Home Economics.
Henderson, David R.
BILL BRYSON. At Home: A Short History of Private Life. DOUBLEDAY.
497 PAGES. $28.95
I HAVE LONG ENJOYED Bill Bryson's books on travel. He has a
rare ability to both entertain his readers, often with side-split-ting
humor, and get them interested in the history of the places he travels.
My favorite, in part because of the humor, is In a Sunburned Country,
his book on Australia. But if I were to judge his books solely on the
importance of the history he uncovers, my favorite, by far, would be his
latest, At Home: A Short History of Private Life.
Bryson has pulled off a marvelous feat. He devotes almost every
chapter to a room in his Victorian house in England. He then considers
why the room is the way it is and what preceded it. In doing so he
produces an important economic history, only some of which will be
familiar to economic historians and almost all of which will be
unfamiliar to pretty much everyone else. A large percentage of it is
important, for two reasons; One, you get to pinch yourself, realizing
just how wealthy you are; and two, you get a better understanding than
you'll get from almost any high school or college history textbook
of the economic progress that made you wealthy. Not surprisingly, given
that I'm an economist and Bryson isn't, I have a few
criticisms of places where he misleads by commission or omission. But At
Home's net effect on readers is likely to be a huge increase in
understanding and appreciation of how we got to where we are.
One of Bryson's most striking descriptions is about the life
of a servant when houses had two stories but no running water. The worst
days for the servant were when family members or guests wished to take a
bath. Bryson writes:
A gallon of water weighs eight pounds, and a typical bath held
forty-five gallons, all of which had to be heated in the kitchen and
brought up in special cans--and there might be two dozen or more
baths to fill of an evening.
Nor did servants seem to get much appreciation from their
mistresses. Although Bryson specifies too infrequently the time periods
of which he writes, one gets the impression that this attitude to
servants lasted into the 20th century. He quotes two 20th-century
mistresses' complaints about servants. Virginia Woolf said that
servants were as irritating as "kitchen flies," and Edna St.
Vincent Millay stated, "The only people I really hate are servants.
They are really not human beings at all."
Bryson describes, in detail, one of the toughest jobs--that of the
laundry maid. One highlight of that description is what she (yes, Ms.
Millay, they actually were human beings) needed to do to get stains out.
The way to deal with stained linens was to steep them in stale urine or
a diluted solution of poultry dung.
BRYSON LEADS OFF his chapter on the drawing room with a discussion
of the words "comfort" and "comfortable." Until
1770, he writes, the idea of being comfortable at home "was so
unfamiliar that no word existed for the condition."
"Comfortable" meant simply "capable of being
consoled." But by the early 19th century, it was quite common for
people to talk about having a comfortable home or making a comfortable
living. "The history of private life," writes Bryson, "is
a history of getting comfortable slowly." In other words, standards
of living increased gradually due to the many labor-saving inventions
that--though they reduced the demand for servants--made even the lives
of servants easier.
Indeed, improvements in technology were so important that the one
chapter Bryson devotes to something other than a room in the house or a
physical area in or around the house is his chapter on the fuse box.
Electricity truly revolutionized life. Bryson writes, "The world at
night for much of history was a very dark place indeed." A good
candle, he adds, "provides barely a hundredth of the illumination
of a single 100-watt lightbulb." Although Bryson makes a good case
for how important lighting was and is, he would have made an even
stronger case had he drawn on the pathbreaking work by Yale University
economist William D. Nordhaus. In a study done in 1996, Nordhaus found
that failure to adjust appropriately for the plummeting cost of light
has led economic historians to dramatically understate the growth of
real wages over the last 200 years. That one invention, plus many
others, led to a burgeoning middle class.
The term "middle class," writes Bryson, was coined only
in 1745. By the early 19th century, of course, the middle class was
substantial. Something that fueled this growth, besides labor-saving
inventions such as running water and light, was the increasing
globalization of production through free trade. Take wood. Before the
British engaged in extensive international trade, they used only one
kind of wood in their furniture: oak. But Bryson notes that the British
started getting (he doesn't say when) walnut from Virginia,
tulipwood from the Carolinas, and teak from Asia.
Because At Home is about various rooms in the home, not all of it
is about technological change. Some of it is simply about how
people's consumption patterns changed as Britain industrialized and
became wealthier, and it is no less interesting for that. In a chapter
titled "The Cellar," for example, Bryson details the enormous
increase in coal usage for heating British homes. By 1842, he notes,
Britain alone used "two-thirds of all coal produced in the Western
world." Coal burning became a bigger problem in cities as the
cities grew: During Queen Victoria's lifetime, writes Bryson, the
population of London alone rose from one million to seven million. It
would have been nice to see Bryson lay out how many people were saved
from death by the switch from coal in fireplaces to coal burning in
electricity generation and to oil, natural gas, and nuclear power for
heating. But, as I noted, that's not his point. Bryson wants to
detail how his early 19th-century house contains a lot of history.
Bryson occasionally breaks with the pattern by using a room as an
excuse to discuss interesting technological developments that had little
to do with the room. No matter--his discussion is always illuminating. A
chapter called "The Study," for example, doesn't really
deal with the study but does discuss mice, mousetraps, rats, plagues
(naturally), mites, bedbugs, and germs. I will never put my head on a
pillow in a hotel room again without remembering that ten percent of the
weight of a six-year-old pillow (six years, says Bryson, is the average
age of a pillow) is made up of "sloughed skin, living and dead
mites, and mite dung." On a somewhat more comforting note, Bryson
points out a positive change in the insect world: the disappearance of
locusts a little over a century ago. We are so used to hearing about a
species disappearing because of man's activity that we sometimes
forget to notice that the disappearance of some species is a welcome
development. It turns out that the locusts hibernated and bred every
winter in the high plains east of the Rocky Mountains. When new farmers
there plowed and irrigated a little over a century ago, they killed the
locusts and their pupae.
It is impossible to read Bryson's chapter on the bedroom
without emerging with an appreciation of economic growth and modern
medicine. At inns, strangers often shared beds into the 19th century,
and "diaries frequently contain entries lamenting how the author
was disappointed to find a late-arriving stranger clambering into bed
with him." He tells of a squabble in 1776 between Benjamin Franklin
and John Adams when they shared a bed in New Brunswick, New Jersey. The
issue disputed was not the role of the federal government. It was the
far more important question of "whether to have the window open or
not." With increasing wealth, people no longer had to share beds.
Bryson tells just how primitive medical knowledge was before 1850
and sometimes even later than that. For example, virtually all doctors
were men, and it was not considered proper for men to examine a
woman's private parts. The American Medication Association expelled
a gynecologist named James Platt White for allowing his students to
observe a woman giving birth, even though the woman had given them
permission. Nor did doctors seem to understand much about germ theory.
Bryson writes that when President James Abram Garfield was shot in 1881,
he wasn't killed by the bullet but by doctors "sticking their
unwashed fingers in the wound."
One shortcoming of the book is that Bryson doesn't seem to
have much appreciation for--or maybe it's just a lack of interest
in--how wealth is created. This comes out most strikingly in his
discussion of "Commodore" Cornelius Vanderbilt. Vanderbilt,
writes Bryson, "had a positively uncanny gift for making
money." True. But then he tells the reader of Vanderbilt's
immense wealth without saying anything about how he acquired it. The
story that Bryson leaves out is that Vanderbilt made a large part of his
wealth by making steamship travel relatively cheap for many Americans in
the New York area, in the process challenging a monopoly that the New
York legislature had unconstitutionally granted to Robert Fulton. In
other words, Vanderbilt created wealth for himself by also creating
wealth for consumers.
Bryson also accepts many of the myths about the evils of child
labor that various defenders of the aristocracy and advocates of
socialism propagated in the 19th century as part of their opposition to
British industrialization. Bryson does what virtually every opponent of
child labor in factories has done: discuss the horrible conditions of
work in mines and factories--they really were horrible--without
comparing them to the even worse conditions in agriculture, which is
where these same children would have been employed had they not worked
in mines and factories. Bryson's work is so well researched
generally that it's a pity that he didn't come across
economist William H. Hutt's careful refutations of the critics of
child labor. (See his "The Factory System of the Early Nineteenth
Century" in the Hayek-edited 1954 book Capitalism and the
Historians.)
SO, WHERE ARE these old Victorian houses and the huge mansions that
the newly rich built in the 19th century? Many of them, notes Bryson,
were torn down after their contents were sold. And the reason so many of
them disappeared is ironic given the author's criticism of property
rights. On the one hand, Bryson chides 19th-century critics of
historical preservation laws, who saw such laws as "an egregious
assault on property rights." Just two pages later, on the other
hand, he details the legal attack on property rights that caused many of
these treasures to be sold off. The law I refer to is the British
government's death duty--in the United States, it is called an
estate tax. This tax started in the late 19th century at a modest eight
percent rate on estates valued at one million pounds or more. But by
1939, the rate was a hefty 60 percent. By the 1950s, writes Bryson, the
stately homes were disappearing at the rate of about two a week.
There is so much more in At Home than I've discussed here. One
thing Bryson does often, for example, is tell the price of various goods
and services at various points in time. Many of these prices were very
high relative to wages. Realizing this gives the reader still another
way of understanding and appreciating the awesome wealth created for all
economic classes--in Britain and the United States--by two centuries of
economic growth.