Methods of privatization.
Berg, Andrew ; Berg, Elliot
Privatization has been in fashion for more than 15 years, if we
date its recent flowering from Margaret Thatcher's initiatives in
the late 1970s. Shrinking the state's economic presence became part
of the economic reform programs that characterized economic policy
throughout much of the world in the 1980s. The collapse of communism in
Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union (FSU) moved privatization
issues onto a much larger stage in the 1990s.
Privatization in the broadest sense means giving private actors a
greater role in decisions about what, where, and how to produce goods
and services. A great deal of experience has now accumulated regarding
this process. Some of it shows the great potential that privatization
has for increasing productivity, income and welfare.(1)
However, it also reveals the complexity and difficulty of
effective privatization. Privatization even in the narrower sense of
"divestiture"--the sale of state-owned enterprises (SOEs)--has
presented greater challenges than its early advocates envisaged.
Relatively few countries account for most of the divestiture
activity in recent years. Thus, of the roughly $300 billion in
divestitures between 1988 and 1994, two-thirds occurred in industrial
countries. (This excludes sales of small enterprises and give-aways such
as "mass privatization" programs.) The five biggest
privatizations--among them Japanese Railways, British Telecom, and
Deutsche Telekom--account for some $60 billion in proceeds. Of the $100
billion in developing country privatizations, more than half took place
in Latin America.(2)
In developing countries, macroeconomic impacts of privatization
activity have been small in most cases. Despite the widespread
privatization rhetoric and many formal structural adjustment programs
under World Bank sponsorship, the average public enterprise sector share
in gross domestic product for 40 low- and medium-income developing
countries between the late 1970s and the early 1990s remained unchanged,
as did the sector's share in wage employment.(3)
In the low-income developing countries (those with average per
capita incomes below $600 a year) the pace of privatization has been
particularly slow. In sub-Saharan Africa, for example, only 1800 (mostly
small) divestiture transactions took place between 1980 and 1995, with a
sale value of about $2 billion. In only six countries (Benin, Ghana,
Guinea, Mozambique, Nigeria, South Africa and Uganda) did total sales
through 1995 amount to more than $50 million, which suggests
insignificant reductions in the relative size of the public enterprise
sectors in most of the continent. Ghana, Nigeria and South Africa
account for almost 70 percent of the total sales value of African
privatizations.(4)
Overall progress has been much faster in Eastern Europe and the
FSU. Most of these countries have succeeded in moving from almost
complete domination by the state sector to predominantly private
economies.(5) However, only a few of these countries have been able to
divest many state enterprises to new managers, and the problem of using
former state assets more efficiently remains problematic in much of the
region.
Many factors enter into the explanation of these patterns of
privatization. In this paper, we focus on only one of these: the
relationship between methods or techniques of privatization and the
objectives that governments seek to attain through privatization. This
has two related dimensions: the fit between method and objectives, and
the incompatibilities between various objectives.
The main objectives, explicit or implicit in most privatization
programs, are: fiscal relief by cutting government subsidies to
money-losing SOEs and/or by generating new revenues from their sale;
increased enterprise efficiency; increased efficiency of the entire
economy through more competitive markets and better allocation of
resources across firms and sectors; increased political support and
broadened institutional underpinnings for a market-based economy or
further liberalization; stronger financial markets; increased investment
and the stimulation of entrepreneurship.
The main methods to be reviewed here fall into five broad
categories: sales of shares or assets; capital dilution;
management-employee buy-outs (MEBOs); broad-based or mass privatization;
and indirect or partial privatizations via management contracts, leases
or service contracts. These categories are convenient but not entirely
mutually exclusive: MEBOs are a type of sale, while mass privatization
involves some combination of the other methods with some type of free
distribution of shares or vouchers.
Before we turn to a discussion of these techniques, we should note
that we are leaving out a number of privatization instruments, the most
important being privatization through liberalization.(6) The creation
and growth of new private firms, along with a withering of state
enterprises, has been even more important in many of the transition
countries than privatization in terms of the reduction of the
state's ownership share.
Consider two otherwise dissimilar examples: Poland and China.
Poland's private sector has grown from 29 percent of gross domestic
product (GDP) in 1989, largely in agriculture, to 56 percent in 1994.
Though classification and data problems make the calculation difficult,
most private sector growth in Poland appears to have come from the
creation and growth of new firms, not from privatization of existing
firms.(7) The workers and, in some cases, the assets for these private
firms presumably originated in the state sector, but these were pushed
out by economic pressures on state enterprises or pulled out by the
attraction of high profits in the private sector. China is perhaps an
even more dramatic example, though definitional and measurement issues
are even more difficult. The share of the non-state sector, including
so-called township-and-village enterprises (TVEs), in gross industrial
output rose from 24 percent in 1980 to 57 percent in 1994, solely
through differential growth rates following liberalization.(8)
This is clearly privatization in the broadest sense, but a full
discussion of this method lies outside the scope of this paper. Suffice
it to say that macroeconomic stability, price and trade liberalization,
elimination of restrictions on start-up firms and a real hardening of
the budget constraints facing state enterprises appear to be required to
allow fast privatization, as well, perhaps, as a tolerance for the
methods by which assets find themselves in private hands.(9)
Turning now to privatization itself, we consider each of the five
methods in turn. We describe each briefly, provide relevant examples,
indicate prevalence, summarize strengths and weaknesses and show how
various methods entail trade-offs between government objectives.
Sale of Shares or Assets
The classic type of privatization is the sale of full or partial
ownership of a state enterprise by public offering on stock exchanges,
by competitive bidding for shares or assets or by non-competitive
placement of shares.
Public Flotation of Shares
Under this method, the state sells to the general public through
the stock market and other financial institutions all or a substantial
part of the stock it holds in a going concern. The initial public
offering (IPO) is often combined with other methods, such as the sale of
shares to employees on favorable terms.
The public flotation is politically appealing and has great
revenue-raising potential. It allows broad ownership, which is always
more popular than a sale to powerful domestic or foreign buyers. Wider
stock ownership is a common objective in most privatization programs, as
it was for example in the United Kingdom, Jamaica, Chile and more
recently in Germany. It also has the effect of locking in privatization
actions. Most observers believe, for example, that renationalization of
Chile's telecom SOE is unlikely because, as a result of mandated
preferences for small investors, one-third of the shares of the major
telecommunications company has passed to the general public.
Public flotation is also flexible. It allows targeting of
particular groups to meet political objectives or social purposes. Thus,
in some Jamaican privatizations, as in Chile and elsewhere, small buyers
were given preference. In the sale of the Jamaican National Commercial
Bank, for example, no investor was allowed to own more than 7.5 percent
of the outstanding shares.(10) Sale via public flotations can also
contribute strongly to the development of local capital markets, as in
Jamaica, where the initial privatizations increased the capitalization
of traded shares by 40 percent.
Public offerings are also more transparent than other methods.
Prices are set by the market for all to see, and for anyone to buy.
Since one of the main obstacles to privatization is widespread public
concern about corruption and cronyism, this is no small advantage. Sale
through the stock market can be accompanied by private placements--to
pension funds, to disadvantaged groups or to employees, thereby
increasing the equity of the transaction.
In addition, public offerings allow gradual approaches. Sales can
be organized in tranches, with first tranche prices and conditions being
designed to win acceptance, and later tranches set at higher prices to
benefit from improved enterprise performance and better knowledge in the
market about the privatized firm.
The characteristics of IPOs that make them attractive also make
them hard to implement, especially if speed is an objective. Their
clarity and transparency bring tremendous transaction costs--such as
preparation for sale, valuations and managing the offer. As a result,
only larger SOEs or large government holdings are usually appropriate.
Moreover, firms have to be readied for sale. They must be made
attractive to buyers. At the same time, the diffuse ownership that tends
to result means management will likely not change, nor will owners exert
strong control after privatization. This often means restructuring,
government absorption of debt and new investment. Also, market
conditions have to be right. Where markets are not buoyant, offerings
can fail. This happened recently in Indonesia, Brazil, Turkey and some
other countries.(11)
Conflicts of objectives are inherent in setting the offer price of
shares to be sold. Governments may seek a high price to achieve its
revenue objective and to avoid later charges of giving away crown jewels at fire-sale prices. The objectives of winning political and market
acceptability, however, dictate a low price. But pricing shares too low
not only invites later political attack, but erodes another objective of
widespread popular ownership. Low-income buyers and employees tend to
sell their holdings if share prices rise rapidly after initial
offerings.
The case of Polish bank privatization illustrates the potential
importance of this pricing problem. The government determined that it
would privatize the major commercial banks partly through IPOs, with the
rest sold to employees or to a strategic investor or remaining with the
Treasury. After one successful offering in April 1993, the second bank
sale in December of that year turned out to be substantially
underpriced, with shares skyrocketing more than 13 times on the first
day of trading. The large windfall gain this provided to those who were
able to buy the shares initially, and in particular to the employees and
management who were able to purchase 10 percent, led to public outcry.
Partly for this reason, the program was halted so that it could be
reformulated. No further major banks have been privatized in Poland,
despite forecasts in 1994 that the remaining seven large banks would be
privatized before 1997.
These pricing dilemmas and how they have been handled have
generated some disappointment with privatization in Europe. A recent
article in the Economist laments the fact that, while privatization has
broadened financial markets (since 1985 it has added about 1 percent a
year to the capitalization of listed shares in European stock markets),
it has not been successful in turning Europe into a continent of
shareholders. While 20 percent of U.S. households own stocks, and around
15 percent in Britain, the comparable figure for Germany and France is
still not much more than 5 percent. One reason is that small investors
have not always done well. In France, privatized company shares have
underperformed the market; a consistent buyer of privatized shares since
1990 would in fact have lost money.(12)
There is also a conflict between providing financing for employee
purchase of shares (installment sales) and the risk that share prices
will fall, leaving employees with net losses and debt obligations. This
can be avoided by providing repurchase guarantees--buy-back arrangements
that insure workers against losses. In recent flotations in Spain, Italy
and Germany, all investors have been sheltered from falling share prices
by such devices. But such protective measures also entail a conflict. As
the Economist noted: "Such tricks seem to subvert the point of
privatization. What purpose, after all, is served by teaching potential
investors that owning equities is all profit and no risk?"(13)
Public offerings result in diffuse ownership and give no assurance
that assets will be better-managed than under government ownership.
Where SOEs have been operating in competitive markets and/or
autonomously, and hence have not been notably inefficient, this may not
matter. This was apparently the case with the privatization of the
National Commercial Bank in Jamaica, where the goal of increased
efficiency at the enterprise level was secondary or absent; political
acceptability through diffuse ownership mattered much more. However,
sacrifice of efficiency objectives undermines a major rationale for some
privatization, especially in poorer and slower-growing countries. Many
governments therefore try to combine public offerings with sale of
substantial ownership shares to core or strategic investors who can
bring about restructuring through better management, new investment and
access to new markets.
One privatization story from Bangladesh illustrates how stock
market flotations of minority ownership shares can fail to improve
management, while sale of majority ownership to a technical partner can
lead to vastly better performance.(14) The stateowned Kohinoor Chemical
Company, a major producer of soaps and cosmetics, sold 49 percent of its
shares in a public offering in 1988. Going public did not affect
corporate performance, however. Because of poor management and
marketing, annual sales fell by two-thirds between 1989 and 1992. The
labor force grew from 350 to 1200, and overtime payments also grew. A
widely cited example of management laxity was the employment of 27
drivers for the company's fleet of 5 cars; drivers and security
staff nonetheless claimed substantial overtime.
In July 1993, the Bangladesh government's 51 percent share in
the company was sold to the highest of four bidders. Soon after, the
work force was cut to 650 people. Overtime disappeared. Production
processes were overhauled and new marketing efforts undertaken. Part of
the terms of sale was that the company would retain the 650-person work
force for a year. Since only 350 employees were needed, the management
introduced a scheme of team competition. The workers were divided into
two teams, each working alternative weeks. Output per worker has shot
up--five-fold, according to some observers. Production has increased by
30 percent. The company has offered continued employment to all its
workers based on future profitability and expansion.
Given the advantages and difficulties of public offerings, it is
not surprising that they are found principally in the developed world
and among the more advanced of the developing countries. Indeed, most
industrialized country privatizations have been through public
offerings. In low-income and transition economies that have not had
well-developed stock markets, financial institutions or regulatory
arrangements, IPOs have been much more infrequent.(15) They are not
unknown in the more developed transition economies, especially in
Hungary, the Czech Republic and Poland.(16) In sub-Saharan Africa, there
appear to have been fewer than 70 public flotations, in only five
countries, namely Cote d'Ivoire, Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria and
Zambia.(17)
Variants of public offerings have been devised in conjunction with
mass-privatization approaches. Mass forms of IPOs have been rare for the
same reasons that it is difficult to arrange even one. Some countries
that distributed vouchers widely allowed their use for the purchase of
shares in individual enterprises, most commonly in the form of auctions,
such as in Russia, the Czech Republic and Mongolia. In Mongolia and in
the former Czechoslovakia, large enterprises were sold through
centralized voucher auctions, with the resulting shares trading on a
stock exchange.
Competitive Bidding
Sale of either part or all of an SOE's shares or assets by
public tender is the most common privatization instrument worldwide.
Most small firms in the transition economies were privatized by auction,
as were many firms in the developing countries. For small retail shops,
small-scale transport and service operations generally, auctions are
quick, present few valuation problems and can generate revenue for the
state budget. Problems of asymmetric information, when present managers
know more about the firm than outsiders, are relatively small. In any
case, the markets in question are easily contestable; competition is
likely to prevail.
Competitive bidding is a component of most mass-privatization
schemes implemented in recent years in Eastern Europe and the FSU. In
Russia, most medium and large enterprises have been privatized in part
through public auctions of shares for vouchers (coupons), which had been
distributed nationwide for a nominal fee. There, and in Mongolia, the
vouchers can be used to buy shares of privatized companies. In the Czech
Republic and Slovakia, investment funds bid for shares in thousands of
medium and large state enterprises in a carefully structured, multi-step
nationwide auction.
Sales of medium- and large-scale enterprises and, in poor
countries, even smaller firms are usually done by formal tendering. As
with share flotations, transaction costs can be substantial, if the
tendering is done right. The accounts of the firms to be sold have to be
brought up-to-date and audited, outstanding liabilities and asset values
determined and future profitability estimated. Pre-privatization
analyses should yield suggested minimum selling prices and should result
in the preparation of an information memorandum for potential bidders.
Governments are frequently interested in other terms of sale besides
price--whether the transaction will be for cash, for example, and, more
importantly, whether the buyer commits to maintaining employment or
injecting new investment.
For larger firms, the pretransaction preparatory work is often
done by investment banks or management-consulting firms, and not
infrequently with financing from foreign aid sources. The consultants
also help with marketing through contacting potential buyers and with
advertising. Tender announcements appear weekly in the Wall Street
Journal, the Economist, the International Herald Tribune, and similar
publications.(18)
Sometimes assets are sold rather than shares in entire going
concerns. This may be done because state entities are too small to
justify the costs of being corporatized--being put in joint stock
company legal form--before privatization. But other reasons are more
important. The government may want to spin off unrelated or unprofitable
divisions or subsidiaries before selling the core enterprise. Sale of
assets allows this kind of unbundling. It also may be the only way to
deal with complicated situations. In the case of a Nicaraguan
construction company, regional branches were sold to workers and
management as separate units; heavy equipment at the main site was
transferred to the state public works department, while the main office
was returned to the former owners.(19)
Some companies cannot be privatized by share sales (in other
words, as going concerns) because uncertainties about their contingent
liabilities are too great. In this case they can be dissolved and
liquidated and their assets sold without attached liabilities. A new
company (very often with the same name) then rises from the ashes. This
is an extremely common phenomenon, as well a major source of confusion
in statistics on numbers of privatizations and liquidations.(20)
Sale of SOEs through competitive bidding avoids the major
deficiency of public flotations: uncertain impact on corporate
governance and therefore on improved firm-level efficiency. Most of
these transactions entail sales of going concerns; they are of the type
commonly called "trade sales." Buyers are technical partners
or core investors who will take over management and will have incentives
to enhance profitability. This presumably means cost-cutting, increased
productivity through better organization and new investment and a search
for new market opportunities. The objectives of increased investment and
penetration of new markets are especially likely to be achieved through
sales to foreign investors.
The objective of raising revenue may also be achieved by
competitive bidding. However, the proceeds will depend on whether
restructuring costs and debt obligations have to be assumed by the
central government. Proceeds depend also on how wide the net is cast in
seeking buyers. Purchase can be restricted to nationals in order to meet
the political acceptability goal, but this will reduce the fiscal
impact. At least as important, and often overlooked, is the fact that
proceeds depend on the intensity and effectiveness of marketing. Too
often in the past, marketing efforts have been perfunctory, with few ads
appearing in the international press. Few potential buyers appear, and
the selling price suffers accordingly.
Tradeoffs often emerge in the bidding process itself. Political
acceptability demands objective criteria and complete transparency--such
as the listing of bid prices and the publishing of bases of all awards.
This works in the direction of acceptance of the highest bid. But
subjective elements invariably cloud the decision. Some bidders are more
credible than others, and most governments have multiple selection
criteria, such as whether injections of new investment will be made,
debt obligations absorbed and commitments about employment entered into.
In the end, bids are often not comparable. Thus, even where
well-specified procedures are carefully followed and the process is
wholly above-board, competitive bidding may not dissipate all suspicions
of foul play. It is nonetheless usually the most even-handed and
transparent option available.
The most pervasive trade-off in the privatization process concerns
time--the sacrifice of key objectives for speedy action. A recent study
of experience in privatizing telephone companies in Argentina, Jamaica,
Mexico and Venezuela illustrates the point.(21) In some of these
countries, haste and a desire for revenues crowded out other goals and
led to deficient regulatory systems and concession agreements that were,
in many instances, unfavorable to the privatizing governments.(22)
In Argentina, the original plan had been to privatize with a view
to increasing competition. It had envisaged breaking up the national
telephone monopoly into two regional companies; free entry into
long-distance services was to be allowed immediately, with entry into
all services allowed after only five years. All cross-subsidies
(financing low price domestic services by charging high prices for long
distance) were to be abandoned. However, as negotiation unfolded, these
ideas were largely dropped to get a quicker sale. The goal of generating
revenues, and demonstrating to investors that the economy was truly
opening up assumed higher priority. Very low targets were set for
expansion and quality, and post-privatization regulatory rules were
sketchy.
The cost of haste is most evident in the case of Jamaica, which
was pressed to meet World Bank conditions regarding the amount of
revenue derived from SOE sales. Buyers received a 24-year monopoly
(compared to 6 years in Mexico), and no specific targets were set for
expansion of service, nor for quality of service; penalties for
non-performance were also inadequate. The Jamaican buyers were
guaranteed a real, after-tax annual rate of return of 17.5 to 20
percent.
More privatization transactions are completed globally by
competitive bidding than by any other method. In industrialized
countries, which mainly use public flotations, it is not the most common
method but does occur. Examples include the sale of Leyland Bus and
Truck in the United Kingdom in 1986, and more recent sales of water and
power companies. It is probably the most common method in middle-income
developing countries. In the transition economies, competitive bidding
using vouchers was used to buy shares in Mongolia's first wave of
privatization. Russia's sales also were by competitive bidding,
using vouchers. In both cases, however, there are problems of
definition, since insiders received such preference that the process
resembled management-employee buyouts more than competitive bidding.
Trade sale-type bidding (one firm bidding to buy control of an
SOE) has been infrequent in the transition economies. Only in Estonia
and Hungary have privatizations by sale to outsiders (non-employees or
managers) been substantial.
Data on transactions by technique applied are also available for
sub-Saharan Africa.(23) Out of some 1800 transactions between 1980 and
mid-1995, almost half were by competitive bids for all or part of going
concerns. It has been the most frequently-used technique in that part of
the world.
Noncompetitive Sales or Transfers
These kinds of sales take many forms. The state may find it
advisable to sell to a preselected buyer without competitive bidding.
This is sometimes called a private placement. A good strategic investor
may have made an offer that meets the government's price and other
requirements, and officials may decide therefore that further bidding is
superfluous. Some or most of the shares (or assets) may change hands in
this kind of transaction, which may be accompanied by public flotation,
award of preferential shares to employees, or other placements.
A noncompetitive sale may follow a failed tender. In Guinea, five
bidders responded to a 1995 request for bids to purchase a controlling
share of the government telecommunications monopoly. After careful
assessment, all these bids were rejected. A later proposal by the
Malaysian telecommunication company was accepted for want of a better
alternative.(24)
Placement of shares with insurance companies, pension funds and
other financial institutions is a common noncompetitive means of
privatizing ownership. Restitution, the return of companies to former
owners, is of course noncompetitive. Joint ventures or mixed companies
are other noncompetitive methods. Private partners often have so-called
preemptive rights, the right of first offer when the public partner
decides to sell shares. This is a common situation where private owners
retain some ownership after bouts of nationalization, as for example in
Zambia, where recent privatization actions included numerous sales to
those with preemptive rights. A key problem here is determination of the
sales price of shares, since there are no market values to go by.
Finally, transfers of shares to trusts can be included in this
category of methods. Various kinds of transactions are currently in
operation. The most famous outside the transition economies is the
special trust set up by the Malaysian government as part of its
preferential program for native Malays, the Bumiputra. Shares of public
corporations reserved for the Bumiputra are deposited in this trust,
which now holds a significant share of the total capital stock in the
country.
The Zambian Privatization Trust Fund is a variation on this
theme.(25) It holds in storage, for future sale to small local
investors, shares in privatized companies. Part of the rationale is to
distance the government from the newly privatized activities; government
no longer votes the transferred shares. The rationale also is that the
fund's managers can operate without haste and in an environment
that is better informed than at the time of implementation of the
privatization program. The fund can issue shares through public
offerings and by sales to pension funds, insurance companies, and other
intermediaries. It can give small investors special incentives and can
set down ownership limits to avoid undue concentration. The board of the
fund is drawn from the private sector and management is contracted by
competitive bidding. If shares are not sold after five years, the fund
will become a unit trust and will be sold to Zambian investors. Unsold
shares could be given away free to Zambian citizens.
Mass-privatization programs have also involved a transfer of sales
to trusts. In Poland, the government established National Investment
Funds (NIFs) and distributed shares from about 500 medium and large
enterprises to these NIFs. Each citizen was then allowed to purchase a
certificate of ownership (voucher), which was essentially a share in
each of the NIFs, for a nominal fee.
The benefit of noncompetitive sales is that they can be cheaper,
easier and quicker than alternative methods. Particular technical
partners with special competence can be sought out, creating good
prospects for more efficient management. Negotiations can be more
flexible than those in formal bids. Political and social objectives can
be well-targeted; for example, shares can be distributed to
underprivileged groups, or to employees and other stakeholders or to
insurance companies and pension funds. Entrepreneurship-nurturing
objectives can be served. The trusts may be able to serve some corporate
governance role.
Noncompetitive approaches thus satisfy many objectives. Aside from
the allocation to trusts, however, these noncompetitive approaches
suffer from one major disability: they are inherently less transparent
than competitive methods, and such transactions are often attacked as
unfair or corrupt. Negotiation with one potential buyer also often
entails long and frustrating dealings with slippery partners.(26)
Perhaps for these reasons, noncompetitive bidding in privatization is
not very prevalent in most countries. A sub-Saharan African inventory
suggests that about a third of the 1,800 transactions (1980-1995) that
involved sales of shares or assets were done noncompetitively.(27)
Capital Dilution or Capitalization
Privatization can occur without the state disposing of any of its
equity, but rather adding to it by allowing a private investor to buy
in. The result is a capital increase, with the government's share
declining. Many joint ventures are formed this way. In Nicaragua, the
government put up the routes of its Aeronica Airline for a 51 percent
share in a joint venture, with the private sector partner contributing
cash, equipment and management. Capital dilution is also an easy vehicle
to transform partially private companies to more fully private firms, as
in the case of the 1995 capital injection to the Guinea Industrial and
Commercial Bank, which reduced government's equity from 89 percent
to 12 percent of the total.
Capital dilution/joint ventures are often politically acceptable,
since the government retains a large or even majority share in
ownership. If the government is a passive owner, allowing full autonomy
to the private management, economic efficiency goals are likely to be
well-served. This approach gives undercapitalized enterprises new life,
although problems of working capital scarcity may remain. It is also
fast, especially where existing partial ownership by a core investor is
supplemented by new capital injections. However, risks do exist
regarding transparency and equity, notably in setting share prices. In
many countries there are no rules for how share prices should be
determined in cases of internal acquisition. Using book values in
prosperous enterprises (especially banks) can result in an underpricing of the government's shares.
The Bolivian capitalization scheme is a variant of capital
dilution. The government is currently transferring to private hands half
the ownership and all the management of the six biggest public
enterprises--the rail, air, power, phone and petroleum distribution
monopolies, and mining smelters. International investors invest new
capital for up to half the equity of the enterprise. Core investors sign
management contracts, including an option to purchase additional shares
later. The new capital can be used for investment or working capital.
The remaining half of the equity will be held by 5 to 10 new private
pension funds, which will provide retirement and disability benefits to
shareholders.(28)
The main disadvantage of the Bolivian approach is that, by giving
away its interests in SOEs, the government may be sacrificing the
revenue-generating objective. This loss of revenue may be mitigated,
however, to the extent that the transfer of assets to pension funds
substitutes for other resources the government would have had to put
into the pension funds. The delays caused by the need to work out the
details of the new pension scheme is a minor inconvenience. On the other
hand, powerful advantages are evident. The removal of government from
ownership of the SOEs deepens the credibility of the government's
commitment to privatization and market reform. This increases the
attractiveness of the firms to be sold, especially to foreign buyers.
The privatized entity benefits from the availability of new resources
for working capital or investment.
In addition, although not directly due to the capitalization
scheme, Bolivia has been able to adopt a near state-of-the-art strategy
for privatizing of its major public utilities involving the abandonment
of old notions about "natural monopolies." In the case of
electric power, for example, monopolies can be broken into at least
three components: generation of power, transmission and distribution to
users. The idea is to introduce competition on the generation and
distribution sides while giving equal access to the transmission
facility. This approach to privatizing infrastructure has been pioneered
in the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Chile, Argentina and the United
States. Bolivia now joins the front ranks of countries that are
privatizing infrastructure with an emphasis on competition. The
government describes its program thus:
The Ministry of Capitalization of Bolivia intends
to transfer the electricity transmission network in
the Bolivian interconnected system, currently
owned by the state company ENDE, to the private
sector through an international public bidding to
be completed in the first quarter of 1997. The transfer
of the transmission network to the private sector
is the latest stage in the wholesale restructuring
of the Bolivian electricity system. This process has
involved the passing of a new electricity law and
regulations, the introduction of a new regulatory
structure for the industry, the capitalization of three
new electricity generating companies formed from
the generation assets of ENDE (through the subscription
of 50 percent share holdings in the capitalized
companies and granting of management
control to three leading US electricity operators)
and the sale of two major distribution companies
to Spanish and Chilean utilities.(29)
Africa is the only region for which there is data regarding the
incidence of privatization by joint ventures or capitalization. The
African inventory data to which we have referred above records only 34
joint ventures or capital dilution privatizations between 1980 and 1995,
out of more than 1800 transactions.
Management-Employee Buyouts (MEBOs)
Three main types of Management-Employee Buyouts (MEBOs) can be
distinguished. In many developing and transition economies, small
establishments--for example, retail outlets, restaurants, hotels,
bookstores, trucks and buses--are sold to employees. Countless
privatizations have taken place this way, though they do not seem to
show up in privatization inventories. One reason is that they are often
under $50,000. Another is that they may be listed as liquidations, since
state enterprises are often legally dissolved before the assets pass
into employee hands.
In Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union, tens of thousands
of small establishments were privatized by transfer to employees.(30) In
Guinea and Mozambique, dozens of regional state food distribution
outlets became employee-owned or leased. In Nicaragua, buyouts were
encouraged by a policy that set 25 percent of each privatized firm aside
for employees. The assets of one gold mine in that country were sold to
workers employed anywhere in the mining industry; in the construction
company fragmentation, six regional entities were sold to employees.(31)
The World Bank's recent study on African privatization was able to
identify only 22 MEBOs, about one percent of total privatization
transactions. This is certainly very much below the true figures, for
reasons suggested above.
The second type of MEBO involves employee stock ownership of
medium- and large-scale enterprises. These are fairly common in
industrial countries. The first major privatization of this type was in
the United Kingdom with the sale of the National Freight Corporation in
1982 to a consortium of existing and retired employees and 4 banks, with
employees taking over 80 percent of the shares. Examples are also found
in developing countries. In Chile, employees bought most of the stock of
Soquimich, a sizeable producer of nitrates. When ENDESA, the state-owned
power company in Chile, was broken up for privatization, one of the
units, EMEL, was sold to employees. There have been cases in Asia and
elsewhere, though usually of middle-sized companies.
A recent example from Pakistan gives the flavor of these
transactions.(32) In January 1992, employees of Millat Tractor Limited
took over management after purchase of 51 percent of the shares. Most
employees participated, financing 40 percent of the purchase with cash
and the rest with a bank loan secured by their pension funds. They won
out over four other bidders. The employees elected seven of the nine
directors, although five of the seven are nominated by the lending
banks. About half of the 49 percent nonemployee share is held by
stockholders who purchased shares through the stock exchange, and the
other half is held by government financial institutions. Of the 51
percent worker share, about 30 percent is held by workers and 70 percent
by executives. The company has made some difficult decisions since and
appears to be thriving.(33)
The third and numerically most significant form of MEBO is de
facto insider domination of nominally open privatizations Examples in
transition economies abound. Most of Russian industry has been
privatized this way. The Russian model took the form of a voucher
program that gave special preferences to employees of state enterprises,
usually resulting in MEBOs in practice. In Mongolia, workers (and their
families) chose to buy shares largely in "their" enterprises,
ending up with 45 percent of the total shares, according to one
survey.(34) Most enterprises privatized in Poland have been privatized
through so-called liquidation.(35) This has taken various forms, but
involves the sale of either the enterprise or its assets through auction
for cash. In most of these, the managers and/or the workers ended up
owning controlling shares after privatization.(36)
MEBOs address one of the central obstacles to privatization,
particularly in the transition economies where ownership rights and
traditions are vague and not well-protected: the fact that finding new
owners means disenfranchising existing stakeholders. Enterprise
"insiders," such as workers and managers, have a traditional
and de facto claim on the enterprise. Which insiders are important
varies from country to country: in Russia and Hungary, it was the
enterprise managers and government bureaucrats who ran the enterprises
prior to the fall of the Soviet Union; in Poland, where this group was
partly disenfranchised by Solidarity, it was also workers. Insider power
derives from a variety of sources. One is political; in some countries,
managers and/or workers have political power and can control the
privatization process, or at least block it. Another source of power is
legal; in Poland, workers voted on privatization schemes for
"their" enterprises. More generally, though, insiders both
care more about "their" enterprise than most others and know
more, which gives them bargaining leverage. Especially where court
systems are weak and laws nonexistent or incomplete, de facto control
can be vital. In Russia, enterprise managers have at times simply locked
shareholders out of meetings or not informed them of the time and place.
MEBOs of shops and other small establishments can be speedily and
easily done. There is no faster way to establish unambiguous private
property rights over state assets. They are also relatively equitable
and favorable to employees and thus may be politically palatable.
However, they fail the revenue generation test, with prices sometimes so
low as to approach free distribution. MEBOs also have a mixed score on
the entrepreneurship-encouragement criterion. On the one hand, evidence
from several studies suggests privatization that leaves the original
management in charge results in much less entrepreneurial activity than
other methods.(37) On the other hand, entry of new investors over time
is presumably facilitated through the establishment of property rights,
and in any case the counterfactual may be no privatization, not
privatization to outsiders.
MEBOs are the vehicle of choice for small companies in general and
for doubtfully saleable enterprises in particular. Efficiency effects
should be positive because of privatized ownership, although management
competence may not change, except if outsiders are brought in later.
Moreover, insiders may have important information advantages over other
owners. Established industries with stable technologies and low
capital-labor ratios, which are producing in competitive markets, are
most likely to have a successful MEBO. In any event, opportunity costs (sacrificed revenues and imported management) in these circumstances are
likely to be small, and few economic distortions will result.
For larger enterprises, MEBOs are generally more problematic. They
can entail obligations by the government to take over enterprise debts.
Sales often have to be financed on credit of one variety or another, and
that can lead to drawn-out involvement, since many MEBOs of this kind do
not succeed, and governments are often induced to take them over again.
The evidence on the impact of MEBOs on enterprise restructuring is not
yet clear. In one survey of Polish enterprises, employee-owned firms
restructured much more aggressively than state-owned or outsider-owned
firms, but this may have been due to the fact that insiders chose to buy
the more promising enterprises.(38)
Mass Privatization
Mass privatization programs privatize hundreds or thousands of
enterprises at one time. To make this possible, they generally combine
one or more of the above techniques with some sort of free distribution
of assets, shares or buying power over assets (vouchers). Something
along these lines has been used or is under consideration in a number of
transition economies, including the former Czechoslovakia, Russia,
Poland, Romania, Lithuania, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan and Mongolia. It is
the subject of widening discussion as an option in other developing
countries, such as Tanzania and Uganda.
It is easy to see why this approach is appealing. In the
transition economies, almost all industrial production and most output
in other sectors was generated in the state sector. The huge scale of
privatization alone ruled out the "classical" sale as a single
or main method; it would take decades, except in the East German case
where vast subsidies and willing buyers allowed the rapid privatization
of some 8,000 enterprises.
There were other reasons for the appeal of this form of
privatization. Valuation of state enterprises in these economies was
difficult and uncertain, given the lack of a market track record and
persistent distortions that ruled out easy estimates of existing
viability and future profitability. Also, small domestic savings, weak
or nonexistent capital markets and embryonic market institutions made
private buyers few and wary. Foreign investment could and did play some
role, but the new governments and their publics found unacceptable the
idea of selling off large parts of the economy to foreigners.
In sorting through these various programs, it may be useful to
consider that each program has two components: a "supply side"
which dictates how enterprises will be chosen and prepared for
privatization and what will be sold, and a "demand side" which
determines how ownership in the privatized enterprises will be
allocated.(39)
Each of these "sides" presents a number of key issues.
On the supply side, the preparation of large numbers of enterprises for
privatization in a short amount of time can be extremely difficult. For
example, the legal definition of the firm often must be
determined--i.e., does it include shared assets such as a municipal
power plant? More importantly, the claims of various existing
stakeholders such as workers and managers must be dealt with. As
described in the section above on MEBOs, these insiders often have
substantial de facto or de jure power over "their" SOE. These
aspects of the problem are related; preparation of enterprises for
privatization on a large scale requires the cooperation of the insiders.
On the demand side, the problem is how to find owners for hundreds
or thousands of enterprises rapidly and in ways that promote good
enterprise governance, equity, public support and capital market
development. A fundamental question is how widespread distribution of
shares or vouchers can translate into effective governance of the
privatized enterprise; when ownership is extremely diffuse, no one owner
has much incentive to monitor or discipline management. More generally,
the question remains as to whether the pattern that emerges will be
conducive to capital market development, including a well-functioning
stock market.
To illustrate these issues, we will briefly describe the
mass-privatization programs in Poland, the Czech Republic, Russia and
Mongolia.
The Polish program, proposed in 1991 but implemented only in 1996,
cover approximately 500 medium and large enterprises. Enterprise
participation in the program required an affirmative vote by the
workers. Workers receive a relatively small share of the privatized
firm--in effect, they receive 10 percent of the shares free of
charge--and, while they anticipated some benefits from privatization,
they also feared its effects. As a result, it has not been easy for the
government to convince large numbers of promising enterprises to
participate, delaying the program's implementation.
On the demand side, the designers of the Polish program wanted
widespread and fair distribution of ownership in the enterprises, but
they were concerned that diffuse ownership would fail to provide the
strong owners required to supervise difficult but necessary enterprise
restructuring. They therefore transferred most enterprise shares free of
charge to 15 National Investment Funds (NIFs), to act as mutual funds of
sorts, owning most of the shares of each privatized enterprise and in
turn owned by the population. The NIFs are managed by private fund
management companies, often with the participation of foreign financial
institutions that were selected by the government and given incentives
to raise the value of their holdings.
One-third of the shares of each company went as a block to one
NIF, ensuring that each company had one owner with a substantial
interest and hence incentive to provide good corporate governance. Each
citizen was allowed to purchase a voucher, essentially a share in each
of the NIFs, for a nominal fee. The initial Boards of Directors of the
NIFs were appointed by the government, allowing some political control
over the NIFs.
It is too early to judge how effective this program will be. The
program met with stiff political resistance, partly from enterprise
insiders and partly from those fearing the power of the NIFs. Although
its design was essentially complete in 1991, its implementation was
delayed until 1995. Certificates became available for purchase in
November of 1995 for 20 zlotys (about $7 now) and, by the end of the
subscription period in November 1995, certificates had been purchased by
26 million people. With a current secondary market price of about 150
zlotys, the government is encouraged and reportedly is considering
further rounds.
The Czech Republic also distributed ownership widely, in this case
through the sale of vouchers at nominal prices to each citizen. In
Czechoslovakia in 1992, all adult citizens could buy for about $30 a
voucher booklet allowing them to purchase 1,000 shares in up to 10
companies. They could do this either through one of the many investment
funds set up by banks and others, or could bid directly for the shares.
On the "supply side," the powerful central government
had weak insiders to contend with as a result of a system that remained
highly centralized until the end of 1989. Thus, the enterprises had no
choice as to which firms the government would identify to participate in
the program. For each enterprise, the government chose a privatization
project from among those submitted to it, and anyone could submit a
project. Reflecting the insider advantage even in Czechoslovakia, the
projects that were eventually chosen in most cases had been submitted by
the managers of the firm.
These projects specified how the shares in the enterprise would be
sold, whether through tender, voucher auction or cash purchase, among
other options. In the first wave of privatization ending in December
1992, property worth more than $23 billion was sold, $7 billion of which
was through vouchers.(40) Investment funds held approximately 70 percent
of the shares sold in the first wave and a similar proportion of the
voucher points invested in the second wave, which was completed at the
end of 1994.
These two cases demonstrate the power of mass privatization
schemes to privatize large numbers of enterprises quickly through free
distribution and financial intermediaries. They also show, in quite
different ways, the difficulties with such funds. Widespread ownership
of investment funds can pose problems somewhat similar to the problems
of diffuse ownership of enterprises themselves: who will control the
behavior of the fund managers when their ownership is divided among
thousands (or millions, in the case of Poland) of small shareholders?
Poland chose a centralized approach, with the government creating the
funds and managing the selection of fund managers. This proved
politically difficult and, for many observers, raised the specter of
government interference in the control of the firms after privatization.
The Czechoslovakian approach avoided such a strong government role and
resulted in a more spontaneous ownership structure.
It is too early, again, to say too much about how this emerging
structure is working. On the one hand, there are some signs that funds
may be helping to provide the impetus to restructure enterprises. On the
other, the ownership of Czech industry and banking is largely
concentrated in a few funds, which are themselves mostly managed by
Czech banks. This raises dangers of conflict of interest between banks
as lenders and banks as fund managers. It also raises the question of
the government's ongoing role in these enterprises, as the
government continues to own a large share of bank stocks. In recent
months charges of lack of transparency in investment fund behavior, in
particular with unregulated trading among investment funds, have spooked
markets and perhaps discouraged some outside investors.
In the Russian case, the vouchers could also be used at auction,
but the role of investment funds was more limited, and the structure of
the auctions led to much more worker/management control of the
privatized firm. The Russian mass privatization program ended in July
1994. It involved 100,000 medium-sized and large firms, including 15,000
in industry. More than 60 percent of the industrial labor force was
affected. Each citizen born before 2 September 1992 (150 million people)
received one voucher with a face value of 10,000 roubles. The vouchers
were traceable and valid until mid- 1994, with the typical market price
varying over time from 4,000 to 42,000 rubles. They could be used to buy
shares in the enterprise where the owner worked, allocated to one of the
many investment funds that emerged or used directly in voucher auctions.
They could also be used to pay for housing and other property, and could
also be bought and sold by anyone, including foreigners.
In order to get insiders to cooperate, the program was structured
to provide them with substantial advantages. Employees had various
options for buying shares, including the right to buy 51 percent in a
closed subscription at a price of 1.7 times nominal value per share,
paid for with vouchers and cash. This and other options gave employees
and managers the possibility of acquiring majority voting stock and
control of the firm. Typically, the legal minimum of company shares were
allocated for distribution through public voucher auctions. Mass
privatization became largely a matter of MEBOs, with more than
two-thirds of privatized firms coming under insider control.
Not all vouchers went to purchase shares by employees in their
privatized firm. According to surveys in mid- 1994, about a third of the
voucher recipients had sold their vouchers and about 30 percent had
exchanged vouchers for shares in voucher funds. It appears that about 10
percent of the privatized medium-sized and large firms in Russia
followed the open access route.
In Russia, the voucher program was unquestionably successful at
privatizing huge numbers of enterprises quickly. Despite insider
dominance, privatization has achieved some of its broader aims.(41)
First, massive depoliticization has taken place. Control rights have
been transferred from government ministries to managers and investors.
The sectoral ministries, only a few years ago the kingpins in Russian
industry, have become irrelevant. The process of depoliticization is
incomplete, since government still has many levers of influence such as
credit policy, heavy regulatory structures, tax policy, and local
governments have stepped in to control the system out of interest in
social services. However, depoliticization has come a long way.(42)
Secondly, Russia has made a giant step toward efficient ownership
patterns. Outsiders have apparently been accumulating shares in the
voucher and share markets. There are some signs of large shareholder
activism, including removal of general directors at initial meetings.
The dominant role of insiders has nonetheless presented troubling
features. First, restructuring has been slow.(43) Indeed, there seems to
be little difference between the behavior of stateowned and worker- or
manager-dominated privatized firms. In insider-dominated firms, managers
have been unwilling or unable to carry out deep reforms, particularly in
reducing overemployment. De nuovo private firms, in contrast,
demonstrated much more dynamism. Second, capital market development has
been hindered, with managers able to control the secondary market for
shares and the behavior of boards of directors, thereby leaving little
room for stock market discipline of poor managers.
Part of the reason for the poor performance of privatized firms
may be that the benefits of privatizations come only after a time lag.
Nonetheless, in the words of some of those involved in the design of the
program:
The principal message we draw from our empirical
evidence is that restructuring requires new people,
who have new skills more suitable to a market
economy. A secondary message is that, without new
people, incentives for old people might not be particularly
effective in bringing about significant
change.... (C)ontinued control by old managers presents
a problem for restructuring, and...more attention
should have been paid to management turnover
as opposed to shareholder oversight over the
existing managers. To some extent, large investors
have begun to force old managers out...(and)old
managers have been given enough wealth that they
can afford to retire in peace and let a new generation
take over. This, however, is probably not
enough.... If privatization were designed from
scratch, these strategies should have received more
attention than they have...(44)
The Mongolian case is of special interest because Mongolia is both
a transition and a developing economy. It is the only developing country
that has used mass privatization/voucher methods. Coupons distributed in
1991 to each citizen were used in a small privatization phase to buy
agricultural and other assets in auctions. In principle these were open
auctions, but workers had first rights to make a joint bid. By early
1993, two years after the program was launched, all small urban
businesses--and 90 percent of the national total--had been privatized.
All agricultural co-ops and more than 90 percent of state farms were in
private hands.
Privatization of Mongolia's large enterprises followed.
Ownership in many of the large firms was transferred through auctions
for vouchers. As with small privatization, these open auctions were
ultimately dominated by the workers from the enterprise. Workers (and
their families) chose to buy shares largely in "their"
enterprises, ending up with 45 percent of the total shares, according to
one survey.(45) However, changes in the way companies are managed have
been slow in coming. The government retained control of many of the
privatized entities, and preexisting management and staff has remained
in place. Diffuse ownership has thus far failed to lead to shareholder
consolidation via secondary trading because the larger denomination coupons are not traceable. The regulatory system surrounding capital
markets remains sketchy.
Indirect Approaches
Management contracts privatize management, leaving ownership in
state hands. Some involve straight fees. In most cases, however,
payments are tied also to performance. The key issues in success or
failure are whether performance is related to the contract terms, and
whether managers have true autonomy in hiring and firing. A recent World
Bank study found that management contracts have improved both
productivity and profitability in most of the cases studied.(46)
Lease contracts are of different types, varying mainly by who is
responsible for financing investment. Under straightforward leasing
(sometimes called affermage) the contractor or lessee pays the public
owner a fee for the right to operate a public facility and bears the
financial risks of its operation. This method is widely used in power,
ports, urban transport, waste disposal and industry. The private firm
finances working capital and replaces nondurable capital assets, with
contracts generally running 5 to 10 years. The contractors collect
tariff revenues directly and pay a share to the government. Regulatory
burdens are considerable.
The Russian "loans-for-shares" program of 1995 might be
classified as a leasing approach. Under this system, private banks lent
money to the government for one year, with shares of large and valuable
natural resource-based SOEs serving as collateral. The banks bid for the
shares at auctions, competing on the size of the loan they would make.
If the government failed to repay the loan after one year, the banks
could auction the shares for a "market price."
The government was evidently not up to the regulatory burdens
implied by this program. It proved difficult to avoid collusion by the
banks in the auctions, resulting in low prices. When the government
failed to repay the loans, it also proved difficult to avoid insider
dealing in the resulting auctions of shares. The program is widely
considered to have led to the transfer of large quantities of valuable
assets to a small number of private owners at low prices.
Concessions involve greater contractor responsibility than leases,
notably for replacement of fixed assets. They also last longer--normally
15 to 30 years. Water supply, waste disposal, toll roads and ports are
among the common areas of usage. One variant coming into wide use is the
creation of two separate companies, a societe de patrimoine, which is an
operating company that owns the assets and is 100 percent state-owned,
and a societe d'exploitation, which is majority-owned by a private
operator with minority state ownership. This approach has become popular
in privatization of water supply and power facilities and state-owned
plantations. It has registered some striking successes--notably urban
water supply power in Cote d'Ivoire and water in Guinea. But it
also raises problems of coordination, since the societe de patrimoine is
responsible for new investment and may not always consult with the
operating company about investment policies.
Contracting out (also known as outsourcing or subcontracting) is
widespread in public-sector service provision. It is an extremely
diverse form of privatization, especially common for municipal services,
and is widespread in the United States. Examples include security and
janitorial services, maintenance services, data processing, and food
service.
The main objection to indirect privatization methods is that they
can be and often are a reflection of government unwillingness to bite
bullets, becoming a substitute for all-out privatization of ownership,
or "real" privatization. However, management contracts, leases
and service contracts can be first steps, opening up further
privatization prospects in situations where full privatization is not
feasible or desirable. The partial and tentative nature of these
contracting arrangements can be beneficial in that it makes them more
politically acceptable than full divestiture. In addition, asset
valuation problems are reduced, because leases with low rental values
are easier to swallow psychologically and politically than sales at deep
discounts from book value. The arrangements are in any case temporary.
They allow for joint learning and experimentation, easing the way to
effective privatization later.
Implementation of management contracts and leases is not without
problems. Too often they are on a fixed-fee basis, divorcing
remuneration from performance. Often, also, governments are unable to
deliver on their promises to keep hands off and/or to provide investment
and other funds as specified in the contract. Capacity building is often
neglected. Additionally, leases often suffer from ambiguity in
specification of responsibilities, as in the societe
d'exploitation--societe de patrimoine model mentioned earlier. This
can lead to disconnects between operational needs and investment
planning; the asset-owning SOE remains responsible for investments, a
situation that demands close coordination, which is not always
forthcoming.
Contracting out has the same advantages as management contracts
and leases in terms of tentativeness, experimentation and political
acceptability. Where workers' trade unions oppose outsourcing, its
political acceptability is less complete. Efficiency impacts are
especially likely, because it is easier to assure privatization into
competitive markets. It also has the crucial advantage of being
well-designed to meet the entrepreneurship-nurturing goals that should
have highest priority in low-income countries.
Contracting out has other efficiency-raising advantages that are
of special value in low-income country environments. It allows SOEs or
central governments to employ specialized skills they cannot otherwise
afford to recruit or retain because of low salaries in the public
sector. It also allows use of specialized skills that are not needed
full-time. It raises economy-wide efficiency by increasing
specialization and by permitting greater exploitation of economies of
scale and scope for specialized activities or functions, and creates
yardsticks for cost comparisons with in-house operations. It tends,
finally, to use less capital-intensive methods of service delivery and
productions: it encourages taxis instead of big bus companies, corner
traders rather than big state trading operators, decentralized maintenance shops rather than concentrated, large workshops.
Three main problems beset contracting-out privatization. First, it
requires substantial decentralized capacity in bid preparation,
specification of norms for contracted services and payment systems that
are prompt. Second, it is open to abuse and corruption. And, finally,
public employees, like private sector workers, generally dislike
outsourcing.
None of this is excessively constraining, as the growth of
subcontracting in many poor countries attests. But it does mean that
special efforts are required to facilitate its wider use, and special
precautions are essential to avoid corruption and favoritism.
Information on the extent of indirect privatization is incomplete
and diffuse; it is not tracked as carefully as other types of
privatization. A recent worldwide search came up with about 160
management contracts, a quarter of them in the hotel industry and
another quarter in agriculture. More are found in Africa than
elsewhere.(47) A survey in the early 1990s could identify only about 40
leases and concessions in infrastructure sectors, divided between power,
transport, and water/sewerage and about the same number of
contracting-out arrangements, almost all of them in transport and most
in Africa.(48) However, these are surely underestimated.(49)
The best evidence for the incidence of contracting-out
arrangements is in cities in the United States. Data shows that local
governments are rapidly shifting to contracting out for many
services.(50) The federal government is also a major user of contracting
out. Its versatility is illustrated by John Glenn's comment after
his space flight, that he could not keep from worrying a little bit when
he reflected that his spaceship was built with components from 50,000
subcontractors.
Conclusion
No privatization glove fits all hands. A public offering may be
right where the priority objectives are development of the stock market
and wider spread of share ownership, and where government has adequate
time and resources. Where overall economic growth is slow and public
sector assets are poorly used, sale to an outside investor may be the
most promising route; it is likely to lead to the fastest restructuring,
especially in the case of trade sales to foreign investors. For the
rapid sale of a large number of small- and medium-sized enterprises,
auctions are the obvious method. Where speed is high on the priority
list, as in transition economies with ambiguous property rights and weak
controls where insiders have a strong stake, MEBOs are appropriate, in
particular for small- and medium-sized firms. To privatize large numbers
of enterprises rapidly, there is no practical alternative to mass
privatization schemes involving widespread distribution of ownership.
Where there is a very small supply of modern sector capitalists and
entrepreneurs, methods that give the highest priority to
entrepreneur-creation should move to the fore. Here small-scale
opportunities have to be generated through the fragmentation of public
sector activities and through the leasing and contracting out.
Much of the frustration that can surround privatization derives
from the inability of any method to fully satisfy the multiple
objectives that characterize typical programs. Public flotations
generate revenues for the state, invigorate capital markets and broaden
share ownership, but hasty implementation and poor price-setting may
seriously dilute positive impacts for corporate governance. Trade sales,
often the most efficient in terms of enterprise governance, raise
nationalist hackles if foreign buyers appear, disturb egalitarians
because of benefits to rich people and also may suffer from too-speedy
implementation or insufficient transparency. Politically attractive and
socially equitable instruments, such as mass distribution or transfers
to trusts, often end up with insider-dominated buy-outs or concentrated
ownership by investment funds; effects on productivity through better
corporate governance are uncertain.
Two persistent trade-offs emerge--one between speed and the
quality of privatization transactions, and the other between equity and
improved corporate governance.(51) As the discussion of Latin American
telecommunications privatizations indicated, pressure to implement
quickly can often lead to relatively unfavorable terms for privatizing
governments and to situations where regulatory arrangements are poorly
defined. In the mass-privatization schemes of transition economies, from
Mongolia to Russia where political conditions required insider
cooperation, positive effects on enterprise productivity remain to be
seen.
The analysis provokes two other general observations. First, it is
easy to be simplistic in judging the "success" or
"failure" of privatization programs. What is probably the most
important criterion in most cases is the extent to which privatization
sets the stage for future private-sector development--that is, whether
it creates the political and/or institutional conditions that are
favorable to further liberalization or marketization.
Judgements on this point are not simple. The approach of
encouraging expansion around the state enterprise sector, as in China
and Poland, has clearly led to extraordinary growth of the non-state
sector, but the problem of inefficient public enterprises remains
unresolved and is worsening. The Russian approach so far has not led to
significant improvements in corporate governance, but whether it has
blocked further change or made change easier is not yet clear.
An emphasis on laying the groundwork for future private sector
growth implies a related conclusion. Policies regarding price and trade
liberalization, demonopolization and deregulation, a hardening of budget
constraints on SOEs, and regulatory systems that encourage external
shareholder participation may be more critical for private sector
development than privatization of ownership by itself.
Second, it is essential to prioritize objectives in defining
privatization strategies. In many low-income countries, aid donors and
local policymakers are now considering the adoption of mass
privatization methods as a way to get lagging privatization efforts
moving again. They may be right. But where, as in sub-Saharan Africa,
the chief problem is the stimulation of entrepreneurship, it may be
wiser to concentrate on methods that hit that target better, such as
fragmentation or unbundling of functions, wider resort to leasing and
contracting-out arrangements and creating an environment in which new
private firms can thrive. (1) Ahmed Galal et al., Welfare Consequences
of Selling Public Enterprises (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1994)
(2) World Bank, Bureaucrats in Business. The Economics and Politics
of Government Ownership. (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1995).
(3) ibid.
(4) World Bank, African Economic and Social Indicators (Washington,
DC: World Bank, 1996).
(5) See European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Transition
Report, (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development,
1995).
(6) We also leave out privatization of finance (shifting payments for
public goods and services from government budgets to private users) and
many issues specific to privatization of infrastructure and the
financial sector.
(7) Luca Barbone, Domenico Marchetti, and Sefano Paternostro,
Structural Adjustment, Ownership Transformation, and Size in Polish
Industry, (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1996).
(8) W. Tseng, E. K. Hoe, et al., "Economic Reform in China: A
New Phase" (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1994);
W.T. Woo, The Art of Reforming Centrally-Planned Economies: Comparing
China, Poland and Russia," Journal of Comparative Economics (June
1994) pp. 276-308; W.T. Woo, Chinese Economic Growth: Sources and
Prospects (University of California, 1996).
(9) This privatization through liberalization is clearly related to
so-called "nomenklatura privatization" in some transition
economies, in which enterprise insiders (especially managers and
bureaucrats) appropriate physical assets or profit streams from the
state enterprises they control. However, such practices are only part of
the story; state enterprises will also release assets and workers if
they are under enough financial pressure. See A. Berg "Does
Macroeconomic Reform Cause Structural Adjustment? Lessons From
Poland," Journal of Comparative Economics (1994) pp. 376-409.
(10) Roger Leeds, Privatization Through Public Offerings: Lessons
From Two Jamaican Cases," Privatization and Control of State-Owned
Enterprises, R. Ramamurti and R. Vernon, eds. (Washington, DC: Economic
Development Institute of the World Bank, 1991) p. 98.
(11) Joseph Borgatti, "Methods of Privatization of State-Owned
Enterprises," paper presented at the Methods and Practices of
Privatization Conference (New York, 1993).
(12) "Privatisation in Europe: Is the Price Right?"
Economist (23 November 1996) p. 87.
(13) ibid.
(14) M. Mohiuddin, Reform of the Bangladeshi Para-Public Sector:
Situation and Prospects, (Clermont-Ferrand, France: CERDI, University of
the Auvergne, 1996).
(15) It is also possible, of course, to use regional or even rich
country stock markets. Ghana's Ashanti Goldfields Co. is listed in
New York, for example, as are many privatized Latin American utilities.
(16) World Bank, From Plan to Market: World Development Report 1996
(Washington, DC: World Bank, 1996), p. 53 provides data on the incidence
of privatizations in transition economies broken down by method.
(17) These typically were used only for small companies. Only 2 of
the 20 biggest privatizations in sub-Saharan Africa as of the end of
1995 used public flotations (World Bank, 1996).
(18) In one week in October 1996, the International Herald Tribune
advertised the sale of cotton ginneries in Uganda, and the Economist had
an advertisement seeking qualified firms that could prequalify to bid
for a 31 percent interest in Mozambique National Airlines. (19)
Borgatti, p. 53
(20) There also may be tax reasons to sell assets rather than going
concerns through share transfers--benefits from tax loss carryovers, for
example.
(21) R. Ramamurti, ed., Privatizing Infrastructure in Developing
Countries: Lessons from the Telecom and Transport Sectors in Latin
America (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994).
(22) In Mexico, political and nationalist objectives led to
stipulations that bidding consortia be controlled by Mexican nationals;
the result was almost surely a lower price than might have been
achieved. The other three countries allowed foreign control.
(23) World Bank data from a special study on privatization in
sub-Saharan Africa (unpublished). Preliminary results are in World Bank,
1996.
(24) Helen Nankani, "Techniques of Privatization of State-owned
Enterprises," World Bank Technical Paper no. 89, vol. 2
(Washington, DC: World Bank, 1988).
(25) World Bank, Private Sector Development in Low-Income Countries,
Development in Practice (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1995).
(26) In Honduras, a steel-rolling mill that had never opened was sold
first on a debt swap basis to a U.S. fabricator, who planned to use the
plant to cast rail crossings. After a while this technical partner fell
out, supposedly because it had been bought out by a French company that
was not interested in the Honduras deal. The mill was then sold by debt
swap to a Miami bank that was associated with the two original promoters
of the first deal. The new group spent years searching for money and
technical partners, while the mill remained unopened (Borgatti, p. 47).
These kinds of problems are not restricted to noncompetitive sales; they
also occur after formal tenders.
(27) Of 549 noncompetitive transactions, almost 300 were sales of
shares, 135 were sales of assets, 77 entailed preemptive rights and 30
restitutions, while sales to trusts numbered 13.
(28) Example: A power company's assets are valued at $100
million. A buyer puts up $50 million in cash for 50 percent of the
equity. The remaining state-owned 50 percent is given to pension funds.
The new $50 million is available for company use.
(29) Advertisement by Bolvian authorities, International Herald
Tribune (October 1996) p.8
(30) John S. Earle et al., "Small Privatization: The
Transformation of Retail Trade and Consumer Services in the Czech
Republic, Hungary, and Poland," CEU Privatization Reports vol. 3
(Budapest: Central European University Press, 1994).
(31) Borgatti, p. 49
(32) As described by Sharit K. Bhowmik, "Takeovers by Employees:
A Response to Privatization in Pakistan," Economic and Political
Weekly (29 April 1995) p. 931-933.
(33) The company had 830 employees when it was taken over, of whom a
third were executives. Some 250 employees were quickly fired, with
generous severance payments. Staffing in 1994 was 533, of whom 170 were
executives. Labor productivity is said to have much increased; output
has more than doubled; profitability has returned and the firm is
diversifying its output and expanding.
(34) Georges Korsun and Peter Murrell, Ownership and Governance on
the Morning After: The Initial Results of Privatization in Mongolia
(College Park, MD: Center for Institutional Reform and the Informal
Sector University of Maryland, 1994).
(35) Of the 3,075 enterprises privatized or in the process of being
privatized from 1990 through 1994, 2,231 of them were done through
"liquidation." See Central Statistical Office, Rocznik
Statystyczny (Statistical Yearbook) (Warsaw: Central Statistical Office,
1995).
(36) Andrew, Berg, "The Logistics of Privatization in
Poland," Jeffrey Sachs, Olivier Blanchard, and Ken Front eds. NBER Conference on Transition in Eastern Europe, (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1994). (37) Earle, page xxviii, says that they "have
found clear evidence that the entry of new entrepreneurs, not connected
with the predecessor retail establishments, is the most significant
factor in increasing the levels of post-privatization investment."
See also Barberis et. al.
(38) John S. Earle and Saul Estrin, "Employee Ownership in
Transition," Froman Frydman, Cheryl W. Gray and Andrzej
Rapaczynski, eds., Corporate Governance in Central Europe and Russia,
(Budapest: Central European University Press, 1996) pp. 62-77.
(39) It is worth noting that "voucher privatization" is not
a useful category, as it fails to specify what will be sold (the supply
side) or even how the vouchers are to be used (MEBOs, auctions, IPOs and
so on).
(40) Many of the best enterprises were apparently sold through
tender, not through vouchers. In part, this reflects the fact that
interested buyers and the enterprise management could negotiate a sale
in the context of the proposed plan.
(41) See Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishney,
Privatizing Russia (Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1995).
(42) A 1994 survey of some 400 Russian enterprises provides support
for these conclusions. For example, privatized firms did indeed have
fewer links with the government than state-owned firms. See Simon
Commander, Qimiao Fan, and Mark E. Schaffer, Enterprise Restructuring
and Economic Policy in Russia (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1996).
(43) These conclusions are based in part on Commander, Fan and
Schaffer.
(44) Barbaris et. al.
(45) Georges Korsun and Peter Murrell.
(46) A. H. Shaikh and M. Minovi, Management Contracts: A Review of
International Experience, (Washington, DC: World Bank, 1994).
(47) ibid.
(48) Christine Kessides, Institutional Arrangements for the Provision
of Infrastructure: A Frame-work for Analysis and Decision-Making,
(Washington, DC: World Bank, 1993).
(49) Elliot Berg, "Privatization in sub-Saharan Africa: Results,
Prospects, and New Approaches," JoAnn Paulson, ed., The Role of the
State in Key Markets, (London: MacMillan, 1996).
(50) Between 1987 and 1995, the percentage of local governments
contracting out rose as follows: janitorial services, 52 to 70 percent;
garbage collection, 30 to 50 percent; building maintenance, 32 to 42
percent; security services, 27 to 40 percent; street maintenance and
repair, 19 to 37 percent and data processing, 16 to 31 percent. (Data
from Mercer Group, Inc.).
(51) The generality of the trade-off between speed and quality is
indicated by its frequency in the case studies detailed in Christopher
Adams, W.P. Cavendish, and Percy Mistry, Adjusting Privatization: Case
Studies form Developing Countries, (London: James Currey, 1992).