Are empowerment and education enough? Underdiversification in 401(k) plans.
Choi, James J. ; Laibson, David ; Madrian, Brigitte C. 等
AT THE END of 2000, current and former employees of the energy
trading company Enron Corporation held $2.1 billion in the firm's
401(k) retirement savings plan. Sixty-two percent of that money was
invested in Enron stock, then trading at $83 a share. In October 2001
Enron's finances began to unravel as its accounting improprieties
came to light. Enron stock plummeted over the next several weeks, and on
December 2, 2001, the company declared bankruptcy, rendering its shares
worthless. Thousands of Enron employees lost their jobs and a large
fraction of their retirement wealth simultaneously.
We thank Hewitt Associates for their help in providing the data. We
are particularly grateful to Lori Lucas and Yah Xu, two of our many
contacts at Hewitt, for their help with the data and their useful
feedback on this project. We appreciate the research assistance of
Ananya Chakravarti, Keith Ericson, Jean Lee, Hongyi Li, Shih En Lu, Dina
Mishra, and Chris Nosko. We are also grateful for comments from
Christopher Carroll, William Gale, Nellie Liang, and other participants
on the Brookings Panel as well as at seminars at the American Economics
Association, the National Bureau of Economic Research, the University of
Chicago, the University of Michigan, and Harvard University. James Choi
acknowledges financial support from the Mustard Seed Foundation. All
three authors acknowledge individual and collective financial support
from the National Institute on Aging (grants R01-AG-021650,
P30-AG012810, and T32-AG00186). David Laibson also acknowledges
financial support from the Sloan Foundation. The opinions and
conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors and do not
necessarily represent the opinions or policy of the National Institute
on Aging, any other agency of the federal government, Hewitt Associates,
or the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Although the Enron 401(k) debacle was highly publicized, Enron was
neither the first nor the last company whose collapse decimated its
workers' 401(k) accounts. Over the past few years a similar fate
has befallen employees of WorldCom, Global Crossing, Polaroid, Kmart,
Lucent, and Providian, among others. In response, many bills have been
proposed in Congress that would regulate employer stock holdings within
401(k) plans. Compared with existing law on defined-benefit pension
plans, which strictly prohibits plans from holding more than 10 percent
of their assets in employer securities, most of the bills proposed for
regulating defined-contribution plans appear mild. Common themes in
these proposals are empowerment and education rather than prohibition:
give employees the right to sell the employer stock in their 401(k), and
inform them about the risks of not doing so.
For example, one of only two bills that have so far come up for a
vote in either house of Congress, the Pension Security Act (see table
A-1 in the appendix), has two key provisions relating to employer stock.
First, it would prohibit employers from requiring employees to invest
their own 401(k) contributions in employer stock. Second, it would
require that employers allow plan participants to diversify any matching
funds contributed by the employer three years after receiving that
match. Other proposed legislation would require that plan participants
be notified if the fraction of their assets invested in employer stock
exceeds a certain threshold (such as 20 percent), that companies offer a
certain number of alternatives to employer stock if it is made an
investment option, or that companies educate plan participants about the
risks of not diversifying their assets.
This paper assesses how effective the "empower and
educate" regulatory approach might be at reducing 401(k) employer
stock holdings. We begin by studying five natural experiments in which
employees experienced a discrete change in the restrictions on employer
stock holdings. In these examples the restrictions changed for one of
two reasons: either employees crossed an age or tenure threshold above
which they were allowed to diversify their holdings, or the company
changed its rules to enable all employees to diversify their
investments. We find only a modest employee response to either type of
change. Merely allowing diversification does not cause it to happen.
We then consider whether educational efforts might motivate
employees to diversify out of employer stock. Although many studies have
concluded that financial education does affect employees' choices,
the subset of studies that randomly assign education and measure
subsequent actions have found small effects. (1) These studies still
leave open the possibility that other kinds of education might yield
larger behavioral changes.
Here we evaluate a different form of education: witnessing the
real-life experience of others. Economists since Armen Alchian in the
1950s have argued that the imitation of successful strategies (and,
conversely, the avoidance of unsuccessful strategies) is an important
force pushing economic actors toward optimal behavior. (2) We test this
hypothesis in the context of the media coverage surrounding the Enron,
WorldCom, and Global Crossing bankruptcies. Specifically, we investigate
how much workers at other companies reduced their employer stock
holdings in response to the blizzard of media stories early in this
decade illustrating the dangers of putting all of one' s retirement
savings in employer stock.
We chose Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing because a large
percentage of their employees' 401(k) assets was held in employer
stock, and because their bankruptcies, the associated accounting
scandals, and their decimated 401(k) plans received so much attention
from so many media outlets. For example, the New York Times ran 1,364
stories mentioning Enron during the last quarter of 2001 and the first
quarter of 2002, of which 112 ran on the front page.
We find that this media barrage had a surprisingly modest impact on
employer stock holdings in other 401(k) plans, reducing the fraction of
assets held in employer stock by no more than 2 percentage points from
an initial 36 percent of balances. We present evidence that this small
reaction is not due to restrictions on diversification. In addition, we
show that workers in Texas, who were likely to have been
disproportionately exposed to Enron-related news, did not reduce their
investment in employer stock any more than did workers outside of Texas.
Even in Houston--Enron's headquarters--where the Houston Chronicle ran 1,122 stories mentioning Enron in the six months surrounding the
firm's collapse, employees did not show evidence of learning the
lesson of Enron.
This paper raises broader questions about retirement savings
policy. It adds to the convergent body of evidence that many employees
do not make optimal financial decisions. Households typically behave
passively, following the path of least resistance. Such inertia often
translates into household acceptance of the investment choices made
automatically by their company on their behalf, even when those default
choices are suboptimal for them. (3) For example, many firms
automatically allocate 401(k) matching funds to employer stock, where
the money typically stays even if employees are permitted to
subsequently rebalance their portfolio.
Two policy solutions present themselves. First, society could give
firms incentives to adopt socially optimal default choices. (4) However,
it is not always obvious what such optimal defaults would be. Moreover,
one default is rarely right for every employee, since employees face
different economic circumstances. Alternatively, society could adopt
default-free systems, which do not confer an advantage on one choice
over another, by forcing employees to explicitly state their preference.
(5) However, default-free systems will work only if employees are likely
to make good decisions when forced to do so.
We begin with a brief summary of the current regulation of employer
stock in 401(k) plans. We then summarize previous research on employer
stockholding in 401(k) plans and how 401(k) outcomes are affected by
plan features. Next we describe the employee-level 401(k) data we have
for the seven companies examined in our analysis. Our empirical analysis
begins with the results from five natural experiments on relaxing
diversification restrictions. We then turn to examining the impact of
the Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing crises on employer stock
holdings for a large sample of employees at other firms. We conclude by
discussing alternative legislative approaches that are likely to
decrease employer stock holdings substantially, and implications for
savings policies more generally.
Regulation of Employer Stockholding in 401(k) Plans
Like defined-benefit pension plans, 401(k) plans are primarily
regulated under the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974
(ERISA). (6)
Under ERISA, plan fiduciaries have four responsibilities: to act
for the exclusive benefit of plan participants and their beneficiaries
(the "exclusive purpose rule"); to act with the care, skill,
prudence, and diligence that a prudent person acting in a similar
capacity would use (the "prudent man rule"); to diversify plan
assets across different types of investments, geographic areas,
industrial sectors, and dates of maturity so as to reduce the chance of
large losses (the "diversification rule"); and to act in
accordance with plan documents.
At the time ERISA was passed, defined-benefit pension plans were
the primary employer-sponsored mechanism for providing income to persons
in retirement. To help safeguard the assets of these plans, ERISA
explicitly caps the holdings of employer stock at 10 percent of total
assets. Defined-contribution plans, however, face no such limit. The
most common type of defined-contribution plan today, the 401(k) plan,
did not exist when ERISA was enacted. Those defined-contribution plans
that did exist consisted mainly of profit-sharing plans, to which
employers made variable contributions based on company earnings, and
employee stock ownership plans (ESOPs), which were explicitly designed
to encourage ownership of employer stock. ERISA exempts these plans from
the diversification requirements for employer securities.
When 401(k) plans were first authorized, in 1978, it was not
anticipated that they would supplant defined-benefit pension plans as
the primary source of employee retirement income. Hence Congress did not
extend the 10 percent limit on employer stock holdings to 401(k) plans.
Employers thus have much latitude in determining how much employer stock
employees may hold in their 401(k).
A common way of holding employer stock in a 401(k) is through an
ESOP. This combination of a 401(k) and an ESOP is sometimes referred to
as a KSOP. Many companies, however, offer employer stock in their 401(k)
plan without an ESOP, and many companies also operate an ESOP that is
separate from the 401(k) plan. A KSOP is a savings plan intended to
benefit employees, but it is also a corporate finance mechanism that
encourages employee ownership. The KSOP's dual purposes can create
a conflict of interest between plan beneficiaries and the employer. As a
result, employer stock regulations for 401(k) plans with an ESOP differ
from those for plans without one.
A 401(k) plan without an ESOP may not require that more than 10
percent of the employee's own contributions be held in employer
stock. This requirement does not hold for a KSOP. Neither plan, with or
without an ESOP, is limited in the amount of matching contributions by
the employer that may be directed into employer stock. All assets within
an ESOP, however, are subject to a set of explicit diversification
requirements. Employees with ten years of tenure must be allowed to
diversify 25 percent of their employer stock holdings once they reach
age fifty-five, and 50 percent once they reach age sixty. (These
diversification requirements do not apply to employer stock holdings
outside of an ESOP.) Companies can and do, however, adopt
diversification policies that are more generous than those mandated by
ERISA. Finally, should a lawsuit arise, the fiduciary standards of
prudence and exclusive purpose against which the company's behavior
is judged are lower for a KSOP than for a 401(k) plan without an ESOP,
because of the dual purposes of the former. (7)
Previous Research on Employer Stock in 401(k) Plans
Olivia Mitchell and Stephen Utkus report that, averaging across all
401(k) plans--including those without employer stock as an investment
option--19 percent of plan assets are held in employer stock. (8) This
statistic understates the diversification problem, since most
participants do not have employer stock as an investment option--their
employers do not offer it or are not publicly held firms. Only about 10
percent of companies offer employer stock in their 401(k) investment
menu. Because these companies tend to be larger firms, 35 percent of all
401(k) participants are in plans that do include employer stock as an
option. (9) These employees often have 401(k) portfolios that are
heavily concentrated in employer stock. William Even and David
Macpherson calculate that 50 percent of assets in plans offering
employer stock were held in employer stock in 1998. (10) Plans offering
employer stock can be further divided into those in which the employee
must choose an investment allocation for the employer match and those in
which the employer match is directed into employer stock by default. In
2001 two-thirds of those plans directing the match into employer stock
allowed participants to immediately trade out of employer stock, whereas
the rest imposed a holding requirement. (11) Sarah Holden and Jack
VanDerhei report that, in plans that offer employer stock as an
investment option but do not direct the match into employer stock, 22
percent of assets are held in employer stock; in plans in which the
employer match is directed into employer stock, a much larger fraction
of assets, 53 percent, is held in employer stock. (12)
The Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing bankruptcies highlighted
two major risks associated with concentrated investments in employer
stock. First, investing in any single security is riskier than investing
in a diversified portfolio such as a mutual fund. Several studies have
estimated that, on a risk-adjusted basis, a single-stock portfolio is
worth less than half the equivalent amount invested in a diversified
portfolio. (13) Second, the value of employer stock may be positively
correlated with employees' labor income; as noted at the outset,
many Enron employees simultaneously lost their jobs and their retirement
savings.
Shlomo Benartzi and coauthors identify some benefits to employees
from holding employer stock in their 401(k) plan, but they note that
these benefits are small relative to the substantial costs of
nondiversification. (14) Why then do employees invest so much of their
401(k) portfolios in employer stock? A number of psychological factors
may be important.
Employees may underestimate the risk of employer stock because of
"familiarity bias." The John Hancock Financial Services Defined Contribution Plan Survey finds that participants on average rate
employer stock as less risky than an equity mutual fund. (15) Similarly,
Benartzi and others find that only 33 percent of participants believe
that their employer stock is riskier than a diversified stock fund,
whereas 39 percent believe it is equally risky and 25 percent believe it
is safer. Furthermore, 20 percent of respondents said they would prefer
$1,000 in employer stock that they could not diversify until age fifty
over $1,000 that they could invest at their own discretion. (16)
Lauren Cohen argues that loyalty to one' s employer motivates
workers to hold employer stock. (17) He finds that the share of employer
stock held in 401(k) plans by employees of standalone firms is 10
percentage points greater than that of employees of conglomerates.
Furthermore, when a division is spun off from a conglomerate, the
average employee's holding of employer stock increases, whereas it
decreases following a merger. Cohen finds no evidence that employees
have superior information about future employer stock returns.
Benartzi, Choi and others, and Gail Huberman and Paul Sengmueller
find that current contributions to employer stock are increasing in the
stock's past returns. (18) If employees think past returns predict
future returns, then the high volatility of employer stock relative to
mutual funds and the inability to sell securities short in a 401(k) will
jointly lead to over-weighting of employer stock in the average 401 (k)
portfolio. Intuitively, employer stock is likely to be in either the
upper or the lower tail of the 401(k) asset return distribution in any
given period. Upper-tail outcomes have a greater impact on asset
allocation than lower-tail outcomes because of the constraint on short
sales. Like Cohen, Benartzi finds no correlation between employee
allocations to employer stock and the stock' s subsequent returns.
Benartzi and Richard Thaler suggest that naive strategies for
diversifying across investment options cause many investors to allocate
part of their contributions to employer stock simply because it is
available in the 401(k) menu. (19) Nellie Liang and Scott Weisbenner
report evidence consistent with this hypothesis specifically for
employer stock. (20) Employees may also perceive the presence of
employer stock in the 401(k) fund menu as an endorsement of the stock by
the employer. Benartzi, Holden, and VanDerhei, and Jeffrey Brown, Liang,
and Weisbenner, find that discretionary contributions to employer stock
are higher in firms where the employer directs matching contributions
into employer stock than in firms where employer stock is simply
available as another investment option. (21)
These investment menu effects are consistent with a growing body of
literature that finds that 401(k) savings outcomes are strongly affected
by the features of the plan, even when those features do not explicitly
restrict employee choices. Madrian and Dennis Shea, as well as Choi and
coauthors, document the tendency of participants to passively accept
401(k) enrollment, contribution, and investment fund defaults. (22)
Switching from an opt-in to an opt-out enrollment mechanism raises
401(k) participation rates six months after hire by over 50 percentage
points at some firms. The vast majority (65 to 87 percent) of newly
hired employees retain the automatic enrollment default contribution
rate and asset allocation upon enrollment in the 401(k) plan. Although
the fraction of employees at the default declines over time, the inertia
is very strong: three years after hire, nearly half of participants are
still at the defaults. Generalizing from these results, one might expect
that employer matching contributions made in employer stock will stay in
employer stock, even if participants are able to immediately diversify
out.
Choi and others show that requiring employees to explicitly choose
within a month of hire whether or not to participate in a 401(k) plan
(thus removing the option of passively accepting a default outcome)
raises the initial participation rate by 28 percentage points, and the
average contribution rate by 1.2 percentage points, relative to a
standard opt-in enrollment procedure. (23) Such an "active
decision" mechanism may also be an effective way of encouraging
employees to diversify their assets. Employees could be told to make an
explicit asset allocation choice for their employer matching funds,
instead of the current system in which employers may direct matching
funds into employer stock by default. (24)
Employee-Level Data on 401(k) Participation
The employee-level data that we use to examine the holding of
employer stock in 401(k) plans come from Hewitt Associates, a large
benefits administration and consulting firm. We use two different types
of administrative data. The first is a series of repeated year-end cross
sections containing all persons employed at the company at the time of
the data snapshot. These cross sections include demographic information
such as birth date, hire date, and compensation. They also include
information on the worker's 401(k) participation at the time of the
cross section, such as date of first participation, total balances in
the plan, and allocation of assets among the available funds. The second
type of data we have is a history of every transaction made in the plan
since Hewitt assumed its administration. These longitudinal data are
available for two of the companies analyzed in this paper (companies D
and F). (25) For all of these firms, our analysis is restricted to
active employees. Tables 1 and 2 summarize the demographic and 401(k)
plan characteristics of the seven firms studied in this paper.
Empowerment: The Effect of Relaxing Diversification Restrictions
As already noted, current 401(k) regulations allow companies to
severely restrict their employees' diversification out of employer
stock. Eighteen of the twenty-one congressional proposals in appendix
table A-1 to reform 401(k) employer stock regulations would relax these
restrictions, permitting employees to trade out of employer stock in
their 401(k) sooner.
To assess whether relaxing holding requirements would significantly
reduce employer stock holdings, we study two types of natural
experiments at five companies, all of which direct the employer match
into employer stock. The first type results from changes in the
diversification restrictions that employees face either as they age or
as they increase their tenure at the company. We examine how much
employees divest themselves of employer stock when they clear the
applicable age or tenure hurdles. The second type of natural experiment
arises from company-wide rule changes that eliminate or relax holding
requirements for all employees. We measure how much employer stock
holdings fall after such regime shifts.
Allowing Older Employees to Diversify out of Employer Stock
We begin with the firm we designate as company D, whose 401(k)
employer stock is in an ESOP and thus subject to the ESOP
diversification rules described above (for employees with ten years of
tenure, 25 percent diversification is allowed at age fifty-five, and 50
percent at age sixty). The middle right panel in figure 1 shows the
effect on employee portfolios of crossing these age and tenure
thresholds. It compares the actual average fraction of employer matching
balances held by individual participants of a given age in employer
stock, as well as the actual dollar-weighted average fraction (that is,
total employer stock balances divided by total balances for all
employees of a given age), with the fraction that employees with at
least ten years of tenure would hold if they all diversified the maximum
amount allowed. The figure shows that actual diversification is minimal.
Across all ages, the average participant holds at least 90 percent of
match balances in employer stock, even as the maximum diversification
allowed increases to 50 percent. There is no consistent divergence between the dollar-weighted and the unweighted series, suggesting that
wealthier employees are not more likely to divest than poorer employees.
This absence of a wealth gradient in diversification holds for many of
the companies we study in this paper.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
As previously noted, some companies have employer stock
diversification policies that are less restrictive than what is legally
required. (26) One of these is company A, which also has an ESOP within
its 401(k) plan. Although this firm is subject to the same ESOP
diversification requirements as company D, it voluntarily adopted less
stringent diversification rules in 2002, allowing employees to diversify
up to 25 percent of the employer stock in their match account at age
forty-five, 50 percent at age fifty, and 100 percent at age fifty-five.
The top left panel of figure 1 plots the relationship at company A
between age and the fraction of match balances in employer stock at the
end of 2003, approximately eighteen months after diversification
restrictions were relaxed. Among employees between the ages of
forty-five and fifty, the average (non-dollar-weighted) fraction held in
employer stock fell by 7 percentage points. This is less than a third of
the diversification available to these employees. Among employees at age
fifty-five, employer stock holdings fell further, to 85 percent of total
match balances, also about one-third of the actual diversification
available. Among employees at age fifty-six, the fraction of match
balances held in employer stock fell to 76 percent, about one-quarter of
the actual available diversification, and the proportion does not drop
below 64 percent through age sixty-five. In this company,
dollar-weighted averages fell slightly more, indicating that richer
employees are more eager to divest themselves of employer stock, but
even the dollar-weighted share is far from the maximum allowed
diversification.
Two other companies that have age- or tenure-based diversification
rules--companies B and C--have life cycle diversification patterns
similar to those of company A. Company B allows participants with at
least ten years of service to diversify 25 percent of their match
balance holdings starting at age fifty, 50 percent starting at age
fifty-five, and 75 percent starting at age sixty. The top right panel of
figure 1 shows the fraction of employer match balances held in employer
stock at company B at the end of 2003 for employees with at least ten
years at the company. The simple average seldom dips below 90 percent
for workers between fifty and sixty-five years of age. Dollar-weighting
the averages yields similar results.
Company C has more complicated diversification rules. Employees
younger than fifty-five can diversify up to 50 percent of the employer
stock balances in their match accounts if they have ten years of plan
participation. Employees aged fifty-five to fifty-nine can also
diversify up to 50 percent but need have only five years of plan
participation to do so. Employees between the ages of 60 and 70 1/2 can
diversify 100 percent of their employer stock balances if they have five
years of plan participation. Finally, employees over age 70 1/2 can sell
all their employer stock regardless of their time in the plan.
Figure 2 plots average employer stock holdings in match balances at
company C at the end of 2002 against tenure in the plan for employees
less than fifty-five years of age. The middle left panel in figure 1
plots average holdings against age for employees at the same company who
are between fifty-five and seventy and have at least five years of
tenure in the plan. It is apparent that, despite greatly relaxed holding
constraints, most employees at this company continued to hold more than
90 percent of their match balances in employer stock years after they
became eligible to diversify.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Rule Changes That Relax Diversification Restrictions for All
Employees
Figures 1 and 2 suggest that allowing employees to diversify their
401(k) holdings has only a modest impact on actual diversification.
However, the complexity of the diversification eligibility schedules may
have confused employees, reducing diversification. Companies that
completely eliminate diversification restrictions for all employees may
see greater divestiture of employer stock. Here we study two companies
that implemented such a change.
The first, company D, adhered to the standard ESOP diversification
requirements (with the results analyzed in figure 1) until early 2002,
when it eliminated all diversification restrictions. The company's
match, however, continued to be directed to employer stock following
this plan change. Employees who wanted to maintain a portfolio free of
employer stock had to initiate trades on an ongoing basis as new
matching contributions were made.
Figure 3 shows the fraction of the employer match account held in
employer stock at company D from January 1998 through November 2003.
Before the plan change, almost all employer match balances stayed in
employer stock. This is not surprising, given that only 6.6 percent of
employees met the standard ESOP age and tenure requirements for any
diversification. After the 2002 rule change, the allocation to employer
stock fell, but very slowly. At the end of 2003, almost two years after
the diversification restrictions were lifted, 84 percent of match
balances were still in employer stock.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Company E eliminated all diversification restrictions in mid-2002.
It, too, continued to direct employer match contributions to employer
stock. Unfortunately, lack of appropriate data prevents us from
producing the analogue of figure 3 for company E. Instead the bottom
left panel of figure 1 shows diversification by age at the end of 2003,
approximately eighteen months after the diversification restrictions
were lifted. At this time the average participant under age fifty still
had 90 percent of his or her employer match balances in employer stock,
and older employees continued to hold over 80 percent of their match
balances in employer stock. There is more diversification on a
dollar-weighted basis, especially among older participants.
The five case studies presented here paint a consistent picture:
relaxing diversification requirements decreases employer stockholding,
but the magnitude of that reduction is modest, especially for younger
employees.
Education: The Effect of Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing
If giving employees the ability to diversify does not prompt them
to do so, perhaps educating them on the perils of underdiversification
will spur them to action. Six of the twenty-one proposed bills listed in
appendix table A-1 include an educational provision. The studies
reviewed in the introduction found that financial education alone
generates only small changes in 401(k) outcomes. However, no one to our
knowledge has formally studied the effect on plan participants of
witnessing the consequences of others' financial follies.
Here we examine whether the media coverage of the plight of
employees at Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing--three companies
frequently mentioned together in news stories on the perils of holding
too much employer stock in one's 401(k) account--caused employees
at other companies to reduce their employer stock holdings. On December
31, 2000, before any of these firms entered serious financial distress,
62, 32, and 29 percent of 401(k) assets were held in employer stock at
Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing, respectively, according to the
companies' Form 5500 filings and their 11-K filings with the
Securities and Exchange Commission. Figure 4 gives a timeline of the key
events leading up to the demise of these companies. For the purposes of
our analysis, the first "Enron event" was the $1.2 billion
reduction in Enron shareholder equity that occurred on October 16, 2001.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
We construct a series of variables to capture the amount of media
coverage surrounding the financial collapses of Enron, WorldCom, and
Global Crossing. These variables are based on the number of news stories
mentioning the three companies published each day starting on October
16, 2001. We employ four different counts. The first is the number of
stories published in five major newspapers: the New York Times, the Wall
Street Journal, the Washington Post, the Los Angeles Times, and the
Chicago Tribune. We used the Lexis/Nexis and Factiva databases to search
these publications, and we excluded republished news, recurring pricing
and market data, obituaries, sports news, and calendars. We examined the
resulting list of stories by hand and deleted results that appeared to
be duplicates as well as stories fewer than 100 words long (mostly
one-paragraph teasers pointing to stories elsewhere in the paper). The
second count includes both these newspaper stories and stories found in
Lexis/ Nexis transcripts of television news programs on three major
broadcast networks: ABC, CBS, and NBC. (27) There were 12,047 relevant
newspaper stories and 1,927 relevant television stories from October 16,
2001, to December 31, 2003. The third and fourth counts exclude from the
first and second, respectively, all stories that do not include the word
"401(k)." This reduces the total number of stories to 761 for
the newspapers-only count and 905 for the television-plus-newspapers
count. Table 3 provides a breakdown of these totals by individual
source. Our constructed variables serve only as proxies for the millions
of items on Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing that appeared in local
and national newspapers and magazines and on websites, radio, and
television.
Using these four news story counts, we created four geometrically time-discounted news impact variables to capture the fact that reaction
to news does not occur immediately. The impact of each story is assumed
to decay by a factor [delta] for each day after its publication or
broadcast. We multiply the product by (1 - [delta]) so that the mean
value of the news impact variables is invariant to the value of [delta].
Thus, for example, a story published on January 2 would receive a weight
of (1 - [delta]) on that day, a weight of [delta](1 - [delta]) on
January 3, a weight of [[delta].sup.2] (1 - [delta]) on January 4, and
so on. The impact of all stories on day t (where t = 0 on October 16,
2001) is the sum of the geometrically discounted impact of all previous
stories:
news [impact.sub.t] = (1 - [delta])[t.summation over
p=0][[delta].sup.t-p][N.sub.p],
where [N.sub.p] is the number of stories published on day p.
Because we have little theoretical or empirical guidance on the
appropriate value of 5, we try a range of values.
Figure 5 shows the number of relevant newspaper stories published
on each day, as well as the value of the news impact variable
constructed from those data using a value of [delta] = 0.9. The most
active news coverage occurred from mid-December 2001 through the end of
February 2002, when Enron and Global Crossing filed for bankruptcy.
There is another peak in June and July 2002, when WorldCom disclosed
accounting irregularities and shortly thereafter filed for bankruptcy.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Having created a proxy for media attention, we estimate its
association with 401(k) employer stockholding in two domains. First we
study its effect on aggregate 401(k) employer stockholding, using data
on 401(k) participants in a number of large firms. However, some of
these employees may have been required to hold employer stock by their
companies or may not have had employer stock available as a 401(k)
investment option. Therefore we also analyze two specific companies that
offered employer stock but had no diversification restrictions. We then
examine whether workers in Texas--and, even more specifically,
Houstonians--reacted more to the Enron bankruptcy than did workers
outside of Texas. Because Enron is headquartered in Houston, workers in
Houston and Texas were exposed to more Enron media coverage and were
more likely to have known people directly affected by the bankruptcy.
The Effect of News about Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing on
Aggregate Employer Stock Holdings
Our aggregate employer stock data come from the Hewitt 401(k)
Index, which measures daily trading activity in a large number of firms
that collectively employ 1.5 million participants with nearly $90
billion in 401(k) assets. (28) Our Hewitt Index data run from August 4,
1997, through November 4, 2003 (seventy-five months). Because the set of
firms represented in the index changes over time, we restrict our
attention to the subset that are in the index for the entire sample
period. These firms hold approximately half the 401(k) assets of all
firms in the index.
For these firms figure 6 shows both the fraction of total 401(k)
assets and the fraction of equities held in employer stock. The former
ranges from 26 to 38 percent, which is higher than the 19 percent
calculated by Holden and VanDerhei using a much larger database. (29)
This discrepancy probably results from the fact that firms in the Hewitt
Index tend to be very large, and large firms are more likely to offer
employer stock as an investment option. The fraction of equities in
employer stock ranges from 36 to 51 percent over the same period.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The share of all assets in employer stock shows a declining trend
from August 1998 through March 2000, an increasing trend from March 2000
through May 2001, relative stability from May through November 2001, and
a declining trend from November 2001 through November 2003. The
beginning of that last declining trend coincides with the financial
collapse of Enron. On October 15,2001, the day before Enron's
shareholder equity fell by $1.2 billion, the fraction of total balances
in employer stock at Hewitt Index firms was 35.9 percent. By April 2003
it had reached a low of 25.8 percent. However, a broader stock market
decline began around the same time, and this would have mechanically
reduced the fraction of 401(k) assets held as employer stock even if
employees were completely passive.
If the decline in employer stock holdings were completely
mechanically driven by a general decline in stock prices, then employer
stock as a fraction of equities should not be greatly affected, because
both the numerator and the denominator in this fraction would decrease
by roughly the same proportion. Figure 6 shows, however, that this
series is not flat over the post-Enron period, but the decline is much
less pronounced than that for employer stock as a fraction of all
balances. Indeed, it is striking that employer stock as a fraction of
equity holdings barely moved during the time that the Enron scandal was
unfolding. However, this stable ratio need not be due to a lack of
trading in employer stock; plan participants could have aggressively
sold both employer stock and other equities. With such concerns in mind,
we turn to an analysis of trading activity in employer stock.
Our dependent variable is the value of aggregate net transfers into
or out of employer stock, normalized by dividing by the preceding
day's aggregate employer stock balance. (30) This variable will be
positive when the total dollars transferred into employer stock exceeds
the total dollars transferred out, and zero or negative otherwise.
Figure 7 plots normalized net transfers over our sample period. (31)
Casual visual inspection indicates that net trading volatility seems to
have increased following Enron's collapse, but the mean direction
of trade does not obviously shift.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
To isolate the impact of the financial collapse of Enron, WorldCom,
and Global Crossing on employer stock trading, we regressed normalized
net employer stock transfers on the news impact variable, current and
lagged market returns on the Standard and Poor's 500 stock index
(calculated so that the returns are nonoverlapping), (32)
day-of-the-week dummies, and a cubic polynomial time trend (in
annualized trading days). Table 4 reports least-squares regression results using the four different versions of the news impact variable
and [delta] values of 0.25 and 0.9.
The coefficients on the news impact variable are negative and
statistically significant across all specifications, indicating that
trading out of employer stock occurred in response to media attention to
the Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing episodes. We calculate the
total media-induced decline in employer stock holdings as a fraction of
401(k) balances using the formula
(1) [T-1.summation over t=0][beta] x news impact x employer stock
[percent.sub.t-1],
where [beta] is the regression coefficient on the news impact
variable, employer stock [percent.sub.t-1] is the fraction of total
balances held in employer stock on day t - 1, and T- 1 is the total
number of post-Enron trading days in our sample. The last row of table 4
shows the calculated economic magnitudes for each specification. (33) No
matter how we defined a news story as relevant, and regardless of the
[delta] value chosen, none of the specifications show that more than a
2.4-percentage-point drop in employer stock holdings as a fraction of
the total portfolio can be attributed to news about Enron, WorldCom, and
Global Crossing. (34) The coefficients become more negative when all
stories rather than just 401(k) stories are included, but they attenuate when we broaden our media sources to include television. There is no
consistent pattern with respect to [delta] values. The small economic
magnitudes also hold in regressions (results not reported) that use
other definitions of the story variable (for example, New York Times
stories only, or stories about Enron only), that use other values of
[delta], that exclude the trend variables, that use data aggregated to
the monthly level, or that use a distributed lag specification for the
impact of news rather than a geometrically decaying specification. (35)
If a large fraction of Hewitt Index firms do not offer employer
stock in their 401(k), or if many employees in those firms are unable to
diversify because of holding restrictions, then the aggregate results in
table 4 will significantly understate the true effect of media education
on employer stock holdings. Unfortunately, we do not know anything about
the prevalence of employer stock availability or holding restrictions
among the companies in the Hewitt Index. However, a 2003 Hewitt
Associates survey that collected data on various aspects of 401(k) plan
design from approximately 450 large firms reports that 49 percent of
these firms offered employer stock as an investment option. (36) Of
those that offered employer stock, 78 percent either had no
diversification restrictions for matching contributions directed into
employer stock or did not match in employer stock. If the Hewitt Index
companies are similar to this sample of firms, and if we assume
counterfactually that none of the employer stock reduction occurred in
companies with holding restrictions, and if the specification that
yields the most negative news impact coefficient is correct, then the
media coverage of Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing caused employer
stock holdings to drop by at most 2.35/0.49 x 0.78 = 6.15 percentage
points in companies without holding restrictions, still a small effect.
In reality, most employees at firms with holding restrictions are not
constrained at the margin by the restrictions, because they hold so much
employer stock in the accounts over which they have full discretion.
Holden and VanDerhei report that employees with holding requirements
invest 33 percent of their own contributions in employer stock, whereas
employees without holding requirements invest 22 percent of their entire
401(k) portfolio in employer stock. (37) Therefore 6.15 percentage
points is an upper bound on the true effect. The magnitude of this
effect is consistent with other estimates of financial education we have
reported elsewhere, and with the finding by Esther Duflo and Emmanuel
Saez that financial education motivates only small changes in 401(k)
saving behavior. (38)
The Effect of News on Companies Offering Employer Stock without
Diversification Restrictions
To further investigate the hypothesis that holding requirements
prevented a dramatic aggregate fall in employer stock holdings following
the Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing scandals, we study two large
firms offering employer stock in their 401(k)s for which we have daily
trading data. The first, company D, had employer stock holding
requirements in the employer match account for most of the sample period
(see above). For this reason we examine only the employee contribution
account for company D, where there were no such restrictions. The
second, company F, had no holding requirements anywhere in its 401(k)
plan. In addition, employer matching contributions at company F were not
directed into employer stock; rather, their allocation mirrored that
which employees chose for their own contributions.
Figure 8 plots the fraction of employee contribution balances held
in employer stock from 1997 through 2003 for company D. Employer stock
holdings declined in the early post-Enron period (October 2001 through
January 2002) but increased for most of the period after that, including
the time of greatest Enron-related media attention (January through
March 2002). These patterns track the company's stock price. Taken
by itself, this figure does not suggest that the employees of company D
responded to news about Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Figure 9 plots for company D the average fraction of employee
contribution flows that went to employer stock on each date, with and
without weighting by dollar value. We examine these series because
employees who have decided to permanently decrease their employer stock
holdings may begin by stanching the flow into employer stock that occurs
at each payroll date. In fact, the allocations steadily increased over
time and show only slight declines in the immediate wake of the Enron
scandal before continuing their march upward. There is thus little
evidence of significant adjustment on the contribution flow margin.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
Figure 10 plots daily net transfers of employer stock at company D
as a fraction of the previous day' s employer stock balance. We
begin the sample in November 1997 because that is when the plan first
allowed trading on a daily rather than a monthly basis. The magnitude of
normalized net trade flows is larger than that observed in the Hewitt
Index, but this is to be expected. An individual company's net
trade flow will have a substantial idiosyncratic component, which will
be averaged away when aggregated with many other companies in the Hewitt
Index.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Table 5 shows the results of regressing this series on the news
impact variable and several control variables, including those used in
the previous subsection. (39) We find that, across all specifications,
the largest news-induced drop in employer stock holdings is a
statistically insignificant 1.21 percent of employee contribution
balances. (40) When [delta] is set to 0.9, the regression results
suggest that news of the major bankruptcies caused company D employees
to trade into employer stock. Since we are studying accounts with no
diversification restrictions, we can conclude that employees did not
trade out of employer stock even in accounts in which they had every
opportunity to do so. (41)
Figure 11 plots the fraction of total 401(k) account balances held
in employer stock over time at company F, which had no holding
restrictions on either the employee contribution or employer match
balances. There are two complications with the company F data. First,
company F allows its participants to put their 401(k) assets in a
self-directed brokerage window, where they can trade securities not
offered in the company's 401(k) investment menu. We do not observe
daily balances in the self-directed window and thus cannot include them
in the daily total balances we calculate. (We do, however, observe the
self-directed window balances at the end of each year.) Therefore figure
11 overstates the fraction of all 401(k) balances allocated to employer
stock. Because we observe total employer stock balances each day, our
trading regressions will not be affected by this data issue. Second, our
company F sample does not start until January 2002, which means that we
do not observe pre-Enron behavior at this company. Therefore our
estimates of the news effect at company F may be less reliable.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
Figure 12 shows that, over the entire sample period, the fraction
of contribution flows that participants at company F directed to
employer stock slowly increased, even during the post-Enron period. This
corresponds to the pattern in figure 11, which showed an increasing
share of balances held in employer stock over time. As at company D,
there is no evidence of Enron-induced adjustment in the contribution
flow allocations.
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Figure 13 plots company F's daily net transfers of employer
stock as a fraction of the preceding day' s employer stock balance.
Table 6 shows the news impact regression results. In calculating the
economic effect, we modify equation 1 to reflect the fact that we do not
observe total 401 (k) balances each day, but only at the end of each
year. Our alternative formula is
(2) [[T.sub.0].summation over t = [[tau].sub.0]][beta] x news
[impact.sub.t] x employer stock [balances.sub.t-1]/ total year-end 2003
401(k) balances,
where [[tau].sub.0] is January 1, 2002, and [T.sub.0] is the number
of trading days for which we have transactions data for company F. (42)
We find that the largest economic effect of media coverage across all
the specifications is a statistically insignificant 5.2-percentage-point
decrease. The average estimate is a 1.8-percentage point-decrease.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
Overall, our analysis of employer stock trading at companies D and
F shows no statistically or economically significant effect of the
Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing debacles on employees'
willingness to hold employer stock, even in accounts not subject to
diversification restrictions.
Impact on Texas Employees Versus Non-Texas Employees
The Enron scandal is more likely to have been salient to workers
living in Texas than those living outside Texas. Not only was local news
coverage likely to have been more active, but residents of Texas are
more likely to have known Enron employees or friends of Enron employees.
About a quarter of Enron' s employees worked at the Houston
headquarters, and more than half of the company's 8,000 job cuts in
2002 were in Houston. Here we explore whether Texan employees at
companies C and G reduced their employer stock holdings more than did
non-Texan employees at the same companies.
Companies C and G are large retail firms chosen for this study
because they have a substantial number of employees both in and outside
of Texas. Company G imposed no diversification restrictions on its
employees, although employer matching contributions had to be initially
invested in employer stock. Employees who wished to diversify had to
initiate a trade periodically, but they were free to do so at any time.
We do not have daily transactions data for company G, and so we rely on
a different identification strategy than in the previous subsection. We
have cross-sectional snapshots of portfolio allocations at the end of
each year from 1998 to 2002. We use these snapshots, exploiting the fact
that employees rarely change their 401 (k) elections after enrolling.
(43) Therefore any year-end differences in employer stock holdings
between Texans and non-Texans who enrolled at the same time are likely
to be due to asset allocation decisions made at the time of enrollment.
We investigate whether Texans who enrolled in the post-Enron period show
an increasing tendency to deviate from non-Texans' employer stock
allocations.
Figure 14 graphs the fraction of total balances held in employer
stock against enrollment date for three groups of employees at company
G: those living in the greater Houston metropolitan area (Harris
County), those living outside of greater Houston but in Texas, and those
living outside of Texas. The portfolio allocation is taken from the
first year-end snapshot after the employee's enrollment date. This
figure shows that the asset allocations of all three groups track each
other fairly closely. There is no greater tendency for either
Houstonians or Texans to reduce their employer stock holdings in the
wake of the Enron scandal.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
Company C imposes age- and tenure-based diversification constraints
on its employees as described previously. Therefore we examine employer
stock holdings in only those accounts over which the employees have full
discretion, employing the same identification method as for company G.
Figure 15 plots the discretionary holdings in employer stock against
initial enrollment date. As in figure 14, the allocation is measured at
the first year-end snapshot after enrollment. As with company G, there
is no significant reduction in the employer stock holdings of Texan
employees relative to non-Texans. There are not enough Houston-based
employees at company C to analyze them separately.
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
The evidence presented here does not seem to support the hypothesis
that proximity to financial disaster leads to wiser decisions about
employer stock.
Conclusions
Our analysis suggests that empowering employees to trade out of
employer stock and educating them about the risks of employer stock will
have only a small effect on 401(k) employer stock holdings. Even after
diversification restrictions were relaxed at five companies, it was
typical for over 90 percent of employer match balances to remain in
employer stock. Two years of headlines about decimated 401(k) accounts
in the early part of this decade did little to drive investors out of
their employer's stock. Our estimates suggest that the media
publicity surrounding the Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing
bankruptcies reduced the fraction of aggregate 401(k) assets held in
employer stock by at most 2 percentage points, from about 36 percent to
about 34 percent. These results support the conclusions of earlier
studies that consumers are often passive, (44) and that educational
interventions yield remarkably small changes in saving behavior. (45)
These conclusions pose a problem for policy, because education and
empowerment are the key components of almost all of the proposals for
401(k) employer stock reform listed in appendix table A-1 (for example,
bills S.9, S. 1992, S. 2032, and S. 2190). None of these legislative
proposals are nearly as stringent as those currently applied to
defined-benefit plans, which cap employer stock holdings at 10 percent
of account balances.
The persistent appeal of employer stock leaves economists in a
policymaking quandary. On the one hand, the well-known benefits of
diversification argue that employer stock should not make up a large
fraction of a worker's retirement portfolio. On the other hand,
economists dislike paternalism and do not want to enact coercive policies such as banning employer stock in retirement accounts. More
generally, household saving decisions are fraught with other
economically significant mistakes, which only the most paternalistic would consider forbidding. (46)
Fortunately, some reasonable policy options are available that are
likely to reduce employer stock holdings without denying investors
freedom of choice. (47) Under today's status quo, many firms invest
matching contributions in employer stock. The natural experiments
reported in this paper show that such matching contributions tend to
stick where they initially land, regardless of any subsequent
diversification opportunities. Hence employer stock holdings would be
significantly reduced if the default asset allocation for employer
matching contributions were changed to provide greater diversification.
For example, default portfolios could be required to meet the same
fiduciary standards that apply to defined-benefit pension plans.
With diversified defaults, investor inertia would be rendered
harmless, because only those investors who actively opt out of the
default could pile into employer stock. As noted above, in 401(k) plans
that offer employer stock as an investment option but lack an employer
stock default for matching funds, only 22 percent of balances end up in
employer stock. By contrast, in 401(k) plans with an employer stock
default for matching funds, well over 50 percent of balances end up in
employer stock. (48)
Strict libertarians may object even to restrictions on default
portfolios. If requiring diversified defaults is deemed too
paternalistic, employees could be asked to explicitly choose their own
asset allocation instead of being defaulted into an undiversified
allocation. (49) Alternatively, legislation could remove the perverse tax benefits that give firms an incentive to choose employer stock as a
default asset allocation. (50)
The common theme is that defaults stick and bad defaults are not
inevitable. Bad defaults could be replaced with either good
(diversified) defaults or with default-free choice. Banning bad defaults
does not coerce employees, since they are free to opt out of a good
default and adopt any asset allocation they choose. However, banning bad
defaults does coerce firms, since they are no longer free to use
defaults to induce their employees to become shareholders. Although we
see this as a good thing for employees, there are some potential
countervailing effects, such as a potential decline in the willingness
of firms to provide a 401(k) match, or, in the extreme, to offer a
savings plan at all.
Requiring (or at least encouraging) good defaults is a plausible
solution to many weaknesses in the nation's retirement savings
system. Defaults can be used to encourage participation in retirement
plans, raise retirement saving rates among at-risk groups, and diversify
401(k) portfolios. In every case, defaults need not be coercive to work.
However, defaults are a two-edged sword, since poorly chosen defaults
can wreak havoc on financially unsophisticated, inertia-bound
consumers.</p> <pre> APPENDIX Table A-1. Congressional
Proposals to Regulate Employer Stock in 401(k) Plans, 2000-05 Bill no.
Title, sponsor, and date introduced Bills under consideration in the
109th Congress (2005-06) H.R.1960
Pension Preservation and Savings Expansion Act of
2005 Rep. Rob Portman (R-OH) April 28, 2005
H.R.1961 Pension Preservation and Savings Expansion Act
of 2005 Rep. Ben Cardin (D-MD) April 28, 2005
S.219 National Employee Savings and Trust Equity
Guarantee Act of 2005 Sen. Charles Grassley (R-IA)
January 31, 2005 Bills under consideration in the 108th
Congress (2003-04) H.R.1000 Pension Security Act Rep.
John Boehner (R-OH) February 27, 2003 H.R.1776 Pension
Preservation and Savings Expansion Act of 2003
Rep. Rob Portman (R-OH) April 11, 2003 H.R.2101
Pension Fairness Act of 2003 Rep. George Miller
(D-CA)
May 14, 2003 H.R.5397 Retirement Enhancement Act
of 2004 Rep. Robert Andrews (D-NJ)
November 19, 2004 H.R.5398 Retirement Enhancement Revenue
Act of 2004 Rep. Robert Andrews (D-NJ)
November 19, 2004 S.9 Pension Protection and
Expansion Act Sen. Tom Daschle (D-SD)
January 7, 2003 S.1892 Sen. Evan Bayh (D-IN)
November 19, 2003 S.2424 National Employee Savings and
Trust Equity Guarantee Act Sen. Charles
Grassley (R-IA) May 14, 2004 Bills under consideration in
the 107th Congress (2001-02) H.R.3640 Pension Protection and
Diversification Act of 2002 Rep. William Pascrell (D-NJ)
January 29, 2002 H.R.3692 Pension Protection and
Diversification Act of 2002 Rep. Sheila
Jackson-Lee (D-TX) February 7, 2002 H.R.3762 Pension
Security Act of 2002 Rep. John Boehner (R-OH)
April 15, 2002 H.R.5110 Omnibus Corporate Reform and
Restoration Act of 2002 Rep. Sheila Jackson-Lee (D-TX)
July 12, 2002 S.1838 Pension Protection and
Diversification Act Sen. Barbara Boxer (D-CA)
December 18, 2001 S.1919 Retirement Security Protection Act
of 2002 Sen. Paul Wellstone (D-MN) February 7,
2002 5.1971 National Employee Savings and Trust
Equity Guarantee Act (NESTEG) Sen. Charles
Grassley (R-IA) February 27, 2002 5.1992 Protecting
America's Pensions Act of 2002 Sen.
Edward Kennedy (D-MA) March 6, 2002 5.2032
Investor-Employees Need Financial Facts and Options for
Responsible
Retirement Plan Management Act of 2002 (INFORM)
Sen. Richard Durbin (D-IL) March 19, 2002
S.2190 Worker Investment and Retirement Education Act
of 2002 (WIRE) Sen. John Kerry (D-MA) April 17, 2002 Bill
no. Provisions relating to employer stock in 401 (k) plans Bills
under consideration in the 109th Congress (2005-06) H.R.1960
Employees may sell employer stock derived from their
own contributions immediately. Employees may sell
employer stock derived from employer contributions
after three years of service or three years after receiving
the employer contribution. Plans that offer employer
stock must offer at least three other investment options.
H.R.1961 Employees may sell employer stock derived from their
own contributions immediately. Employees may sell
employer stock derived from employer contributions
after three years of service or three years after receiving
the employer contribution. Plans that offer employer
stock must offer at least three other investment options.
S.219 Employees may sell employer stock derived from their
own contributions immediately. Employees may sell
employer stock derived from employer contributions
after three years of service. Plans that offer employer
stock must offer at least three other investment options.
Bills under consideration in the 108th Congress (2003-04) H.R.1000
Employees may sell employer stock three years after
receiving it. Companies may not require employees to invest
their own contributions in employer stock. H.R.1776 Employees may
sell employer stock derived from their own contributions
immediately. Employees may sell employer stock derived from
matching contributions after three years of service, and
employer stock derived from all employer contributions
after five years of service. Plans that offer employer
stock must offer at least three other investment options.
H.R.2101
Employers must notify participants and inform them of
the risks of not diversifying assets if employer stock
exceeds 10 percent of balances. Participants must be
informed of large employer stock sales by a corporate
insider or plan fiduciary. Employees may sell employer
stock after three years of service. H.R.5397 Companies may
not require participants to invest their own contributions
in employer stock. Employees may sell employer stock
derived from employer contributions after three years of
service. Plans that offer employer stock must offer at
least three other investment options. H.R.5398 Employees may sell
employer stock derived from employer contributions after
three years of service. Plans that offer employer stock
must offer at least three other investment options. S.9
Employers must notify participants if employer stock
exceeds 20 percent of 401(k) balances. Companies must
certify that employer stock is a prudent investment.
Firms may match in employer stock or offer it for employee
contributions, but not both. S.1892 Plan administrators must
notify participants that they may be overinvested in
employer securities and real property if such assets'
value exceeds 50 percent of 401(k) balances. S.2424
Employees may sell employer stock three years after
receiving it. Plans that offer employer stock must offer
three other investment options. Bills under consideration in the
107th Congress (2001-02) H.R.3640 Employer stock is capped at 20
percent of 401(k) assets. Employees may sell employer stock
ninety days after receiving it. In ESOPs, employees may
sell employer stock after five years of participation or at
age thirty- five. H.R.3692 Employer stock is capped at
20 percent of 401 (k) assets. Employees may sell employer
stock ninety days after receiving it. In ESOPs, employees
may sell employer stock after five years of participation
or at age thirty- five. H.R.3762 Companies may not require
participants to invest their own contributions in employer stock.
Employees may sell employer stock after three years in the
plan. Plans that offer employer stock must offer at least
three other investment options. H.R.5110 Employer stock
is capped at 20 percent of 401 (k) assets. In ESOPs,
employees may sell employer stock after five years of
participation or at age thirty-five. S.1838 Employer stock is
capped at 20 percent of 401(k) assets.
Employees may sell employer matching contributions
made in employer stock ninety days after receiving it.
S.1919
Employer stock is capped at 20 percent of 401(k) assets.
Companies may not require participants to invest their
own contributions in employer stock. Employees may
sell employer contributions made in employer stock after
one year of service. 5.1971 Employees may sell
employer stock three years after receiving it. Plans that
offer employer stock must offer at least three other
investment options. 5.1992 Employees may sell employer stock three
years after receiving it. Companies may not require
participants to invest their own contributions in employer
stock. Plans
must provide information regarding diversification
rights and the importance of diversifying assets. Plans
that offer employer stock must offer at least three other
investment options. 5.2032 Employers are liable
for excessive losses on employer securities during
lockdowns on plan assets. Employers must notify
participants if employer stock exceeds 30 percent of
balances, and further employer contributions to employer
stock are prohibited until the participant signs a form
acknowledging the risks of not diversifying assets. S.2190
Plans must provide investment guidelines to participants.
Companies may not require participants to invest their own
contributions in employer stock. Plans that offer employer
stock must offer at least three other investment options.
Employees may begin selling employer contributions of
employer securities after five years in the plan, with full
divestment permitted after seven years. Employees may begin
selling employer matching contributions of employer
securities after three years in the plan, with full
divestment permitted after five years. Bill no. Status as of August
19, 2005 Bills under consideration in the 109th Congress (2005-06)
H.R.1960 In House subcommittee H.R.1961 In House subcommittee
S.219 In Senate committee Bills under consideration in the 108th
Congress (2003-04) H.R.1000
Passed in House; no vote taken in Senate H.R.1776
No vote taken H.R.2101 No vote taken H.R.5397 No vote
taken H.R.5398 No vote taken S.9 No vote taken S.1892 No
vote taken S.2424 No vote taken Bills under consideration in the
107th Congress (2001-02) H.R.3640 No vote taken H.R.3692
No vote taken H.R.3762 Passed in House; no vote
taken in Senate H.R.5110 No vote taken S.1838 No vote
taken S.1919 No vote taken 5.1971 No vote taken 5.1992 No
vote taken 5.2032 No vote taken S.2190 No vote taken Source:
Library of Congress, THOMAS data and authors' analysis.
</pre> <p>(1.) Duflo and Saez (2003); Choi and others
(2002); Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2005a).
(2.) Alchian (1950).
(3.) Madrian and Shea (2001); Choi and others (2002); Choi,
Laibson, and Madrian (2005a).
(4.) Choi and others (2003, 2005).
(5.) Choi and others (2005); Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2005b).
(6.) This section draws heavily on Ng (2003) and Reish and Faucher
(2002).
(7.) Ng (2003); Reish and Faucher (2002).
(8.) Mitchell and Utkus (2003), citing Holden and VanDerhei (2001)
and VanDerhei (2002).
(9.) Even and Macpherson (2004).
(10.) Even and Macpherson (2004).
(11.) Fidelity Investments (2002).
(12.) Holden and VanDerhei (2001) and VanDerhei (2002); these
authors use administrative data to calculate the fraction of assets held
in employer stock, whereas Even and Macpherson (2004) use IRS Form 5500
(tax reporting) data. The numbers in the two sources are not directly
comparable.
(13.) Poterba (2003); Meulbroek (2005); Brennan and Torous (1999).
(14.) Benartzi and others (2004). See also Brown, Liang, and
Weisbenner (forthcoming) for a discussion of the costs and benefits to
firms and workers of holding employer stock in the 401(k) plan.
(15.) John Hancock Financial Services (2002). Interestingly, the
perceived risk of employer stock in the John Hancock survey has not
changed much over time, even following the Enron scandal.
(16.) Benartzi and others (2004).
(17.) Cohen (2005).
(18.) Benartzi (2001); Choi and others (2004b); Huberman and
Sengmueller (2004).
(19.) Benartzi and Thaler (2001).
(20.) Liang and Weisbenner (2002).
(21.) Benartzi (2001); Holden and VanDerhei (2001); Brown, Liang,
and Weisbenner (forthcoming).
(22.) Madrian and Shea (2001); Choi and others (2002, 2004a).
(23.) Choi and others (2005).
(24.) We are exploring this possibility in an additional natural
experiment not discussed here.
(25.) The names of the companies are withheld for reasons of
confidentiality.
(26.) Many firms have voluntarily relaxed their diversification
restrictions following the collapse of Enron (Fidelity Investments,
2002), probably because of the negative publicity surrounding employer
stock diversification restrictions and the liability risks of
maintaining such restrictions.
(27.) The transcripts were limited to national news programs (such
as the CBS Evening News, Nightline, and 20/20); transcripts of local
news broadcasts were not available.
(28.) Hewitt Associates (undated-a, undated-b). Historical values
for the index can be found at
was4.hewitt.com/hewitt/services/401k/index.htm. We do not use the index
itself but only certain inputs into the index.
(29.) Holden and VanDerhei (2001); VanDerhei (2002). They use the
EBRI/ICI database compiled by the Employee Benefit Research Institute
and the Investment Company Institute.
(30.) Dollars traded includes only balances that are actively
transferred from one investment option to another. It does not include
payroll contributions that are invested in employer stock, nor does it
include withdrawals out of the plan entirely.
(31.) Occasionally, large changes in employer stock balances were
observed because data for certain component companies were missing on
those days, generating outliers in the calculated normalized trading
activity. We eliminated such outlier days from our data.
(32.) The S&P return variables are the returns today,
yesterday, last month, the last six months, and the last one, two,
three, and four years. The short-horizon return variables allow us to
control for transfers due to day traders.
(33.) Note that the coefficients across regressions where the story
counts differ are not directly comparable, because the average magnitude
of the news impact variable differs. The economic magnitudes, not the
coefficients themselves, should be used to compare effects.
(34.) We also ran regressions including a post-Enron dummy variable to see if there was a discrete drop in employer stock holdings once the
Enron scandal broke. We did not find any statistically significant or
economically large coefficients, and the coefficient signs often
indicated that the Enron scandal caused a small movement into employer
stock.
(35.) When lags of [N.sub.p] are included in the regression, only
the preceding day's lag is statistically significant. As so often
in empirical exercises, we cannot rule out the existence of omitted
variable bias, despite the robustness of our results to various
specifications.
(36.) Hewitt Associates (2003).
(37.) Holden and VanDerhei (2001).
(38.) Choi and others (2002); Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2005a);
Duflo and Saez (2003).
(39.) We control for employer stock returns in excess of the
S&P 500. Like Choi and others (2004b), we find that positive excess
employer stock returns cause trading out of employer stock. We also add
a dummy variable for the date when diversification restrictions on the
match account were lifted at the company.
(40.) The coefficients in this regression and in the company F
regression below are not directly comparable to those in the Hewitt
Index regression, because the total economic effect depends upon the
initial fraction of the portfolio held in employer stock, which differs
across the three samples. The time trends should also not be expected to
be similar across the three sets of regressions, because of
firm-specific trends that are averaged away in the aggregate series.
(41.) The economic effect of one of the control variables in these
regressions is anomalously large. The coefficients on the linear time
trend imply a 60-percentage-point drop in employer stock holding due to
the time trend. Since this would result in a negative average employer
stock position in the absence of other forces, we do not interpret this
magnitude literally but consider it an artifact of a nonlinearity (see
figure 8) that is not well fit by a cubic polynomial.
(42.) We have data on employer stock balances for company F as of
December 31, 2001, from the cross-sectional data.
(43.) Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988).
(44.) Madrian and Shea (2001); Choi and others (2002).
(45.) Duflo and Saez (2003); Choi and others (2002); Choi, Laibson,
and Madrian (2005a).
(46.) See Choi, Laibson, and Madrian (2005a).
(47.) See Sunstein and Thaler (forthcoming) for a general
discussion of noncoercive prescriptive policies, which they call
"libertarian paternalism."
(48.) Although employees in these plans are required to hold a
significant fraction of this employer stock, the evidence in this paper
and in others shows that these requirements are not binding at the
margin for most employees, since voluntary employer stockholding is so
high in these plans.
(49.) Choi and others (2005).
(50.) However, some perverse incentives would not be easy to
remove. For example, stock held by employees is often viewed as a
protection against hostile takeover (Rauh, forthcoming).
JAMES J. CHOI
Yale University
DAVID LAIBSON
Harvard University
BRIGITTE C. MADRIAN
University of Pennsylvania
Table 1. Workforce Characteristics of the Firms in This Study, End of
2003
Average age of
Company employees (years) Percent male Percent married
A 44.9 76 n.a.
B 39.7 54 n.a.
C 39.0 35 n.a.
D 41.2 40 62
E 34.9 52 n.a.
F 44.8 28 n.a.
G (a) 37.3 64 n.a.
Memorandum: 39.7 53 59
U.S. workforce
Average annual Median annual
Company salary salary Total employees
A n.a. n.a. ~20,000
B n.a. n.a. ~10,000
C n.a. n.a. 100,000+
D $57,422 $46,910 ~40,000
E $51,991 $37,040 ~10,000
F $66,253 $61,975 ~15,000
G (a) n.a. n.a. 100,000+
Memorandum: $36,522 $27,000 n.a.
U.S. workforce
Sources: Authors' calculations and March 2004 Current Population
Survey.
(a.) As of the end of 2002.
n.a. Not available.
Table 2. Features of the 401(k) Plans at the Firms in This Study, End
of 2003
Percent of Employer match
No. of assets in
investment employer Percent of assets
Company options stock in match account
A 9 58 45
B 9 65 49
C (a) 14 69 50
D 7 28 25
E 8 21 24
F 11 46 36
G (a) 8 77 21
Employer match
Allowable employer
stock
Company Match structure Vesting diversification
A 55 to 125 percent 100 percent Old: 25 percent at
match, depending on immediate age fifty-five and
profitability, up to 50 percent at age
6 percent of pay sixty with ten
contributed; directed years of tenure
into ESOP New: 25 percent at
age forty-five, 50
percent at age
fifty, 100 percent
at age fifty-five
B 50 percent match up Five-year 25 percent at age
to 6 percent of pay graduated fifty, 50 percent
contributed; directed at age fifty-five,
into ESOP 75 percent at age
sixty with ten
years of tenure
C (a) 100 percent match up Three-year 50 percent after
to 5 percent of pay graduated ten years in plan
contributed; directed or age fifty-five
into ESOP with five years in
plan; 100 percent
at age 70 1/2, or
age sixty with five
years in plan
D 50 percent match up 100 percent Old: 25 percent at
to 5 percent of pay immediate age fifty-five and
contributed; 50 percent at age
additional profit- sixty with ten
contingent match years of tenure
possible; directed New: 100 percent
into ESOP immediately
E 100 percent match up Graduated 100 percent
to 4 percent of pay (100 percent immediately
contributed; directed at 5,000
into employer stock hours)
F 75 percent match up Five-year 100 percent
to 6 percent of pay graduated immediately
contributed
G (a) 150 percent on first Three-year 100 percent
1 percent of pay cliff immediately
contributed; 50 per-
cent on next 4 per-
cent of pay contri-
buted; directed into
employer stock
Source: Plan documents. All companies offer employer stock as one of
the investment options.
(a.) Plan information as of end of 2002.
Table 3. News Stories on Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing, October
16, 2001, to December 31, 2003
All stories
Days with Total story
Medium stories count
Newspapers
New York Times 639 3,134
Wall Street Journal 534 3,294
Washington Post 681 2,374
Los Angeles Times 712 2,567
Chicago Tribune 327 678
Television
ABC News 182 700
NBC News 163 459
CBS News 246 768
All newspapers 810 12,047
All television 322 1,927
All newspapers and television 810 13,974
Stories mentioning
"401(k)" only
Days with Total story
Medium stories count
Newspapers
New York Times 125 184
Wall Street Journal 115 157
Washington Post 134 176
Los Angeles Times 112 133
Chicago Tribune 86 111
Television
ABC News 26 37
NBC News 37 55
CBS News 43 52
All newspapers 332 761
All television 79 144
All newspapers and television 344 905
Source: Lexis/Nexis and Factiva databases.
Table 4. Effect of News about Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing on
Net Employer Stock Transfers, August 4, 1997, to November 4, 2003 (a)
All stories
[delta] = 0.25
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0008 ** -0.0007 **
(0.0003) (0.0002)
Return on S&P500 (c)
Same day -0.0149 ** -0.0150 **
(0.0026) (0.0026)
Preceding day -0.0028 -0.0029
(0.0023) (0.0023)
Preceding month -0.0013 -0.0012
(0.0007) (0.0007)
Time trend (d)
Linear 0.0150 0.0140
(0.0450) (0.0450)
Quadratic -0.0100 -0.0096
(0.0173) (0.0173)
Cubic 0.0011 0.0011
(0.0014) (0.0014)
Intercept 0.0370 0.0341
(0.0502) (0.0504)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0821 0.0825
Total news effect (e) -2.35 -2.22
All stories
[delta] = 0.90
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0008 * -0.0006 *
(0.0004) (0.0003)
Return on S&P500 (c)
Same day -0.0148 ** -0.0148 *
(0.0027) (0.0027)
Preceding day -0.0027 -0.0027
(0.0024) (0.0024)
Preceding month -0.0012 -0.0012
(0.0007) (0.0007)
Time trend (d)
Linear 0.0205 0.0209
(0.0418) (0.0417)
Quadratic -0.0106 -0.0106
(0.0168) (0.0167)
Cubic 0.0009 0.0009
(0.0015) (0.0015)
Intercept 0.0589 0.0593
(0.0402) (0.0399)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0814 0.0818
Total news effect (e) -2.00 -1.90
Stories mentioning 401(k) only
[delta] = 0.25
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0075 -0.0057 *
(0.0035) (0.0024)
Return on S&P500 (c)
Same day -0.0148 ** -0.0149 **
(0.0027) (0.0027)
Preceding day -0.0027 -0.0027
(0.0023) (0.0023)
Preceding month -0.0012 -0.0012
(0.0007) (0.0007)
Time trend (d)
Linear 0.0153 0.0151
(0.0449) (0.0449)
Quadratic -0.0097 -0.0096
(0.0173) (0.0173)
Cubic 0.0011 0.0011
(0.0014) (0.0014)
Intercept 0.0262 0.0254
(0.0509) (0.0509)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0826 0.0826
Total news effect (e) -1.30 -1.20
Stories mentioning 401(k) only
[delta] = 0.90
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0107 ** -0.0087 **
(0.0041) (0.0032)
Return on S&P500 (c)
Same day -0.0148 ** -0.0148 **
(0.0026) (0.0026)
Preceding day -0.0027 -0.0027
(0.0023) (0.0023)
Preceding month -0.0012 -0.0012
(0.0007) (0.0007)
Time trend (d)
Linear 0.0156 0.0160
(0.0317) (0.0315)
Quadratic -0.0100 -0.0101
(0.0140) (0.0139)
Cubic 0.0011 0.0011
(0.0014) (0.0013)
Intercept 0.0302 0.0300
(0.0316) (0.0316)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.0830 0.0834
Total news effect (e) -1.79 -1.74
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) The dependent variable is aggregate net transfers of employer
stock in 401(k) plans, as a percentage of the preceding day's employer
stock balance. The unit of observation is a trading day. The sample
size in all regressions is 1,534. All regressions include
day-of-the-week dummies, month-of-the-year dummies, and additional
stock market return controls extending back four years. Number
parentheses are Newey-West (1987) standard errors with five lags.
* denotes statistical significance at the 5 percent level.
(b.) See the text for definition.
(c.) In percentage points.
(d.) Time is measured in years.
(e.) Calibrated percentage-point reduction in the fraction of the
total portfolio allocated to employer stock due to the aggregate
effect of the news impact variable over the sample period.
Table 5. Effect of News about Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing on
Net Employer Stock Transfers at Company D, December 1, 1997, to
December 31, 2003 (a)
All stories
[delta] = 0.25
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0017 -0.0012
(0.0025) (0.0017)
Company D excess return (c)
Today -0.0758 ** -0.0758 **
(0.0229) (0.0229)
Previous day -0.0193 * -0.0193 *
(0.0086) (0.0086)
Previous month -0.0051 * -0.0051 *
(0.0024) (0.0024)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.0970 ** -0.0971 **
(0.0190) (0.0190)
Previous day -0.0414 ** -0.0415 **
(0.0137) (0.0137)
Previous month -0.0032 -0.0032
(0.0055) (0.0055)
Time trend (e)
Linear -0.8247 ** -0.8258 **
(0.3133) (0.3134)
Quadratic 0.2511 0.2514
(0.1661) (0.1661)
Cubic -0.0195 -0.0195
(0.0185) (0.0185)
Diversification dummy (f) 0.2484 0.2370
(0.1338) (0.1288)
Intercept 0.3867 0.3873
(0.7065) (0.7065)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.1766 0.1766
Total news effect (g) -1.21 -0.99
All stories
[delta] = 0.90
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) 0.0021 0.0013
(0.0047) (0.0032)
Company D excess return (c)
Today -0.0761 ** -0.0761 **
(0.0228) (0.0228)
Previous day -0.0194 * -0.0194 *
(0.0085) (0.00085)
Previous month -0.0052 * -0.0052 *
(0.0024) (0.0024)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.0967 ** -0.0966 **
(0.0190) (0.0190)
Previous day -0.0410 ** -0.0409 **
(0.0137) (0.0137)
Previous month -0.0030 -0.0030
(0.0053) (0.0054)
Time trend (e)
Linear -0.8292 ** -0.8277 **
(0.3055) (0.3053)
Quadratic 0.2653 0.2650
(0.1662) (0.1621)
Cubic -0.0234 -0.0234
(0.0184) (0.0184)
Diversification dummy (f) 0.1945 0.2103
(0.1689) (0.1531)
Intercept 0.5650 0.5467
(0.5215) (0.5229)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.1767 0.1766
Total news effect (g) 1.35 0.99
Stories mentioning 401(k)" only
[delta] = 0.25
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0037 -0.0141
(0.0241) (0.0183)
Company D excess return (c)
Today -0.0759 ** -0.0758 **
(0.0230) (0.0229)
Previous day -0.0194 * -0.0193 *
(0.0086) (0.0086)
Previous month -0.0051 * -0.0051 *
(0.0024) (0.0024)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.0969 ** -0.0970 **
(0.0189) (0.0189)
Previous day -0.0412 ** -0.0412 **
(0.0137) (0.0137)
Previous month -0.0029 -0.0032
(0.0054) (0.0054)
Time trend (e)
Linear -0.8281 ** -0.8134 **
(0.3136) (0.3144)
Quadratic 0.2530 0.2457
(0.1661) (0.1665)
Cubic -0.0198 -0.0188
(0.0185) (0.0185)
Diversification dummy (f) 0.2272 0.2251
(0.1302) (0.1240)
Intercept 0.3839 0.3825
(0.7077) (0.7058)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.1765 0.1765
Total news effect (g) -0.15 -0.68
Stories mentioning 401(k)" only
[delta] = 0.90
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) 0.0336 0.0139
(0.0421) (0.0324)
Company D excess return (c)
Today -0.0762 ** -0.0761 **
(0.0229) (0.0228)
Previous day -0.0195 * -0.0194 *
(0.0085) (0.0085)
Previous month -0.0054 * -0.0052 *
(0.0024) (0.0024)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.0970 ** -0.0967 **
(0.0190) (0.0190)
Previous day -0.0413 ** -0.0411 **
(0.0137) (0.0137)
Previous month -0.0031 -0.0031
(0.0053) (0.0053)
Time trend (e)
Linear -0.8664 ** -0.8369 **
(0.3070) (0.3074)
Quadratic 0.2824 0.2687
(0.1631) (0.1632)
Cubic -0.0251 -0.0238
(0.0185) (0.0185)
Diversification dummy (f) 0.1864 0.2209
(0.1528) (0.1443)
Intercept 0.5488 0.5659
(0.5222) (0.5249)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.1771 0.1767
Total news effect (g) 1.33 0.65
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) The dependent variable is aggregate net employer stock transfers
in the employee contribution account, as a percentage of the preceding
day's employer stock balance. The unit of observation is a trading day.
The sample size in all regressions is 1,520. All regressions include
day-of-the-week dummies, month-of-the-year dummies, and additional
stock market return controls extending back four years. Numbers in
parentheses are Newey-West standard errors with five lags. * denotes
significance at the 5 percent level, and ** at the 1 percent level.
(b.) See the text for definition.
(c.) Annual rate of return on company stock in excess of the return on
the S&P 500, in percentage points.
(d.) In percentage points.
(e.) Time is measured in years.
(f.) Equals 1 if the date of transfer is after the employer began to
allow for full diversification of matching contributions for all
employees.
(g.) Calibrated percentage-point change in the fraction of the total
portfolio allocated to employer stock due to the aggregate effect of
the news impact variable over the sample period.
Table 6. Effect of News about Enron, WorldCom, and Global Crossing on
Net Employer Stock Transfers at Company F, January 1, 2002, to December
31, 2003 (a)
All stories
[delta] = 0.25
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0003 -0.0013
(0.0041) (0.0026)
Company F excess return (c)
Today -0.2038 ** -0.2041 **
(0.0397) (0.0397)
Previous day 0.0407 * 0.0406 *
(0.0204) (0.0204)
Previous month 0.0019 0.0020
(0.0061) (0.0062)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.1632 ** -0.1632 **
(0.0496) (0.0497)
Previous day 0.1188 ** 0.1189 **
(0.0369) (0.0370)
Previous month -0.0127 -0.0125
(0.0108) (0.0108)
Time trend (e)
Linear -1.2238 * -1.2660 *
(0.5983) (0.5740)
Quadratic 0.9555 0.9848
(0.6023) (0.6029)
Cubic 1.4361 * 1.4536 *
(0.6105) (0.5924)
Intercept -1.1622 -1.1222
(0.7088) (0.7101)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.2333 0.2334
Total news effect (f) -0.48 -2.87
All stories
[delta] = 0.90
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0031 -0.0017
(0.0055) (0.0036)
Company F excess return (c)
Today -0.2038 ** -0.2039 **
(0.0397) (0.0397)
Previous day 0.0406 * 0.0406 *
(0.0204) (0.0204)
Previous month 0.0020 0.0020
(0.0062) (0.0062)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.1628 ** -0.1630 **
(0.0496) (0.0496)
Previous day 0.1192 ** 0.1190 **
(0.0372) (0.0371)
Previous month -0.0124 -0.0125
(0.0109) (0.0108)
Time trend (e)
Linear -1.3465 * -1.2988 *
(0.6503) (0.6159)
Quadratic 1.0106 0.9977
(0.6078) (0.6088)
Cubic 1.5269 * 1.4883 *
(0.6453) (0.6228)
Intercept -1.1483 -1.1479
(0.7020) (0.7020)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.2334 0.2334
Total news effect (f) -5.21 -3.32
Stories mentioning
"401(k)" only
[delta] = 0.25
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0048 -0.0140
(0.0353) (0.0223)
Company F excess return (c)
Today -0.2036 ** -0.2032 **
(0.0396) (0.0396)
Previous day 0.0409 * 0.0412 *
(0.0203) (0.0203)
Previous month 0.0019 0.0019
(0.0061) (0.0061)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.1631 ** -0.1631 **
(0.0497) (0.0498)
Previous day 0.1189 ** 0.1191 **
(0.0370) (0.0370)
Previous month -0.0128 -0.0132
(0.0108) (0.0108)
Time trend (e)
Linear -1.2258 * -1.2397 *
(0.5635) (0.5548)
Quadratic 0.9656 1.0081
(0.6054) (0.6036)
Cubic 1.4348 * 1.4264 *
(0.5894) (0.5843)
Intercept -1.1631 -1.1496
(0.6996) (0.7004)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.2333 0.2335
Total news effect (f) -0.51 -1.74
Stories mentioning
"401(k)" only
[delta] = 0.90
Newspapers Newspapers
Independent variable only and TV
News impact (b) -0.0002 -0.0017
(0.0513) (0.0304)
Company F excess return (c)
Today -0.1632 ** -0.1632 **
(0.0496) (0.0497)
Previous day 0.1188 ** 0.1189 **
(0.0371) (0.0370)
Previous month -0.0127 -0.0129
(0.0108) (0.0108)
Return on S&P500 (d)
Today -0.2038 ** -0.2037 **
(0.0396) (0.0396)
Previous day 0.0408 ** 0.0408 **
(0.0204) (0.0204)
Previous month 0.0019 0.0019
(0.0061) (0.0061)
Time trend (e)
Linear -1.2140 * -1.2182 *
(0.6000) (0.5823)
Quadratic 0.9507 0.9562
(0.6128) (0.6129)
Cubic 1.4300 * 1.4315 *
(0.6079) (0.5971)
Intercept -1.1670 -1.1665
(0.6980) (0.6985)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.2333 0.2333
Total news effect (f) -0.02 -0.21
Source: Authors' calculations.
(a.) The dependent variable is aggregate net employer stock transfers,
as a percentage of the preceding day's employer stock balance. The unit
of observation is a trading day. The sample size in all regressions is
504. All regressions include day-of-the-week dummies,
month-of-the-year dummies, and additional stock market return controls
extending back four years. Numbers in parentheses are Newey-West
standard errors with five lags. * denotes significance at the 5 percent
level, and ** at the 1 percent level.
(b.) See the text for definition.
(c.) Annual rate of return on company stock in excess of the return on
the S&P 500.
(d.) In percentage points.
(e.) In years.
(f.) Calibrated percentage-point reduction in the fraction of the total
portfolio allocated to employer stock due to the aggregate effect of
the news impact variable over the sample period.