Moral arguments for land redistribution in contemporary Zimbabwe and Gracchan Rome: a comparative and critical analysis.
Mlambo, Obert Bernard ; Mwatwara, Wesley
Introduction
Since the turn of the century, attempts by Zimbabwe to solve the
land question through agrarian reform, and its attendant economic
decline, have attracted widespread academic interest (See Chitiyo 2000,
Moyo 2000, Chaumba 2003, Moore 2001, Chitando 2005 and Sadomba 2011). We
seek to contribute to this burgeoning interest in agrarian reform from a
classical history perspective, and thus draw comparisons between the
moral justifications for land reform brought forward by the Gracchi
(Roman brothers who tried to reform Rome's social and political
structure to help the lower classes, in the 2nd century B.C. Events
surrounding the politics of the Gracchi led to the decline and eventual
fall of the Roman Republic) in the Roman Republic and by the Zimbabwe
African National Union--Patriotic Front (hereinafter ZANU-PF) in
contemporary Zimbabwe. Indeed, in both cases scholarly attention has
focussed on the existence and nature of alleged crises but the validity
of the moral arguments mobilised by both regimes is subject to debate.
This article is therefore sensitive to the ethical complexity in the
events both in ancient Rome and modern Zimbabwe. Instead of right versus
wrong, in a fairy-tale narrative, this article demonstrates how
difficult it is to judge. It advances the argument that no one uniquely
occupies the moral high ground, and even when a cause for land
redistribution is just, one may not always be able to predict the
consequences of one's actions (this is true when one considers
methods used by veterans and also methods used by politicians to get the
land).
Even when unspoken, the importance of land will dominate all major
questions of power and economics, especially in agrarian societies.
Accordingly, corruption and its problems (which are inherently about the
wealth of the government) compel us to focus on land. In this respect,
we need to examine the relationship between politics and economics: land
reform driven by political or economic imperatives or both, with the
problem of the former at times masquerading as the latter (Mlambo 2013:
9). This is essential to interpreting what is happening in contemporary
Zimbabwe, and it is also essential to the late Roman republic and
especially, the Gracchi in the 2nd century BC. The article thus seeks to
distinguish between the real motives for reform and the objectives
proclaimed by the reformers. This distinction may especially be
significant if the proclaimed objectives are imposed upon the reformers
by political circumstances. For example, reformers may proclaim certain
objectives (without any intention of enforcing them) to appease
peasants, to reward war veterans and sometimes to undermine the
opposition such that it became difficult to isolate the real from the
proclaimed purpose of land reform (Onoma 2011).
We argue that the different faces of the land reforms in both case
studies do not fit seamlessly into the moral argument. In fact, even if
one accepts a good-bad dichotomy on the fundamental questions, the claim
to moral influence is unmasked as mere political rhetoric or cheap
propaganda. Tiberius Gracchus, who was the tribune of the Roman people
in 133 BC, introduced his agrarian law specifically to eradicate poverty
and the shortage of potential recruits, which was a result of the misuse
of public/state land in Rome's past, by putting a limit on holdings
in order to distribute the surplus in small plots to the landless poor.
During the process of distributing the land, commissioners were
denounced for failing to account for the records of land holdings
professionally leading to malicious accusations and lawsuits (App. BC
1.18).
In Zimbabwe, there are conflicting views of what benefits
Independence brought to the country, as land appears to be one of the
promised gains that were not immediately actualized in the first two
decades, directly following the ascent of the Black majority, a gain
which was realized in the upheavals over land ownership, early in the
21st century. Therefore we argue that in both cases the moral good of
the exercises of land reforms leads to a messier and murkier moral zone
in which the means do not appear to be justified by the ends. A
comparative examination of the Zimbabwean agrarian crisis with that of
Gracchi Rome can contribute to our understanding of the pitfalls and
complex problems of land reform and how they impact on the general
economic, social and political wellbeing of society.
The Roman Context
Debate on the crisis phenomenon of land redistribution in Rome
during the Gracchi era has produced two schools of thought, the
pro-Gracchan tradition and the anti-Gracchan tradition. The pro-Gracchan
tradition is a version of interpretation that subscribes to the thesis
of severe crisis in the second century BC Roman Italy, which the Gracchi
attempted to alleviate through the lex Sempronia agraria (a law that
would reorganize control of the ager publicus meaning land conquered in
previous wars that was controlled by the state. Previous agrarian law
specified that no citizen would be allowed to possess more than 500
jugera, approximately 125 hectares of the ager publicus (public land),
and any land that they occupied above this limit would be confiscated by
the state).
Appian and Plutarch mainly support this view. Appian presents the
lex Sempronia agraria as the most appropriate response to the crisis
(Gargola 2008:489, 490, 491, 492). In Appian, an extensive depiction of
the use and abuse of public/state lands by the rich was evident (App. BC
1.9 35-11. 47, see also Plut. Ti Gr 8). Appian argues that the
senatorial elite in Rome controlled the land from the time of the regal
period, with power firmly entrenched in the hands of the oligarchy and
that class struggles (the struggle of the orders, 494 BC-289 BC) over
the status of the agerpublicus/public land which led to the creation of
the office of the Tribune of the Plebs.
Thus, the tribune was a direct response to the unequal political
field that the plebeians had to negotiate to secure some form of parity
in the political discourse at that time. Ownership of land was not
merely a symbolic representation of power, but it meant possession of
actual power, as agriculture was the mainstay of the Roman economy. On
account of their ownership of the land, the optimates (loosely speaking,
a political party of the aristocracy, who were thoroughly opposed to
ideas of reform at the expense of conformism and the spirit and
tradition of conservative politics) controlled the livelihoods of a
large part of the population.
This control propelled the political ascendancy of the optimates
(the nobility or aristocrats). Landowners were able to furnish their
slaves with arms; they were able to use their land as security to
finance their acquisition of more land from those without the means to
fully utilise it.
The ownership of large tracts of land dictated that the optimates
hire more labour in order to augment their wealth. Since Rome was
frequently engaged in wars against the other Italian cities, native
Roman labourers also doubled as Roman soldiers. During their absence,
the landowners acquired great numbers of slaves to work the land.
Consequently, whenever the legionnaires returned home, they found their
presence as labourers' surplus to traditional requirements. With no
work, no land, and thus, no power, the citizens resorted to the
extraordinary measure of voting for whichever orator promised them what
they wanted. The beginning of this practice is obscured within the
promises of returning land to the peasant population that had been
deprived of the resource through no fault of their own. Later on, with
the advent of the years, and the dearth of plebeians willing to work the
land, monetary recompense was the preferred modus operandi (method of
operation).
Plebeian politicians and occasionally patrician demagogues
mobilised support for their candidature by claiming to desire the
restoration of the ager publicus (public land) to those who had lost out
in the creation of the latifundia (large farms that were formed when
landowners bought up smaller farms), as well as to those who were
citizens, but did not own land. The plebeian candidates almost always
got elected on the promise of land allotment to disenfranchised
citizens. The division between the patricians and the plebeians became
more marked as the plebeians found champions for their cause for seeking
land distribution. The establishment of the magistracy of the tribune of
the plebeians was created to aid them in addressing the inequality of
the land allocations.
The above discussion opens up a vast array of questions and
problems regarding the aims and methods of the Gracchi. It also opens up
the question of how the achievements and fate of the Gracchi exposed the
flaws of the senatorial government in Roman politics. The Gracchan era
poses serious questions in so far as the motives of the reformers were
concerned. Tiberius Gracchus' argument emphasises action, based on
moral grounds. Indeed, what Tiberius demonstrates is a moral crisis. He
invoked the moral question of social justice. His programme allegedly
sought to help the landless poor who were suffering at the expense of
the vested interests of the rich and the politically connected. Did
Tiberius Gracchus conceal other motives? These questions call for an
in-depth analysis of his moral argument and to examine the extent to
which land functioned as the focal point for mobilization of political
support.
While we do not deny that there was a crisis in Roman Italy, we
want to investigate the extent to which the crisis might have been
exaggerated by the Gracchi. e also advance the argument that the
selfishness and vested interests of the rich in government exposed the
Roman state to populist politics and worsened the crisis. After the
Gracchi episode, there occurred in the Roman political landscape a
growing self-consciousness on the part of the peasantry, about whose
economic plight the state had demonstrated little concern. The said
questions will help us gain some insight into contemporary
Zimbabwe's situation.
Gracchan Altruism
From a reading of Plutarch, Tiberius Gracchus' reform aimed to
tackle the plight of the soldiery in order to gain support from this
section (Plut. Ti Gr, 9.5). Following Plutarch, Scullard argues that
Tiberius Gracchus' land bill targeted war veterans as beneficiaries
(Scullard 1960, 63; Plut. Ti Gr 9.5). Gaius Gracchus, Tiberius'
younger brother in 123 BC, also exhibited a quest for the affection of
the soldiery when he made provision of clothes and food for the same at
a time when the Senate had turned its back on the army doing duty in
Sardinia (Plut. C Gracch 2.1-20). The first, and most obvious, strand
linking the Zimbabwean land reform and that of the Gracchi is the
significance of war veterans, earmarked as the titular beneficiaries of
the exercise. Let us find out how the situation panned out in Gracchan
Rome. Contemporary sources Liv. Per.58, App. BC 1.11, Dio. 24.4-5, Plut.
C. Gr 5.1-7, and Cic. Brut 103 all reveal that the Gracchi's land
redistribution programme was designed to attain personal power or regnum
(the inheritable power to govern).
For most of these ancient sources, the Gracchi aimed at grabbing
power while hiding their intentions behind a benevolent land
redistribution programme, a charge that has also been levelled against
the prime orchestrators of the fast-track land reform programme in
Zimbabwe. Florus argues thus:
The original cause of all the revolutions was the pretence of
protecting the common people, for whose aid it was originally
established, but in reality aiming at domination for itself, courted
popular support and favour by legislation for the distribution of lands
and corn and the disposal of judicial power (Flor. 2.1.13).
Modern historians (Earl 1970, Smith 1955 and Taylor Taylor 1962.)
concur that the Gracchi brothers aimed at gaining political revenue
rather than carrying out social reform. Earl's words regarding
Tiberius are representative of this consensus among historians:
Regnum, in fact, was precisely what Ti. Gracchus and his faction
aimed at and, as Cicero says, for a few months achieved.... The tribune
Ti. Gracchus began as merely another manoeuvre in the restless factional
politics of the second century; it ended with the nobility fighting and
murdering the political life and power. No less than Julius Caesar, Ti.
Gracchus perished for his regnum (Earl 1970:64).
Revisionist scholars emphasize the severity of poverty of the Roman
peasant. Rathbone posits that the Late Roman Republic peasant was
miserably poor; deducing evidence from the archaeology of peasant
farmstead, which to him was so poor that it left little archaeological
trace (Rathbone 2008:328). He argues thus:
... the settlement schemes of the Gracchan and triumviral phases
created massive new cohorts of smallholders with restricted means of
livelihood evidenced by their revival of the rural market for ceramic
fine wares. The interpretation of archaeological field survey data
points to the fact that these peasants were poor hence the importance of
the agrarian settlement schemes carried by the Gracchi and the triumvirs
(ibid).
Rathbone points to the paucity of even the average black gloss
sherds in the late Republic which to him reflects the economic
instability of the settled peasantry (Rathbone 2008:328). He notes that
the Greek and Hellenistic smallholdings and farmsteads were larger than
Roman citizen allotments and farmhouses; hence he argues that Roman
peasants were significantly poorer than their counterparts in the Greek
and Hellenistic worlds (ibid). Rathbone, in the pro-Gracchan tradition,
sees inequalities in land ownership and politics at hand in his
explanation of the poverty of the Italian farmer (Rathbone 2008:307).
Contrary to this, Rosenstein argues that there was a life-cycle balance
built into the Roman system of warfare, with men serving in the army
before marriage, then returning to their farms, hence there was no
inherent conflict between long service overseas and the viability of the
Italian economy (Rosenstein 2004).
Toynbee and Frank, like Rosenstein, argue that the situation was
the same in the second century, despite the portrayal of conditions of
grave economic inequality by Plutarch and Appian. They corroborate
Rosenstein's argument of an exaggerated crisis as they argue that
Roman land was still good and cereal cultivation was lucrative (See
Toynbee 1965:228-235 and Frank 1993). Furthermore, Rosenstein argues
that the main problem facing rural Italy was overpopulation not
underpopulation, that is, farms were productive. One cannot, therefore,
help but see an exaggerated crisis by politicians.
Rosenstein, therefore, downplays the significance of
latifundia/large scale farms operated through slave labour as opposed to
wage labour in the 2nd century and gives emphasis to changes in
political culture in the second century, especially with Scipio
Aemilianus (236-183 BC; renowned as one of the greatest generals of the
Roman republic) and his use of the popular assemblies to subvert the
authority of the Senate (for a detailed argument on this theme see
Rosenstein 2012).
However, Rosenstein fails to analyse the impact of capital influx
on land prices. Prices rise when there is too much money in the economy,
leading ultimately to the property bubble scenario. Such a scenario may
not be ruled out to have happened in Rome in the 2nd century with
private wealth rising exponentially among the elite. One may, contrary
to Appian's pro-Gracchan tradition, be sympathetic with
Rosenstein's argument that peasants were forced off the land and
the rich bought up estates on the cheap (App. BC 1.7). It is rather more
tempting, unlike Rosenstein, to embrace a scenario where the rich having
accumulated more money and thus having the economic power simply bought
out smallholdings without the violence attested in the pro-Gracchan
tradition. In this model, the small farmer is not entirely the loser, as
he does receive a cash windfall in a rising property market in return
for his farm.
The situation described above is quite reminiscent of what has
happened in some parts of rural England where wealthy people from the
cities buy weekend cottages. The locals are priced out of the housing
market in their own villages, but since the locals already have
property, they are often tempted to sell out for high profits. A similar
situation might have obtained in Rome. So some small farmers in
Middle/late republican Rome who left the land for the cities may perhaps
have done so with large amounts of cash after selling their properties
to the rich and not necessarily as lampenproletariats (working class
people that are unlikely to achieve class consciousness and are
therefore lost to socially useful production that is of no use in a
revolutionary struggle, and perhaps may even be an impediment to the
realization of a classless society).
Rosenstein subscribes to the thesis of a crisis caused by over
population as opposed to under population; a crisis nevertheless,
exploited by the new breed of demagogues, that is, the Gracchi. Although
Gruen believes, contrary to Rosenstein, that there was a decrease in
rural population (Gruen 1968:48). He argues that there was an increased
rate of rural immigration to the city of Rome thereby increasing the
urban population. This urban population, which comprised men who had
done military service, according to Gruen (1968:47), '... did not
fancy returning to the Italian countryside even if they did not feel an
economic pinch.'
This casts a shadow of doubt on Tiberius' gloomy portrayal of
the plight of the ex-fighters in his speech: "... the men who fight
and die for Italy enjoy the common air and light, indeed but nothing
else; houseless and homeless they wander about with their wives and
children" (Plut. Ti Gr 9.5).
There is also another problem with the argument of the Gracchi. The
Gracchi identified a general lack of access to land as the main problem
that triggered the crisis (Roselaar 2008:218). A passage below
demonstrates this:
... for the rich getting possession of the greater part of the
undistributed lands, and being emboldened by the lapse of time to
believe that they would never be dispossessed, absorbing any adjacent
strips and their poor neighbours' allotments, partly by purchase
... and partly by force, came to cultivate vast tracts instead of single
estates (App. BC 1.7).
Nonetheless, any deeper analysis that dwells on what modern
scholars have expressed will not bear much fruit, as it will mostly
amount to conjecture from limited available data. The Zimbabwean
scenario discussed below further helps us to appreciate the problems of
the moral argument for land reform.
The Zimbabwean Context
In this section we show how the search for an alternative
explanation to the Roman problem through the lens of contemporary
Zimbabwe can offer intriguing insights into the politics of land reform,
both past and present. We demonstrate how the Zimbabwean experience
provides a more modern example we can relate and identify with. It
offers primary evidence for the motives of the beneficiaries of land
reform. Indeed, our examination of the facets of the land reform in
contemporary Zimbabwe avails an opportunity to assess the extent to
which public officials are motivated by the moral argument or are able
to walk into their political claims. Thus, ultimately we hope that
through this analysis, we can contribute to solving not only the
Gracchan debate, but also the general problem with land redistribution
that has affected Zimbabwe in recent decades. Like the Gracchan reforms,
Mugabe's motives in carrying out the land reform programme have
been similarly criticized as a self-serving political exercise. His
critics argue that he aimed at bolstering declining ZANU (PF) support in
the rural constituencies, and harnessing the paramilitary group of war
veterans.
As we have already demonstrated, the moral verdict of the land
reform agenda as expressed by the argument of the Gracchi is
problematic. Similarly, the moral argument expressed by President Robert
Mugabe in the contemporary Zimbabwean scenario also gets excessively
complicated, even if we were to accept a good-bad dichotomy on the
fundamental questions. President Mugabe's moral argument is
captured in the following speech where he argued thus:
We have repeatedly told the world that the on-going land reform
programme seeks to redress land imbalances deriving from the history of
colonialism in this country. It is also meant to transform the
agricultural set-up, which we inherited from colonial governments. The
set-up is not just: it is not fair, it is not productive (Mugabe
2001:141).
Mugabe explained:
It is my hope that if we put our heads together and believe in the
efficacy of this process (of land distribution), we shall see it go a
long way towards addressing the twin evils of poverty and overcrowding
in most rural areas...We are indeed called upon to deliver once and for
all (Mugabe 2001:106).
Indeed apocalyptic language such as the one mobilised by Mugabe is
commonplace in political history as politicians often justify
themselves. And as Daniel Gargola noted, with regards to the evils
depicted by Appian for the Gracchan period, 'Whether or not there
actually was such a crisis ... is a far more complicated matter (Gargola
2008:500, note 28).'
This poses a challenge of shedding light on the other motives of
the 'crisis' metaphor often mobilised by politicians. Thus, it
is paramount to examine whether President Mugabe's
'altruistic' reform agenda can help us expose flaws in the
Gracchan moral argument. We appropriate Mugabe's
'altruistic' reform agenda to clarify the Gracchi's moral
standpoint by examining the situation of the 'conservative'
peasants. Conservative peasants in the Gracchan era were those peasants
whose plight was relatively not bad and who believed in a rational and
methodical approach to land reform. In Zimbabwe, these elements did not
play a leading role in the land invasions (Moore 2001, 258). The results
of a doctoral fieldwork carried out in 2010 in various provinces in
Zimbabwe speak to this effect. For instance, in Masvingo province,
especially in Bikita and Zaka rural communities, most peasant families
indicated that their unwillingness to leave the graves of their
ancestors played a role in their not participating in land occupations,
and that they had supplementary sources of livelihood such as gardening,
and also buying and selling. Some families in the Zimunya area in
Manicaland and some peasant families in the Chipinge, and Chirinda area
were content with their crop yields, and indicated that they depended on
their sons and daughters who worked in South Africa for supplementary
food supplies. This is not to say others did not happily welcome an
allocation of land. Hence, the above information is fairly
representative of rural lifestyles in other provinces with better
climatic conditions. Roselaar, who comments on similar survival
strategies but in a different geographical context, argues:
Even if the accumulation of public land by the elite was not
dangerous for most small farmers (in Roman Italy), they still had to
cope with serious problems. Population growth and the accumulation of
(private) land led to a shortage of land for many farmers in central
Italy. Under such conditions small farmers could employ various other
strategies to ensure a sufficient income (Roselaar 2008:205).
However, some peasants doubted the sincerity of the reform
process--itself a by-product of previous disappointments with what they
thought was the government's inconsistent land policy. The
following quote trenchantly captures this concern:
In 1981 and 1982 we occupied Bhiri farm (Bill's farm) but we
were kicked out by armed police. Seventeen years later, that is, in
2000, the same politicians encouraged farm occupations. We doubt if this
land revolution would not have the same results as the last one. We will
farm these allotments left for us by our ancestors. In fact this year we
had a fairly good harvest (Interview with the elders of a certain clan
in Murinye communal areas, Masvingo central, 1 June 2013).
This paradox finds parallels with the plight of the Italian
peasant--the alleged targets of Tiberius' agrarian reform (App. BC
1.11). In 91 BC, M. Livius Drusus, a tribune of the plebs proposed to
give all Italians Roman citizenship but the Italians were against it as
Appian notes:
Even the Italians, in whose special interest Drusus was devising
these plans, were apprehensive about the law providing for the colonies,
because they thought that the Roman public land (which was still
undivided, and which they were cultivating, some by force and others
clandestinely) would at once be taken away from them, and that in many
cases they might even be disturbed in their private holdings (App. BC
1.36).
Peasants evidently doubted the sincerity of politicians and were
suspicious that the reformers could have been motivated by politics more
than any moral arguments they advanced. This attitude is reminiscent
with Gaius' peasants who were so critical of the reformer's
proposals, choosing, instead, to take sides with the Senate (App. BC
1.23; 1.24). The plebeians actually scoffed at the laws proposed by
Gaius, an indication that he had lost the favour of the common people
(App. BC 1.23). Appian also records that a certain plebeian named
Antyllus was critical of Gaius Gracchus' actions and even pleaded
Gaius ... to spare his country." (App. BC 1.25).
What this means is that the plebeians, seized with emotions
pertaining to the crisis and turmoil about to be caused, then distanced
themselves from riotous and treasonous actions, whose end result they
must have known was worse off than their present circumstances. This
reluctance is also reflected in Zimbabwe where mostly urbanites feared
the economic backlash of the exercise more than they approved of getting
the land promised with the advent of Independence in 1980.
Also, the scenario in which the erstwhile beneficiaries of the land
reform programme, the impoverished black population of Zimbabwe, acquire
the land of the white population, but have neither the means, nor the
expertise required to make a successful endeavour of the agricultural
experience, serves as a counterpoint in the morality of land reform as a
boon to a nation. This is just to reflect on the fact that what might
seem to some to be an unequivocal moral right can actually be more
complicated.
As mentioned, before, this disaffectedness appears within the urban
psyche of black Zimbabwean citizens at the outbreak of the fast-track
element of land redistribution. The ZANU (PF) altruistic claim that all
Zimbabweans needed the land for their livelihood was to some extent
contradictory as their language reveal some frustration at these
'unpatriotic' citizens whom they accused of not supporting
their inalienable 'birth right' to land (Machingura 2012:
267). It is also necessary to note that most beneficiaries and current
residents of the confiscated land were formerly domiciled in the
communal areas, but some were to some extent forced onto their new plots
(ibid). In some cases, there was neither infrastructure nor agricultural
services. The new farmers have no title deeds for the land, apart from
the promises that they will get them, and the insecurity of the 99-year
leases. The irony, then, of the exercise, is that the land was given to
those who arguably could not utilize it, while those who could, had no
desire to be involved or were blocked from taking part in the programme.
Furthermore, former farm workers' needs were not taken care
of. Moyana (2002:189) argues, 'But as things were, the masses of
landless Africans could not reconcile their condition with a situation
in which African political leaders had replaced the white farmers on the
land for which they had fought for ...'
Thus, the contemporary Zimbabwean peasant reaction to land reform
provides some insights in our appreciation of the responses of the Roman
peasantry.
'Ancestral' Lands Motif
Interviews conducted with peasant families reveal the fluidity of
the idea of 'ancestral lands'. Paradoxically, their
conceptualisation of 'ancestral' land is where the family had
been in recent generations, while land in white commercial farms is not
usually viewed as theirs (in contrast with the narrative of the
Independence movement).
Isu takati hatina kwatinoenda tichisiya makuva emadzitateguru edu.
Tiningoitawo zvamasunda chando gore rakunenge kusina kunyatsonaya.
Hongu, ivhu redu rinoratidzawo kuti raneta asi mazuvano zvoda kuruka
mazano emari kuti urarame. Ukagara wakatarisa denga kuti kuchanaya unofa
nezhara. Tinoitawo mimwe mibato yamaoko kuti tirarame. (We decided
against leaving our ancestral tombs. We just try to make ends meet in
case of a drought. These days you cannot rely on the climate. It is no
longer reliable. We do other money generating projects to survive
(Interview with Mr XX of Mudzami village, Bikita, 15 June 2013).
Sense of belonging to a particular piece of land seems to be shaped
by recent memory rather than a remembrance of how the land was
originally taken. As such, the following statement is representative of
this situation:
Ndimo matakazvarirwa, ndimo matakakurira. Tajaira nzvimbo yedu.
Anochengeta munhu ndiMwari" We were born and we grew up in this
area. We are used to this place. We will survive by God's grace
(Interview with Mr TK of Mapurisa village, Bikita).
The 'ancestral' motif also features in ancient Rome. For
example, in the idea of soldiers abroad fighting for Italy with the home
front defined as ancestral tombs (subverted by the Gracchi into class
interpretation of ancestral tombs not defining the collective view of
'home' but exclusively the family histories of the aristocracy
and the better off). The following quotation demonstrates this point:
The wild beasts that roam over Italy have every one of them a cave
or a lair to lurk in; but the men who fight and die for Italy enjoy the
common air and light, indeed, but nothing else; houseless and homeless
they wonder about with their wives and children. And it is with lying
lips that their imperators exhort the soldiers in their battles to
defend sepulchres and shrines from the enemy; for not a man of them has
an hereditary altar, not one of all these many Romans an ancestral tomb,
but they fight and die to support others in wealth and luxury, and
though they are styled masters of the world, they have not a single clod
of earth that is their own (Plutarch, Ti Gr 9.5).
There were also the complaints of the Italians forced off the land
by the Gracchan commission.
Others said that the graves of their ancestors were in the ground,
which had been allotted to them in the division of their father's
estates. Others said that their wives' dowries had been expended on
the estates or that the land had been given to their own daughters as
dowry (App. BC 1.10).
This motif reveals the ambiguities and the interesting continuity
over time with land reform. It can therefore be said that the moral
argument of land reform while applicable to some instances, cannot be
generalised to have appealed to all peasants. We can give an example of
land reforms initiated for infrastructural development (the construction
of Kariba dam, for example) and the risk of flooding to those staying
too close to Lake Kariba in the Tonga communal areas. The people
resisted to be moved from those areas as they argued that they did not
want to leave their ancestral tombs. The end result is, although some
thought was given to these socio-cultural niceties, the overriding theme
of appropriating land in the hands of the white minority for black
resettlement led to the ignoring of these issues for the people who
would be the titular beneficiaries of land reform.
Methodology
The contemporary Zimbabwean scenario depicts more organised mob
protest actions in the city. This performative element, which comes out
very clearly in Zimbabwe in the television footages of armed and angry
mobs is something which viewers from outside Zimbabwe recoil from, but
which speaks differently to those participating (Mlambo 2015). The
problem with the urban crisis, capitalised upon by ZANU (PF), was that
rural to urban migration created an urban population that had abandoned
rural life to seek employment in the cities, thereby creating an urban
crisis, and was less concerned with land. Thus, looking at contemporary
Zimbabwe, it is difficult to ascertain the motives of a million people
who marched in the city of Harare in support of both President
Mugabe's candidature and for his calls for land redistribution in
the run up to the 2002 presidential elections. Veterans, peasants, the
unemployed youths, the urban mob and hooligans, all marched in Harare,
but it is difficult to say that they all marched because they all were
in support of the land reform programme. Some youths were lured by the
promised free alcohol to join the march. One Miss B, claimed to have
joined the march because "Vakauya kuzotikokorodza kuDZ nemota
tikatanga tadhakiswa. Kuregerei kunwa hwahwa hwemahara."
("They mobilised us from DZ (Dzivaresekwa residential suburb) and
drove us to town. They gave us free beer. Tell me, who would not drink
free beer"?) (Interview with Miss B at Da Eros restaurant in
Harare, 8th April 2013)
The Populares in Roman politics prevailed through the use of
violence and money. The lynch mobs, for example, were mobilized using
money to perform acts of violence for the furtherance of Marius'
political struggles (Gabba 1976:46). The issue of immediate rewards such
as beer and money motivated most youths, and perhaps not that they were
consciously rallying behind President Mugabe's land reform
programme. However, in marching they were following the script of the
programme of land redistribution thereby giving political gravitas to
President Mugabe, as the voice and hand of the disenfranchised, while
most people who marched were actually not peasants.
There is also the question of lawlessness as war veterans took the
law into their own hands. The Zimbabwe War Veterans Liberation
Association was the institution ostensibly at the head of the
'land' army but it must be noted that some of its leaders have
dubious war histories and, therefore, not in line with the image of
peasant revolutionaries. The rise of Joseph Chinotimba and Jabulani
Sibanda is a good example. This casts doubt to the sincerity of the
moral argument of land redistribution as beneficiaries turned out to be
imposters of the narrative they supported thereby rendering what looked
like genuine moral protestation against inequalities in land ownership
into something morally more ambiguous.
War veterans were certainly marching (during the 1 million man
march) in order not only to campaign but also to intimidate the
electorate. Addressing supporters at the Forty-Fifth Ordinary Session of
ZANU-PF Central Committee on the 13th of December 2001, President Mugabe
acknowledged the role played by veterans in campaigning for the party
(Mlambo 2015: 179):
I want to thank all those of you who were involved in campaign work
in the last by-elections, and specifically the war veterans who have now
come back into the Party structures in such a massive, resounding and
re-invigorating way. We need to harness the same energy to win the
forthcoming local government and mayoral elections ... Looking ahead, we
should remain principally focused on the forthcoming Presidential
elections scheduled for sometime in 2002. Our wish is that land
resettlement should have been completed by the end of the year so that
in 2002, we would only have the worry to make the newly resettled
farmers more productive (Mugabe 2001:128).
This presence of the war veterans within the ruling party echelons
was a reactive measure as they were criticized when the farm invasions
began in 2000, before their usefulness as cadres in the election
strategy was utilized, in a manner reminiscent of the veterans of the
late republic. In the process of taking over the white-owned land, war
veterans ended up committing atrocities in the countryside and on farms.
To some extent, actions exhibited by the angry mobs of veterans did not
follow the script of the reformer's proclaimed altruistic agenda.
Equally so, the Gracchi attempts mirror the human capacity for
action and the broader social and political consequences which such
actions have on the political landscapes marred by challenges of land
redistribution. Hannah Arendt's theory of beginnings states that
one side of the unpredictability of action is lack of control over its
effects (see Arendt 1998). Arendt aptly argues thus:
Action sets things in motion, and one cannot foresee even the
effects of one's own initiatives, let alone control what happens
when they are entangled with other people's initiatives in the
public arena. Action is therefore deeply frustrating, for its results
can turn out to be quite different from what the actor intended (Canovan
1998, XVIII).
It is therefore necessary to note that a politician's claims
of an altruistic moral good can never be reconciled with the social and
political actions they undertook. Livy articulated the threat posed by
the Gracchi's agrarian law and the mob that participated in the
political process. Cicero's views on Tiberius' motives also
represent the voice of a lawyer and custodian of principles of the rule
of law hence, politicians and their supporters who called for land
redistribution are vilified and depicted as enemies of the state, peace
and order.
There is a degree to which the actions of the Gracchi when compared
with the actions of President Mugabe, slowly and eventually caused a
culture of political violence. Such actions when critically examined can
reveal some concealed political motives. This observation provokes the
following fundamental question: In what ways was land functional as the
categorical focal point for political control, mobilisation and
resistance? In this case 'resistance' refers to the political
actions of protest staged in Rome by the plebeians (both rural and
urban) under the leadership of the Gracchi. This did not only mark the
beginning of a radical revolutionary challenge to systems of inequality
and domination in the social and political landscape of Rome but it also
opened the big question of the plight and reward of the soldiery in
Roman politics and the political gravitas which could benefit
politicians who attracted their support by promising a distribution of
land. The origins of the veteran phenomenon (which became a leitmotif
throughout the first century BC) can be related to politics with
Tiberius Gracchus' lex agraria because the soldiery in the
pre-Gracchan era had already started to demand some measure of reform
(Scullard 1960:63).
One can be sympathetic to the general principle of land reform
after reading the speeches of President Mugabe but the rhetoric of a
moral good might conceal darker motives. One cannot help to think that
President Mugabe was surely thinking about his political career. The
same can be said about Tiberius Gracchus. The problem of the Gracchi in
Rome had more to do with the political culture than it had to do with
the economic crisis. In contemporary Zimbabwe, land was clearly turned
to by politicians as a political market to win the support of the
peasantry during elections, having been largely ignored until the
vibrancy of the invading citizens presented itself as a clear force that
could be harnessed to overwhelm opposition politicians. It was during
the run up to the 2002 Presidential elections when President Mugabe
addressed his party supporters thus:
The thrust of our programme emphasizes the small-holder peasant
farmer first, because it is he or she who badly needs land for a living
(Mugabe 2001:131).
Clearly Mugabe's stance was a major deviation from his
party's land policy since the 1980s. The government's initial
commitment to the willing buyer willing seller principle was
occasionally tested by hordes of land hungry black Africans. For
instance, in 1980, some former ZANLA war veterans in Masvingo who felt
that nationalist leaders had betrayed the armed struggle by not taking
land from the white elite settlers attacked white commercial farmers
(Sadomba 2011:78) They were arrested and handed long prison sentences,
averaging 15 years by the state (ibid). Furthermore, it was reported in
1984 that 'squatters' were posing severe encroachment problems
in Karoi, Tengwe and Chinyoyi areas to which the politicians responded
by siding with the large scale commercial farmers. Speaking at a
Commercial Farmers Union Conference, the then Minister of Agriculture
Mahachi declared
'Let me assure you, the elections are over ... the honeymoon
is over, we don't want anyone twisting the arm of government and we
will be acting vigorously against squatting.' (Financial Gazette,
19 July 1985, 17).
Clearly, at the time the land hungry did not have state support
hence culprits were brought to book. Sometimes, politicians exposed the
lack of a clear ideology regarding land redistribution. For instance,
Prime Minister Mugabe, speaking at a meeting of the Commercial Farmers
Union in 1985, urged farmers to feel 'rooted' as they had an
important role to play within the agricultural sector.
'We are unable to say when we will be able to say that
socialism has been implemented in full. It will take a long time to do
so. In the meantime, there are non-socialist modalities that must be
promoted' (Mugabe quoted in Weiner 1989:408-9)
But after telling farmers to 'stay where you are', he
warned that 'if you have land to spare, we will want that land for
resettlement' (ibid). During the 1990s the key trend appeared to be
a gradual revision of the strategy of compulsorily acquiring underused
land with partial compensation for land improvements, towards a policy
of using donor funds to buy willingly offered land. Notable in the
government's revised policy proposals of 1996 was the continuation
of a bifurcated approach of transferring land to 'better off black
farmers, including medium-scale producers, and to the landless or
'poor but capable' farmers in overcrowded communal areas (Moyo
2000:12). By the late 1990s, ZANU PF had managed to make land a key
political issue. In fact, Zanu PF rewrote the liberation war narrative
to pin it on the land question as it averred that that black ownership
of land was consistent with the divine order of things as reflected in
the Christian declaration 'As it was in the beginning, so shall it
always be.' (Chitando 2005:224).
The initial promise of altruistic reform, for both the Gracchi and
President Mugabe leads to more complex micro-narratives which offer a
very different perspective from the macro-view of the rich versus the
poor, the enfranchised versus the disenfranchised. Looking to modern
thought on situations of crisis of land redistribution, Marx observed
that in the social production of their life; men are bound to enter into
definite relations that are indispensable and independent of their will,
relations of production which correspond to a definite stage of
development of their material productive forces (Konstan 1990:83-94).
This observation helps us to grasp the mechanics of mass mobilization
and how the masses fell prey to some political machinations of reformers
who used land redistribution as bait to acquire power (in the case of
the Gracchi), and to maintain it (in the case of Zimbabwe). At this
stage in Roman politics, the only thing in the absence of land to farm
on or jobs to feed their families is that the poor became an alternative
source of power whose gravitas was easily appropriated by populist
politicians to gain or retain power as the landless poor were more than
ready to rally behind such individuals.
Plutarch, who saw Tiberius Gracchus as a populist, shows how the
question of land ownership started violence in Roman politics (Plut. Ti
Gr 14.1-2). The Gracchan reform movement demonstrates how the Gracchi
manufactured discord by their methods which exposed the ruling class to
the masses and portrayed the government as an encumbrance to social
equality. Speaking for the landless poor and the ex-soldiers, Tiberius
addressing the people crowding the rostra remarked:
And it is with lying lips that their imperators exhort the soldiers
in their battles to defend sepulchers and shrines from the enemy; for
not a man of them has an hereditary altar, not one of all these many
Romans an ancestral tomb, but they fight and die to support others in
wealth and luxury, and though they are styled masters of the world, they
have not a single clod of earth that is their own (Plut. Ti Gr 9.1-5).
Octavius' opposition to Tiberius' laws also illustrates
this point. No crime known to the law had been charged against Octavius
but Tiberius pitted the masses against his fellow tribune. Octavius
exercised his sacred duty as a tribune of the people but he was
presented by Tiberius as having offended the will of the majority
(Greenidge 1970:21). Members of the tumultuous popular assembly that
deposed Octavius to a certain degree were incited by Tiberius Gracchus.
This resulted in the production of negative energy which threatened the
Roman body politic and the status quo (See Plut. Ti Gr 8.3).
Resultantly, the 'Law was overwhelmed by force and greater respect
was accorded to greater power, and civil strife which in the past had
been resolved by agreement was settled by the sword.' (Vell. Pat.
3.3, see also Vell. Pat. 2.2-3)
Conclusion
In conclusion, we quote Marx's time tested observations about
peasants as a social class. This will help to put into perspective
contemporary Zimbabwean politicians and the Gracchi's use and
manipulation of the peasantry for ascending to greater political
heights. He argues thus:
... [Peasants] do not form a class. They are consequently incapable
of enforcing their class interest in their own name ... they cannot
represent themselves, they must be represented. Their representative
must at the same time appear as their master, as an authority over them,
as an unlimited governmental power that protects them against the other
classes and sends them rain and sunshine from above. The political
influence of the small-holding peasants, therefore, finds its final
expression in the executive power subordinating society to itself. (As
quoted in Moore 2001:257)
The rhetoric of the Gracchan 'revolution' was about
"land to the tillers" and it was, like in contemporary
Zimbabwe, structured by violence. Such structural and processual
imperatives gave birth to a situation whereby the politicians ended up
subordinating society to their will. Thus, the Gracchi was seeking an
unlimited regnum which thrived on blaming the Senate for the
non-implementation of land reform and that they should give up the
excess ager publicus (public land) they confiscated for redistribution
to the landless poor, in much the same way President Mugabe was blaming
the white commercial farmers for owning more than what was necessary at
the expense of the poor peasants. During the Gracchi era, Rome was at
the most critical point of its history, struggling to chart a peaceful
path beyond its devastating political and economic conditions. Such a
scenario is mirrored in the political landscape of Zimbabwe between 2000
and 2008. This calls for serious questions to be asked about
contemporary Zimbabwe in order to chart a meaningful road for the future
of the country.
Obert Bernard Mlambo, Ph.D.
ob ertmlamb o@gmail.com
Senior Lecturer, University of Zimbabwe, Harare
&
Wesley Mwatwara, Ph.D.
wesmel@gmail.com
Senior Lecturer, University of Zimbabwe, Harare
References
Arendt, H., (1998). The Human Condition. Second edition, Chicago,
IL: University of Chicago Press.
Canovan, M. (1998). "Introduction," in, Arendt, H., The
Human Condition, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Cary, E., Trans. (1942). Dio, Roman History, William Heinemann,
Massachusetts, Harvard University Press
Chaumba J., (2003). 'New Politics, New Livelihoods: Agrarian
Change in Zimbabwe,' Review of African Political Economy, 30, 98.
Chitando E., (2005). "In the Beginning Was the Land': The
Appropriation of Religious Themes in Political Discourses in
Zimbabwe,' Africa: Journal of the International African Institute,
75, 2
Chitiyo T.K., (2000). 'Land Violence and Compensation:
Re-conceptualizing Zimbabwe's War Veterans' Debate,'
Track Two, 9, 1.
Freese, J. H., trans. (1961). Cicero: The Speeches, London
Heinemann.
Forster, E.S., trans. (1929). Lucius Annaeus Florus: Epitome of
Roman History, London, William Heinemann.
Foster, O., (trans.) (1949). Livy, Massachusetts, Harvard
University Press.
Gabba, E. (1976). Republican Rome: The Army and the Allies,
Translated by P.J. Cuff, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
Gargola, D. J. (2008). "The Gracchan Reform and Appian's
Representation of an Agrarian Crisis," in de Ligt, L., and
Northwood, S.J., People, Land and Politics, Demographic Developments and
the Transformation of Roman Italy, 300 BC-AD 14, Leiden: Brill
publishers.
Greenidge, A H J., (1970). The First Sign of a Great Awakening in
Riddle John M (ed.) Tiberius Gracchus: Destroyer or Reformer of the
Republic?, Massachusetts, D C Heath and Company.
Konstan, D., (1990). Wesleyan University Review: History and
Theory, Vol. 29, No. 1. 83-94, Published by: Blackwell Publishing for
Wesleyan University Stable.
McGregor J., (2002). 'The politics of disruption: War veterans
and the state in Zimbabwe,' African Affairs, 101, 9-37.
Mlambo Obert Bernard (2013). The Dialectics of Land Redistribution
in the Late Roman republic and Contemporary Zimbabwe, Ph.D Diss.
University of Zimbabwe, Print.
Mlambo, Obert Bernard. (2015). Images of Masculinity and Militarism
in Veteran Land Movements in Contemporary Zimbabwe (2000-2008), and the
Late Roman Republic: Towards a Global History, In: Makwavarara,
Zifikile., Magosvongwe, Ruby., & Mlambo, Obert. Bernard. (Eds).
Dialoguing Land and Indigenization in Zimbabwe and Other Developing
Countries: Emerging Perspectives, University of Zimbabwe Publications,
168-183.
Moore D., (2001). 'Is the Land the Economy and the Economy the
Land? Primitive Accumulation in Zimbabwe,' Journal of Contemporary
African Studies, 19, 2.
Moyo S., (2000).'The Political Economy of Land Acquisition and
Redistribution in Zimbabwe, 1990-1999,' Journal of Southern African
Studies, 26, 1, 5-28.
Mugabe, R. G., (2001). Inside the third Chimurenga, Harare,
Department of Information and Publicity.
Muzondidya J., (2007). 'Jambanja: Ideological Ambiguities in
the Politics of Land and Resource Ownership in Zimbabwe,' Journal
of Southern African Studies, 33, 2, 325-341.
Onoma, A. K., (2010). The Politics of Property Rights Institutions
in Africa, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Rathbone, D., (2008). "Poor peasants and silent sherds",
(in) ed. L. de Ligt & S. Northwood, People, Land and Politics.
Demographic Developments and the Transformation of Roman Italy, 300 BC -
AD 14. Leiden, 305-32.
Riddle John, M., (1970). Introduction, in Riddle John M (ed.)
Tiberius Gracchus: Destroyer or Reformer of the Republic?,
Massachusetts, D C Heath and Company.
Roselaar, S. T. (2008). Public Land in the Roman Republic: A Social
and Economic History of Ager Publicus in Italy, 396-89BC, Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
Sage, T., (trans.) (1948). Livy, Massachusetts, Harvard University
Press.
Sadomba W.Z., (2011). War Veterans in Zimbabwe's Land
Occupations: Complexities of a Liberation Movement in an African
Post-Colonial Settler Society, London: James Currey.
Scullard, H. H. (1960). Scipio Aemiliunus and Roman Politics, The
Journal of Roman Studies, Vol 50, London, Society of Roman Studies,
59-74.
Shaw W. H., (2003). "They Stole Our Land': debating the
expropriation of white farms in Zimbabwe,' Journal of Modern
African Studies, 41, 1, 75-89.
Sibanda N., (2010). 'Where Zimbabwe got it wrong--lessons for
South Africa: A comparative analysis of the politics of land reform in
Zimbabwe and South Africa,' Master of Arts (International Studies),
Stellenbosch University.
Weiner, Daniel. (1989). "Agricultural Restructuring in
Zimbabwe and South Africa." Development and Change 20.3: 401-428.
Financial Gazette, 19 July 1985.