Producing Security: Multinational Corporations, Globalization, and the Changing Calculus of Conflict.
Li, Quan
Producing Security: Multinational Corporations, Globalization, and
the Changing Calculus of Conflict, Stephen G. Brooks (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 2005), 316 pp., $35 cloth.
Multinational corporations (MNCs) have always been controversial.
Proponents praise them for creating jobs in host economies, raising
labor's wage rate, bringing in scarce capital and managerial
know-how, generating technology spillovers, and increasing economic
growth. Opponents criticize them for introducing inappropriate
technologies, setting up sweatshops, exploiting and destroying the
environment, reducing market competition, and wielding excessive
economic and political power in host economies. In these debates,
however, most scholars, social activists, and policy-makers have ignored
the implications of MNCs and international production for international
security.
In this path-breaking book, Stephen Brooks provides a systematic
analysis of the causal mechanisms by which MNCs influence international
security and offers predictions about the kind of influence they are
likely to have on the security relations among different countries in
the future. Now, 65,000 MNCs and their 850,000 affiliates account for
30-50 percent of international trade and a significant portion of global
value-added activities (pp. 17-18). More importantly, MNCs have
geographically dispersed their production activities and technological
development in a way that is qualitatively different from that of the
first, pre-1914 globalization era. Since the 1970s, there have been not
only increases in the stand-alone MNC foreign affiliates and the
within-MNC research and development activities, which are traditional
features in the history of multinationals, but also MNCs' newer
growing strategic reliance on international subcontracting, outsourcing,
and interfirm alliances in technological development. For example, the
value of international outsourcing by U.S. manufacturing firms rose from
$48.8 billion in 1972 to $356 billion in 1987 (p. 22), and the number of
interfirm alliances reached 4,182 in the 1980s (p. 34). All these
developments in international production have made foreign direct
investment (FDI) the key source of advanced technology and capital. As a
result, being closed to MNCs has become costly for states in terms of
lost opportunities to raise their international competitiveness. States
have rushed to liberalize their controls over MNCs, relaxing entry and
operational conditions, national control, and sectoral regulation, while
they have competed to offer various investment incentives. However,
while competitive pressures to internationalize production have become
pervasive, the dispersion of international production across regions has
not been uniform--it tends to be concentrated in North America, Western
Europe, and Japan, which appears attributable to the influence of
regional economic integration agreements (p. 30). It is noteworthy that
new forms of dispersed international production such as interfirm
alliances, which have transformed the advanced countries into
knowledge-based economies, have not occurred in most developing
countries, even in China, which has received the largest amount of FDI
among all developing countries.
Brooks argues that these characteristics of international
production affect international security by changing the incentives,
capabilities, and, hence, the nature of the actors. First, the
geographic dispersion of international production reduces the economic
benefits of military conquest, particularly among the advanced
countries, because military conquest repels foreign capital, undermines
interfirm alliances, often results in economic centralization in the
conquered land, generates less spoil for the conqueror along the
dispersed value chain, and reduces technological innovation in
knowledge-based economies. Brooks demonstrates this by reference to the
experience of the Eastern European countries under the Soviet rule,
particularly Hungary. The Hungarian government sought to attract foreign
production capital after 1972 by liberalizing FDI regulations and
offering tax concessions and new source capital. However, the influence
of the Soviet Union, with its centralized management of the economy,
prevented Hungary's policy efforts from producing any significant
amount of FDI inflow before 1990. Soviet economic centralization also
repressed innovations and the rise of knowledge-based economies in other
Eastern European countries and, in the end, brought little economic
benefit to the Soviet Union itself.
Second, competition for global production capital deepens regional
economic integration among long-standing security rivals, producing
better political relations--but only for cases in which these countries
are parties to regional trade agreements with few other member
countries, all of whom have large economies and would have difficulty
attracting foreign capital unless they cooperate through the agreements.
For example, the development of Mercosur, the Southern Cone Common
Market, motivated partly by the pursuit for foreign capital, helped
Argentina and Brazil to resolve their 150-year-long security rivalry.
Third, the existence of MNCs also implies the internationalization of weapons production and the rising cost, complexity, and scale of
developing new military technologies. States pursuing cutting-edge
military technology can no longer resort to autarkic defense production
without falling behind. The internationalization of U.S. defense
production and military technology, Brooks notes, stood in sharp
contrast with the autarkic production of the Soviet Union and
contributed to the technological gap between the Cold War superpowers.
In short, great powers can no longer afford to pursue autarkic
defense-related production.
Overall, the postwar dispersion of international production could
be credited with producing peaceful relations among great powers, and
can be expected to do so in the future. This stands in contrast to the
pre-1914 era when, critics argue, globalization failed to secure peace.
Brooks further argues, however, that the dispersion of international
production capital has not produced such pacifying effect on security
relations among developing countries and has had only a mixed effect on
security relations between great powers and developing countries. This
is mainly because the noted economic and institutional conditions under
which international production reduces economic benefits of military
conquest and deepens regional integration among security rivals are not
present in the developing countries. Furthermore, since developing
countries most often employ their militaries in regional actions and
focus on less complicated, smaller weapons systems, it is unlikely that
the globalization of defense-related production would be relevant to
their security relations.
Three issues, however, may challenge Brooks's causal analysis,
suggesting the need for future research. First, the game theoretical
literature of international conflict, which Brooks has ignored, posits
that the decision to go to war results from the failure of bargaining
between states due to their uncertainty about their opponent's
payoff structure and resolve over a contested issue. Globalization,
measured in terms of trade, FDI, and financial openness, reduces the
probability of war by serving as a means of costly signaling, rather
than by changing the cost-benefit calculus. That is, since both parties
already know the value of their economic exchange before engaging in
military action, the size of the economic stake per se is not
informative as to the opponent's resolve to uphold its position on
the contested issue. But a military threat over the contested issue has
the effect of repelling international production capital, and so carries
an economic cost that gives the state's threat additional
credibility. Such costly signaling informs the other state of its
opponent's resolve, often resulting in bargaining success and
avoidance of violence. While Brooks focuses on the role of globalized
production as a structural constraint that prevents any great power from
complete dominance in bargaining (p. 217), one may wonder how his
argument fits into the bargaining framework, since the quality of
security relations eventually boils down to the decision to go to war.
Second, the rapid dispersion of international production appears itself
to be a consequence of the end of the Cold War. Brooks claims that his
book focuses on the impact of globalization, touching on this
endogeneity issue only in passing. But the empirical evidence he uses
shows that multinationals' international production increased much
more rapidly and dramatically after 1989 (for example, fig. 2.2, p. 18).
Third, given the theoretical and policy significance of Brooks's
predictions about security relations among various countries, it is
important to verify their empirical validity in large cross-national
samples to avoid case selection bias, rather than focusing on a few
countries. Of course, it should be acknowledged that the lack of
reliable data poses a significant challenge to such an exercise.
Despite these quibbles, this is an innovative, sound, systematic,
and insightful volume for all those who are interested in the
implications of economic globalization for interstate war and peace.
QUAN LI
Pennsylvania State University