Are successive generations getting wealthier, and if so, why? Evidence from the 1990s.
Gale, William G. ; Pence, Karen M.
THE 1990S WERE a remarkable decade for saving and wealth
accumulation. After averaging 3.4 times GDP between 1950 and 1990,
aggregate net worth rose from 3.5 times GDP in 1990 to 4.2 times GDP in
2000, its highest *level since at least 1950. In nominal dollar terms,
net worth rose from $20 trillion in 1990 to $42 trillion in 2000. Much
of the increase in wealth was fueled by skyrocketing capital gains in
the stock market, which helped boost the aggregate market value of
equities from $3 trillion in 1990 to $15 trillion in 2000. The decade
also saw widespread diffusion of stock ownership (directly and
indirectly through mutual funds) and substantial increases in
participation in and contributions to defined-contribution pension
plans, typically 401(k)s. At the same time, however, the measured saving
rate, excluding capital gains, fell over the decade, continuing a
longer-term pattern. (1)
These patterns created a rich environment in which to examine
household saving and wealth accumulation. Previous researchers have
followed particular birth cohorts through the 1990s, separating the
wealth changes that each cohort experienced into a component due to
capital gains and a component due to active saving. These studies aimed
to develop estimates of the age-wealth and age-saving profile, and to
determine among which birth cohorts and among which types of assets
wealth rose and active saving fell during the 1990s. Other studies have
examined the extent to which households chose to use their accumulated capital gains in the 1990s to finance increased consumption expenditure
or early retirement. (2)
This paper also focuses on the 1990s but addresses a different set
of questions and thus takes a different approach to the data. Unlike
previous studies, ours does not focus on tracking particular birth
cohorts through time. Instead we examine the relative wealth status of
different birth cohorts as they reach similar stages of the life cycle.
Thus, for example, we compare (using data from the 1989-2001 Surveys of
Consumer Finances) the 2001 wealth of households where the head was
between the ages of 65 and 74 in 2001 with the 1989 wealth of households
where the head was between 65 and 74 in 1989. The idea behind this type
of comparison is to exploit the fact that households of a given age in
1989 had not experienced the 1990s, whereas households of the same age,
observed in 2001, had. Thus, by controlling for other factors that may
vary across generations-such as educational attainment, marital status,
health status, and differing work norms for women--we can measure the
effects of exposure to the 1990s on saving and wealth.
Our approach can provide insights regarding three questions: To
what extent are successive generations of American households wealthier
than their predecessors? What are the principal determinants of the
trends in wealth across successive generations? And what are the
implications? The answers to the first two questions turn out to be
surprising and simple. The answer to the third is more complex.
We find that the rise in aggregate net worth over the 1990s (that
is, the rise in net worth in 2001 relative to 1989) accrued almost
entirely to older age groups. Older households (those with heads aged
55-64, 65-74, or 75-84 years) in 2001 had significantly more wealth than
did similarly aged households in 1989. For example, real median wealth
among 65- to 74-year-olds in 2001 was about $100,000 (60 percent)
greater than among 65- to 74-year-olds in 1989. For these older
households, economically and statistically significant increases in
wealth occurred at almost all points in the wealth distribution and
across all major wealth categories: retirement accounts, other financial
assets, housing equity, and other real assets. In contrast, the typical
younger household (aged 25-34, 35-44, or 45-54) in 2001 did not have
more wealth than a typical younger household in 1989.
We also show that, despite the large capital gains, the rapid
diffusion of stock ownership, and the significant increase in 401(k)
participation and contributions in the 1990s, the principal factor
determining changes in wealth across successive generations appears to
be changes in household-level demographic characteristics, and not
changes in the relationship between these characteristics and wealth.
Informally, certain key demographic characteristics that affect wealth
accumulation shifted substantially across age groups in a manner
consistent with the differing trends in wealth. For example, compared
with similarly aged households in 1989, older households in 2001 were
more likely to be married, more likely to report their health as
"excellent" or "good," and more likely to contain
men who had completed postsecondary education. In contrast, for younger
households in 2001, each of these trends was reversed relative to
similarly aged households in 1989. Formal regression and decomposition analysis shows even more strongly that changes in demographic
characteristics are closely tied to changes in median wealth, mean
wealth, and the distribution of wealth between 1989 and 2001 for older
generations. Indeed, information on households' 2001 demographic
characteristics and the relationship between those characteristics and
wealth that held in the 1989 sample predicts extremely accurately the
distribution of wealth in 2001, without any reference to changes in
capital gains, stock ownership, or participation in defined-contribution
plans.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. We begin by
describing the data set. We then present trends across successive
cohorts in wealth holdings and demographic characteristics. Next we
describe the various tests and the econometric specifications we use to
compare the wealth of successive cohorts. We then present our main
empirical findings. Next we provide information on the role of capital
gains, diffusion of stock ownership, and pension coverage across
successive cohorts. We conclude by discussing alternative
interpretations and implications of the results.
Data
The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) is designed specifically to
measure household wealth (net worth) and its components. (3) To capture
how assets and debt are held broadly in the population, about two-thirds
of the unweighted sample are drawn from a stratified, nationally
representative random sample. To capture the concentration of assets and
debt among high-wealth households, the remaining third are randomly
selected from statistical records derived from tax returns, using a
stratification technique that oversamples households likely to have
substantial wealth. This sample design allows for more efficient and
less biased estimates of wealth than are generally feasible through
simpler designs.
Although the SCF has been conducted every three years since 1983,
we focus on the data from 1989 to 2001, a period during which the survey
has employed a consistent methodology. This period, of course, also
brackets the sharp increase in the ratio of aggregate net worth to GDP
described earlier. A key advantage of the SCF is that it covers all age
groups and almost all household assets and liabilities, financial and
real, including defined-benefit pension wealth. The only important
exception is that households wealthy enough to be in the Forbes 400 are
excluded. The main drawback of the SCF is its relatively small sample
size of approximately 4,000 households in each survey year.
Our measures of net worth and its components follow the SCF
definitions except for the treatment of pension wealth. Because the SCF
defines net worth as resources that a household may access and control
immediately, the survey's definition of wealth excludes
defined-benefit pensions (which cannot be accessed until retirement) and
includes only liquid defined-contribution plans: 401(k)s, thrift plans,
defined-contribution plans from past jobs, and other plans that can be
borrowed against or withdrawn from. These definitions understate pension
wealth at any point in time and likely lead to systematic overstatements
of the growth in pension benefits over time. Over the past twenty years,
the employer pension system has moved dramatically toward
defined-contribution plans and away from defined-benefit plans.
Furthermore, among defined-contribution plans, firms have shifted from
illiquid to liquid plans (as defined by the SCF). To address these
issues, we include all defined-contribution balances, as well as
estimates of defined-benefit wealth, in the wealth definition. (4)
Our definition of net worth, like the measure in the SCF, does not
include expected future Social Security or Medicare benefits or taxes.
Although Social Security benefits are a significant part of wealth for
many lower- and middle-income households, their inclusion would not
alter the results. There were no new legislated changes in Social
Security over the sample period, although the retirement age did rise
slightly as legislated by the 1983 Social Security reform. If anything,
Social Security benefits increased over this time period for elderly
households, accentuating rather than offsetting the trends in private
wealth. Data from the Current Population Survey, for example, indicate
that the median annual household Social Security benefit received by a
household aged 65-74 was $9,935 in 1989 (expressed in 2001 dollars) and
$11,330 in 2001. This increase likely reflects higher lifetime real
wages and increased female labor force participation among the cohort
aged 65-74 in 2001 compared with the cohort aged 65-74 in 1989 (as
described below). Although legislated changes to Medicare over this
period affected health care providers, it is not clear what net effect,
if any, these changes had on household wealth. (5)
The SCF also includes information on household demographic
characteristics, income, and current and past jobs held by the household
head and spouse. We use these data to construct a series of variables
described below.
Trends in Wealth and Demographics
In this section we explore the differences in total wealth between
the 1989 and 2001 samples for each of the different age groups, on
average, at the median and other selected points in the wealth
distribution, and for the entire distribution for two of the age groups.
We also look at differences across the same period for the different age
groups with respect to each of several main categories of wealth. Among
demographic variables, we examine trends in marital status, longevity,
health, education, and labor force participation.
Wealth
Although the growth in equity markets and aggregate net worth over
the 1990s is well documented, the distribution of these gains across age
groups is not, and the differences in trends across age groups are
striking. Older households, defined as those headed by a person aged 55
or older, had significantly more wealth in 2001 than did households in
the same age range in 1989, whereas younger households in 2001 generally
had the same amount of wealth as similarly aged households in 1989. (6)
The top panel of figure 1 shows that real median wealth for
households with a head between the ages of 65 and 74 rose by almost 60
percent, from $169,000 in 1989 to $264,000 in 2001.7 The other two older
age groups--those aged 55-64 and 75-84--also enjoyed substantial
absolute and relative increases in wealth. In contrast, the median net
worth of households with a head between the ages of 35 and 44 actually
fell from $108,000 in 1989 to $99,000 in 2001. The other two younger age
groups--those aged 25-34 and 45-54--fared similarly. The bottom panel of
figure 1 shows similar trends for mean net worth. Mean wealth for each
of the older three cohorts was roughly 50 percent higher in 2001 than
for households of a similar age in 1989. For the three younger age
groups, mean wealth grew by only about 10 to 20 percent.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 2 shows similar trends for the 10th, 25th, 75th, and 90th
percentiles of the wealth distribution for each age group. At each
percentile the older cohorts in 2001 had substantially more wealth than
did their counterparts in 1989. The younger cohorts in 2001 had about
the same wealth as did their counterparts in 1989.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The top panel of figure 3 shows the entire distribution of net
worth in 1989 and 2001 for households with heads aged 65-74 in those
years--the "middle" older cohort. For this group the
cumulative distribution function (CDF) of net worth in 2001 lies to the
right of the corresponding CDF in 1989, indicating that the 2001 sample
was richer all across the distribution. The differences are
statistically significant at a 95 percent confidence level at each
decile break from the 30th to the 80th percentile. (8) The bottom panel
of figure 3 shows the analogous results for households aged 35 to 44 in
1989 and 2001--the "middle" younger cohort. For these groups
the distribution of wealth in 1989 approximately coincides with the
distribution of wealth in 2001. No statistically significant differences
occur at any decile of these distributions. (9)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Data for average holdings of particular components of
wealth--retirement assets, other financial wealth, home equity, and
other real assets--show patterns that are similar to those in the
aggregate data but, not surprisingly, somewhat noisier, given that not
all households hold all types of assets: some own their home but hold no
financial wealth, for example, whereas others have pension wealth but do
not own a home, and so on. In general, however, for each component of
wealth, average holdings were higher in 2001 than in 1989 for older
cohorts but not necessarily for younger cohorts.
The first panel of figure 4, for example, shows that average
retirement wealth was $79,000 higher in 2001 for the 55-64 group,
$37,000 higher for the 65-74 group, and $63,000 higher for the 75-84
group. Among the younger groups, the 45-54 group had a mean increase of
$27,000, but the increases for the other two groups were $4,000 or less.
Likewise, the average home equity of households in the 65-74 group rose
from $95,000 in 1989 to $133,000 in 2001 (second panel of figure 4). In
contrast, households in the 45-54 group had about the same average home
equity ($104,000) as the 65-74 group in 1989, but by 2001 the home
equity of households in this age group had not advanced beyond its 1989
level. (10) Mean financial assets rose for all age groups (third panel
of figure 4). Although the absolute difference was larger for the older
groups, the proportional increases were quite large for all groups.
Other real assets, which include equity in vehicles, investment real
estate, closely held businesses, and other miscellaneous assets, rose
for the 55-64 and 65-74 groups and were roughly flat for the younger
groups and the 75-84 group (last panel of figure 4).
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Several aspects of the wealth trends noted above are significant.
First, given the well-known trend toward greater income inequality over
the sample period, (11) it is worth noting that the data do not simply
show that wealthy age groups became wealthier. Median wealth for 45- to
54-year-olds in 1989 was $193,000, for example, substantially larger
than that for households aged 65-74 ($169,000) or 75-84 ($131,000). Yet
by 2001 median wealth for households aged 45-54 was virtually the same
as in 1989 ($191,000), whereas median wealth had risen by about $100,000
for cohorts aged 65-74 and 75-84 relative to similarly aged counterparts
in 1989 (figure 1).
Second, the results do not show that, within each age group, the
rich got richer. The differences at the 75th and the 90th percentile
occur only in the older groups, not in the younger groups (figure 3).
Moreover, in the distribution of net worth for 65- to 74-year-olds,
significant differences exist between the 1989 and 2001 distributions
for the 30th to the 80th percentiles but not for the 90th percentile.
These results are consistent with the finding by Arthur Kennickell that
although the share of wealth held by households in the top 1 percent of
the wealth distribution appears to have increased from 1989 to 2001, the
change is not statistically significant. (12)
Third, the results are not consistent with the view that younger
households (as defined here) simply do not save very much, so that they
benefited little from the capital gains of the 1990s. In fact, median
wealth for 45- to 54-year-olds in 1989 was the second highest of all
groups (figure 1).
Fourth, the results show increases in all forms of wealth and
increases in overall wealth across the entire wealth distribution for
older households. This suggests that the determinants might be more than
just capital gains or the spread of 401(k) plans, because both of these
are distributed quite unequally across the wealth distribution.
Finally, it is worth noting that the facts documented here do
indeed look like trends that have occurred over time, rather than simply
two isolated sets of data points. Figure 5 shows median and mean wealth
for successive cohorts for each SCF year in the sample period: 1989,
1992, 1995, 1998, and 2001. Because of the relatively small sample size
within each age-year cell, and because economic conditions and asset
returns naturally vary over time, the year-by-year data in these figures
are necessarily noisier than the snapshots of the 1989 and the 2001
data.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Nonetheless, the figure shows that although macroeconomic conditions clearly affected all households, older households fared
better than younger households regardless of the state of the economy.
The median net worth of older households stayed level during the
early-1990s recession and then skyrocketed in the booming second half of
the decade (first panel of figure 5). In contrast, the median net worth
of households aged 35-44 and 45-54 fell in the recession years and only
came close to regaining its 1989 level in 2001 (second panel of figure
5). Likewise, older and younger households experienced comparable drops
in average wealth between 1989 and 1992, but older households
subsequently experienced much larger wealth gains (last two panels of
figure 5). By focusing on 1989 and 2001--two years that were both
preceded by several strong years in the stock and housing markets--we
are able to abstract from some of this year-to-year macroeconomic
variability.
Demographics
There is a long tradition in economics, dating at least as far back
as Franco Modigliani's work in the 1950s, relating household
demographic characteristics to wealth accumulation. Even after
controlling for age, demographic factors such as marital status, health,
education, and labor force participation can have significant effects on
wealth and saving. Married households benefit from the economies of
scale and household production associated with marriage and thus may
save a larger fraction of their income than unmarried households. (13)
Widowed households, in contrast, often face a negative income shock from
decreased pension and Social Security benefits after a spouse's
death, as well as a wealth shock from large out-of-pocket medical
expenses incurred in the last year of the deceased spouse's life.
(14) Advances in health affect wealth indirectly by reducing the number
of widowed households. In addition, workers with better health may spend
more years in the labor force and face lower out-of-pocket medical
expenses. (15) Better-educated workers generally have higher lifetime
earnings and are more likely to be invested in the stock market. (16)
Education also appears to promote better health outcomes, even after
controlling for income and wealth. (17) Finally, workers who spend more
years in the labor force will have higher lifetime earnings, all else
equal.
Notably, the trends in these key demographic characteristics across
cohorts in the 1990s generally mirror the patterns shown in the wealth
accumulation data. Specifically, demographic characteristics
"improved" in a number of ways for older households in 2001
relative to those in 1989, and they either did not improve or actually
deteriorated for younger households in 2001 relative to their 1989
counterparts. (18) For example, the share of married household heads
rose among older households and decreased among younger households. In
2001, 58 percent of household heads between the ages of 65 and 74 were
married, compared with 50 percent in 1989. In contrast, among 35- to
44-year-olds, the share fell from 64 percent to 58 percent (table 1).
Data from the CPS (not shown) display a similar but more muted pattern,
with the share of married households increasing from 53 percent to 55
percent for the 65-74 age group and decreasing from 65 percent to 61
percent for the 35-44 age group. (19)
The increase in the share of older married households may stem from
increases in male longevity. Since 1975, male longevity at older ages
has increased relative to female longevity, because smoking-related
deaths have increased relatively more for women and because men have
benefited disproportionately from decreases in cardiovascular disease.
(20) Over the 1989-2001 period, for example, male life expectancy at age
65 increased by 12 months, whereas female life expectancy increased by
only 2 months. (21) Perhaps reflecting these trends, the share of SCF
households headed by a widow in the 65-74 age group fell from 31 percent
in 1989 to 17 percent in 2001.
Among younger households, the decline in the married share appears
to stem from delays in the age of first marriage. From 1989 to 2001 the
share of households aged 35-44 with a never-married head (some of whom
are living with a partner) increased from 16 percent to 22 percent.
Although the share of married 35- to 44-year-olds fell, the share living
with a partner or married held constant at 67 percent in both years.
Consistent with the increases in longevity noted above, the share
of older households who reported their health as "excellent"
or "good" increased over the 1989-2001 period (table 1). Among
households in the 65-74 age group, that share rose from 57 percent in
1989 to 61 percent in 2001. Similarly, the share of CPS respondents aged
65-74 who described their health as "excellent," "very
good," or "good" increased from 67 percent in 1995 to 70
percent in 2001 (not shown). (22) These self-reported health
improvements are consistent with documented declines in chronic
disabilities among older households. (23) The self-reported health of
younger households, however, deteriorated: the share of households in
the 35-44 age group who rated their health as "good" or
"excellent" fell from 87 percent in 1989 to 83 percent in
2001. Although sampling fluctuations may account for this drop, there is
some evidence that increased rates of asthma and diabetes have eroded the health of younger households. (24)
Educational attainment rose substantially for women in all age
groups between 1989 and 2001 but rose more for successive older male
cohorts than for younger male cohorts. The share of men in the 65-74 age
group with postsecondary education increased from 31 percent in 1989 to
49 percent in 2001, whereas the share fell from 60 percent to 56 percent
for men in the 35-44 age group (the other two younger age groups saw
moderate increases in the share of men with postsecondary education;
table 1). For women the corresponding increases were from 27 percent to
40 percent for the 65-74 group and from 49 percent to 59 percent for the
35-44 group. CPS data show similar trends. (25) These increases are
consistent with the surge in college matriculation rates after World War
II. Although college enrollment increased strongly throughout the
twentieth century, the rise was especially pronounced after World War
II, when the share of 18- to 24-year-olds enrolled in college rose from
10 percent in 1945 to nearly 30 percent in 1965. (26) The GI Bills for
World War II and Korean War veterans, the democratization of the college
application process, the rise in community colleges, and the advent of
birth control account for some of this and later increases. (27)
Lifetime labor force participation increased for women in all age
groups over this period but stayed constant for men. For example, on
average, women in the 65-74 group had nineteen years of full-time work
experience in 1989 and twenty-two years of experience in 2001 (table 1).
Men in this age group had forty-two years of experience in both years.
The forces underlying the increase in women's labor force
participation include laborsaving devices that made housework less
burdensome, the rise of the clerical sector, the growth of formal
education, and decreased sex discrimination, as well as increased access
to birth control. (28)
Modeling the Effects of Demographic Changes on Wealth
We use four different methods to provide perspectives on how
changes in demographic characteristics affect the wealth accumulation of
successive cohorts. The methods focus on differences in the median,
mean, and distribution of wealth.
Median
We run least absolute deviation (LAD) regressions on the pooled
1989 and 2001 data. Initially, we specify wealth for household i as a
function of just a constant and an indicator variable for being an
observation in the 2001 sample:
(1) [w.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] [(year =
2001).sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.1i].
In this specification the coefficient [[beta].sub.1] captures the
change in median wealth between the 1989 and 2001 groups and is equal to
the change in medians shown in figure 1.
In the second LAD specification, we incorporate demographic
variables, denoted by X:
(2) [w.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.2] + [[beta].sub.2] [(year =
2001).sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.2][X.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.2i].
If demographic changes explain most of the change in wealth between
1989 and 2001, [[beta].sub.2] should be close to zero, and the
demographic variables should enter as economically and statistically
significant. (29) This method assumes that the relationship between
wealth and demographic characteristics is the same in both years (other
than a shift in the intercept).
Mean
We use the familiar Blinder-Oaxaca decomposition to examine how
much of the change in mean wealth for each age group comes from changes
in the demographic characteristics over time and how much comes from all
other factors, that is, from changes in the relationship between wealth
and demographic characteristics over time. (30) Whereas the median
regression imposes the same coefficients on the 1989 and 2001 data, this
decomposition technique allows the relationship between demographics and
wealth to differ in the two years.
Suppose that wealth w in a given year (say, 2001) is estimated as a
linear combination of demographic characteristics X: [w.sub.01]=
[X.sub.01] [[beta].sub.01] + [[epsilon].sub.01]. By the assumptions of
ordinary least squares, E([w.sub.01]) = E([X.sub.01][[beta].sub.01]) =
E([X.sub.01]) [[beta].sub.01]. We estimate E([X.sub.01]) with its sample
analog [[bar.X].sub.01] and thus can express the difference between mean
wealth in 2001 and mean wealth in 1989 as
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In equation 3 the term in which X is constant shows the change in
wealth attributable to changes in [beta], whereas the term in which
[beta] is constant shows the change in wealth attributable to the change
in X. The term in which [beta] is constant will be large if changes in
demographic factors explain a substantial share of the change in wealth.
Dividing each term in this equation by the change in expected wealth,
E([w.sub.01]) - E([w.sub.89]), yields the share of the change in wealth
due to demographic characteristics versus the share due to other
factors.
Distribution
To examine the effects of demographic changes on the distribution
of wealth, we ask the following counterfactual question: what would the
distribution of wealth in 2001 look like if we took the distribution of
demographic characteristics from 2001 but applied the relationship
between demographics and wealth from 1989? Note that the latter
relationship (loosely, [[beta].sub.89]) excludes all effects of the
1990s. Thus the counterfactual question allows us to calculate the share
of the actual difference in wealth that can be explained by differences
in demographic variables alone. If the relationship between demographics
and wealth was approximately the same in 1989 and 2001, this
counterfactual distribution should look quite similar to the actual 2001
distribution. If instead the demographics-wealth relationship was quite
different in the two years, the counterfactual and the actual 2001
distributions should diverge.
We generate the counterfactual distribution in two ways. The first
is a reweighting technique based on a paper by John DiNardo, Nicole
Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux. (31) The idea is to reweight the households
in the 1989 SCF so that they reflect the distribution of demographic
characteristics in the 2001 SCF. The resulting distribution of household
wealth thus reflects the 2001 demographic characteristics (due to the
reweighting) and the 1989 relationship between demographics and wealth
(since it still uses 1989 data). The second approach is a resampling
technique based on a paper by Jose Machado and Jose Mata. (32) Here we
create a predicted wealth value for 2001 by pairing the demographic
characteristics from a randomly chosen household in the 2001 SCF with
the coefficients from a quantile regression (using a randomly chosen
quantile) of wealth on demographic characteristics from the 1989 SCF.
Repeating this procedure over and over generates a counterfactual
distribution.
More formally, we want to simulate the distribution of net worth as
a function of demographic characteristics from 2001 and of the
relationship between wealth and demographics from 1989. Borrowing
notation and exposition from DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux, we write the
density of wealth at a point in time, f(w), as the integral of the
density of wealth conditional on a set of demographic characteristics X
and on a date [t.sub.w], f(w|X, [t.sub.w]), over the distribution of
individual attributes F(X|[t.sub.x]) at a date [t.sub.x]:
(4) f(w;[t.sub.w] = 1989, [t.sub.x] = 2001) = [integra]f(w|X,
[t.sub.w] = 1989)dF(X|[t.sub.x] = 2001).
DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux note that equation 4 can be rewritten
as
f (w;[t.sub.w] = 1989, [t.sub.x] = 2001) = [integral] f (w|X,
[t.sub.w] = 1989)[[psi].sub.x]dF(X|[t.subx] = 1989),
where the weight [[psi].sub.x] = dF(X|[t.sub.x] =
2001)/dF(X|[t.sub.x] = 1989). (33) This term reweights the households in
the 1989 SCF so that their distribution of demographic characteristics
matches the distribution from the 2001 survey.
To estimate [[psi].sub.x], note that by Bayes' law,
dF(X|[t.sub.x] = 2001)/dF(X|[t.sub.x] = 1989 =
prob(year=2001|X)prob(year=1989)/ prob(year=1989|X)prob(year=2001).
The first term on the right-hand side can be obtained by estimating
a logit model on the pooled 1989 and 2001 SCF data in which the
dependent variable is a dummy variable for "year = 2001" and
the independent variables are demographic characteristics. (We use the
sample weights in estimating this logit.) Exponentiating the predicted
value for each observation gives the odds prob(year = 2001|X)/prob(year
= 1989|X). We can ignore the second term because it is constant for all
observations. We generate this weight for each household in the 1989
SCF, multiply it by the existing sample weight for the household, and
then use standard methods to estimate the weighted quantiles of the
distribution.
Whereas the DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux technique uses the actual
relationship in the 1989 data to characterize the relationship between
demographics and wealth, the Machado and Mata technique specifies this
relationship parametrically. Machado and Mata note that the conditional
distribution of wealth given demographics can be approximated at each
quantile [theta] in [0,1] by quantile regressions of the form w =
X[[beta].sub.[theta]] + [epsilon]. This specification imposes a linear
relationship between wealth and demographic characteristics at each
quantile. We estimate this specification at each percentile from the 1st
to the 99th.
To obtain the distribution of wealth that would occur with the 2001
distribution of demographic characteristics and the 1989 relationship
between wealth and demographics using the Machado and Mata technique, we
employ the following procedure: In step 1 we randomly draw a quantile
[theta] from a uniform [0,1] distribution and obtain the corresponding
quantile regression coefficients [[beta].sub.[theta]] from the 1989 SCF.
(We use the 1989 sampling weights when estimating these regressions.) In
step 2 we randomly draw an observation from the 2001 SCF and obtain its
set of demographic characteristics X. (34) Then we combine the
coefficients [[beta].sub.[theta]] from step 1 and the characteristics X
from step 2 to obtain an observation from the counterfactual wealth
distribution. We repeat this procedure until a sample of the desired
size is obtained, and we estimate weighted quantiles from this sample
using the 2001 SCF sample weights. (35) In both decompositions, if
changes in demographic characteristics explain much of the changes in
the distribution in wealth, the counterfactual density based on 2001
demographic characteristics and the 1989 relationship between wealth and
demographics should lie near the actual 2001 wealth distribution.
Specification of Demographic Characteristics
Each of the tests above requires the specification of demographic
characteristics and wealth. Our specification of demographic variables
balances three factors. First, we allow demographic trends to affect men
and women differently. Second, our unit of observation is a household,
not an individual. Third, our sample size is relatively small (about 500
households per age group per year), which places increased importance on
having a relatively parsimonious specification.
To characterize marital status, we define indicator variables for
"married couple or unmarried partners" (where the partners can
be either of different sexes or of the same sex), for "second or
subsequent marriage," and for "divorced or separated."
(36) Single or widowed households are the omitted category. Since a
divorce or death of a spouse can affect men and women differently, we
include an indicator for female-headed households (which can include
same-sex households). We also add variables for the number of years a
married household has been married and the number of years an individual
has been widowed or divorced.
We define variables for postsecondary education, years in the
full-time workforce, and fair or poor health separately for men and
women. (37) For a married couple the "male" variables
correspond to the characteristics of the husband, and the
"female" variables to those of the wife. For a household with
only one head, the "male" or "female" variables are
used and the others are set to zero. For a same-sex couple, the
characteristics of the partner designated as the "head" are
used, and the demographic characteristics of the other partner are
ignored.
Under this specification, the effect of a marriage on wealth
accumulation is not simply measured by the coefficient
[[beta].sub.marriage], but also varies with the characteristics of the
spouses. For example, the expected wealth of a married couple in which
both spouses have postsecondary (post-HS) education is predicted by
summing the coefficients [[beta].sub.marriage],
[[beta].sub.male-post-HS], and [[beta].sub.female-post-HS], along with
the appropriate male and female labor force and health coefficients,
whereas the expected wealth of an otherwise observationally identical
married couple without postsecondary education would differ by
[[beta].sub.male-post-HS] + [[beta].sub.female-post-HS].
Wealth Transformations
To establish the robustness of our results, we use the above four
techniques to analyze changes in both the level and the inverse hyperbolic sine of wealth. The level-of-wealth results explore the
absolute changes in wealth over time, whereas the inverse hyperbolic
sine results explore the proportionate changes in wealth over time. We
use this transformation, rather than the traditional logarithmic transformation, because it approximates the logarithm but is defined for
the zero and negative values that are common in wealth data.
More formally, if [theta] is a scaling parameter and w is a measure
of wealth, the inverse hyperbolic sine of wealth can be written as
[[theta].sup.-1][sinh.sup.-1]([theta]w) = [[theta].sup-1]ln[[theta]w +
[([[theta].sup.2][w.sup.2] + 1).sup.1/2]]. This symmetric function is
linear around the origin but approximates the logarithm for larger
values of wealth. To see this, note that if w is large, ln[[theta]w +
[([[theta].sup.2][w.sup.2] + 1).sup.1/2]] [approximately equal to] ln20
+ lnw, which is simply a vertical displacement of the logarithm.
Following previous research, we set [[theta] = 0.0001. (38) When
multiplied by this scaling parameter, coefficients from an inverse
hyperbolic sine specification, like coefficients from a logarithmic
specification, can be interpreted as the effect of a change in a given
demographic variable on the percentage change in wealth, for wealth
values that are sufficiently large. (39)
Results
We report results for median regressions, Blinder-Oaxaca
decompositions, and decompositions of the entire net worth distribution.
Median Regressions
Table 2 reports the results of the median regressions. The first
column shows the coefficient [[beta].sub.1] from equation 1, that is,
the effect of the 2001 indicator before adding demographic
characteristics to the equation. The values are small and imprecisely estimated for the three younger age groups, indicating no economically
or statistically significant differences in wealth over the course of
the 1990s. In contrast, the estimated coefficients are large and
significant for the three older age groups. These results, of course,
mirror the results in figure 1.
The last column of table 2 shows the coefficient [[beta].sub.2] in
equation 2, that is, the effect of the 2001 indicator after adding all
of the demographic characteristics described above. The addition of
demographic variables removes almost all of the 1989-2001 increase in
wealth for the older cohorts. The difference in median wealth falls from
$66,308 to $12,674 for the 55-64 group, from $94,996 to -$12,919 for the
65-74 group, and from $95,435 to $18,940 for the 75-84 group and is now
statistically insignificant in all three groups. Controlling for
demographic characteristics also changes the difference in median wealth
for the younger households, but not in a systematic or statistically
significant manner. Thus the [[beta].sub.2] coefficient in equation 2
indicates that once one controls for demographic characteristics, the
increase in wealth observed in older cohorts disappears.
The middle four columns in table 2 show the effects of adding some
but not all of the demographic variables to the right-hand side. These
specifications are consistent with the demographic changes documented in
table 1: when a demographic characteristic is added to the
specification, the coefficient [[beta].sub.2] changes the most for those
age groups in which that characteristic changed significantly from 1989
to 2001. The marital status variables, for example, have the largest
effects on the two age groups--65-74 and 75-84--that saw large increases
in the share of married households. The labor force variables affect
only the 55-64 group, the group that saw the largest increase in female
labor force participation. The health and education variables, which
changed for all three older age groups, likewise contribute to a
decrease in the [[beta].sub.2] coefficient across all three groups.
The pattern of coefficients from the inverse hyperbolic sine
specification, shown in table 3, is similar. The first column shows
that, when expressed in proportionate terms, the net worth of younger
households was approximately the same in both 1989 and 2001. (40)
Households in the 35-44 group, for example, had 8 percent less wealth in
2001 than 1989, whereas households in the 45-54 group had 1 percent less
wealth. Older households, however, experienced substantial and
statistically significant wealth gains: the 65-74 group had 56 percent
more wealth in 2001 than in 1989, and the 75-84 group had 73 percent
more wealth. These results follow the figure 1 numbers when expressed in
percentage terms.
As with the levels specification, older households had about the
same amount of wealth in 1989 as in 2001 once demographic variables are
included. As shown in the final column of table 3, in the full
specification, households in the 65-74 group had 4 percent less wealth
in 2001 than in 1989; households in the 75-84 group had 12 percent more.
These changes are not statistically different from zero. As before,
adding the marital variables has a meaningful effect only on the 65-74
and 75-84 groups, whereas the education variables affect all three older
age groups. The younger households have a near-zero change in wealth in
almost all specifications, regardless of the control variables.
The coefficients on the demographic variables follow expected
patterns across the various specifications (table 4). Wealth increases
with educational attainment for both men and women; these coefficients
are large and statistically significant at the 1 percent level.
Households in which either men or women describe their health as
"fair" or "poor" have lower wealth. Wealth increases
with male labor force participation but not female labor force
participation. Female labor force participation may have little effect
on wealth accumulation because, historically, lower-income women have
been more likely to work outside the home. Over the twentieth century
this pattern changed somewhat, as the stigma attached to working outside
the home decreased and the returns from market work for most women
exceeded the returns from home production. Consistent with this pattern,
our regressions indicate that female labor force participation is
positively associated with wealth accumulation for the younger groups
and negatively associated with it for the older age groups, although
neither relationship is statistically significant. (41)
Married couples have more wealth than widowed or single households;
divorced and separated households have about the same wealth as widowed
or single households. Wealth increases with years of marriage for the
35-44 age group, but not the 65-74 age group. Since the coefficients are
conditional on age group, the results suggest that the marginal returns
to an extra year of marriage are high for younger households but not for
older households, who may have been married for many years. The number
of years since becoming widowed or divorced is associated with wealth
decreases for the older group but not for the younger group.
Blinder-Oaxaca Decompositions
Turning next to average net worth, we focus on the Blinder-Oaxaca
decompositions for age groups that had statistically and economically
significant increases in mean wealth. This includes the three cohorts
aged 55-64, 65-74, and 75-84. The bottom three rows of each panel in
table 5 show that by far the greater part of the change in the average
wealth of older households stems from demographic changes. In the
levels-of-wealth decompositions, about half of the increase in net worth
for the group aged 55-64 and almost all of the increase for the groups
aged 65-74 and 75-84 can be attributed to changes in demographic
variables. In the inverse hyperbolic sine decompositions, nearly all of
the net worth increase in all three age groups can be attributed to
changes in demographic variables. (42) Notably, these results are robust
to whether the decomposition holds 2001 characteristics and 1989 [beta]s
constant, or holds 1989 characteristics and 2001 [beta]s constant. In
addition, at traditional significance levels, we can reject the
hypothesis that the change stemming from changes in demographic
variables is zero.
Consistent with our finding that changes in demographic variables
explain most of the change in average wealth for these age groups,
almost none of the 1989 [beta]s are statistically significantly
different from the 2001 [beta]s (not shown). Only two coefficients
change in a consistent and statistically significant manner across
specifications and age groups: One is the "female, postsecondary
education" coefficient, which is larger in 2001 than in 1989 for
the 45-54 group in both specifications, and smaller in 2001 than in 1989
for the 75-84 group in the levels specification and for the 65-74 and
75-84 groups in the inverse hyperbolic sine specification; the other is
the "years since divorce or death of spouse" coefficient,
which is smaller in 2001 than in 1989 in the levels specification for
all three younger age groups and in the inverse hyperbolic sine
specification for the 25-34 group.
For purposes of completeness, table 5 also reports Blinder-Oaxaca
decompositions for groups that did not have statistically significant
changes in wealth. In principle, these regressions are more difficult to
interpret, because there is no statistically significant change in
wealth to explain in the first place and because many of the changes in
means are small in economic terms as well. In practice, the results of
the decomposition are significantly less stable for the younger groups
than for the older groups. Although some of these decompositions
indicate that demographic characteristics explain part of the change in
average wealth, our main finding for these groups is that the results
are not consistent across X and [beta] combinations or across the levels
and inverse hyperbolic sine specifications. Some of the results are also
not statistically significant. The jumbled and inconsistent pattern of
results that emerges for the younger groups (where there were no
significant changes in wealth) is, at the very least, quite different
from the very clear and dominant role for demographic factors that
emerges for the older groups (where the changes in wealth are large in
economic terms and precisely estimated).
Distribution of Net Worth
The decompositions of the entire net worth distribution provide
perhaps the most powerful evidence that demographic characteristics are
a significant determinant of the greater wealth of older households in
2001. Figure 6 shows the 1989 and 2001 distributions of net worth and a
counterfactual distribution of net worth based on the 2001
characteristics and the 1989 coefficients (that is, the 1989
relationship between demographics and wealth) for the three older age
groups and for both the DiNardo-Fortin-Lemieux decomposition and the
Machado-Mata decomposition. For expositional ease, net worth is shown on
a logarithmic scale on the vertical axis; these decompositions are
estimated only for the inverse hyperbolic sine specification. If the
change in demographic variables explains the change in wealth, the
counterfactual and the actual 2001 distributions should largely
coincide. If instead other factors (such as historically unique capital
gains) explain the changes in wealth, the counterfactual and the actual
2001 distributions should diverge.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The figure presents the striking result that the counterfactual
distributions of net worth (as defined above) nearly exactly coincide
with the actual distribution of net worth in 2001 for the 55-64 and
65-74 age groups. This implies that almost all of the change in wealth
for those successive cohorts can be explained by changes in demographic
status, without appealing at all to any special factors in the 1990s;
those special factors would show up as changes in the relationship
between demographic characteristics and wealth. Likewise, changes in
demographic characteristics can explain about half of the wealth
increase for the 75-84 group. The deciles of the counterfactual
distribution are statistically significantly different from the deciles
of the actual 1989 distribution except at the tails. (43) This result is
robust to the choice of decomposition technique, although the
Machado-Mata technique appears to behave erratically in the tails of the
distribution.
For the younger age groups (figure 7), the 2001 distribution of net
worth is almost the same as the 1989 distribution. Thus the
decomposition has very little difference in wealth to explain, and the
counterfactual distribution lies close to the actual distribution. The
deciles of the counterfactual distributions are not statistically
significantly different from the 1989 distribution for any of the
younger age groups.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
To explore the robustness of our results for the older age groups,
we repeat the exercise but attempt to backcast 1989 wealth based on 1989
demographic characteristics and the 2001 relationship between
demographics and wealth. Note that the latter relationship includes any
impact of the 1990s. If the change in demographic characteristics is a
major factor in the change in wealth, and if the relationship between
demographics and wealth was the same in 1989 and in 2001, we should find
that this counterfactual 1989 distribution is similar to the actual 1989
distribution. Indeed, as shown in figure 8, for the three older age
groups this counterfactual distribution lies almost on top of the actual
1989 distribution.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
The fact that the results from both these decompositions and the
earlier Blinder-Oaxaca decompositions are robust to which year is used
for the distribution of demographic characteristics, and to which year
is used for the relationship between demographics and wealth, is notable
evidence of a robust relationship. In some empirical literatures the
results are sensitive to this choice. Barsky and his coauthors, for
example, note that the role that the black-white earnings gap plays in
explaining the black-white wealth gap appears to depend on whether the
decomposition is based on the black or the white earnings distribution.
(44)