999 and
2003.) The deficit of $811 billion in 2006 produced no change in the
NIIP, on preliminary figures. Remarkably, the ratio of the NIIP to GDP
declined from over 23 percent in 2001 to less than 17 percent in 2006,
despite large and growing U.S. current account deficits during this
period. Indeed, D/Y was only 4 percentage points of GDP higher in 2006
than eight years earlier, despite a cumulative current account deficit
of 38 percentage points of GDP. The dollar depreciated on balance over
this period, and the NIIP would have equaled 19 percent of GDP at the
end of 2006, or 2.6 percentage points higher than it was, if the dollar
had not depreciated. Most of the valuation changes, in other words, were
not due to exchange rate changes.
The ratio of the U.S. NIIP to GDP is far below where it would be in
a world without home bias, as described above, where foreigners would
hold nearly 30 percent of their assets in the United States (over twice
the ratio they currently hold). On these grounds, then, the NIIP could
still rise significantly.
How much of the United States do foreigners own? Here it is
necessary to look at gross foreign investment in the United States,
before netting it against American investment abroad. Total foreign
claims on the United States at end-2005 were $11.1 trillion (including
only the net position of U.S. banks), equal to 89 percent of GDP during
that year and roughly the same percentage of the private nonresidential
fixed capital stock. Total foreign claims then grew to $13.6 trillion by
the end of 2006, much faster than GDP. The share of foreign ownership
has increased steadily for the past two decades. But foreigners do not
generally invest in the domestic capital stock, and their share of
ownership of U.S. assets is not rising nearly as rapidly as one might
suppose based on the dollar values alone. A remarkable feature of the
U.S. economy is that the total value of financial assets has risen
significantly more rapidly than the underlying economy. The Federal
Reserve estimates total financial assets in the U.S. economy at the end
of 2006 to have been $129 trillion (this figure is of course sensitive
to the system of classification used in the flow of funds accounts, and
does not include derivatives), or 9.7 times 2006 GDP. Forty years
earlier, in 1965, total financial assets were only 4.8 times GDP. Put
another way, while nominal GDP grew by 7.4 percent a year over
1965-2006, total financial assets grew by 9.2 percent a year.
This phenomenon reflects, among other things, innovation by the
financial sector, which has devised a host of new financial instruments
to appeal to a wider variety of circumstances and tastes. This
articulation of financial assets appeals to many foreigners as well as
to Americans, and foreigners invest in a wide array of these
instruments. So although the stock of gross foreign investment in the
United States exceeded GDP in magnitude in 2006, it amounted to only 12
percent of total financial assets in the United States. The share has
risen from 3 percent in the mid-1980s, but the rise has been slow.
Total financial assets include claims by one sector on another.
Ultimately, the U.S. economy is "owned" by households in the
United States, plus nonprofit organizations (churches, foundations,
universities, etc.), plus foreigners. The foreign share of financial
assets owned by these parties (after netting out intersectoral claims)
grew from 7 percent in 1980 to 14 percent in 2000 to 15 percent in 2006.
This ownership represents claims on future output of the U.S. economy.
It remains well below the level of foreign ownership that would obtain
in a "no home bias" world. It also remains below levels of
foreign ownership (relative to GDP) that have been reached in many other
countries, including Australia, Britain, France, Germany, Italy, and
Spain. So although the foreign-owned share of U.S. financial assets
cannot grow without limit, it can grow for many years before it begins
to strain the American capacity to provide financial assets.
Should We Worry about the U.S. Current Account Deficit?
Viewed in the context of globalization and demographic change in
other rich countries, the large U.S. current account deficit is both
comprehensible and welfare-enhancing from a global point of view,
reflecting intertemporal trade, so long as Americans invest the funds
productively. Prospective retirees around the world are making
investments in the United States that are profitable and secure. If this
is so, strong governmental efforts to reduce the current account deficit
might be deeply misguided at best, and run a serious risk of
precipitating the financial crisis or economic recession that proponents
of such action hope to forestall.
Not so long ago it was argued that, as a rich country, the United
States should be running a current account surplus, not a deficit. More
recently it has been suggested that, to achieve sustainability, the
deficit needs to be reduced to no more than around 3 percent of GDP from
the current 6 percent. Reduction of the deficit by 3 percent of GDP
would require that U.S. expenditure also drop, relative to output, by 3
percent of U.S. GDP, or roughly 1 percent of GDP in the rest of the
world. Foreign surpluses, taken together, would have to decline by 3
percent of U.S. GDP, implying a rise in demand relative to output by
that amount elsewhere in the world.
It is also usually said that, to bring about the required
substitutions in product demand, the dollar must depreciate, and
probably significantly--perhaps by 30 percent on a trade-weighted basis.
So the additional demand in the rest of the world must be domestic
demand. For export-oriented economies such as Japan, Germany, and China,
currency appreciation is likely to discourage, not encourage, productive
investment. So the additional demand must come from domestic consumers
or governments. But many governments have been concerned about excessive
budget deficits in recent years and are engaged in fiscal consolidation.
This is especially true for Japan and Germany, two countries with large
current account surpluses. That leaves consumers. What will induce aging
consumers outside the United States to spend more? Easier monetary
policy, which in Euroland is outside the control of national
governments, would in a world of high capital mobility tend to weaken
currencies, not strengthen them. The prescription must therefore combine
stimulative fiscal policy with tighter monetary policy and currency
appreciation. Yet Europe's mid-term policy focus, reflected in the
Lisbon agenda of 2000, has on the contrary been on fiscal consolidation
plus measures to improve productivity and output, resulting (as
explicitly desired) in greater international competitiveness, not
greater domestic demand.
China, which controls its exchange rate, could decide to revalue
substantially, as many have urged. But even if China were to eliminate
its current account surplus entirely, only a fraction of the resulting
reduction in global imbalances would accrue to the United States, as
U.S. imports from China would largely switch to other low-income
countries. That would still leave a U.S. current account deficit in
excess of the targeted level. Moreover, what would an appreciation large
enough to eliminate China's surplus do to China's economy,
where exports of manufactures containing mostly imported inputs have led
growth? True, exports have not been China's only source of growth
in demand. Public and private construction has boomed, and Chinese
consumption grew in excess of 8 percent a year during 1989-2005, faster
than anywhere else in the world. But exports have been the driving
sector.
The argument developed here suggests that the U.S. current account
deficit can continue for some years and even widen. Of course, a
significant depreciation of the dollar might nevertheless occur.
Financial markets are driven by psychological as well as by economic
factors. If enough people decide to sell dollars, the dollar will
depreciate. Or if foreigners collectively decide to invest less in the
United States than the current account deficit (plus American capital
outflow), the dollar will depreciate.
A large drop in the dollar would have grave economic consequences,
reducing exports and depressing investment in other rich countries. For
this reason, their monetary authorities are likely at some point to
intervene in foreign exchange markets to limit the resulting downturn,
in effect substituting official for private capital investment in the
United States and thereby putting effective limits to any depreciation
of the dollar.
But, of course, the current account deficit cannot rise
indefinitely relative to GDP, nor can foreign-owned assets rise
indefinitely as a share of total U.S. assets. Sooner or later the
process of financial globalization will slow and eventually stop,
probably well before the hypothetical state of "no home bias"
is reached. Moreover, aging societies will eventually reach the point at
which they cease acquiring new foreign assets and begin to liquidate
their outstanding claims. Then the U.S. deficit must decline, perhaps
significantly. The trade deficit will need to decline even earlier, as
foreigners begin to consume the earnings on their U.S. investments. But
that point may not be reached for a decade or longer, especially if
people work longer and continue to save past the conventional retirement
age, as many do.
As Asians and Europeans begin to consume their overseas earnings
and the underlying assets, total expenditure in their countries will
rise relative to output, and their current account surpluses will
decline and eventually disappear. This process alone will help reduce
the U.S. deficit, without any depreciation of the dollar against their
currencies. To what extent the dollar needs to depreciate will depend on
the emerging consumption patterns in the aging societies, and in
particular on the mix between tradable and nontradable goods and
services, keeping in mind that these categories are themselves
constantly changing, as increased possibilities for offshoring push more
nontradables into the tradables category. Even nontradables can enter
the international accounts insofar as they are provided by temporary
migrant workers who remit earnings to their home countries. Elder care
is likely to involve both processes, with diagnoses performed in remote
locations and treatment provided by migrant workers in situ, as the
children and grandchildren and great-grandchildren of the aged choose to
stay in the labor force.
Another possibility involves Asians and Europeans retiring in the
United States, just as some Canadians do now. Their assets would then
cease to be foreign claims on the United States.
The adjustment process involves the classic transfer problem in a
more complex setting. How much, if at all, the dollar needs eventually
to depreciate will depend on all of these factors, and certainly cannot
be foretold years in advance of the required adjustment.
The United States has a vibrant, innovative economy. Its
demographics differ markedly from those of other rich countries, in that
birthrates have not fallen nearly so far and immigration, concentrated
among young adults, can be expected to continue on a significant scale.
In these respects the United States, although rich and politically
mature, can be said to be a young and even a developing country. It has
an especially innovative financial sector, which continually introduces
new products to cater to diverse portfolio tastes. The United States has
a comparative advantage, in a globalized market, in producing marketable
securities and in exchanging low-risk debt for higher risk equity. It is
not surprising that savers around the world want to put a growing
portion of their savings into the U.S. economy. The U.S. current account
deficit and the corresponding surpluses elsewhere, although
conventionally described as imbalances, do not necessarily signal
economic disequilibria in a globalized world economy, and they may well
remain large for years to come.
General Discussion
William Nordhaus agreed with Richard Cooper that saving is
understated in the national accounts, but he noted some improvements in
this area, such as the addition of software spending to investment and
output in the core accounts, the creation of a satellite account for
research and development, and ongoing work to create a satellite account
for education. Nordhaus wondered why Cooper used gross rather than net
saving and investment. For most countries net investment is much smaller
than gross, and the current account is a net saving concept. Cooper
replied that gross saving and investment are the relevant concepts
because firms do not distinguish between depreciation allowances and
other sources of internal funding, but instead treat all investments in
the same manner based on an assessment of their profitability.
Charles Schultze suggested that the magnitude of Cooper's
adjustments to saving and investment was overstated. For example,
including advertising makes some sense because it provides information
to consumers, but it also creates negative externalities for other
firms, as one firm's gain is another firm's loss. Similarly,
recent large increases in aggregate public spending for elementary and
secondary education have not had a large payoff. From 1974 to 2004, real
per pupil spending for public K-12 education doubled, but the
performance of seventeen-year-olds on national assessment tests in math
and reading was more or less flat. Competition regulates rates of return
on private investment, but the same is not true for public education.
Schultze added that the same problems apply to many other government
investments, such as highways and flood control infrastructure. Because
no method exists for properly determining the scale and allocation of
these investments, the relationship between the money spent and the
return is complicated.
William Gale added that including additional forms of saving raises
the estimated level of saving but does not reverse its decline over
time. Gale also wondered how much the analysis of the U.S. current
account deficit changes if Americans' foreign borrowing is mostly
done for consumption rather than for investment. Similarly, he wondered
how the analysis changes if investment from abroad is composed more of
foreign central banks buying Treasury bonds than of foreign private
investors buying real assets. Cooper replied that inflows to the United
States are overwhelmingly private. In fact, he noted, even official
flows are often mediated private flows: In Japan, for example, where
large quantities of domestic savings are conservatively held in domestic
banks, the central bank invests some of these assets in foreign markets
in order to meet the country's retirement needs.
Olivier Blanchard suggested that uncertainties about the factors
supporting the current capital inflow to the United States tilt heavily
toward a reduction in that inflow in the future: foreign official
purchases seem more likely to decline than to increase, the
institutional setting for investments in other countries is likely to
improve, recent declines in the value of the dollar are likely to
heighten perceptions of exchange rate risk, and America's role as a
risk-taking financial intermediary in the world economy may backfire.
Martin Feldstein pointed out that the real foreign exchange value
of the dollar has dropped about 15 to 20 percent over the last five
years, depending on the measure used. Therefore the current account
deficit should decline further, and he wondered about the implications
for Europe and other countries. To avoid recession in their countries,
he suggested, foreigners will have to increase their consumption by 2 or
3 percent of their GDP, which may be possible given their current high
saving rates.
Robert Gordon emphasized that differences in asset returns and
changes in the value of the dollar have prevented an explosion of U.S.
net international indebtedness so far: U.S. net debt to foreigners was
the same fraction of GDP in 2006 as it had been in 2001 (19 percent),
despite a cumulative current account deficit of 30 percentage points of
GDP over this period. Robert Lawrence pointed out that receipts on U.S.
assets abroad exceed payments on foreign assets in the United States by
about 1/4 percent of GDP, the same as twenty years ago. Given that the
burden has not increased--partly because of the different mix of
investments here than abroad--it is difficult to argue that the current
position is unsustainable. Lawrence added that the demographic factors
described in the paper were interesting, but the same factors are more
pronounced in Europe, yet Europe's capital account is basically
balanced, so there must be more to the story.
Cooper emphasized that he did not consider the current imbalance a
"steady state," nor did he expect it to last forever. Still,
he did expect imbalances to persist for a decade or more. Eventually,
retirement in Japan and Germany will exhaust savings in these countries,
and current account positions will change.
References
Cline, William R. 2005. The United States as a Debtor Nation.
Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Corrado, Carol A., Charles R. Hulten, and Daniel E. Sichel. 2006.
"Intangible Capital and Economic Growth." Working Paper 11948.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (January).
RICHARD N. COOPER
Harvard University
(1.) See, for example, Cline (2005).
(2.) U.S. current account and international investment position
data are from the Bureau of Economic Analysis international accounts.
(3.) Following Corrado, Hulten, and Sichel (2006).
(4.) World Bank, Global Development Finance 2007.
(5.) The NIIP here and below values inward and outward direct
investment at market values as estimated by the Bureau of Economic
Analysis rather than at historic or current cost. Financial derivatives
are excluded.
Table 1. Hypothetical Investment Flows in a Fully
Globalized World Trillions of dollars
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
Actual world saving
(exc. United States) 5.02 5.23 6.21 7.44 8.27 9.16
Foreign investment in
United States (a) 1.61 1.67 1.84 2.10 2.31 2.52
U.S. investment
abroad (b) 1.13 1.01 1.02 1.11 1.16 1.32
Net inward
foreign investment 0.48 0.66 0.82 0.99 1.15 1.20
Source: Author's calculations based on IMF, World Economic
Outlook (April 2007), tables 1 and 43, and World Bank, World
Economic Indicators.
(a.) Assumes that the share of non-U.S. saving invested in
the United States would equal the share of the United States
in world GDP.
(b.) Assumes that the share of U.S. saving invested abroad
would equal the share of the rest of the world in world GDP.
Table 2. Population Aged Fifteen to Twenty-Nine in
Selected Economies, 2005 and 2025
Millions Change,
2005-25
Country or group 2005 2025 (percent)
China 321 259 -19
Japan 22.6 17.8 -21
Germany 14.2 11.9 -16
Newly rich Asian economies (a) 18.6 14.2 -24
United States 61.9 66.0 7
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.
(a.) Hong Kong. Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan.