Is the U.S. Current Account Deficit Sustainable? Will It Be Sustained?
COOPER, RICHARD N.
IT IS ESTIMATED that in 2001 the U.S. current account deficit will
reach $450 billion, or 4.4 percent of GDP, up from 3.6 percent in
1999.(1) Current account balance was last achieved in 1991 (1981 if Gulf
War-related special receipts are excluded for 1991). One has to go back
to the two decades before 1914, a period of mass immigration and
extensive infrastructure construction, to find deficits even
approximately as large, relative to GDP, as those of recent years.(2)
The United States is reckoned, by global standards, to be a country
relatively rich in capital. Why, then, is it importing more capital than
ever before? Are deficits on this scale sustainable? Are they likely to
be sustained?
The Size and Significance of the Current Account Deficit
It is useful to put the U.S. deficit into its global context;
foreign trade, after all, is with other countries. In 1999 (the latest
year for which worldwide data are available) the U.S. deficit, at $331
billion, dwarfed all others. Brazil was the runner-up with $25 billion;
Poland and Argentina each had deficits of $12 billion. Japan had the
largest surplus at $107 billion (2.5 percent of its GDP), followed by
Russia and the Republic of Korea--both still reeling from financial
crises--with roughly $25 billion each (13.7 percent and 6.0 percent of
GDP, respectively) and China with $16 billion (1.6 percent). Among these
countries, Poland, Brazil, and Argentina had larger deficits than the
United States relative to GDP, at 8.0 percent, 4.7 percent, and 4.3
percent, respectively. But some of the largest current account
imbalances relative to GDP were recorded by smaller countries, including
outsize surpluses in Singapore (25 percent), Kuwait (17 percent), and
Norway (4 percent), and deficits in Cote d'Ivoire (3 percent) and
Israel (2 percent).
But globally the numbers do not add up. In principle, the world
should be in current account balance every period; in fact, the records
show a deficit of $130 billion for 1999, suggesting substantial
underrecording of receipts.(3) But where? Given its size in the world
economy, it would be surprising if the United States were not receiving
a substantial amount, net, of these unrecorded receipts. Thus the
recorded deficit is undoubtedly exaggerated, perhaps by tens of billions
of dollars. Even this correction, however, would still leave a U.S.
deficit that is large by twentieth-century standards, and a dominating
feature of the world economy in recent years, lending support to the
claim that Americans are the world's consumers of last resort.
It is often suggested that the large current account deficit poses
a serious financing problem for the United States. Each year, the lament
goes, the United States must attract net inflows of capital sufficient
to "cover" the huge current shortfall. But this proposition
gets the logic backward: the U.S. deficit is "financed" by net
capital inflows only in an ex post accounting sense. In economic terms
it is more nearly correct to say that net capital inflows cause the
current account deficit.
The currencies of most major U.S. trading partners--the Canadian
dollar, the yen, the pound sterling, the deutsche mark (or the euro
since 1999)--have been floating against the U.S. dollar since the early
1970s. Foreign trade in goods and services is determined by many
factors, among them exchange rates. Exchange rates in turn are
determined by, among other things, the net purchases of financial and
other assets denominated in each currency. Net purchases of
dollar-denominated assets (which need not be domiciled in the United
States) will, ceteris paribus, push up the value of the dollar relative
to the currency being exchanged for dollars to purchase those assets.
The United States has no controls of any consequence on the inflow
or outflow of capital--on purchases of foreign assets by Americans, or
of American assets by non-Americans. The basic story of the past two
decades is that, on balance, foreigners have wanted to buy more American
assets than Americans have wanted to invest abroad. This imbalanced
tendency increased during the early 1980s, leading to a peak in the
current account deficit of $161 billion (3.4 percent of GDP) in 1987.
The deficit then receded, crossed over into surplus territory (by $7
billion) in 1991,(4) and finally experienced a virtually uninterrupted
year-to-year "deterioration" throughout the 1990s (table 1).
Table 1. U.S. International Transactions, 1960-2000
Billions of dollars
Balance on
Current Investment
Year account Goods Services income(a)
1960 2.8 4.9 -1.4 3.4
1965 5.4 5.0 -0.3 5.4
1970 2.3 2.6 -0.3 6.2
1975 18.1 8.9 3.5 12.8
1980 2.3 -25.5 6.1 30.1
1985 -118.2 -122.2 0.3 25.7
1990 -77.0 -109.0 30.2 28.6
1991 6.6 -74.1 45.8 24.1
1992 -47.7 -96.1 60.4 23.0
1993 -82.7 -132.6 63.7 23.9
1994 -118.6 -166.2 69.2 16.7
1995 -109.5 -173.7 77.8 20.5
1996 -123.3 -191.3 89.2 18.9
1997 -140.5 -196.7 90.7 6.2
1998 -217.1 -246.9 80.0 -6.2
1999 -331.5 -345.6 80.6 -18.5
2000 -435.4 -449.5 81.0 -13.7
Foreign
investment
in the
U.S. United States(c)
investment
Year abroad(b) Official Other
1960 -4.1 1.5 0.8
1965 -5.7 0.1 0.6
1970 -8.5 6.9 -0.6
1975 -39.7 7.0 10.1
1980 -85.8 15.5 47.1
1985 -44.8 -1.1 147.2
1990 -81.2 33.9 107.7
1991 -64.4 17.4 93.4
1992 -74.4 40.5 130.2
1993 -200.6 71.8 210.3
1994 -176.1 39.6 266.4
1995 -352.4 109.9 355.8
1996 -413.9 126.7 445.0
1997 -488.9 18.9 738.1
1998 -335.4 -20.1 502.4
1999 -430.2 42.9 710.7
2000 -553.3 35.9 916.5
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, International Transactions
Accounts.
(a.) Net of income received on U.S. assets minus payments on U.S.
assets abroad.
(b.) Change in U.S.-owned assets located abroad.
(c.) Change in foreign-owned assets located in the United States.
The language of current account deficits is unfortunate: it
reverses the economic logic and suggests that in the U.S. case a deficit
is undesirable, even though it reflects a vote of confidence by the rest
of the world in the United States, or at least in claims on Americans.
Put another way, the United States has demonstrated strong comparative
advantage in exporting stocks, bonds, bank deposits, and other claims on
such U.S. assets as real estate and U.S.-domiciled firms under foreign
management control (that is, foreign direct investment; see table 2).
Foreign private parties invested $711 billion, net of sales, in the
United States during 1999, which rose to an astonishing $916 billion in
2000; Americans invested $442 billion abroad during 1999.(5) Governments
also invested abroad, although on a much smaller scale.
Table 2. U.S. International Investment Position, 1979-99(a)
Billions of dollars
Asset 1979 1989 1999
U.S.-owned assets abroad(b) 508.9 1,944.2 7,173.4
Official reserves 19.0 168.7 136.4
Other government 58.4 84.2 84.2
Private(b) 431.5 1,691.3 6,952.7
Foreign direct investment(b) 186.8(c) 807.7 2,615.5
Bonds 56.6 98.5 556.7
Corporate stocks 56.6 91.7 2,026.6
Other 188.1 642.2 1,753.8
Foreign-owned assets in the United
States(b) 413.9 2,211.9 8,647.1
Foreign official 159.5 337.3 869.3
U.S. government securities 106.6 265.7 628.9
Other 9.9 9.6 50.7
Private(b) 254.4 1,874.7 7,777.7
Foreign direct investment(b) 54.5 533.5 2,800.7
Bonds(d) 58.6 228.5 1,063.7
Stocks 58.6 260.6 1,445.6
U.S. currency n.a. 40.4 473.8
Other 127.2 648.7 1,556.3
Net U.S. international investment
position 95.0 -267.7 -1,473.7
Source: Economic Report of the President, various years.
(a.) End of period, selected years.
(b.) At market prices, except where noted otherwise.
(c.) At book value.
(d.) Includes marketable short-term U.S. Treasury securities.
Why So Large?
Why do foreigners invest so much in the United States? The answer
is not hard to find. The U.S. economy alone accounts for more than a
quarter of the world economy, its fundamentals are strong, and it
performs well. Nearly half of all foreign claims on the United States
are interest bearing, and U.S. interest rates in recent years have been
higher than those in Europe, and much higher than in Japan. This has
allowed the United States to attract and hold funds from those areas and
elsewhere. Other parts of the world have been through financial crises,
resulting in higher interest rates, but also in much greater uncertainty
about their exchange rates and even the prospect of repayment.
Returns on equity capital also tend to be higher in the United
States than in Europe and Japan, and more reliable than in many
developing countries. In 1997, for instance, the business sector
capital-output ratio in the United States, at 1.3, was lower than that
in any other advanced industrial country, and less than half that in
France, Germany, Japan, or the United Kingdom.(6) A series of
industry-level productivity studies by McKinsey & Company also
report significantly higher returns to capital in the United States than
in other industrial countries, and indeed than in some developing
countries.
Moreover, because of the size and character of U.S. markets, stocks
and bonds traded on them tend to be more liquid, as measured by
transactions costs, than those in most other markets. And the U.S.
public markets are considered to offer better protection for creditors
and minority shareholders, and against insider trading, than those in
most other countries. In short, investments in America are viewed
favorably around the world, and for good reason: the U.S. economy is a
good, steady performer, less sluggish than Europe and Japan, less
volatile than emerging markets. Inflows of investment funds therefore
push up the dollar--and this, in turn, makes foreign goods more
competitive and pushes up the current account deficit.
Like all investments, some will go bad, and foreigners will lose
their money, as some surely did on real estate purchased in the late
1980s and on stock purchased in the late 1990s. But on balance the
claims will generate future income, especially for aging Japanese and
Europeans. When they eventually withdraw their accumulated savings, U.S.
exports will be stimulated by a consequently weaker dollar. Until then,
American obligations to the rest of the world will grow.
Investment by foreigners in the United States serves them well. It
is also good for Americans, so long as Americans invest in improved
productive capacity and innovation in the U.S. economy. If investment
projects in the United States yield 10 to 15 percent, as many do, and
U.S. obligations to foreigners issued to finance those projects yield 5
to 10 percent, as many do, all will benefit.
Business investment in the U.S. economy has recently been strong,
reaching 12.9 percent of GDP in 1999, the highest level in many years,
and up from below 11 percent in the recovery years 1993-94. In the 1980s
it could be said that foreign capital financed the U.S. budget deficit
rather than private investment (and indeed there were many foreign
purchases of U.S. government bonds). By 1998, however, the federal
government was running a surplus, which has risen substantially since
then; state and local governments have also run growing surpluses. Thus
the foreign contribution to U.S. saving permitted both some increase in
business investment and some decline in household saving rates.
In the meantime, however, some American businesses found themselves
under severe competitive pressure from foreign goods, which was not
fully offset by increased foreign demand for U.S. exports. That resulted
in political pressure for increased protection and in increasing abuse
of the antidumping provisions of U.S. trade law, which were not designed
to cope with fluctuating exchange rates.
How Sustainable?
How sustainable is the U.S. deficit? Put another way, how long will
foreigners be willing to invest an additional $400 billion a year, year
after year, in the United States, net of U.S. investment flows abroad?
Gross world saving outside the United States probably exceeded $5
trillion in 2000, implying a world (ex-U.S.) saving rate of 22 percent.
The U.S. deficit, at $400 billion, was equal to 8 percent of that $5
trillion. It is not beyond imagination that foreigners will want to
continue to invest 8 percent of their annual saving in the United
States. After all, the United States in 1999 accounted for over 28
percent of gross world product,(7) and its listed securities account for
nearly half the world's total by value.(8) Foreign investment in
the United States would have to be a few percentage points above 8
percent to allow net investment by Americans in the rest of the world to
continue at current levels, in a continuing process of diversification,
but even that falls comfortably within the range of plausibility.
Another way to look at the issue: Americans would have had to invest 44
percent of their total national saving abroad in 1999 to achieve current
account balance, given the foreign capital that flowed into the United
States.
To repeat, investments in the United States have provided, and are
likely to continue to provide, returns that are both high and reliable
compared with most other parts of the world, where they are either
reliable but low, or sometimes high but unreliable. In short, extensive
foreign investment in the United States makes economic sense. In the
fundamental (but not politically correct) sense of the term, the United
States is a developing country, particularly compared with aging Europe
and Japan.
How Likely to Be Sustained? And by Whom?
Will the deficit be sustained? Perhaps not, at least by private
capital alone, the above analysis notwithstanding. Suppose private
foreigners collectively decided to invest less in the United States than
is required to "finance" a current account deficit on the
order of $400 billion, plus perhaps $100 billion to $200 billion to
allow for net investment abroad by Americans. Because of inertia leading
to response lags, the current account deficit would not at once drop in
parallel with the decline in private net capital inflows. What would be
the consequence? The dollar would depreciate, making foreign goods more
expensive for Americans and making U.S. products more competitive in
world markets. In time, the U.S. current account deficit would decline
to match the remaining net foreign investment in the United States. A
cheaper dollar would also make some investments in the United States
even more attractive, drawing new capital inflows.
Given the lags, however, and the fragility of expectations in
financial and especially in foreign exchange markets, it is possible,
indeed likely, that the dollar would depreciate further than necessary
to correct the underlying imbalance. Cries of alarm would then appear in
the financial press and in other quarters. There would be grim
headlines, and pundits would pronounce the early end of the new American
century. Prospective foreign investment might hesitate, waiting for an
even cheaper dollar, thereby pushing the dollar further downward.
However, excessive depreciation of the dollar is likely to alarm
foreign exporters, and their governments, more than it alarms
knowledgeable Americans. Many American firms, of course, would welcome
it. In the end, however, foreign central banks would be likely to
intervene in foreign exchange markets to brake a large fall in the
dollar, in effect supplementing foreign private investment in the United
States with foreign official investment. That is how world official
foreign exchange reserves rose to their 1999 magnitude of $1.9 trillion,
around two-thirds of which is held in U.S. dollars. This has happened
even though exchange rates among major currencies have been floating for
more than twenty-five years, supposedly (at least according to some
economists in the early 1970s) eliminating the need for official
reserves.
Do we want to rely entirely on foreign officials to stem a sharp
drop in the dollar, if it occurs? Can they be relied on? Japan has shown
a reliable willingness to intervene in foreign exchange markets to
prevent a too rapid or too extensive appreciation of the yen, and in the
process it has built up $350 billion in official reserves, most,
presumably, in U.S. government securities. The new European Central Bank
(ECB), for its part, has demonstrated a marked reluctance to intervene
in foreign exchange markets despite a substantial depreciation of the
euro from $1.17 when it was introduced in January 1999. A flurry of
intervention in the fall of 2000 earned the ECB criticism both from
those who oppose intervention on principle and from those who questioned
its handling of the episode. The German Bundesbank had been charged with
ensuring the "stability of the currency," an artful phrase;
the ECB is more narrowly charged with ensuring price stability, which
leaves less room for maneuver, and this will make it reluctant to
intervene in foreign exchange markets on a substantial scale.
However, currency depreciations and currency appreciations differ
importantly in their domestic impacts, and it is an appreciation of the
euro (and depreciation of the dollar) that is contemplated here. Could
the ECB have stayed aloof from the foreign exchange market if, instead
of depreciating by over 25 percent from its inauguration, it had
appreciated by 25 percent, from $1.17 to $1.46? I doubt it. The
deflationary pressure on an economically fragile Europe would have been
too great to be politically bearable.
The ECB would probably be relaxed about a return of the euro to the
neighborhood of $1.17 and even higher, but European business and
agriculture would chafe even at that, and they would protest loudly at
any appreciation substantially beyond that rate. They would press both
for greater monetary ease and for increased protection, for example
through the (mis)use of antidumping duties. And that would put Europe in
a position similar to that of the United States in 1985, when the
"hands-off" Reagan administration reversed course and called
for weakening the dollar, in part through foreign exchange market
intervention.
The resulting Plaza Accord of 1985 called for coordinated
intervention by the United States, Japan, and several European countries
to counter the strong dollar. In the hypothesized future circumstance of
a weakening dollar, Europe and Japan would intervene by selling their
currencies and buying dollars. Selling one's own currency involves
no drawdown of limited foreign exchange reserves. But to engage in a
coordinated intervention, the United States would need foreign currency
to sell. What resources could it draw on to intervene with? In 2000 U.S.
monetary authorities held over $40 billion in foreign exchange reserves
and special drawing rights (SDRs), and the United States had another $15
billion in its reserve position at the International Monetary Fund, plus
$11 billion in gold valued at $42 an ounce. It could also borrow from
the Fund, where its quota is $48 billion (SDR37 billion at $1.30 to the
SDR).
But international capital flows have become massive, with the
potential for massive reversal. The United States would be more
comfortable if its holdings of foreign exchange reserves were greater.
This suggests that the U.S. authorities should now be acquiring
additional foreign exchange, especially euros and possibly yen, for
future use. These currencies have the advantage of being relatively
cheap (or were at the time of the March Brookings Panel meeting). Some
yield would be sacrificed on the euros, and much on the yen, relative to
U.S. Treasuries, but that would be recouped by a capital gain under the
hypothesized circumstance of a significantly depreciated dollar.
The purchase of euros and yen today would itself put some downward
pressure on the dollar, reducing some of the exchange rate pressures on
U.S. producers, at a time when some export stimulus would be helpful.
And the purchases would provide the Federal Reserve with some experience
in undertaking open market operations in vehicles other than Treasuries,
something it will eventually need in any case if the marketable federal
debt is paid off. The administration and Congress are, however, making
that prospect less likely with their proposed tax reductions, thus
pushing the need for Federal Reserve adaptation further into the future.
(1.) U.S. net exports in the national accounts were $254 billion in
1999, or 2.7 percent of GDP. Apart from relatively minor adjustments to
trade for coverage and timing, the current account in the balance of
payments includes net earnings (net payments since 1998) on foreign
investment and net transfers to foreigners, which do not affect GDP. For
international comparability, I will use figures from the balance of
payments accounts rather than the national income accounts.
(2.) The U.S. current account deficit reached an estimated 3.3
percent of GDP in 1872, and 2.3 percent in 1888 (calculated from
Historical Statistics of the United States, 1975); the current account
was mostly balanced over the period 1885-1913, averaging +0.1 percent of
GDP in those years, according to Jones and Obstfeld (1997).
(3.) World Bank, Global Economic Prospects, 2001, p. 179.
(4.) The balance was still in deficit if $43 billion in foreign
payments to the United States for the Gulf War is excluded.
(5.) Of this figure, $78 billion represented reinvested earnings.
Reinvested earnings by foreigners, amounting to $26 billion, are counted
as current payments to foreigners, which are notionally offset by a
corresponding capital inflow.
(6.) Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD in
Figures, 1998, pp. 14-15. An "advanced industrial country"
here is defined as a member of that organization in 1994.
(7.) World Bank, World Development Report 2000/2001, p. 275.
(8.) Statistical Abstract of the United States 1998, table 1385;
Bank for International Settlements, International Banking and Financial
Market Developments, August 2000, table 16A).