The Long and Large Decline in U.S. Output Volatility.
BLANCHARD, OLIVIER ; SIMON, JOHN
SINCE THE EARLY 1980S the U.S. economy has gone through two long
expansions. The first, from 1982 to 1990, lasted thirty-one quarters.
The second started in 1991 and, although showing signs of faltering, has
recorded its fortieth quarter as this volume goes to press and is
already the longest U.S. expansion on record.
One view is that these two long expansions are simply the result of
luck, of an absence of major adverse shocks over the last twenty years.
We argue that more has been at work, namely, a large underlying decline
in output volatility. Furthermore, we contend, this decline is not a
recent development--the by-product of a "New Economy" or of
Alan Greenspan's talent. Rather it has been a steady decline over
several decades, which started in the 1950s (or earlier, but lack of
consistent data makes this difficult to establish), was interrupted in
the 1970s and early 1980s, and returned to trend in the late 1980s and
the 1990s.(1) The magnitude of the decline is substantial: the standard
deviation of quarterly output growth has declined by a factor of three
over the period. This is more than enough to account for the increased
length of expansions.
Having established this fact, we reach two other conclusions.
First, the decrease in volatility can be traced to a number of proximate causes, from a decrease in the volatility of government spending early
on, to a decrease in consumption and investment volatility throughout
the period, to a change in the sign of the correlation between inventory
investment and sales in the last decade. Second, there is a strong
relationship between movements in output volatility and movements in
inflation volatility. The interruption of the trend decline in output
volatility in the 1970s was associated with a large increase in
inflation volatility; the return to trend is associated with the
decrease in inflation volatility since then.
This paper is organized as follows. We start by documenting our
basic fact, namely, the secular decrease in output volatility. We then
look at the stochastic process for GDP and show that this decrease in
volatility can be traced primarily to a decrease in the standard
deviation of output shocks, rather than to a change in the dynamics of
output. Finally, we show how this decrease in the standard deviation of
shocks accounts for the increased length of expansions.
We then take up the question of whether recessions are special, in
a way that the formalization used earlier does not do justice to. Put
another way, we ask whether what we have seen over the last twenty years
is simply the absence of large shocks and nothing more. We show that
this is not the case. The measured decrease in output volatility has
little to do with the absence of large shocks in the recent past.
We then turn to the relationship between output volatility and
inflation. We show that there is a strong relationship both between
output volatility and the level of inflation, and between output
volatility and inflation volatility. Both volatilities went up in the
1970s and have come down since. Correlation does not, however, imply
causality. The correlation in both periods may have been due to third
factors, such as supply shocks in the 1970s. This leads us to consider
evidence from the other members of the Group of Seven (G-7) large
industrial countries. Our motivation here is that the different timings
of disinflation across these countries can help us separate out the
effects of inflation from those of supply shocks. We first show that
these other countries have also experienced a decline in output
volatility, although with some differences in timing and in magnitude.
(An interesting exception is Japan, where a decline in output volatility
has been reversed since the late 1980s.) We then show that, even after
controlling for common time fixed effects, inflation volatility still
appears to be strongly related to output volatility.
As a matter of accounting, the decline in output volatility can be
traced either to changes in the composition of output or to changes in
the variances and covariances of its underlying components. We therefore
look at the components of GDP and find that, at least at the level of
disaggregation at which we operate, changes in composition explain
essentially none of the trend decline. The composition of GDP has
changed, but the effects of the various changes have mostly cancelled
each other out. We also find that, apart from a decrease in the
volatility of government spending early in the postwar period, most of
the decrease in output volatility can be traced to a decrease in both
consumption volatility and investment volatility, and more recently to a
change in inventory behavior, with inventory investment becoming more
countercyclical.
We conclude by discussing the agenda for further research. In
particular, it is clear that we have addressed only the proximate causes
of the volatility decline. The deeper causes, from changes in financial
markets to better countercyclical policy, remain to be identified.
The Decline in Output Volatility
Figure 1 shows the rolling standard deviation of quarterly real
output growth (measured at a quarterly rate) since the first quarter of
1952. The measure of output is chain-weighted GDP. We use a window of
twenty quarters, so that the standard deviation reported for quarter t
is the estimated standard deviation over quarters t - 19 to t. The first
available observation for chain-weighted GDP is 1947:1, and so the first
observation for the standard deviation of the growth rate is 1952:1. The
figure shows a clear decline in the standard deviation over time, from
about 1.5 percent a quarter in the early 1950s to less than 0.5 percent
in the late 1990s. This decline is not continuous, however. Volatility
increases from the late 1960s to the mid-1980s, and this is followed by
a sharp decline in the second half of the 1980s.
[Graph omitted]
One can think of other ways of measuring volatility. One
alternative is to look at the standard deviation of an output gap, for
example, the difference between the level of (the logarithm of) output
and a Hodrick-Prescott-filtered series.(2) Another is to look at annual
rather than quarterly changes in GDP. These alternatives yield very
similar conclusions. The basic reason is that the standard deviation of
quarterly output growth primarily reflects the high-frequency properties
of the series, which are largely invariant to the detrending method.
Changes in the Output Process
The natural next step is to think about the process generating
output movements over time and ask how it has changed. Does the lower
volatility of output reflect a lower standard deviation of output
shocks, or a change in the dynamic process through which these shocks
affect output, or both?
More concretely, assume that output growth follows an
autoregressive (AR) process given by
(1) ([[Delta]y.sub.t] - g) = a(L)([[Delta]y.sub.t-1] - g) +
[[Epsilon].sub.t],
where [y.sub.t] denotes the logarithm of output in quarter t,
[Delta] denotes a first difference, g is the underlying growth rate of
output, [[Epsilon].sub.t] is a white-noise shock with standard deviation
[[Sigma].sub.[Epsilon]], and a(L) is a lag polynomial.
The standard deviation of output [[Sigma].sub.y] then depends both
on the standard deviation [[Sigma].sub.[Epsilon]] and on the lag
polynomial a(L). If a(L) = a, for example, output growth follows a
first-order AR process, and [[Sigma].sub.y] = [[Sigma].sub.[Epsilon]] /
[square root of 1 - [a.sup.2]], so that the higher is a, the higher is
the standard deviation of output.
With these points in mind, we estimate equation 1 over a rolling
sample from 1952:1 on, again with a window of twenty quarters. We assume
the process to be first-order autoregressive, or AR(1); although this
does not fully capture the dynamics of output growth, it makes for an
easier interpretation of the changes in the process, and all of our
conclusions extend to higher-order AR processes. The top panel of figure
2 shows the mean growth rate thus estimated, the middle panel the
estimated AR(1) coefficient, and the bottom panel the estimated standard
deviation of the shock. The other two lines in each panel show
two-standard-deviation bands on each side of the estimate.
[Graphs omitted]
The conclusions to be drawn from figure 2 are straightforward.
Neither the growth rate nor the AR(1) coefficient shows clear movement
over time. The AR(1) coefficient is slightly lower at the end of the
1990s than in the rest of the sample, but the difference is not
significant.(3) The standard deviation of the regression residual shows
the same time pattern as the standard deviation of output growth in
figure 1. Indeed, if plotted on the same graph (not shown), their
profiles would be nearly identical. In short, the decrease in output
volatility appears to come from smaller shocks, rather than from a
decrease in the persistence of the effects of these shocks on output.
Back to the Length of Expansions
Having estimated the process for output growth, we can return to
the issue of the length of expansions. We proceed in two steps. First we
estimate two processes, one for the period 1947 to 1981, the other for
the period 1982 to 2000. We choose the split in the sample to coincide
with the peak of the cycle preceding the last two expansions. The intent
of the split is to capture the major changes in the process between the
start and the end of the sample.
The estimated equations for the two subperiods are
([[Delta]y.sub.t] - 0.87) = 0.31([[Delta]y.sub.t-1] - 0.87)+
[[Epsilon].sub.t], [[Sigma].sub.[Epsilon]] = 1.12 (for 1947-81)
and
([[Delta]y.sub.t] - 0.85) = 0.48([[Delta]y.sub.t-1] - 0.85)+
[[Epsilon].sub.t], [[Sigma].sub.[Epsilon]] = 0.56 (for 1982-2000).
Using the first estimated equation, we generate a sequence of
100,000 observations for output growth, based on draws of the shocks
from a normal distribution. Following a long tradition of using a simple
rule to approximate the dating of recessions by the National Bureau of
Economic Research (NBER), we define the beginning of a recession as two
consecutive quarters of negative growth. Similarly, we define the
beginning of an expansion as two consecutive quarters of positive growth
following a recession. We then compute the mean and median lengths of
expansions in the sample of 100,000 observations. Finally, we repeat the
process using the second estimated equation.(4)
The results are shown in table 1. The estimates are seventeen and
thirteen quarters for the mean and the median expansion length,
respectively, for the first subsample; and fifty-one and thirty-five
quarters for the second subsample. These means compare with actual mean
expansion lengths of nineteen quarters for 1950:1 to 1981:4 (with
recessions defined by the same rule as in the simulation, not by NBER
dating) and thirty-six quarters for 1982:1 to 2000:4 (but with the
second expansion not having ended yet). In other words, the differences
between the two estimated AR processes account well for the increase in
expansion length from the first to the second sample.
Table 1. Actual and Simulated Lengths of Expansions, 1947-2000
1947-81 1982-2000
Item Mean Median Mean Median
Actual 19 15 36 n.a.
Simulated(a) 17 13 51 35
Switching growth rate 17 12 55 38
Switching AR(1) coefficient 15 11 83 55
Switching volatility 99 67 14 11
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from Bureau of Economic
Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts.
(a.) Using parameters for each period that are estimated from actual
data from that period. Additional simulations are performed switching
one parameter with its opposite-period counterpart, leaving all other
parameters unchanged.
To show which parameter changes are responsible for this increase,
we next show the results of switching either the estimated mean growth
rate, or the AR(1) coefficient, or the standard deviation of the shocks,
across the two samples. Not surprisingly, given that the growth rates are nearly the same in the two samples, switching them has no effect on
the length of expansions. Switching the AR(1) coefficients leads to
shorter expansions in the first subsample (because the effect of a
negative shock on output growth is now more persistent, making it more
likely that output will decrease for two quarters in a row), and longer
ones in the second. But nearly all the action comes from switching
standard deviations. If the standard deviation had remained the same as
in the first subsample, the mean length of expansions would now be only
fourteen quarters, and the median eleven quarters. In short, the large
decrease in the standard deviation of output shocks is at the root of
the two long expansions the United States has recently experienced. And
unless this changes, expansions are likely to be much longer in the
future than they were in the past.
Are Recessions Special?
A widespread view of recessions and of output volatility holds that
the estimation and the exercise we carried out in the previous section
are largely tautological at best, and misleading at worst. According to that view, recessions are largely the result of infrequent large
shocks--indeed, sufficiently large and identifiable that they often have
names: the first and second oil shocks, the Volcker disinflation, and so
on. These shocks, in this view, dominate output volatility, and
therefore there is no great mystery in the measured decline in output
volatility. We simply have not had large shocks over the last two
decades.(5)
To see whether this is indeed what has been going on, we explore
two approaches.(6) First, we look at what happens to our measure of
volatility if we include a recession dummy. Second, we look for signs of
large shocks, and associated skewness and excess kurtosis, in the
relevant distributions. Both approaches yield similar conclusions. The
measured decline in output volatility is not due to the absence of large
shocks over the last twenty years. What it captures instead is the
decline in the volatility of "routine" quarter-to-quarter
changes in GDP growth.
If the decline in volatility simply reflected the absence of large
negative shocks and associated recessions, excluding recessions would
eliminate our finding of a decline in output volatility. Indeed,
excluding recessions from the sample is clearly too strong a correction
under our null hypothesis. It corresponds to eliminating large negative
realizations just because they happen to be large and negative. But if a
decrease in volatility remains even after this overly strong correction,
it makes for convincing evidence.
To implement this approach, we reestimate the same rolling AR
regressions as before, but we allow for the presence of a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 in each quarter of an NBER-dated recession.
The resulting time series for the estimated standard deviation of the
residual is plotted in figure 3, together with, for ease of comparison,
the standard deviation obtained without a recession dummy (from figure
2).(7) The results are quite clear. Output volatility is indeed lower in
recessions (by construction). But the general pattern is very similar,
with a clear trend downward, from roughly 1.2 percent a quarter at the
start of the sample to 0.4 percent at the end.
[Graph omitted]
The other approach is to actually look for signs of infrequent,
large shocks. For example, if the economy is subject to two types of
shocks, one frequent and small, the other infrequent and large, we would
expect the distribution of output growth to exhibit either skewness or
excess kurtosis, or both. It would exhibit skewness if large, infrequent
shocks are typically negative, and excess kurtosis if such shocks are
equally likely to be positive or negative. Other, more complex models of
recessions have similar implications. Although, from the Wold
representation theorem, we know that even these models are still
consistent with the linear representation given by equation 1, the
residuals are likely also to exhibit either skewness or excess
kurtosis.(8)
This suggests looking at the skewness and excess kurtosis of
[[Epsilon].sub.t], the residual obtained from the estimation of equation
1. The results are shown in figure 4. Each point represents the estimate
of skewness (top panel) or excess kurtosis (bottom panel) of the
residual from estimation of an AR(1) process over the current and
previous nineteen quarters. The two panels also show the standard 95
percent confidence bands for the hypotheses that the true measure of
skewness or excess kurtosis equals zero. The two panels yield similar
conclusions. Except for a brief period during the 1980 recession, there
is little evidence of either significant skewness or significant excess
kurtosis.(9)
[Graphs omitted]
We have also explored other approaches. Following Blanchard and
Mark Watson,(10) we estimated a specification in which the output shock
is assumed to be the sum of two underlying shocks, one drawn every
period from a normal distribution, the other equal to zero with
probability (1 - p) and drawn from a normal distribution with larger
variance, with probability p. We could not reject the hypothesis that p
was equal to zero, and we could not find evidence of a decrease in p
over time. In other words, we could not find evidence that the decrease
in output volatility has been due to a decrease in the likelihood of
large shocks over time.(11)
Output Volatility and Inflation
Having established the basic fact, we now turn to its
interpretation. There are at least two ways to look at the path of
output volatility in figure 1 or, equivalently, at the path of the
standard deviation of the residual in figure 2, as the two are nearly
identical. The first, which we have implicitly relied on until now, is
to see the pattern as a trend decline, temporarily interrupted in the
1970s and early 1980s. This interpretation is shown in the top panel of
figure 5, which reproduces the path of the standard deviation of output
growth from figure 1 and draws in addition an estimated exponential trend over the period.
[Graphs omitted]
The second interpretation, which has been suggested in a number of
recent papers,(12) instead invokes a step decrease some time in the
early to mid-1980s. This interpretation is shown in the bottom panel of
figure 5, which shows how an estimated step function can also fit the
general pattern of volatility. Here the step function is drawn assuming
that the step decline occurs in 1986:1. The more careful econometric work of Margaret McConnell and Gabriel Perez-Quiros, who estimate rather
than assume the break date, finds a slightly earlier date, 1984:1, as
the most likely break point.(13)
This second interpretation suggests looking for factors in the
economic environment that changed around the mid-1980s. Plausible
candidates are an improvement in the conduct of monetary policy or
changes in inventory behavior.(14)
Under the first interpretation, however (which, we will argue, is
more likely to be the right one), one needs to look for two sets of
factors: those behind the underlying trend decline in volatility over
the last fifty years,(15) and those behind the interruption of that
trend in the 1970s. Put another way, the focus shifts from what happened
in the 1980s (to explain the step decline in volatility) to what
happened in the 1970s (to explain the interruption of the trend for a
bit more than a decade).
Inflation and Inflation Volatility
That the 1970s were different is not very controversial. The U.S.
economy was affected by major increases in the prices of raw materials,
including oil. Inflation increased, to return to a lower level only
after the disinflation of the early 1980s. That these shocks, and
perhaps inflation itself, may have led to more output volatility does
not seem implausible.
Figure 6 shows the relationship between inflation and output growth
volatility. The top panel plots output growth volatility against the
twenty-quarter rolling mean of the inflation rate, with inflation
measured using the GDP deflator. The bottom panel plots output
volatility against inflation volatility, both constructed as
twenty-quarter rolling standard deviations. All variables, including
mean inflation, are measured at quarterly rates.
[Graphs omitted]
The temporary increase in output volatility in the 1970s and early
1980s is clearly correlated with the temporary increase in the level of
inflation. Output volatility seems, however, more strongly related to
the volatility than to the level of inflation. Simple regressions of
output volatility on the level of inflation, inflation variability, and
an exponential time trend show all three factors to be significant, with
the level and the variability of inflation playing roughly similar roles
quantitatively, and the negative time trend remaining important and
statistically significant.(16)
Correlation between inflation and output volatility, however, does
not imply causality from inflation to output volatility. At least one
plausible alternative is that the correlation reflects a common
dependence of inflation and output volatility on third factors, such as
the supply shocks of the 1970s. Here international evidence can help.
First, and obviously, it can tell us whether the patterns observed in
the United States are representative of what happened to output
volatility, and to the relation between output and inflation volatility,
elsewhere. But also, if we are willing to assume that the supply shocks
of the 1970s were largely common across countries, then cross-country
evidence gives us a way of controlling for the presence of these shocks,
by treating them as fixed effects in a cross-country panel regression.
In other words, such a regression can help us establish the relationship
between output and inflation volatility, controlling for supply shocks.
With this in mind, we now turn to the evidence from the G-7 countries.
A Look at the Other Group of Seven Countries
Figure 7 shows the path of output volatility for all the G-7
countries. For clarity's sake, we have grouped the countries into
three panels: the United States, the United Kingdom, and Canada (top
panel); France, Germany, and Italy (middle panel); and Japan (bottom
panel). In each case the measure of output volatility is again the
five-year rolling standard deviation of output growth, using a window of
twenty quarters. Because the data we have start only in 1960 (in 1982
for Italy), the different measures are available only from 1965:1 on
(1987:1 for Italy), resulting in a shorter sample than the one used for
the United States above.
[Graphs omitted]
The top and the middle panels show that output growth volatility in
six of the G-7 countries has followed a roughly similar path over the
period. In all of these countries the standard deviation of output
growth has declined: whereas in the early 1960s it ranged from about 1.5
percent in Germany to a little below 1.0 percent in the United States,
by the late 1990s it was around 0.5 percent in all six countries. One of
the striking characteristics of these two panels is indeed how similar
the standard deviation of output growth is across these countries today.
The general decline and convergence suggest the presence of common,
long-lasting forces across countries. Looking more closely, however,
there are also clear differences across countries, especially in timing.
After the general increase of the early 1970s, the decrease in
volatility took place earlier in Germany, and later in Canada.
The only G-7 country where the pattern is clearly different is
Japan. After falling from the early 1960s to the late 1980s, the
standard deviation of Japanese output growth rose in the 1990s and is
now higher than it was at the start of the sample. To the extent that
this increase largely coincides with the long Japanese slump of the
1990s, it is tempting to search in that direction for an explanation.
For example, a decrease in liquid asset holdings by both firms and
consumers may have led to stronger effects of cash flows on consumption
and investment, leading to stronger multiplier effects of shocks on
output. The zero floor on nominal interest rates may have constrained monetary policy responses. We do not explore these hypotheses further in
this paper, but we find the coincidence of the long slump and the
increase in volatility intriguing and potentially useful in learning
what has happened in other countries.
Leaving Japan aside, we return to the relationship between output
volatility and inflation in the other six countries. To do so, we run
the following panel regression:
(2) [[Sigma].sub.yit] = [[Beta].sub.i] + [[Beta].sub.t] +
[a.sub.1][[bar][Pi].sub.it] + [a.sub.2][[Sigma].sub.[Pi]it] +
[[Epsilon].sub.it],
where i indexes countries and t time, so that the [[Beta].sub.i]s
are country fixed effects, the [[Beta].sub.t]s are time fixed effects,
[[Sigma].sub.y] and [[Sigma].sub.[Pi]] are rolling standard deviations
of output and inflation, and [bar][Pi] is a rolling mean of the
inflation rate.
If the effects of the supply shocks of the 1970s on output
volatility were indeed common across countries, this specification will
give us the relationship between output volatility and inflation
volatility, controlling for supply shocks. The assumption is probably
too strong, however: the effects of supply shocks were different across
countries, and these differences may well have been associated with
different paths through time of both the level and the volatility of
inflation. In this case the coefficient on inflation will still pick up
some of the effects of supply shocks. Nevertheless, even in this case,
this cross-country specification is an improvement over the U.S.
regression (in which we could not introduce fixed time effects)
presented earlier. (Note that, even under the assumption of common
supply shocks, this specification does not resolve other potential
identification problems. One of these is the possibility that the
relationship between output volatility and inflation volatility reflects
causality from output to inflation volatility, through the response of
monetary policy, or a dependence on other, third causes, such as an
improvement in the conduct of monetary policy leading to both lower
output volatility and lower inflation volatility.)
Estimation yields coefficients of [a.sub.1] = -0.02, with a t
statistic of -0.7, and [a.sub.2] = 0.67, with a t statistic of 13.7.
Thus it is inflation volatility, rather than the level of inflation,
that appears to matter, and to matter strongly. The best way to
summarize the implications of the regression is through the three panels
of figure 8. The top panel shows the actual and the fitted values of
output volatility for the United States (dropping [[bar][Pi].sub.it]
from the panel regression; nothing is changed by this). The conclusion
to be drawn is that the panel specification does a good job of fitting
the U.S. data.
[Graphs omitted]
The other two panels show how much of the variation derives from
movements in inflation, and how much is due to the common time
components. The second panel shows the fitted value of output volatility
(repeated from the first panel), together with the inflation component,
[a.sub.2][[Sigma].sub.[Pi]it]. This panel makes clear that the increase
in inflation volatility accounts for the reversal in trend from the
early 1970s to the early 1980s. The third panel shows the fitted value
of output volatility (again repeated from the first panel), together
with the common time component, [[Beta].sub.t]. This suggests a steady
underlying trend decrease from 1960 on.
In short, this decomposition suggests a trend decrease in output
volatility, temporarily interrupted by an increase in inflation
volatility. Under that interpretation, the sharp decline in output
volatility in the 1980s appears to be associated with a sharp decline in
inflation volatility at that time. To get a better understanding of both
the trend decrease and the temporary reversal in output volatility, the
next section goes one level down and looks at trends in the individual
components of GDP.
A Disaggregated Look
In his 1960 presidential address to the American Economic
Association, Arthur Burns argued that a trend decline in output
volatility was indeed under way.(17) Composition effects (including the
steady shift to services), improvements in capital markets, the
increasing ability of consumers to smooth consumption in the face of
variations in income, the increase in the income tax, and stronger
automatic stabilizers all led and, Burns argued, would continue to lead
to more economic stability.
He was clearly right about the trend. Was he right about the
channels? Here we make a first pass at the answer. From a statistical
accounting point of view, one can think of the volatility of output as
depending on three sets of factors: the volatility of its components,
their covariation, and their relative weights. We look at each in turn.
Volatility of Output Components
Take the standard decomposition of GDP by type of purchase and type
of purchaser: consumption, investment, government spending, net exports,
and inventory investment. Let each of these components, in real terms,
be denoted by [X.sub.i] so that
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [Y.sub.t] is real GDP, measured quarterly. For each component
we consider two measures of volatility.
The first is the same as for GDP earlier, namely, the rolling
standard deviation of the rate of growth of [X.sub.it], which we denote by [[Sigma].sub.xit]. This measure makes little sense, however, for
inventories and net exports, which change sign and are frequently close
to zero. Thus we construct the rolling standard deviation of growth for
consumption, investment, and government spending only.(18)
The second measures the volatility of a variable commonly called
the "growth contribution" of each component, which adjusts for
the share of the component in GDP. A very volatile component may have
little effect on overall output volatility if it accounts for a small
share of GDP. The variable is defined as [Delta][X.sub.it]/[Y.sub.t-1],
and our measure of volatility is once again the rolling standard
deviation. Note that this measure is well defined for all components of
GDP regardless of whether they change sign or are close to zero. Note
also that the variable can be rewritten as
([Delta][X.sub.it]/[X.sub.it-1])([X.sub.it-1]/[Y.sub.t-1], so that, if
the share is stable at high frequency, the standard deviation will be
roughly equal to the share of the component of GDP times the standard
deviation of that component's growth rate. For both volatility
measures, the window we use to compute standard deviations is again
twenty quarters. Rates of change are quarterly, not annual, rates.
The results are plotted in figures 9 and 10. The figures show that
the two measures move together at high frequency, reflecting the
stability of the shares.
[Graphs omitted]
From figure 9 we draw the following conclusions:
--The volatility of government spending (and of fiscal policy in
general) was very high during the Korean War. It fell rapidly in the
1950s and has remained low ever since.
--There is no clear trend in the volatility of net exports or in
the volatility of inventory investment, although the latter was low in
the 1990s. (This, together with the change in correlation reported
below, suggests a recent change in the behavior of inventory
investment.)
--Most of the trend decrease in output volatility can be traced to
a decrease in the volatility of consumption and investment. After a
large decrease in the 1950s, consumption volatility has continued to
decrease, from about 0.75 percent in the 1960s to 0.30 percent in the
late 1990s. The decrease in investment volatility has been more limited.
The standard deviation of our second measure is nearly the same in the
late 1990s as in the 1960s.
Given that much of the action comes from consumption and
investment, figure 10 goes one step further in the disaggregation, to
trace the volatility of the components of consumption and investment.
Relative declines in the volatility of all three components of
consumption--spending on durables, on nondurables, and on services--are
roughly similar. Their timing is slightly different, however, with much
of the trend reversal in consumption in the 1970s and the early 1980s
coming from consumption of services.
We think these are slightly surprising findings. One might have
expected improvements in financial markets to lead consumers to choose a
smoother consumption path, thus leading to smoother consumption of
services and nondurables. But one would also have expected an improved
ability to borrow and lend to lead to a stronger stock-flow adjustment
for purchases of durables, and thus potentially to more volatility of
durables purchases. This, however, does not seem to be the case.
The two series for investment volatility exhibit quite different
patterns. Nonresidential investment shows a steady decline and a limited
increase in the 1970s. Residential investment volatility shows a steady
increase from the 1950s to the mid-1980s and a sharp decrease after
that. The latter coincides with the elimination of interest rate
ceilings on savings and loan institutions (the end of Regulation Q),
making it a plausible candidate explanation.
Correlations of Output Components
The standard deviation of output depends not only on the standard
deviations of its components, but also on their correlations. To show
what has happened in this regard, we construct the correlation of each
component with final sales (GDP minus inventory investment) or, more
specifically, the correlation of [Delta][X.sub.it]/[Y.sub.t-1] with
[Delta] [S.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t-1], where [S.sub.t] is final sales. Again we
use a window of twenty quarters.
These results are shown in figure 11. The correlations change over
time (as we would expect if the subsamples are dominated by different
shocks, with different implications for the correlation between each
component and final sales). But except for one series, they do not show
clear trends. The exception is the correlation between inventory
investment and sales. Until the mid-1980s, inventory investment tended
to move with sales, leading to a higher variance of production than of
sales--a fact studied at length in the research on inventory behavior.
Since the mid-1980s, inventory investment has become countercyclical,
leading to a decline in the variance of output relative to sales. This
fact, which Kahn, McConnell, and Perez-Quiros have examined, must have
come from a change in the inventory management methods of firms. It is
clearly one of the factors behind the decrease in output volatility in
the 1980s, although only the last in a long series of structural
changes.(19)
[Graphs omitted]
Composition Effects
The composition of GDP has changed substantially over the last
fifty years. The three main changes, at the level of disaggregation
examined here, are an increase in the share of (high-volatility) fixed
nonresidential investment, from 9.4 percent of GDP in 1950 to 13.7
percent in 2000; a decrease in the share of nondurables consumption,
from 33.4 percent to 20.2 percent; and a mirror increase in the share of
(low-volatility) consumption of services, from 21.7 percent to 39.4
percent.
To characterize the effects of composition on output volatility, a
simple approach is to compute the volatility of a counterfactual series
for output growth, using 1947 shares rather than current shares to
weight the components. Specifically, we construct the counterfactual
output growth series as follows. Write the rate of growth of output as
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where the terms in the first sum are the terms that are always
positive, and the terms in the second sum are the terms that change sign
in the sample (net exports and inventory investment). We can rewrite this expression as
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[Alpha].sub.it-1] is the share of component i at time t - 1.
Once again, constructing [Delta][X.sub.jt]/[X.sub.jt-1] does not make
much sense for inventories and net exports, as they are frequently
around zero. Consequently, we treat them separately. We then construct
the counterfactual series for output growth as
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[Alpha].sub.i1947] is the 1947 share of component i. We then
construct rolling standard deviations for actual and counterfactual
output series. There is no need to present a figure, as the two series
are nearly indistinguishable. The different changes in composition
nearly offset each other, and the final values are within 0.05 percent
of each other. Composition effects therefore have little to do with the
general pattern of output volatility over the last fifty years.
Conclusions
We have documented the long and large decline in output volatility
over the last half-century. We have shown that this phenomenon does not
have one, but many proximate causes. Among them are a steady decrease in
investment volatility and, even more so, of consumption volatility; a
decrease in the volatility of government spending early on; and a change
from procyclical to countercyclical inventory investment in the 1990s.
Many questions remain, however.
The first set of questions concerns the deeper causes of the
decrease in volatility, from the role of policy (especially monetary
policy) to the role of structural changes (especially changes in
financial markets). Our findings suggest that monetary policy has played
a complex role. On the one hand, the trend decrease in output volatility
from 1950 on does not lend much support to the idea that what we are
seeing is primarily the result of a dramatic recent improvement in the
conduct of monetary policy--that is, of a Greenspan effect. On the
other, the dramatic decrease in output volatility in the mid-1980s can
be interpreted in two ways, both related to monetary policy.
The first is that this decrease was indeed the result of smarter
countercyclical monetary policy, leading to better output stabilization
from the 1980s on. This explanation runs into a puzzle, however. Given
the lags in the effects of monetary policy on output, one would have
expected better monetary policy to show up primarily as shorter-lived
effects of shocks on output, and thus as a decrease in the AR(1)
coefficient in the univariate AR representation. There is no evidence
that this has been the case.(20) The other interpretation is that the
decrease in output volatility was associated with--and may have been
largely caused by--the decrease in inflation volatility that occurred
around the same time. But even this second interpretation implies a role
for monetary policy. The increased stability of inflation is likely to
be have been due, in large part, to better monetary policy.
Our findings also suggest a role for improvements in financial
markets in reducing consumption and investment volatility. But here
again the argument is not straightforward. On theoretical grounds, it is
not obvious that more efficient financial markets should lead to lower
consumption volatility. Although, for given interest rates, they
plausibly lead to a decrease in the volatility of consumption services
and nondurables, they also allow consumers to adjust faster toward their
desired stock of durables, leading, other things equal, to more
volatility of spending on consumer durables. The same argument applies
to investment. The evidence is, however, of a decrease in volatility in
all components of consumption and investment.
The issue of the relative roles of monetary policy and financial
market improvements in reducing output volatility is a fascinating one.
In that respect, developments in Japan in the 1990s are both intriguing
and inconclusive. As we saw, output volatility increased substantially
in Japan in the 1990s. But was that increase due to monetary policy or
to changes in financial markets (or to something else)? The answer is
far from obvious. Monetary policy, both current and anticipated, was
clearly limited by the constraint that interest rates be
nonnegative--the liquidity trap. And because of the problems Japanese
banks were facing, intermediation was clearly disrupted. Only a more
disaggregated examination will help attribute blame.
A second set of issues concerns the implications of our findings.
We feel reasonably confident in predicting from our results that the
increase in the length of expansions is here to stay. (This, however, is
not a prediction that the United States will not go through a recession
in the near future, nor do we claim that the New Economy has eliminated
the business cycle.) The decrease in output volatility appears
sufficiently steady and broad based that a major reversal appears
unlikely. This implies a much smaller likelihood of recessions.
Lower output volatility suggests lower risk, and thus changes in
risk premiums, in precautionary saving, and so on. Interestingly,
however, the decrease in output volatility has not been reflected in a
parallel decrease in asset price volatility. As others have documented,
there is little evidence of a trend in the volatility of the Dow Jones
Industrial Average.(21) Ultimately, of course, what matters is not
aggregate risk but the risk borne by individuals. We do not know what
has happened to the volatility of idiosyncratic shocks during the
period. We intend to explore all these avenues in the near future.
(1.) What has happened to output volatility over a much longer time
span is the subject of a well-known debate, which this paper does not
revisit. See Romer (1986), Weir (1986), and Balke and Gordon (1989).
(2.) This is the approach taken by Taylor (2000).
(3.) A perhaps obvious point: changes in the estimated AR(1)
coefficient for this univariate representation of output growth do not
imply a change in the dynamic structure of the economy. Output movements
come from many underlying shocks, each with its own dynamic effects. At
different times, different shocks may dominate the (short) subsample
used for estimation, leading to different estimated univariate dynamics
of output.
(4.) Note that the average length of expansions is a very nonlinear function of the underlying parameters of the AR process. By
construction, an expansion ends when a recession starts; under our
definition of a recession, this requires two consecutive quarters of
negative growth. The probability of such an event depends nonlinearly on
the average growth rate, the standard deviation of the residual, and the
AR(1) coefficient. If, for example, the standard deviation is far below
the average growth rate, small changes in the standard deviation will
have little effect on the probability of a recession. If it is closer,
the same small changes will have a substantial impact on the probability
of a recession, and in turn on the length of expansions.
(5.) This view was forcefully communicated to us by the editors at
the start of this project.
(6.) Obviously, the fact that recessions are typically associated
with negative realizations of the output process is an implication of
the definition of a recession, not an indication that recessions are
special in any particular way. In the same way, the fact that recessions
often come with unusually large negative realizations of the shocks also
follows from the definition of the recession, and from the fact that the
distribution of shocks, conditional on being in a recession, implies a
higher probability of large negative shocks.
(7.) Introducing a dummy for recessions can be thought of as a way
of allowing for a lower mean growth rate in recessions. In this sense,
this estimation is in the spirit of the Markov switching process
estimated by Hamilton (1989) for U.S. GDP.
(8.) Take, for example, the idea that serial correlation of output
is greater in expansions than in recessions, clearly a nonlinear
feature. Capture this by assuming that output growth is a two-state
Markov process, with a high probability that output growth will remain
high if it is initially high, and a low probability that output growth
will remain low if initially low. It is easy to show that this Markov
process will have an AR(1) representation given by equation 1, with the
distribution of the residual skewed so that most residuals are small and
positive, but with a long negative tail associated with recessions.
(9.) Under the assumption that large shocks are indeed infrequent,
the use of a short window (twenty quarters) implies that there are many
subsample periods during which no large shock occurs. Those subsamples
will not show evidence of skewness or excess kurtosis. But we would
expect many or most recessions to be associated with measured skewness
or excess kurtosis. This does not appear to be the case. Nor do we see
more evidence of skewness or excess kurtosis if we use a longer window.
Over the sample as a whole, there is indeed evidence of significant
excess kurtosis, but this appears simply to be due to the decrease in
the standard deviation over time. (The distribution of draws from a set
of normal distributions with different variances will exhibit excess
kurtosis.) Other evidence that skewness and excess kurtosis are not
important here is that the earlier simulation results on expansion
length are roughly unaffected if we draw shocks by sampling with
replacement from the estimated residuals rather than from a normal
distribution, as we did in our stochastic simulations earlier.
(10.) Blanchard and Watson (1986).
(11.) One hypothesis is that there are large shocks but that their
effects appear over a few quarters, making them more difficult to
detect. If this were the case, the results of our exercise would be very
different if we were to use lower-frequency data. In fact, the results
are nearly identical when using annual rather than quarterly data.
(12.) In particular, McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000).
(13.) The difference comes from our use of a rolling window to
capture volatility. A decline in 1984:1 will not necessarily show up
until enough earlier observations have dropped out of the
window--something that happened around 1986:1.
(14.) The first hypothesis is argued by, for example, Taylor
(2000), and the second by Kahn, McConnell, and Perez-Quiros (2001).
(15.) Or, indeed, over the past century, if one takes a longer
view, informed by evidence from earlier research on volatility since the
late 1800s.
(16.) One worry is that measurement noise in the decomposition of
nominal GDP will create a spurious positive correlation between output
and inflation volatility. But the results are very similar if we use the
consumer price index, where the issue is likely to be less important.
Another problem with regressions of this kind is the use of moving
averages for standard deviations and means on both the left- and the
right-hand sides. Estimation of a potentially more appropriate GARCH (generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity) model for
output growth, allowing the variance of output shocks to be a function
of inflation volatility, the inflation level, and a time trend, yields
very similar results.
(17.) Burns (1960).
(18.) In parallel with our exploration of GDP, we have estimated AR
processes for each component. Although we do not present the results
here, the general conclusion is the same as for GDP. For the most part,
the decrease in volatility comes from a decrease in the volatility of
the shocks rather than from a change in dynamics.
(19.) There is a puzzle here as well. The change in correlation
roughly coincides with the introduction of just-in-time inventory
management methods, which have led to lower inventory-to-sales ratios.
It is not clear, however, why they should have led the correlation to
change from positive to negative. Better tracking and forecasting of
sales, and the ability to maintain a stable inventory-to-sales ratio,
should lead to more procyclical, not less procyclical, inventory
investment.
(20.) A more sophisticated argument is that, despite the lags in
monetary policy, better policy might have reduced the variance of
measured output shocks, leading agents to expect shorter-lived effects
of the underlying shocks on GDP, and thus to react less to these shocks
in the first place. But even in this case, better policy should be
reflected both in a smaller variance of measured output shocks and in
shorter-lasting effects of shocks on output--and thus in a decrease in
the AR(1) coefficient.
(21.) This is not necessarily a puzzle. If we think of the better
use of monetary policy as one of the factors behind the decrease in
output volatility, stronger stabilization efforts may require sharper
movements in interest rates, and thus potentially stronger movements in
asset prices. There is, however, little evidence of increased volatility
in real interest rates.
Comment and Discussion
Benjamin M. Friedman: The goal of Olivier Blanchard and John
Simon's paper is to study the business cycle, focusing in
particular on aggregate real output in the United States. Their
principal finding is that the shocks affecting output growth have become
less volatile in recent years. The standard error of the autoregression
that serves as their central vehicle of analysis, estimated on a
rolling-sample basis, has declined from about 1 percent a quarter (4
percent annualized), on average from the 1950s through the mid-1980s, to
roughly 1/2 percent a quarter since then. Because the average growth
rate of real output for the entire sample, from 1947 through 2000, is
0.9 percent a quarter, this sharp decline in the absolute magnitude of
the estimated shocks obviously means that lately there have been fewer
quarters when the measured growth rate has been less than zero. To the
extent that movements of real GDP as measured by the U.S. Department of
Commerce capture the broadly based fluctuations in nonfinancial economic
activity that the NBER business cycle dating process emphasizes, there
have therefore been fewer recessions.
The immediate question is what to make of this finding. In their
introduction the authors say that their paper will "take up the
question of whether recessions are special.... whether what we have seen
over the last twenty years is simply the absence of large shocks and
nothing more." They preview their conclusion as follows: "...
this is not the case. The measured decrease in output volatility has
little to do with the absence of large shocks in the recent past."
Later on they summarize their results by stating, "The measured
decline in output volatility is not due to the absence of large shocks
over the past twenty years. What it captures instead is the decline in
the volatility of `routine' quarter-to-quarter changes in GDP
growth."
To be sure, one should not read the results of Blanchard and
Simon's paper to say that the infrequency of recessions in the
United States over the last two decades has reflected the absence of
large shocks and nothing more. But the absence of large shocks certainly
is a major part of what the authors have to report. Inspection of the
estimated residuals from the authors' equation (which Olivier
Blanchard was kind enough to provide to me) shows that, without
exception, every one of the nine official NBER recessions in the United
States since World War II has involved at least one negative residual
larger (in absolute value) than the 0.9 percent mean quarterly growth
rate of real output. And in the past there were plenty of large
residuals other than just during recession episodes. Including both
positives and negatives, from 1947 through 1984 their results show
fifty-eight estimated residuals larger than 0.9 percent.
By contrast, since 1985 only four of their estimated quarterly
residuals have exceeded 0.9 percent; two of these were positive and two
negative. And one of the two large negatives occurred during the lone
recession the United States has experienced during these years, that of
1990-91. (The other was in the first quarter of 1993.) Blanchard and
Simon's basic point is that output has become less volatile, and
this is surely true. But there is no way to duck the fact that, in their
estimated autoregression, the absence of recessions is very much
associated with the absence of large negative shocks.
Yet another way of looking at the data, which the authors do not
discuss, leads to the same conclusion. It is conventional to estimate
regressions for real output using quarterly data, presumably because the
Commerce Department reports GDP this way. But no economic theory of
which I am aware guarantees that the calendar quarter is the right level
of time aggregation for investigating the kinds of shocks that matter
for business cycles. A single large shock spread out over more than a
single measured quarter would look in quarterly observations like a
series of smaller shocks occurring over a sequence of consecutive
quarters.
Blanchard and Simon's autoregression exhibits no meaningful
serial correlation. (The Durbin-Watson statistic is a comforting 2.05.)
Nonetheless, from time to time there are runs of consecutive estimated
negative residuals, and these runs are also very much part of the story
of recessions. Of the nine recorded postwar recessions, seven have
involved three or more consecutive negative residuals, and six of those
seven have involved four or more negative residuals in succession. (The
only two exceptions each involved a "near run," in which four
out of five consecutive residuals were negative.) Moreover, the
identification of a recession with a run of negative Blanchard-Simon
residuals is not only almost necessary, but almost sufficient as well.
Only once in their sample spanning more than 200 quarterly observations
does their regression exhibit three successive negative residuals
outside of an NBER recession period. And that episode was during 1989,
which numerous analyses have indicated was unusual, and in particular
recession-like, in a variety of ways.(1)
In sum, whether the matter is to be framed in terms of the absence
of large shocks or more generically in terms of reduced volatility, the
result from this part of the paper is clear: the time-series behavior of
output in the United States has changed (or, to anticipate the
discussion below, has been changing), and that change has a lot to do
with the recent infrequency of recessions. The broader question to be
put to this part of Blanchard and Simon's analysis, however, is,
What is learned from viewing the time series of real output in this
way--that is, through the lens of their first-order autoregression? The
regression, estimated over the full sample, has an adjusted [R.sub.2] of
0.11. The coefficient on the lagged dependent variable is 0.34. (These
figures are not reported in the paper. I am again grateful to Olivier
Blanchard for providing them.) Hence the fitted value of real output
growth for each quarter is simply the 0.9 percent mean adjusted by
one-third of whatever was the difference between the measured growth
rate and this mean in the previous quarter. All else is
"shocks." To put the question in more quantitative terms, What
do we learn from excluding this 11 percent of the variation of real
output growth, and focusing our attention on the remaining 89 percent,
that we did not already know from looking at real output growth
itself--as, indeed, Blanchard and Simon do in much of the rest of the
paper?
The most interesting part of Blanchard and Simon's paper, and
the part that I think offers the greatest promise for future research,
is the demonstration that the decline in the volatility of output growth
(focusing now on the raw series, not the estimated autoregression
residuals) roughly lines up with a decline in the volatility of price
inflation. In particular, the match-up with output volatility is
distinctly better for the volatility of inflation than for the mean of
inflation. Taking the research in this direction opens room to
investigate (although the authors do not do so) how familiar, systematic
forces like monetary and fiscal policies, and understandable categories
of shocks like energy price movements and other supply shocks, can enter
the central story of business cycles.
For example, one longstanding view of how recessions come about in
the postwar U.S. economy is that the Federal Reserve makes them happen,
either deliberately or by overshooting the mark, but in either case
through the application of tight monetary policy. The presumed
motivation for that tight policy is, of course, the need to prevent
inflation from developing or to slow an inflation that has already
begun. Hence recessions should be observed following periods in which
monetary and fiscal policies have stimulated the economy beyond its
productive capacity, or in which exogenous movements in consumer
spending or business investment (due to a surge of confidence, for
example) have done the same, or perhaps both. A separate but highly
similar view is that recessions follow after an adverse shock, such as a
rise in oil prices, has reduced the economy's ability to produce
outputs from inputs at any given cost, and the central bank chooses not
to allow rising prices to absorb the entire backshift in the aggregate
supply curve.
The rough correspondence shown in the lower panel of the
authors' figure 6 is consistent with either of these accounts of
how recessions occur, both of which assign a central role to monetary
policy reacting to either the reality or the anticipation of inflation.
The correspondence is also consistent with a quite different view,
however: that recessions come and go for reasons entirely independent of
inflation, and that it is the fluctuation of output, sometimes above the
economy's productive capacity and sometimes below, that then causes
inflation to move up or down.
As Blanchard and Simon rightly point out, in this context
correlation does not necessarily imply causality. Their response to this
problem is to turn to evidence from the other G-7 economies, using a
panel regression (omitting Japan) of moving-average output volatility on
moving-average inflation volatility and the moving-average inflation
mean, allowing for time effects. The result mirrors the finding for the
United States alone that is evident from figure 6: output volatility is
systematically related to inflation volatility, not to the inflation
mean.
But the panel regression resolves the causality question no better
than a single equation for the United States would--nor, for that
matter, any better than does simple inspection of figure 6. The
authors' results are consistent with the interpretation that
shocks, some common across all six countries and some not, create
inflation; that central banks respond with tight monetary policies that
slow output growth; and that these episodes of tight monetary policy in
turn render output more volatile (perhaps in a way that involves
out-and-out recessions, perhaps not). But the results are also
consistent with the alternative account whereby movements in output
relative to capacity trigger movements in inflation, so that independent
forces that sometimes render output more volatile then cause inflation
to be more volatile as well.
The authors' aim in turning to the panel regression is to
control for any such independent forces--for example, oil price
shocks--that act in common across the six included economies. It is
instructive that the results hold up when they do so. But controlling
for common supply effects (and common demand effects, too) is not the
same as resolving the causality issue. On the assumption that the
authors are right that what is involved here is inflation volatility and
not inflation itself, the panel regression is no more informative than a
single-country regression on the question of whether we should be
regressing output volatility on inflation volatility or vice versa.
Finally, the analysis at the end of the paper, focusing on changes
in the time-series behavior of individual components of aggregate
spending (now again for the United States only) is instructive in its
own right. But it, too, cannot resolve the more interesting question of
whether output volatility is driving inflation volatility or vice versa.
At first blush, the finding that all major components of U.S. GDP have
shown less volatility in recent years lends credence to the story that
places Federal Reserve (over)reaction to inflation at the heart of the
matter. Otherwise, why would all of the components have become less
volatile over the last fifty years? Exogenous shocks to spending, such
as changes in consumer confidence or in the "animal spirits"
of entrepreneurs, would more likely have affected different components
of spending differently.
On closer inspection, however, the timing of the decline in
volatility does turn out to vary from one component of GDP to another.
Moreover, Blanchard and Simon themselves identify some, but far from
all, of the structural changes in the U.S. economy that plausibly have
accounted for the most salient reductions in output volatility for
reasons other than the response of monetary policy to inflation. For
example, the sharp decline in the volatility of homebuilding after the
early 1980s nicely corresponds to the removal of Regulation Q interest
ceilings (which they mention) and the development of the secondary
market for home mortgages (which they do not). The steep decline in the
volatility of consumer durables purchases after the Korean War similarly
corresponds to the removal of Regulation W controls on consumer
financing (which they also do not mention). Perhaps the most interesting
single element of what the authors find is the dramatic change in
inventory behavior, in the mid-1980s, from what used to be production
unsmoothing--a phenomenon that runs counter to standard economic
theory--to production smoothing. As they rightly point out, this
development in particular has potentially important implications in the
context of many other discussions not pursued here.
But this component-by-component dissection of real GDP growth also
makes the pattern that Blanchard and Simon see in the data and choose to
emphasize throughout the paper--a trend decline in output volatility
throughout their half-century-long sample period, "temporarily
interrupted in the 1970s and 1980s"--appear less satisfactory as a
comprehensive description of what has happened. The volatility of
spending on durable consumption and that of both residential and
nonresidential investment initially declined but then began to increase
again starting around 1965. Volatility of services consumption began a
similar reversal in either 1967 or 1971, depending on how one reads the
authors' figure 10, reached a peak in 1975, then declined to an
even lower level through 1990, and finally rose again through the
mid-1990s. To be explicit, in each of these cases the midsample reversal
predated the first OPEC oil price increase and the other familiar supply
shocks of the 1970s. Of the five components of GDP shown in figure 10,
only for nondurable consumption does the movement of volatility over
time look much like a declining trend throughout, with an interruption
beginning in the 1970s and peaking in the mid-1980s.
The subject of this paper is important. Within our lifetimes the
death of the business cycle has been foretold as often as the coming of
the messiah (perhaps because, in so many people's minds, the two
are identical). Every run of a few good years produces much talk, much
of it from the business community and much of it fatuous, to the effect
that new techniques of business management, or improved understanding on
the part of policymakers, has relegated business cycles to the realm of
historians. Perhaps some day this will come to pass. In the meanwhile,
as the circumstances in which this panel met remind us, all it takes is
a whiff of slowdown--companies that fail to meet overly optimistic earnings projections, or a down stock market, or an easing in the pace
of industrial production or housing starts or retail sales--and all such
talk is readily forgotten.
The more important questions, however--those that form the proper
basis for economic inquiry, as in this paper--persist. The world does
not always remain the same. Carefully documenting how it has changed, or
is changing, is an important task for economists. So is seeking to
understand the origins of those changes. The paper by Blanchard and
Simon, especially in its highlighting of the relationship between
declining output volatility and declining inflation volatility both in
the United States and elsewhere, points toward a useful direction in
which to look.
General discussion: Several participants discussed how much of the
credit for decreased output volatility should be ascribed to better luck
and how much to policy. Gregory Mankiw suggested that the behavior of
food and energy prices during the 1970s was a piece of bad luck, which
turned into good luck in the 1990s. He believed the volatility of food
and energy prices relative to those of other goods, a measure of supply
shocks, had decreased in the past ten or fifteen years and was
responsible for some of the increase in stability. On the other hand, he
acknowledged, a number of studies have found that interest rates are
much more responsive to inflation than they were in the past, suggesting
that better monetary policy should also get part of the credit.
Alan Blinder agreed that improved Federal Reserve behavior is a
candidate for explaining the dramatic reduction in volatility in the
second half of the 1980s. But, he suggested, this is not a fully
satisfactory way to view the performance of policy. One could argue that
then--Fed Chairman Paul Volcker's crackdown on inflation in the
early 1980s was important in creating a more stable environment later in
the decade, but it was also a large shock to output, increasing
volatility in the short run. Blinder also found it hard to understand
the precise timing of the abrupt decline in volatility.
Robert Gordon commented that the drop in volatility was likely to
be in part an artifact of using rolling regressions to estimate the
output process. A large fluctuation in output has a large effect on
estimated volatility at the time it occurs and an opposite effect of the
same magnitude when it drops out of the sample five years later. The
decline in volatility looks like a reflection of the dramatic inventory
swing between the fourth quarter of 1982 and the first quarter of 1983.
Hence not too much should be made of the precise timing of changes in
volatility. William Brainard suggested that this problem could be
avoided by using an explicitly time-varying parameter model rather than
rolling regressions.
Gordon observed further that the suggestion of a causal relation
running from inflation volatility to output volatility had a taste of
deja vu, recalling a famous New York Times headline of the mid-1970s:
"Inflation triggers recession." We have learned that not all
price shocks are adverse: some are benign, decreasing rather than
raising volatility. In recent years we have experienced falling real
import prices, an acceleration in the rate of decline of computer prices
(and higher productivity growth), and, for a while, falling real energy
and medical care prices. These have created an environment in which the
Federal Reserve could refrain from its normal response to rapid output
growth, which in past circumstances would have been to create a spike in
short-term interest rates, bringing on the next recession.
Several panelists wondered how sensitive the authors' results
were to particular observations or assumptions about the underlying
processes. Gordon would have preferred to omit the Korean War episode,
because consumption and government spending during that period were too
peculiar (and highly correlated) to be of general significance. George
Perry questioned the authors' decision to divide their sample
period into halves and assume a constant rate of growth for each. He
noted that many observers thought the underlying growth rate had varied
significantly within each of the two subperiods. Since the probability
of a recession and the expected length of an expansion are quite
sensitive to this rate of growth, such a refinement might have resulted
in a quite different picture. For example, it seems plausible that the
growth rate at the end of the 1960s was relatively high; hence,
according to the model, falling into a recession in 1970 was an
extremely low probability event.
Edmund Phelps found anomalous the paper's conclusion that
volatility is much lower than it used to be, given that we recently
experienced one of the most powerful booms of the last 100 years. Robert
Hall agreed: he found it hard to say we have been in a period of low
volatility when recent five- and ten-year forecast errors have been
huge. Hall concluded that the focus of the paper's analysis was on
movements in real GDP of too high frequency, and he thought it would be
more appropriate to look at the medium-frequency movements. He also
cautioned against identifying a decline in volatility on the basis of a
small sample; after all, from 1875 to 1929 volatility had decreased
before shooting up during the 1929 crisis. Robert Shimer suggested that
inflation and output variability may have common determinants (such as
the 1970s oil shock) and that it would have been more appropriate to
treat both as dependent variables rather than try to explain one with
the other.
Gordon and Hall expressed surprise at the insignificant effect of
changes in the composition of output over a period that has seen a
massive shift from factory work to desk jobs. Phelps would have liked to
have seen an analysis of changes in the volatility of the employment (or
the unemployment) rate, both for its intrinsic interest and as a
possible explanation of changes in output volatility. He conjectured
that employment has become a more sluggish variable, in part because of
changes in the composition of output, in part because of institutional
changes, and in part because of developments that we need to understand
better, such as the fact that quit rates have decreased. Perry was
interested in the results on inventory, where it appeared the
correlation with output has reversed. If, as is widely believed, firms
are getting much better at anticipating sales and adjusting production
quickly, one might have expected the correlation to have become more
positive.
Susan Collins thought that a more detailed look at the components
of output (investment, inventory, and so forth) in European countries
would be informative. She believed that a quite different picture would
emerge from that in the United States in the aggregate.
References
Balke, Nathan S., and Robert J. Gordon. 1989. "The Estimation
of Prewar Gross National Product: Methodology and New Evidence."
Journal of Political Economy 97(1): 38-92.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Mark Watson. 1986. "Are Business
Cycles All Alike?" In The American Business Cycle: Continuity and
Change, edited by Robert J. Gordon. University of Chicago Press.
Burns, Arthur F. 1960. "Progress Towards Economic
Stability." American Economic Review 50(1): 1-19.
Hamilton, James D. 1989. "A New Approach to the Economic
Analysis of Non-stationary Time Series and the Business Cycle."
Econometrica 57(2): 357-84.
Kahn, James, Margaret M. McConnell, and Gabriel Perez-Quiros. 2001.
"The Reduced Volatility of the U.S. Economy: Policy or
Progress?" Unpublished paper. Federal Reserve Bank of New York (March).
McConnell, Margaret M., and Gabriel Perez-Quiros. 2000.
"Output Fluctuations in the United States: What Has Changed Since
the Early 1980's?" American Economic Review 90(5): 1464-76.
Perry, George L., and Charles L. Schultze. 1993. "Was This
Recession Different? Are They All Different?" BPEA, 1: 1993,
145-95.
Romer, Christina D. 1986. "Is the Stabilization of the Postwar
Economy a Figment of the Data?" American Economic Review 76(3):
314-34.
Simon, John A. 2000. "Essays in Empirical
Macroeconomics." Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
Taylor, John B. 2000. "Remarks for the Panel Discussion on
`Recent Changes in Trend and Cycle.'" Paper prepared for the
conference on Structural Change and Monetary Policy, sponsored by the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and the Stanford Institute for
Economic Policy Research, March 3-4.
Weir, David R. 1986. "The Reliability of Historical
Macroeconomic Data for Comparing Cyclical Stability." Journal of
Economic History 46(2): 323-65.
We thank Benjamin Friedman for his comments, as well as Robert
Solow and participants in the MIT macro lunch. This paper builds on John
Simon's doctoral thesis (Simon, 2000). The views expressed are our
own and should not be attributed to the Reserve Bank of Australia.