Maritime fragmentation: Inherent or people-made?
Sandberg, L. Anders
The reasons behind Maritime industrial decline continue to be hotly
debated. Capitalism and capitalists are blamed by some. Others favour
cultural interpretations. Neo-classical economists see the process as a
rational outcome of the decisions of profit-seeking capitalists.
Regionalists blame discriminatory policies of the federal government. In
a recent article in this journal, geographer Larry McCann, using the
example of the rise and decline of the Nova Scotia Steel and Coal
Company [Scotia], focusses on the fragmentation of the region. (1)
Fragmentation, McCann argues, refers to several conditions: a variegated
coastline; large uninhabited forests; scattered areas of usable
agricultural lands; cultural groups limited to original hearth areas;
political, ethnic and religious diversity; dispersed and scattered
resources that shift in relative value and quality; and income
differentiation. It is McCann's thesis that Scotia was a tenuous
affair. Its promoters struggled valiantly to integrate a series of
diverse operations, succeeded for some time (fragmented integration),
but in the end succumbed to three forces of fragmentation: dispersed and
limited regional markets, increased costs of producing poor quality
resources, and the minimal presence of external economies. McCann is
careful to argue that, "[o]f course, no one explanation can be
offered to account solely for the deindustrialization and urban
population losses of this hinterland region." But he nevertheless
feels that "the forces of fragmentation associated with the
Maritime space economy shaped 'Scotia's' unwillingness to
emphasize internal growth over external markets, and also contributed to
the company's eventual demise." (2)
There are at least two major problems with McCann's thesis.
The first relates to the elevation of the concept of Maritime
fragmentation to something inherent and timeless to the region. The
second refers to the role of location and resources in industrial
decline, elements which do have obvious credence, but which cannot be
held up as general and absolute factors of industrial decline.
Let me start with the concept of fragmentation. McCann quotes Ian
McKay's proposition that the Maritimes' "links to the
world capitalist economy in the period of merchant's capital
focused development in export enclaves [and] undermined the
socio-economic potential for integrated and balanced growth ..., leaving
a fragmented and dependent region vulnerable to rapidly expanding
central Canadian capital." (3) But he never follows up on this very
important thesis by exploring the legacy of merchant capital in the fate
of Scotia in the industrial era. He conveniently leaves McKay's
thesis stranded in time, moving on to his own question: "But what
of community isolation and independence in the industrial era?"
This is, I believe, a serious error. Fragmentation in the mercantile and
industrial eras are not separate phenomena. Nor is Maritime industrial
capital fragmented as a result of geography. McKay suggests that the
Maritime industrial geography was fragmented because of merchant
capital. Scotia suffered from the legacy of merchant capital, which
included fragmented industrial activities and limited local markets.
There was nothing in geography that pre-determined the Maritimes to this
fate. It was instead a history of dependent development shaped by
colonialism.
This is what I tried to build on in an earlier article on
Scotia's rise and decline, where I argued that the company's
ties to external financial and industrial inputs and markets (its
disarticulation), had its roots in the mercantile era. Yet, so I
maintained, that did not determine Scotia's fate, and I outlined
the role of the local management, its work force and the provincial and
federal states in the decline of company, arguing that the investment
strategies under 'local control' perpetuated a dependent
development path.
The company's development was thus contingent and not
pre-determined by such formal and static concepts as disarticulation and
fragmentation (wherever they might come from). This has also been argued
for other industries. Sager and Panting's seminal Maritime Capital
suggests that the failure of the Maritime shipbuilding industry to make
the transition from wood and wind to iron and steam was in large part be
due to the legacy of merchant capital, and the lack of coordination
among and between Maritime shipbuilders and the federal and provincial
states. Maritime shipbuilders and shippers were, in fact, primarily
shippers, and were more inclined to support entrepot trade, based on
railways and foreign steamers, rather than to support an indigenous
shipbuilding industry. (4) The Maritime forest industry suffers from a
similar legacy. Forest fragmentation, for example, rather than being a
natural phenomenon, is the result of the exploitation and degradation of
the forest by the colonial and post-colonial lumber trade, and
provincial governments' more recent abdication of forest management
to transnational pulp and paper companies. (5)
The second problem with McCann's argument refers to the
causality attributed to resource base and location in industrial
decline. This suggestion does not stand up to historical scrutiny.
Regions are made and unmade by people's actions, not by their
geographies. (6) True, resource bases, locations, and geographies are
important conditioning and constraining factors but to isolate them for
separate analysis, divorced from social considerations, is a serious
error. Indeed, examples abound of regions and states which have
succeeded industrially in spite of (some would go as far as arguing
because of) poor resource bases and peripheral locations. The province
of Smaland in Sweden, the home of Moberg's emigrants, the land of
stones and rocks, legend for its poor resource base, became an important
industrial region in the twentieth century, based on the manufacture of
plastics, glass, and secondary steel products. (7) Peripheral Finland,
so one author argues, has prospered as a function of Toynbee's
claim that "ease is inimical to civilization." (8) At the
national level, peripheral and resource-poor Japan is today one of the
world's leading industrial powers.
A similar point is necessary to understand the industrial decline
of the Maritimes. As Sager and Panting state, at "a certain point
the emphasis on the allegedly weak resource or locational disadvantages
of the Maritime provinces becomes reductionist and
question-begging." (9) Social considerations need to be considered
as a complement. Capitalists readily sold out in the Maritimes. Why was
this so? Other regional bourgeoisies were more likely to invest and
remain loyal to place, at least at this particular time. (10) The
answer, I think, lies in the legacy of merchant capital, dependent
development and associated political and social institutions, and the
constraints they imposed on the expansion of Scotia. This is not a
voluntarist interpretation, suggesting that Scotia's leaders could
have overcome all their problems. They might not have, given local and
external constraints. But, as Bluestone and Harrsion suggest, the
specific path of industrial decline "does not just happen."
(11) Besides the historical constraints of merchant capital, conscious
decisions were made by Scotia's managers to wind down and
restructure the operations. These things did not happen automatically,
nor were they simply a response to inevitable external forces. The
deindustrialization process was a contested terrain with winners and
losers. Scotia's industrialists did well for themselves, while
their workers and Nova Scotia communities bore the brunt of the
company's demise.
The McCann thesis has the most unfortunate implications for the
present Maritimes. It suggests that the region is destined to perpetual
industrial depression, except for those rare and ephemeral moments when
the region's resources are in demand. This is somehow due to the
concept of fragmentation. What sort of implication does this have for
transfer, equalization, and UI payments in the region? It might call for
more such regional aid, given the region's inherent geographical
problems. More likely, perhaps, in this era of neconservatism, budget
deficits and cost-cutting, is that the concept of fragmentation can be
used to promote further deprivation of the Maritime region (after all,
the funds could or should be employed more efficiently elsewhere). (12)
This is unfortunate since Maritime economic underdevelopment, given the
region's colonial heritage and present integration in national,
continental and international economies, needs to be understood more in
the context of global capitalist development, and local people's
compliance and fight against this process. Pollard's concept of a
differential of contemporaneousness might be useful as a tool of
interpretation here. He suggests that capitalist technologies have
different impacts on different regions. The railway, for example, was an
aid to industrialization in some regions. In other regions, while
serving as a symbol of political virility, it served to subordinate
regions to dependent export enclaves of staples. (13)
My call, then, is for a more people-based and dynamic
interpretation of Maritime industrial decline. (14) References to
resources "scattered randomly" throughout the region and a
landscape "[s]o dissected" as something unique to the
Maritimes, and an important aspect of industrial decline, just
won't do. Fragmentation is not a useful concept unto itself. It is
not a mere number in a mathematical equation that can be considered in
isolation. It needs to be considered as part of the whole equation. It
is forever changing and contingent and part of the social internal and
external dynamic of the Maritime region.
Notes
1. L. D. McCann, "Fragmented Integration: The Nova Scotia
Steel and Coal Company and the Anatomy of an Urban-Industrial
Landscape," Urban History Review, 2, 2 (Spring 1994).
2. This is a challenge to my own interpretation of Scotia's
demise. See L. Anders Sandberg, "Dependent Development, Labour and
the Trenton Steel Works, Nova Scotia, c. 1900-1943," Labour/Le
Travail, 27 (Spring 1991), 127-62.
3. I. McKay, "The Crisis of Dependent Development: Class
Conflict in the Nova Scotia Coalfields, 1872-1876," Canadian
Journal of Sociology, 13 (1988), 9-48.
4. E. Sager with G. Panting, Maritime Capital (Montreal and
Kingston, 1990).
5. L. Anders Sandberg, "Dependent Development and Client
States: Forest Policy and Social Conflict in Nova Scotia and New
Brunswick," in Trouble in the Woods: Forest Policy and Social
Conflict in Nova Scotia and New Brunswick ed. L. Anders Sandberg
(Fredericton, 1992), 1-21.
6. Though this point cannot, of course, be carried too far. The
Antarctic remains void of most human economic activity for obvious
reasons.
7. V. Moberg, The Emigrants (New York, 1951).
8. Quoted in W. Hall, The Finns and Their Country (London, 1967),
15.
9. Sager with Panting, Maritime Capital, 17.
10. This is, of course, less true in today's global economy.
11. B. Bluestone and B. Harrison, The Deindustrialization of
America (New York, 1982), 15.
12. This is also the case of another recent statement on Maritime
economic history, Kris Inwood's Farm, Factory and Fortune
(Fredericton, 1993). For a critical review, see L. Anders Sandberg,
"Underdevelopment: A 'Reasonable' Proposition?," New
Maritimes, XII, 1 (September/October 1993), 26-30.
13. S. Pollard, Peaceful Conquest. The Industrialization of Europe,
1760-1970 (Oxford, 1981). See also P. Knox and J. Agnew, The Geography
of the World Economy (London, 1989), 136.
14. For a very important recent contribution to this endeavour,
emphasizing the role of the rural in Maritime industrialization, see
Daniel Samson, editor, A Contested Countryside: Rural Workers and Modern
Society in Atlantic Canada, 1800-1950 (Fredericton, 1994).