Research locally, diffuse globally? American universities, patents and global public health.
Sampat, Bhaven N.
An important challenge in sustainable development is promoting the
creation of new medical technologies and ensuring their diffusion in
developing countries. There is growing concern that, with the
implementation of the World Trade Organization's agreement on Trade
Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs), pharmaceutical patents
will restrict access to medicines globally. Profit-oriented companies
are now aggressively pursuing intellectual property protections in
developing countries, many of which had previously not allowed product
patents on drugs. The concern is that absent generic competition,
patients will not be able to access life-saving medications. Recent
attention has focused on a perhaps unlikely set of actors to help
ameliorate the access to medicines problem: American research
universities. A decade-old student movement has argued that universities
own intellectual property rights on many important drugs, and has pushed
for inclusion of "humanitarian licensing" clauses that would
compel the pharmaceutical firms that license these technologies to allow
generic access in developing countries. In this paper, I discuss the
emergence and evolution of this student movement, and the set of patent
policy changes that got us here. I also summarize data on the
feasibility of these policies: for how many drugs would changes in
university policies plausibly affect access? Next, I discuss the
desirability of changing university licensing practices and the
tradeoffs universities face when considering humanitarian licensing
approaches. I conclude with a discussion of the limits of campus-level
initiatives alone, and the potentially important role for research
funding agencies, such as the National Institutes of Health, in
promoting humanitarian licensing and access to medicines.
**********
Over the past decade, global public health has been identified as a
crucial driver of sustainable human development. Yet marshaling
collective action toward global health goals is difficult, since the
developing world lacks the resources to do so and taxpayers in developed
countries traditionally have been anemic in providing financial support
for this purpose.
In the face of these difficulties, recent attention has focused on
a potentially useful role for U.S. universities in promoting global
public health. For example, Professor Jeffrey D. Sachs, director of
Columbia University's Earth Institute, has argued that, relative to
private sector actors, universities are less myopic, less motivated by
commercial interest, more cosmopolitan and, therefore, better suited to
play a central role in the advancement of global public health. (1)
Optimism that universities can help promote global health finds support
in history: U.S. universities have a long and storied record of rising
to address important social and economic challenges. They were integral
in promoting agricultural development in the 19th century; in developing
indigenous American chemical and engineering industries in the early
20th century; and most famously perhaps, in advancing U.S. research
efforts during the Second World War. (2) In the postwar era,
universities have had an important role in biomedical research,
including in the war on cancer and in drug development. Sachs suggests
that "the challenge today is to extend such local actions to global
problems, with universities taking on the challenges in other parts of
the world." (3) U.S. universities appear to be rising to this
challenge; university activity in the global health arena has grown
dramatically over the past decade. Dr. Michael Merson, director of the
Duke Global Health Institute based at Duke University, recently
suggested that 270 U.S. academic institutions had some sort of global
health program, of which seventy had global health centers. (4)
Academic institutions might contribute to global health through
numerous channels, including training, research and development
(R&D), and program evaluation and delivery. This paper examines the
potential for university action in another domain: the diffusion of
pharmaceuticals. Specifically, I examine how changes to university
patenting and licensing policies can promote broader access to
medicines.
Access to medicines is widely viewed as a crucial component of
global public health. (5) Recognizing this, and the lack of private
sector incentives to promote access, a cross-campus student movement
called the Universities Allied for Essential Medicines (UAEM) attempts
to shape university licensing policies to ensure that drugs researched
and developed at universities, in whole or in part, are licensed at low
cost in the developing world. (6) In this paper, I first provide an
overview of the potential role that university intellectual property
right policies could play in improving the diffusion of biomedical technologies in developing countries. I then set the stage by discussing
the problem of access to medicines and new international patent laws
that may contribute to it. Next, I examine the rise of academic
patenting and licensing. Finally, I discuss the initiatives now underway
to use academic technology transfer policies--in particular, so-called
humanitarian licensing policies that seek to encourage low prices for
university-developed technologies in developing countries--to overcome
barriers to diffusion created by patents. In this section, I summarize
data on the feasibility of these policies and the tradeoffs universities
face when considering humanitarian licensing approaches. I conclude by
arguing that campus-level action may need to be reinforced by national
policymaking (and/or guidance from U.S. federal funding agencies) for
humanitarian licensing policies to be more widely adopted.
PATENTS AND ACCESS TO MEDICINES
Access to drugs is widely recognized as an important component of
global health and sustainable development. (7) Many factors affect the
extent to which the population in developing countries has access to
medicines, including the strength of health systems, the general state
of infrastructure, indigenous manufacturing capabilities and national
income levels. (8)
Recently, another potential factor has been added to the mix:
patents. Patents on new drugs give their owners limited term
rights--currently, twenty years from patent filing--to exclude other
firms from selling the same technologies. The theory underlying patent
policies is that, absent this limited term monopoly, firms would not
invest in costly research and development. Patents are more important in
pharmaceuticals than in other industries because R&D in the area of
new drug development and testing is particularly expensive. Once a
compound is discovered, however, imitation is easy. (9) Furthermore,
drug patents are difficult to invent around and thus effective at
preventing competition. Because they are subject to generic competition,
drugs without patents are priced much lower and are more broadly
available. This is why Doctors Without Borders has argued that generic
competition is "the most significant factor in lowering
prices" for drugs. (10) Oxfam similarly notes that it is "the
single most important tool to remedy the access gap." (11)
Historically, developing countries have had flexibility in how they
designed their patent laws, and many (probably most) chose not to allow
patents on pharmaceuticals. (12) This reflected the view among
policymakers in the developing world--and among development
economists--that the benefits of increased innovation due to patents and
other intellectual property incentives were minimal for developing
countries; after all, most pharmaceutical R&D is performed on the
basis of profit expectations from developed country markets. (13)
Additionally, the benefits generated from lower prices and broader
access to drugs are potentially large in developing nations. (14)
The World Trade Organization's 1995 agreement on Trade Related
Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) appears to have changed this. TRIPS
led to an upward harmonization of patent standards to match those of the
developed world. TRIPS forbids excluding entire fields from
patentability. Most developing countries were compelled to introduce
TRIPS-compliant patent laws by 1 January 2000. They have been in place
now for roughly one decade. Carolyn Deere observes that, as a result,
"by the end of 2007 the intellectual property standards of
developing country laws were higher than ever before," and most
governments now grant pharmaceutical product patents. (15)
There was some enthusiasm that TRIPS would promote research on
so-called neglected diseases (those without significant first-world
markets) and/or promote innovation by indigenous firms in developing
countries; however, the empirical record on both expectations remains
mixed (16) There has also been widespread concern that the introduction
of drug patents in developing countries will lead to limited generic
competition, higher prices and restricted access to medicines. Joseph E.
Stiglitz, professor of economics at Columbia University, has, for
example, suggested that the TRIPS-mandated changes "were intended
to reduce access to generic medicines and they succeeded. As generic
medicines cost a fraction of their brand name counterparts, billions
could no longer afford the drugs they needed." (17) These concerns
about post-TRIPS access to medicines have been most pronounced in the
HIV/AIDS arena, perhaps because of the presence of generic suppliers in
India and elsewhere that were previously the dominant sources of
low-cost drugs to much of the developing world, but whose activities
could be foreclosed by TRIPS.
As a result of these concerns, Stiglitz, among others, has
advocated replacing our current system of financing drug innovation via
patents with other models, including prize-type systems)" In these
systems, firms are offered financial or other rewards based on the size
of the benefit conferred by a given innovation. While they differ
considerably in their detailed recommendations, each of these new
proposals stems from the argument that reliance on patents to finance
innovation requires putting broad access to potentially life-saving
medicines in the hands of private sector pharmaceutical firms. Since
these firms are profit-maximizing, they generally do not--and perhaps
cannot, given their responsibilities to shareholders--diffuse drug
technologies broadly in developing countries.
However, private sector firms are not the only important actors in
drug development. A large share of U.S. biomedical research is funded by
the public sector and conducted by research universities. Given the
characteristics that make universities potentially important actors in
global health and sustainable development and their growing engagement
in global health, might they also play an important role in drug
development and access to medicines?
To answer this question, I begin with a discussion of an important
change in U.S. patent policy that led American research universities to
become more aggressive claimants of intellectual property rights to
campus-based research, known as the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980.
BAYH-DOLE AND ACADEMIC PATENTING
Throughout the 20th century, university patenting was rare. This
was especially true of biomedical technologies. Even universities that
allowed for patenting generally tended to restrict faculty patenting of
medical inventions. Columbia University's patenting policy, up
until 1975, allowed patenting generally, while also asserting that
"no member of the faculty or staff of the College shall take out a
patent on any medicinal, therapeutic, or health substance or
process." (19) Similar policies were in place at most other major
U.S. universities, reflecting a belief that medical patents were
particularly difficult to reconcile with the academic mission to advance
and diffuse knowledge. (20)
These restrictions began to be relaxed in the 1970s. The sources of
these changes are complex and included academic institutions seeking
other revenue sources in the wake of reduced federal funding, and the
growth of biotechnology, a field where university research was directly
valuable to industry. Federal funding agencies, including the National
Science Foundation (NSF) and National Institutes of Health (NIH), also
initiated a series of reforms allowing universities to patent through
case-by-case petitions or blanket Institutional Patent Agreements
(IPAs). Historically, funding agencies had been ambivalent about
allowing grantees to patent. This ambivalence reflected a long-standing
policy presumption that publicly-funded research should be placed in the
public domain, and that taxpayers should not be compelled to pay for
research twice: first by funding it and again through monopoly pricing.
(21)
What changed? Following the competitiveness crisis of the 1970s and
fears about global economic competition, policymakers sought in the
1970s and 1980s to make changes to patent U.S. policies to promote
innovation. (22) A range of interest groups highlighted that the lack of
patent protection on university research was one reason the United
States was getting relatively little return on academic R&D
investments. (23) Specifically, they argued that university inventions
were typically embryonic technologies. Absent patents, the argument
continued, firms would lack incentive to develop academic technologies
to the point where they would be commercially viable and useful. In
pharmaceuticals, for example, the argument was made that, even when
potential therapies were discovered in the laboratory, private firms
would not advance them through expensive clinical trials without
exclusive market rights. Compounds placed in the public domain would, as
a result, simply "languish on the shelf." (24)
This argument, which also applied more broadly to
non-pharmaceuticals, was the basis of the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980. The
agency-by-agency reforms advanced before Bayh-Dole and discussed above
stood on questionable legal footing, and vacillation by individual
agencies created considerable uncertainty for university grantees and
their potential commercial licensees.
The Bayh-Dole Act was centrally motivated by concerns about lagging
U.S. competitiveness and the belief that, in a global economy in which
scientific and technological knowledge moves across national boundaries
far more rapidly and can be exploited far more easily by non-U.S,
enterprises, the U.S. economy (and U.S. taxpayers) would benefit from
federal support of academic R&D only if the results of this research
were patented. (25) As such, the congressional passage of the Bayh-Dole
Act was part of a broader wave of so-called techno-nationalistic
technology policies enacted in the 1970s and 1980s aimed at promoting
high-technology industry in the United States in an era of increased
global competition. (26)
At its most basic level, Bayh-Dole created a uniform government
patent policy, clarifying procedures for obtaining academic patents and
making them uniform across funding agencies. (27) Bayh-Dole also had an
important normative impact, allowing and encouraging universities to
patent and exclusively license their inventions, something they had
previously avoided and considered somewhat contrary to their academic
missions. (28)
Over the past quarter century, academic patenting and licensing
activities have grown dramatically. While only a handful of universities
had formal technology transfer offices before Bayh-Dole, nearly every
major research university now houses a dedicated patenting and licensing
office. University patenting has increased sharply. This growth has been
most pronounced in the biomedical arena, where the share of
university-owned patents in all patents has increased from about 5
percent to about 20 percent between the late 1970s and today. (29)
How does university patenting and licensing work? Consider the case
of Xalatan[R], a glaucoma drug developed at Columbia University in the
early 1980s by chemistry professor Laszlo Bito. Xalatan[R] was funded by
a series of grants from the National Eye Institute, part of the NIH.(30)
Though Bito had originally planned to publish only his
research--consistent with the practices of the time--he learned that,
under Columbia University's post-Bayh-Dole patent policy, he had to
report his creation to the university technology transfer office. He did
so, and the university acquired a patent on the invention. Because the
scientific theory behind Bito's discovery was not well-accepted
when the drug was being developed, it was difficult for Columbia to
secure a licensee to develop the drug. Eventually, it was licensed
exclusively to Pharmacia (later, Pharmacia-Upjohn), which financed the
drug through human clinical trials. In time, Xalatan[R] became a
blockbuster drug, generating major profits for Pfizer (which eventually
acquired Pharmacia-Upjohn). Like most licensing contracts between
universities and industry, Columbia's contract included a
sales-based royalty. The drug generated significant revenues for
Columbia University, much of which was plowed back into research.
Most policy discussions about Bayh-Dole have focused on whether it
really fulfills its mandate to promote technology transfer. This remains
an open and important empirical question. (31)
Scholars and policymakers have also expressed concerns about
whether the Bayh-Dole act has had unintended effects. Has the growth of
academic patenting been accompanied by a shift from basic to more
applied, commercially attractive research? Does academic medical
patenting create conflicts of interest among those conducting research
on patients? Can patenting of the inputs into research (gene sequences,
reagents, research tools, proprietary data, etc.) hinder the progress of
science?
While these arguments focus on the unintended costs of academic
patenting, there have also been recent discussions about its unintended
benefits; namely, the potential control over dissemination, and possibly
pricing, conferred by academic ownership of the basic technology. (32)
This is particularly important since drug firms, once they develop a
useful product, will generally charge the highest price the market will
bear.
The Bayh-Dole Act was about creating incentives for innovation, but
since the early days of debates about Bayh-Dole, there have been
concerns about the dissemination and fair pricing of taxpayer-funded
drugs. These included provisions for "recouping" profits from
drugs developed through public funding. Such provisions were dropped
from the final legislation at the last hour, though they have
occasionally re-emerged in policy discussions since then. (33) There
have also been initiatives to use the so-called march-in provisions of
the Bayh-Dole Act to promote lower pricing of drugs in the United
States, though none have been successful yet. (34) In the next section,
I discuss proposals aimed at harnessing the role of American
universities in drug development to affect prices and broaden access to
medicines in developing countries.
ACADEMIC PATENTS AND ACCESS TO MEDICINES
Ironically, given the techno-nationalistic motivations behind
Bayh-Dole described above, initiatives to use university ownership of
drugs to promote access to medicines appear to have been more successful
in the context of developing countries than in the United States. These
initiatives were triggered by the case of Stavudine, an important HIV treatment that was exorbitantly priced in South Africa and therefore
unobtainable for many of the country's dying patients in need of
this life-saving drug. Student activists and civil society groups
learned that the drug was developed at Yale University via NIH funding.
These groups successfully pressured Yale to compel Bristol-Myers Squibb,
the firm that had licensed the drug from the university, to allow
generic competition in South Africa. As a result, according to one
source, the price of the drug dropped dramatically, from $1,600 per year
to $55 per year. (35) This drop in price instantly meant that many more
HIV patients in South Africa were able to afford the drug and proved
that a change in university licensing practices could, in fact, save
lives.
This remarkable incident spawned a broad student movement called
Universities Allied for Essential Medicines (UAEM). UAEM currently has
nearly fifty university chapters. Its members are comprised of
undergraduates, law students, medical students and those working in
various areas of public health. Its slogan, "Our Drugs. Our Labs.
Our Responsibility," is based on UAEM's position that
"many important medicines and public health technologies are
developed in academic laboratories. Their accessibility in poor nations
is profoundly affected by the research, patenting and licensing
decisions made by universities." (36)
The main goal of UAEM has been to convince universities to build
humanitarian licensing language into their licensing policies. This
language would compel licensees of university patents to allow generic
competition in the production of these compounds in developing
countries. Importantly, this would not prevent pharmaceutical companies
from enjoying their monopoly rights in developed countries, where they
earn the vast majority of their profits. UAEM's flagship proposal
to concretize these principles into a model licensing policy--the
Equitable Access License (EAL)--also has a viral component: preventing
the enforcement of any follow-on patents associated with a university
technology against generic competition in developing countries. (37)
Assuming that profit-oriented firms are unlikely to promote broad
access to medicines on their own, the potential role of universities is
an intriguing solution to the problem of global access to medicines. How
impactful could these interventions be if they were widely adopted? In
an earlier work, I assessed the scope for these policies, using data on
ownership of all drugs launched between 1988 and 2005. (38) I found that
universities owned patents on about 10 percent of new molecular entities
and about 20 percent of the most innovative, priority drugs. About a
quarter of HIV/ AIDS drugs had academic patents. These figures are
likely to understate the potential role of universities for several
important types of drugs. For example, the dataset used for the analyses
above does not include many biotechnology drugs, a fast-growing segment
of the market and one where university research is likely to be
particularly prominent. Recent work on the human papillomavirus (HPV)
vaccine--a biotechnology drug with large potential markets in the
developing world--demonstrates that universities played acritical role
in enabling research on this technology. (39) Overall, I read these data
as suggesting that the scope for university action is significant and
likely to be even more important in the future.
The student movement has had other notable successes beyond the
Yale University case. UAEM's members helped to shape the language
in the licensing policies for several universities, including Emory
University and the University of North Carolina. While the EAL per se
has not been adopted by any major university yet, the movement has
raised awareness of the relationship between intellectual property and
access to medicines on campuses nationwide. As just one example of this,
the Philadelphia Consensus Statement outlining the group's main
goals has numerous eminent academics among its signatories, including
four Nobel Laureates. (40) Last year, the Association of University
Technology Managers and six universities--Boston University, Brown
University, Harvard University, Oregon Health and Science University,
the University of Pennsylvania and Yale University--announced a
Statement of Principles and Strategies for the Equitable Dissemination
of Medical Technologies, in which the universities pledged a general
commitment to global access goals, stating: "In our negotiations
with potential licensees we will make vigorous efforts to develop
creative and effective licensing strategies that help to promote global
access to health-related technologies." (41)
This statement has since been endorsed by other U.S. universities:
the University of Illinois, the University of Vermont, Duke University,
New York University (NYU) and Florida State University.
Most universities, however, including the most active ones on
patenting and licensing, have not signed on yet, though it is true that
the statement is still less than one year old. Moreover, at least based
on my own impressions, even those that have endorsed this statement or
humanitarian licensing principles more generally, have yet to make major
changes to their licensing terms or practices. (42)
Given the potential for academic institutions to facilitate access
to medicines, and their growing commitment to global public health, why
has the responsiveness of academic institutions' licensing policies
and practices been so limited?
On the one hand, universities may be concerned that these
intellectual property provisions to protect global health will thwart
the overall goal of the Bayh-Dole regime, i.e., technology transfer. The
specific concern is that potential commercial licensees will balk at
humanitarian licensing clauses. Previous empirical research suggests
some justification for this concern. Technology transfer is generally
thought to be a buyers' market: the modal number of potential
suitors for academic technologies is zero. (43) In this context,
imposing additional demands on licensees may cause them to walk away
from developing academic drugs, which is not the goal anyone intends.
Moreover, while one reason for general optimism about the role of
universities in global health is predicated on the fact that they are
not profit-motivated institutions (see Sachs's argument in this
paper's introduction), in this arena of university licensing and
intellectual property they are more so. Previous work by Richard Jensen
and Marie Thursby reveals that generating licensing income is, in fact,
a main goal of university technology transfer managers. (44)
That said, with pharmaceutical firms increasingly reliant upon
academic technologies for their new drug pipeline, it is unclear whether
these firms would rationally walk away from promising technologies just
because they cannot prevent generic competition in developing countries.
After all, the bulk of profits from most drugs comes from developed
country markets, which are unlikely to be affected by these proposals.
If Xalatan[R] for example, was viewed as worthy of commercial
development, surely it likely remained so without the Brazilian or
Ghanaian markets. The situation may be different for drugs that address
neglected tropical diseases because the bulk of the market for that
class of drugs is indeed in the developing world. There is relatively
little academic or commercial research on these diseases anyhow, so that
is an entirely different problem.(45)
In bargaining negotiations, however, pharmaceutical and other firms
may threaten to walk away. In this context, individual universities may
be reluctant to push their luck, even for the important cause of global
health. Universities tend to be risk-averse and cautious, especially in
the context of technology transfer. Professor Louis Menand, in his
recent book on U.S. universities, notes an old observation by the
classicist F. M. Cornford that at universities, "nothing should
ever be done for the first time." (46)
CONCLUDING THOUGHTS
Whether real or perceived, limits to bottom-up action by
universities on these issues suggest that more top-down approaches may
also be necessary. After all, research universities are not entirely
autonomous, but rather are heavily influenced by their funders. For
example, in biomedical research, a strong statement of support for
humanitarian licensing principles from the NIH could shape university
grantees' practices in a profound way. It may even provide cover
for individual universities in their negotiations with their commercial
licensees: "the NIH made us do it." However, though the NIH
has endorsed the statement on broad access principles discussed above,
it has not formally conveyed what actions it expects from its research
grantees.
And there are some limits to what we might expect a U.S. taxpayer
agency to do in order to promote global health. This relates to familiar
problems already raised in the introduction about how to persuade U.S.
taxpayers to evince more concern for the promotion of global public
health.
How might Congress and/or funding agencies be convinced to take
action? One argument is quite straightforward: the United States should
care about access to medicines in the developing world simply because it
is the right thing to do. This might be particularly persuasive if the
costs of humanitarian licensing policies--i.e., effects on incentives to
develop and test drugs emanating from academic labs--were, in fact,
small. Another set of arguments for why rich nations should care about
global health might appeal to self-interest rather than ethics:
infectious diseases know no boundaries and sick countries make poor
trading partners, while also creating security risks. (47)
This highlights another potential role for members of U.S. research
universities. University researchers, students and administrators have
historically been important advocates in foreign policy and research
policy deliberations. They could have a central role in shaping these
dialogues and perspectives. Starting a conversation about the costs and
benefits of national-level policy changes regarding humanitarian
licensing is a critical new task for the movement to harness university
patent ownership to promote global public health.
NOTES
(1) Jeffrey D. Sachs, Common Wealth: Economics for a Crowded Planet
(New York: Penguin Press, 2008), 328.
(2) Nathan Rosenberg and Richard Nelson, "American
Universities and Technical Advance in Industry," Research Policy
23, no. 3 (May 1994), 323-48; also reprinted in Richard Nelson, Sources
of Economic Growth (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1996).
(3) Sachs, 329.
(4) Michael Merson, "Global Health: How U.S. Universities Are
Responding to A Global Priority," (Grand Rounds speech, Maihnan
School of Public Health, Columbia University, New York, NY: 15 September
2010).
(5) Jonathan D. Quick, "Essential Medicines Twenty-Five Years
On: Closing the Access Gap," Health Policy and Planning 18, no. 1
(2003), 1-3.
(6) "About Us," Universities Allied for Essential
Medicines, 2010, http://essentialmedicine.org/ about-us.
(7) Quick, 1-3.
(8) Amir Attaran and Lee Gillespie-White, "Do Patents for
Antiretroviral Drugs Constrain Access to AIDS Treatment in Africa?"
Journal of the American Medical Association 286, no. 15 (17 October
2001), 1886-92.
(9) Frederic M. Scherer, "The Pharmaceutical Industry,"
in Handbook of Health Economics, eds. Anthony J. Culver and Joseph R
Newhouse, 1:25 (Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier, 2000), 1298-1322.
(10) As quoted by Amy Kapczynski, Samantha Chaifetz, Zachary Katz,
and Yochai Benkler in "Addressing Global Health Inequities: An Open
Licensing Approach for University Innovations," Berkeley Technology
Law Journal 20, no. 2 (2005), 1048.
(11) ibid., 1049.
(12) Carolyn Deere, The Implementation Game: The TRIPS Agreement
and the Global Politics of Intellectual Property Reform in Developing
Countries (New York: Oxford University Press USA, 2009), Chapter 2.
(13) Ricki Lewis, "Fighting the 10/90 Gap," Scientist 16,
no. 10 (13 May 2002), http://www.fl000scientist.com/article/
display/13038.
(14) Jean O. Lanjouw, "A Patent Policy for Global
Diseases" (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 11 June
2001), 26, http://www.brookings.edu/papers/2001/0611development_lanjouw.
aspx.
(15) Deere, 12.
(16) Arora Ashish, Lee Branstetter, and Chirantan Chaterjee,
"Strong Medicine: Patent Reform and the Transformation of the
Indian Pharmaceutical Industry," (working paper, National Bureau of
Economic Research (NBER) draft paper for Conference on Location of
Biopharmaceutical Activity, 6-8 March 2008),
http://chirantanc.weebly.com/ uploads/3/7/4/9/3749410/branstetter.pdf.
(17) Joseph E. Stiglitz, "Scrooge and Intellectual Property
Rights," BMJ: British Medical Journal 333 (21 December 2006), 1279.
(18) Prominent proposals include Alden Hollis and Thomas Pogge, The
Health Impact Fund: Making New Medicines Accessible for All (New Haven,
CT: Incentives for Global Health, Yale University, 2008),
http://www.yale.edu/macmillan/igh/hif.html; Michael Kremer and Rachel
Glennerster, Strong Medicine: Creating Incentives for Pharmaceutical
Research on Neglected Diseases (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 2004), http://press.princeton.edu/titles/7830.html.
(19) Archie M. Palmer, "Medical Patents," Journal of the
American Medical Association 137, no. 6 (5 June 1948), 497-508.
(20) David C. Mowery and Bhaven N. Sampat, "University Patents
and Patent Policy Debates in the USA, 1925-1980," Industrial and
Corporate Change 10, no. 3 (Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, 2001),
781-814.
(21) David Mowery et al., Ivory Tower and Industrial Innovation:
University-Industry Technology Transfer Before and After the Bayh-Dole
Act (Stanford, CA: Stanford Business Books, 2004), Chapter 3, 35-57,
and, in particular, 36-38, 42-45.
(22) Sylvia Ostry and Richard R. Nelson, Techno-Nationalism and
Techno-Globalism (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1995),
49-61.
(23) Mowery and Sampat, 781-814; See also Mowery et al., 89-91.
(24) Yudhijit Bhattacharjee, "Indian Government Hopes Bill
Will Stimulate Innovation," Science 319 (1 February 2008), 556a.
(25) The Bayh-Dole Act or "University and Small Business
Patent Procedures Act" is codified in 35 U.S.C. [section] 200-212,
and implemented by 37 C.F.R. 401, http://www.access.gpo.gov/nara/cfr/
waisidx_02/37cfr401_02.html; Mowery et al., (2004), Chapter 5, "A
Political History of the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980," 85-98.
(26) Ostry and Nelson.
(27) David Mowery et al., "The Growth of Patenting and
Licensing by U.S. Universities: An Assessment of the Effects of the
Bayh-Dole Act of 1980," Research Policy 30 (2001), 99-119; Mowery
et al., (2004), 90-92.
(28) Bhaven N. Sampat, "Patenting and US Academic Research in
the 20th Century: The World Before and After Bayh-Dole," Research
Policy 35, no. 6 (July 2006), 776-77.
(29) Pierre Azoulay, Ryan Michigan, and Bhaven N. Sampat, "The
Anatomy of Medical School Patenting," New England Journal of
Medicine 357, no. 20 (Waltham, MA: Massachusetts Medical Society, 2007),
2049-26.
(30) Mowery et al., (2004), 166-69.
(31) This section draws on the discussion in Mowery et al., (2004).
(32) Peter Arno and Michael Davis, "Why Don't We Enforce
Existing Price Controls? The Unrecognized and Unenforced Reasonable
Pricing Requirements Imposed Upon Patents Deriving In Whole or In Part
From Federally-Funded Research," Tulane Law Review 75, (January
2001).
(33) Matthew Herder, "Asking for Money Back: Chilling
Commercialization of Recouping Public Trust in the Context of Stem Cell Research?" Columbia Science and Technology Law Review 203 (14 May
2008), 211.
(34) Essential Medicines, a public interest group, filed a
"March In" petition under the Bayh-Dole Act seeking to lower
consumer prices for Xalatan,
http://www.ott.nih.gov/policy/March-in-xalatan.pdf. In a separate case,
CellPro asked the Clinton Administration for a compulsory license to
four patents held by Johns Hopkins University, also under the
"March In" provisions of the Bayh-Dole Act, http://
www.cptech.org/ip/health/bd/cellpro.html.
(35) Amy Kapczynski et al., "Addressing Global Health
Inequities: An Open Licensing Approach for University Innovations,"
Berkeley Technology Law Journal 20, no. 2 (2005), 1048.
(36) "Homepage," Universities Allied for Essential
Medicines, 2010, http://essentialmedicine.org/.
(37) Follow-on patents are additional patents filed on an invention
that is already patent-protected, for the purpose of extending the
original patent term. This is often referred to as
'evergreening.'
(38) Bhaven N. Sampat, "Academic Patents and Access to
Medicines in Developing Countries," American Journal of Public
Health 99, no. 1 (January 2009), 9-17.
(39) Swathi Padmanabhan et al., "Intellectual Property,
Technology Transfer and Manufacture of LowCost HPV Vaccines in
India," Nature Biotechnology 7 (28 July 2010), 671-678.
(40) "Notable Signatories," Universities Allied for
Essential Medicines, 2010, http://essentialmedicine.
org/cs/notable-signatories.
(41) "Statement of Principles and Strategies for the Equitable
Dissemination of Medical Technologies," signed by Association of
University Technology Managers (AUTM), Boston University, Brown
University, Harvard University, Oregon Health & Science University,
University of Pennsylvania and Yale University,
http://www.autm.net/Content/NavigationMenu/TechTransfer/GlobalHealth/
statementofprincliples.pdf.
(42) UAEM's activities have recently broadened, in addition to
continuing to push for changes in university licensing policy, the group
now advocates for neglected disease research; is involved in development
of metrics to assess the social impact of university research; and
evaluates a range of patent policies affecting access to medicines,
e.g., the international emulation of the Bayh-Dole Act,
www.essentialmedicines.org.
(43) Richard A. Jensen, Jerry G. Thursby, and Marie C. Thursbv,
"Disclosure and Licensing of University inventions: The Best We Can
Do With the Sh*t We Get to Work With," International Journal of
Industrial Organization 21, no. 9 (2003), 1271-1300.
(44) Richard Jensen and Marie Thursby, "Proofs and Prototypes
for Sale: The Licensing of University Inventions," American
Economic Review 91, no. 1 (1 March 2001), 240-59.
(45) Jenny Lanouw and Margaret MacLeod, "Statistical Trends in
Pharmaceutical Research for Poor Countries," (20 April 2005),
http://www.who.int/intellectualproperty/studies/Lanjouw_Statistical%20
Trends.pdf.
(46) Louis Menand, Marketplace of Ideas: Reform and Resistance in
the American University (New York, NY: W. W. Norton &Company, Inc.,
2010), 15.
(47) Lawrence O. Gostin, "Why Rich Countries Should Care About
the World's Least Healthy People," Journal of the American
Medical Association 298, no. 1 (4 July 2007), 89-92.
Bhaven N. Sampat, PhD, is an assistant professor in the Department
of Health Policy and Management at the Mailman School of Public Health
and (by courtesy) in the School of International and Public Affairs at
Columbia University.