Re-examining current paradigms and concepts: rural development, environmental sustainability, and poverty alleviation in Africa.
Ezeanyika, Samuel Ezeanyika ; Okorie, Hilarie Anyanwu ; Osita-Njoku, Agnes 等
Introduction
It is a truism that terms such as rural development, environmental
sustainability, and poverty alleviation are poorly defined and elusive.
At best, they represent desired end states. Earlier paradigms of
development were largely Keynesian and centered on the state, laying a
strong emphasis on growth. More recent understandings have negated that
early belief. Analysts no longer see the nation as the engine of
production, growth, and equity. Instead, new paradigms support the local
over the national, civil society in preference to government, and
micro-entrepreneurship rather than industrialization as the way to
overcome absolute, acute and disproportionate poverty and achieve
sustainable rural development. The private sector rather than the state
is seen as the preferred supplier of agricultural services, whether
speaking of marketing, credit, or input supply. Furthermore, lapses in
reaching desired end states tend not to critique these means-ends
hypotheses themselves. Instead, excuses about the lack of capacity and
participation are proposed as a justification for the failure to
appreciate what is the real problem (Kuhn, 1996).
Notwithstanding the many issues and questions that have arisen in
the application of these new paradigms, there is still a strong belief
in their ability to contribute more effectively to rural development,
environmental sustainability, and poverty alleviation than past
approaches. Like the pure sciences, donors and academics tend to cling
to their paradigms. Unlike them, paradigms tend to shift when they are
unfashionable or politically out of tune rather than when they are
wrong.
This article raises a few major questions and discusses some of the
pressing issues that have emerged when these new paradigms of
development have been applied in the field. The intent is to highlight
problems faced by rural people on a daily basis in the face of these new
paradigms. Our hope is that the analysis below will lead to critical
thinking about the paradigms themselves and the means to achieve them,
thereby raising a few questions about current thinking and what is to be
done in the future. Section 2 extensively discusses the concept of
decentralization and attempts to show how it fails to bring development
to the rural communities because of the existing and entrenched
patron-clients cleavages already existing, and differing level of access
to state power. Section 3 assesses the possible contributions of the
civil society toward the actualization of sustainable development in
Africa. It also examines its problems and prospects. Section 4 analyses
the relationships between the macro-micro sectors and the problems
created by donor agencies in their efforts to separate them as if they
existed in isolation. Section 5 addresses the problems of sustainable
rural development and poverty alleviation, particularly those
accentuated by donor agencies that tend to ignore the dynamic realities
that both affect and characterize the rural poor. In section 6, the
article evaluates the impact of donors' policy encouraging
de-industrialization to the development of small enterprises. Marketing,
input supply and rural financial services are at the nucleus of dynamic
poverty alleviation strategies. Section 7 examines the private sector
initiative encouraged by donor agencies targeted at eliminating the
inefficiency of the state in providing these vital services.
Section 8 discusses the confusion arising from the introduction of
poorly defined paradigms such as capacity-building and their impact on
sustainable development. The article concludes that a number of these
new paradigms discussed, instead of solving old and existing development
problems are rather raising both conceptual problems and creating
operational difficulties. It therefore, suggests their comprehensive and
systematic re-evaluation.
Decentralization and Service Delivery
The concept of decentralization has become popular and a recurring
theme in the plans and policies of international assistance agencies and
developing nations in recent years (Rondinelli, 1981: 133). It involves
the deconcentration and delegation of legal and political authority to
plan, make decision and manage public functions from the central
government to subordinate units of government, semi-autonomous public
corporations, area-wide or regional development authorities; functional
authorities, autonomous local governments or non-governmental
organizations (NGOs) (Rondinelli, 1981: 137). Decentralization also
involves the devolution of power from the central government to the
local governments (Ezeani, 2004: 3).
Decentralization has become a central linchpin of the new paradigm
of rural development. Its institutionalization is seen as an antidote to
corrupt extractive nations that characteristically have exploited the
rural poor, a means of improving service delivery to them, and the best
way of encouraging popular participation so that rural people will
participate in their own development (Hyden, 1983).
The above ideal-type vision of what would occur if this paradigm
was put into practice is not necessarily what has happened. Instead,
when decentralization has been implemented in Africa, two situations
have commonly arisen: first, although decentralization was partly
conceived as a way of overriding the nation of its negative
characteristics, its implementation often has reproduced the state in
another guise. Formally, decentralization is in place in the majority of
African states. Informally, however, decentralized authorities are often
just new clones of the nation (Nyerere, 1972; Conyers, 1974). When this
happens, as it often does, decentralized authorities are no different
than their predecessors: that is, not more accountable, not more
democratic, and not more interested in the plight of the rural and urban
poor, integrated rural development, or environmental sustainability than
the centralized state preceding them. In addition, the rural poor
sometimes have fewer avenues of redress than in the past when they could
appeal to a less parochial and higher authority that was removed from
their day-to-day situations. Instead, because rural communities are
often highly stratified, authoritarian, corrupt, and repressive, as well
as responsive to parochial interests, citizens often feel they cannot
exercise their rights even when formally speaking, they have
decentralized institutions through which they can articulate their
grievances (Khalil, 2007).
The reality of decentralization is not always what is projected by
donor agencies. Usually absent from the decentralization thinking are
two fundamental elements. The first is that there is no uniformity among
Africa's rural communities. Instead, class and patron-client
relations stemming from complex cleavages based on family ties,
ethnicity, religious differences, as well as differing levels of access
to state power divide populations. These divisions and cleavages tend to
reproduce themselves institutionally in decentralized authorities, often
offering no improvements over the central state, and sometimes a further
regression to the mean from the standpoint of the rural poor. The second
is that the decentralization equation falls into an unfortunate
intellectual trap: it assumes one can change the way in which
organizations operate solely by making formal changes in institutions or
by developing new organizations. As a matter of fact, this simplistic
assumption is not true.
It is therefore, obvious from the above argument that similar
formal institutions in different places operate differently because of
different norms, belief systems, and enforcement mechanisms. These have
been called "rules of the game" (North, 1994) and tend to
change over long periods of history rather than overnight. This is
apparent from what has happened when the decentralization paradigm has
been put into practice in Africa. The results raise the broader question
of whether the implementation of formally decentralized institutions is
likely to achieve the mythical ends desired in the light of existing
theories about change and development, as well as concrete realities on
the ground.
It has been the central and generally erroneous argument of
champions of decentralization that local authorities tend to be less
corrupt, more accountable, and more likely to improve rural service
delivery than the centralized state. In reality, this has not happened
in the majority of those African nations that seem to champion
decentralization and have institutionalized its basic structures.
Nigeria is a very good example where decentralization is
constitutionally institutionalized creating a third tier of government.
However, its practice and applicability in the rural areas are generally
wanting. Instead, by virtue of setting up multiple foci of fiscal
autonomy, decentralized authorities have the potential to be no better
than the centralized state on all of the above counts (Treisman, 2000).
The Nigerian example illustrate the observations of North (1994)
that changing the formal rules of the game is far easier than
transforming the informal rules of the game and the norms and incentive
systems that support them. In addition, the fact that in the past, the
state often has performed poorly does not imply that it is inherently
incapable of being the engine and purveyor of dynamic change. In some
African countries, it depends very much upon who is in charge, the tone
that is set, and the degree to which the rule of law is entrenched and
not on the intrinsic characteristics of the nation state per se (Joseph,
2003).
Our position is therefore that, instead of criticizing the
shortcomings of African states, international development agencies
should re-examine how they think about institutional change, both at the
national and local level, and what they expect from it and under what
conditions. The paradigm of decentralization as a panacea for most rural
ills has been elevated to a level not supported historically (Amsden,
1989; Amsden, Kochanowicz, and Taylor, 1994) or by current realities. It
is important to face, whether with centralized or decentralized
institutions, the day-today experiences of many of today's rural
poor: lack of anonymity; fear of retribution and sanctions for
criticizing the powers that be; few opportunities for genuine
participation (Cooke and Kothari, 2001; Green, 2000); and a lack of
services, regardless of the formal characteristics of institutions.
Civil Society and Sustainable Development
Walzer (1991) defined civil society as the "space of uncoerced
human association; a set of rational networks formed for the sake of
family, faith, interest and ideology that fills this space."
According to Shaw and McLean (1996: 248) "civil society is
comprised of the various nongovernmental organizations, human rights
groups, cooperatives, unions, media, religious assemblages, professional
associations, and so on, through which individuals collectively and
voluntarily carry out their social enterprises." The civil society
is composed of reciprocity-based organizations not established by a
state which are concerned with the betterment of man's life in
society. They have a role to play in the actualization of sustainable
development. In a research carried in Italy, Putnam (1993) found an
early and statistically significant relationship between the growth of
non-state organizations and developmental effectiveness. This study
followed the collapse of the Union of Soviets Socialist Republics (USSR)
and a renewed emphasis by western donors on democratization in
developing countries, particularly those of Africa. During this brief
hiatus, western donors, in the majority, no longer found it
geopolitically necessary to support corrupt and repressive regimes. For
both reasons, donors promoted civil society organizations--particularly
in African countries--as a means of circumventing and developing an
antidote to states that were extracting more from their rural
populations than they were investing to achieve sustainable rural
development (Khalil, 2005). Certainly, there are many excellent examples
of what local populations and international donors can achieve by
working with civil society organizations. Nevertheless, the assumptions
both about civil society and what can be achieved with its assistance
are often overblown and out of tune with the realities of rural life.
There has been a good deal of critical academic discussion on the
concept of civil society and its applicability in many developing
countries (Briton, 1989; Korten, 1990; Walzer, 1991; Lemarchand, 1992;
McLean, 1993; Nyang'oro, 1993; Wellard and Copestake, 1993;
Harbeson, et. al., 1994; Osaghae, 1995; Ndegwa, 1996; Shaw and McLean,
1996; Harris, 2002). Nevertheless, donors and international agencies
have tended to analytically conflate NGOs with the concept of civil
society. They have assumed, often incorrectly, that the former is
synonymous with the latter, simply because NGOs are not legally or
formally part of the state.
On the ground, the reality is that many NGOs in African countries
are not necessarily part of civil society (Chabal and Daloz, 1998;
Kasfir, 1998; Rahman, 2002). The very moment donors began assiduously to
assist NGOs in preference to the state, numerous and sometimes
questionable individuals, as well as relatives of state employees and
even the state in a new guise, began to set up NGOs to attract
'foreign assistance.' Consequently, in many cases, NGOs
represented vested interests both outside and inside the state, were not
always distinguishable from it, were sometimes a means of aggrandizing
foreign aid, and were not necessarily more attuned to the rural poor or
sustainable development than government or other organizations (Korten,
1990; Wellard and Copestake, 1993).
In situations when NGOs have not been incorporated into the state
in a new guise, they are not inherently preferable to it. This is
because NGOs have, in some instances, been tied to local parochialisms,
are not necessarily technically qualified to assume tasks that have been
foisted upon them, and often lack a national vision of development. This
notwithstanding, in the face of declining financial assistance leading
to more and more privatization of aid, in addition to the current view
of the state as the enemy of development, international agencies and
other donors are working with the civil society, and with NGOs.
Macro-Micro and Sectoral Relationships
It is a fact that any critical analysis of contemporary paradigms
dealing with rural development, environmental sustainability, and
poverty alleviation acknowledges the importance of government in setting
sound macro-economic, political, and social policies. These policies
determine the parameters of what is possible in terms of development.
However, the tendency among international development organizations has
been to separate the macro from the micro, as if the former does not
matter. Within many of these agencies, disciplines and sectors also
often operate in isolation from each other. However, poor rural people
live in an integrated rather than a segmented world. It is a truism to
say that the macro affects the micro and vice versa and that sectors do
not exist in isolation (Deng, 1999).
However, often, one would hardly know this, looking at donor
agencies' strategies and their lending operations. Several examples
exist, some of which are discussed here. They demonstrate how such
approaches lead to assistance packages that misconceive problems and
solutions and hence are designed to fail in their attempt at promoting
rural development or alleviating poverty (Adedeji, 1990, 1995).
Malawi received the patronage of donor agencies in the 1980s and
1990s. The assistance was targeted at pro-poor development strategy.
Mostly, this consisted of rural development policies designed to support
local producer groups and to increase the production of improved maize.
In doing so, there was a failure to acknowledge one central
macro-economic policy issue that radically reduced the possible
effectiveness of these micro-level initiatives.
This was that government prohibited poor farmers on communal land
from growing tobacco, the only lucrative cash crop. Until this policy
changed, their incomes would not improve. Instead of dealing with this
central economic policy of the state, donors, including most
international organizations, spent considerable effort supporting local
grassroots intermediaries to give credit to poor farmers to produce
improved maize. This strategy was not economically viable. The result
was that the problem was misconceived, farmers went into debt, and the
proposed solutions did not work.
In the case of Uganda, donors assisted local groups to develop
organizations to protect the environment in an area where the hills were
virtually denuded. These hills were of marginal interest to community
members because their livelihood was mostly nonfarm and did not stem
from toiling their land. Hence, they did not have much incentive to put
their labor into environmental protection. It is obvious that not enough
time was spent analyzing how individuals from rural communities, who
looked like farmers, made their income or what their incentives were to
engage in certain types of rural development initiatives. These examples
suggest that rural incomes and employment are usually multi-sectoral,
and involving a strong nonfarm component. They are also directly
affected both by macro-economic and national policy considerations
(Bagachwa and Stewart, 1992; Barret, Reardon and Webb, 2001; Brycesson,
1996, 1999; Haggablade, Hazell and Reardon, 2006). It is, therefore, not
possible to ignore the relationship between macro-level phenomena and
micro-level behavior or to leave participation on social issues to
anthropologists, political issues to political scientists, and economics
to economists (Chambers and Conway, 1991; Ellis, 2000; Ellis and
Freeman, 2004).
Related to the above is the fact that many seemingly perfect
technical solutions are not perfectly extrapolated for all places and at
all times. Agricultural economists have devised theoretically sound
technical interventions that often are not implemented because of a lack
of political will by government, because of household labor constraints
that make it difficult for poor farmers to carry out the steps that
would optimize production, or because of cultural prohibitions and
various types of constraints that keep markets from operating
(O'Brien and Ryan, 2001).
Addressing the Problems of Sustainable Rural Development and
Poverty Alleviation
The daily lives of the rural poor should constitute the central
departure point for donor agencies concerned with the problems of
sustainable rural development and poverty alleviation. This approach
will involve the integration of the micro and the macro, as well as the
economic, political and socio-cultural realities of the rural poor. It
has been observed that international organizations and donor agencies do
not support the above increasingly important approach. There is little
attempt to recruit individuals who can think cross-sectorally. Routine
tasks are turned into pseudo-specialties.
One result is that agencies search for "experts" on NGOs,
decentralization, poverty and other non-fields rather than for social
scientists with sound training and solid analytical skills in one of the
major established disciplines.
It has also been observed that the creation of new development
jargons is a strategy by these donor agencies to run away from the
dynamic reality of dealing with the above mentioned situation. These
jargons include sustainable livelihoods, capacity-building, civil
society, decentralization, informal education, appropriate technologies,
micro-enterprises, rural financial intermediaries, and so on. They are
intended to camouflage the need for a serious rethinking of issues,
approaches, and questions concerning the soundness and utility of one
solution over another. Instead, the tendency is to think in a segmented
fashion about problems that require integrated thinking, not to
appreciate the constant relationship between the micro and the macro, to
ignore political considerations, to pretend that often powerful states
do not exist, to turn mere tasks into nonexistent pseudo-disciplines,
and to invent new jargon to homogenize extremely complex and diverse
situations. The ultimate result is to seriously threaten, if not hamper,
the ability of international agencies to address the very critical
problems of rural development, poverty alleviation, and environmental
sustainability today. Instead, the untouchable "isms" of bad
jargon spewed forth by these new paradigms suppresses rather than
invites questions (Asante, 2003).
Small Enterprise Development and De-Industrialization
In the majority of South-East Asian countries and in South Africa,
available evidence show that the process of industrialization and the
development of manufacturing spurred growth that led to the
transformation of rural life. Contemporary development paradigms seem to
be oblivious of this fact and now place their emphasis on small
enterprise development. In the majority of developing countries,
particularly those in Africa, the environment for economic investment,
whether domestic or foreign, has been negative. Many countries still are
locked in patterns of single-commodity production, often representing
legacies from the colonial period. For poor farmers, this has meant
experiencing something akin to the great depression of 1929 every few
years (Collier, 2001).
Donor agencies have initiated discussions bordering on the
diversification of rural livelihoods, while at the same time,
encouraging the development of small enterprises. In part, this is a
stopgap recognition that many rural poor are landless and that even
others cannot rely on agriculture alone to survive. While these small
enterprises constitute the real economy for many rural poor, they do not
offer a substitute for employment, an assured wage, or much hope for
improving their lives in the future. Instead, the rural poor overwork
and under-consume. In such situations, what is produced often cannot be
sold or markets for such products are limited due to gluts of similar
products (whether agricultural or non-agricultural), lack of quality
control, the high costs of transport, or international standards.
It has been observed that donor agencies and entrepreneurs engaged
in small businesses often neglect to conduct in-depth feasibility
studies to ascertain the viability to have a local rice factory, a fish
feeds project, or to produce local potato seeds, tools, and crafts into
something that can turn to a profit. It is a fact that much donor
agencies' assistance for the formation of small enterprise is both
unviable and unprofitable. The following examples will buttress our
point: farmers in Lesotho, Ghana and Cote d'lvoire were encouraged
to produce potato seeds only to discover that the same extension
officers assisting them had, not only a nearby community do the same
thing, but owned similar farms within the vicinity, thus resulting in a
glut. Donors supported women with sewing machines to expand dressmaking
in Mauritius. However, the liberalization of the market accompanying
Mauritius's impressive economic transformation also crushed these
businesses and others, as they could no longer compete either with
factory-made garments made locally or with imports. Both were more
competitive in terms of price and quality. In Nigeria, a pilot fish
feeds project that might have been viable for one or two people produced
almost no profits for a large group. In Mozambique, local farmers
preferred to buy South African tools instead of what their own neighbors
made because the quality of the former was superior and lasted longer.
International development organizations need once again to discuss
the possibilities for developing manufacturing and industry as a means
of providing employment opportunities to address rural poverty and
development. Donors have tended to concentrate on micro-level rural
solutions to micro-level poverty when the real solutions may not be, and
historically have not been, in situ at all. Here one is reminded of the
statement by Chang (2002) that the development advice offered by donors
has tended to follow the motto "do as I say, not as I do".
Privatization of Marketing, Input Supply, and Rural Financial
Services
African governments, as purveyors of development in the
post-independence era, set up parastatals to provide marketing, input
supply, and financial services. This was both a legacy of the colonial
period and a reaffirmation of the dominant Keynesian state-centric
paradigm. It is true that parastatals did not serve their rural populace
well. They tended to take the lion's share of the world market
prices, had high administrative costs, supported vested interests, often
did not collect perishable commodities on time, and paid farmers late,
if at all. Many rural development banks chose their borrowers badly,
relied on weak financial intermediaries, had high arrears, eventually
went bankrupt, and were closed. Lending also tended to be highly
politicized. Most rich farmers often deliberately defaulted, with the
collaboration of corrupt bank officials with whom they often shared the
loot.
The majority of the poor engaged in rural subsistence agriculture
made very small profits. As a result of their absolute and acute
poverty, they were compelled to choose between eating and paying back
their loans. Both groups had many clever male fide borrowers, whom the
state lured in by saying incorrectly that loans to them were free.
The experience of the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh and Pride Africa
in Tanzania gave rise to the somewhat misleading phrase, "the poor
are bankable". Consequently, donors pressured African
countries' governments to push more and more credit out to poorer
and poorer clients, making repayment increasingly improbable.
New trends emerged with the collapse of the USSR. International
donors began more critically to assess the performance of the state in
many areas. In terms of marketing, rural financial and input supply
services, the state received poor marks whether from the standpoint of
quality of service delivery, cost effectiveness, or reaching their rural
clientele. Instead, it was seen correctly to be wasteful, self-serving,
and corrupt. With this new trend came a new paradigm promoting private
sector development and a greater emphasis on market forces. In many
respects, this new emphasis has been salutary. Most parastatals have
been either commercialized or privatized and the few that remain are
being forced to compete with the private sector.
Market forces and not state policies have emerged as a new
development paradigm championed by donor agencies. This new development
has brought along new problems. In the era of state-centric paradigms,
rural areas, particularly in Africa, were inundated with
government-owned and operated community development banks, cooperative
parastatal marketing agencies, and a host of other state organs that
provided credit, marketing, and input supply services, even when they
were very poorly delivered. Now that government has scaled back or
privatized these parastatals, numerous rural areas are bereft of
agricultural services. Many banks and private marketing agents have
found it too costly and unprofitable to go to remote rural areas where
roads are bad, clients are dispersed, and production output is often low
and of poor quality. Even when private businessmen go to these places,
rural producers often are faced with a monopoly buyer or provider and
are just as vulnerable to the exploitation and poor services they
experienced in the past (Ariyo and Jerome, 1999).
It is true that, to a certain extent, the goal of withdrawing
subsidies for inputs, targeted at eliminating many market distortions in
African economies succeeded. However, this withdrawal, accompanied with
the devaluation of many African countries' currencies in the 1990s
often radically increased the price of inputs. Although agricultural
prices for small farmers also have increased with devaluation, the
margin of difference is still not necessarily enough to compensate for
the high cost of inputs. In addition, even in cases where privatization
of services has occurred, the state often still is involved in
agriculture and continues to capture a margin of the profits (Creevey,
Vengroff and Gaye, 1995; IMF, 1997, 1998).
It is arguable that the post-colonial African state tended to
deliver inadequate and unreliable agricultural services to the rural
farmers. Presently, the majority of farmers now receive almost no
services, and the few that are privileged to receive same do so, far in
between. This is a serious problem yet to be solved by donor agencies.
They are still basking in the euphoria that the new market paradigm has
been successful, as it has been in some cases.
However, currently many farmers have poor access to services, have
an output that is barely remunerative, and have few alternative
employment opportunities. In the past, when farming became
uncompetitive, individuals engaged in remunerative nonfarm activities,
or moved to large cities and worked in factories and construction sites.
Currently, in most African countries, there is already a mass
out-migration of labor, but with little chance of employment either in
the rural areas, where they are already marginalized, or in the urban
areas where there is great competition for few jobs.
Capacity-Building for Sustainable Development
The word 'capacity' has been elevated in the
developmental nexus, thanks to new development paradigms. It is now used
widely without any specificity. Donors and others often speak about a
'lack of capacity' to describe a problem or
'capacity-building' as a way of solving it. The question is,
what does all of this mean? It is common knowledge institutions that are
not performing well can have any number of problems. These include being
badly managed, having unqualified staff, having workers who lack
incentives because they are poorly paid or otherwise demoralized, not
having proper equipment, or being engaged in state-supported or
individual corruption. Each of these problems is very different and
requires very different solutions.
The 'capacity-building' contraption has been extensively
popularized in many discussions on rural development, poverty
alleviation and environmental sustainability. Its use has been random,
without stating what is meant and proposing solutions that mostly have
nothing to do with the real problems, which are rarely spelled out.
Routinely, donors choose to modernize equipment and to train staff as a
means of improving how organizations function. However, often a lack of
equipment and a lack of training, while relatively easily provided as
solutions, are not the real problems.
According to the approach popularized by North (1994), it is
important, from the onset, to try and understand the formal and informal
rules of the game and the incentives and disincentives that support
certain types of behaviors. This would help to ground the idea of
institution--or capacity--building in some reality. It would do so by
specifying the real problem behind badly functioning institutions, while
tying ideas about how to strengthen them to specific problems.
Discussions of a lack of access by the poor to social services and
the problem of developing a supportive environment for private sector
development, to take just two examples, often regress to highly general
euphemisms, such as institutional "capacity-building" in
proposing solutions. Such euphemisms avoid analyzing situations to the
point where they identify specific problems or discuss causal means-ends
relationships, indicating whether there are any concrete solutions to
the problems identified and, if so, what actions by donor agencies would
best support them.
The resultant effect of the above discussion is that many problems
experienced by the rural poor in a host of areas--whether health,
education, social security, access to land and other services, or poorly
functioning institutions that do not serve them--often are found to be
political rather than technical. Donor agencies need to acknowledge
political impediments as such strategies to promote integrated rural
development, address poverty and its related problems, and ensure the
maintenance of a sustainable environment.
Conclusion
The analysis in this article has singled out a series of issues, by
no means comprehensive, to highlight problems arising from the
application of recent development paradigms. The argument is that a
number of these new paradigms of rural development, environmental
sustainability, and poverty alleviation raise both conceptual problems
and operational difficulties when they are implemented on the field. In
some cases, the ideas currently being proposed by donor agencies as
solutions bear little relationship to the realities or problems
experienced by the rural poor on a daily basis. In other cases, the
paradigms themselves are often mythical in their conception,
representing desired end states. Hence, when implemented in a dynamic
environment, they tend not to work as they conflict with existing
realities and are theoretically unsound.
In addition, in all of the paradigms discussed, there is a common
tendency to ignore or escape the reality of dealing with the monster in
the room--poorly functioning corrupt African governments that contribute
to poverty and often destroy rather than promote development. Donor
agencies have responded by supporting a plethora of actors nominally
outside the state. Often, however, these non-state actors are not
independent, and even when they enjoy some degree of independence, they
are still subject to the laws, policies, regulatory procedures, and
power of the state, an entity that has always been of paramount
importance. There is a dangerous tendency to ignore this reality.
Historically, the state, either directly or indirectly, has been a
critical engine of growth and the purveyor of development, something
that cannot be denied.
From a policy perspective, this analysis is intended as a point of
departure to generate critical thinking about current approaches to
rural development. It is also an attempt to get away from much of the
simplistic thinking that has characterized current analysis. While the
road ahead may be fraught with difficulties, they must be acknowledged.
Current thinking about rural development, environmental sustainability,
and poverty alleviation should dynamically address African
countries' problems of development. One of the main barriers to
sound inquiry are bad paradigms, and the refusal to engage in hard
thinking hard and deal honestly about the very difficult problems of
rural development, environmental sustainability, and poverty
alleviation.
References
Adedeji, A. 1990. The African Challenges in the 1990s: New
Perspectives for Development. Indian Journal of Social Sciences 3:
255:269.
Adedeji, A. 1995. Economic Progress: What Africa Needs. In:
Mengisteab, K. and Logan, B.I. (eds.) Beyond Economic Liberalization in
Africa: Structural Adjustment and the Alternatives. London: Zed Books.
Amsden, A. 1989. Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late
Industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press.
Amsden, A. Kochanowicz, J. and Taylor, L. 1994. The Market Meets
Its Match: Restructuring the Economies of Eastern Europe. Cambridge,
Mass: Harvard University Press.
Ariyo, A. and Jerome, A. 1999. Privatization in Africa: An
Appraisal. World Development 27 (1): 137-148.
Asante, K.S.B. 2003. New Partnership for Unequal Partners. New
African 419: 13-14.. Bagachwa, M.S.D. and Stewart, F. 1992. Rural
Industries and Rural Linkages in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Survey. In:
Stewart, F., Lall, S. and Wangwe, S. (eds.) Alternative Development
Strategies in Sub-Saharan Africa. New York: St. Martin's.
Barret, C.B., Reardon, T. and Webb, P. 2001. Nonfarm Income
Diversification and Household Strategies in Rural Africa: Concepts,
Dynamics and Policy Implications. Food Policy 26: 315331.
Briton, M. 1989. Beyond the State: Civil Society and Associational
Life in Africa. World-Politics 41 (3): 407-430.
Brycesson, D.F. 1996. Deagrarianization and Rural Employment in
Sub-Saharan Africa: A Sectoral Perspective. World Development 30:
725-739.
Brycesson, D.F. 1999. African Rural Labor, Income Diversification
and Livelihood Approaches: A Long-term Development Perspective. Review
of African Political Economy 80: 171-189.
Chabal, P. and Daloz, J. 1998. Africa Works: Disorder as a
Political Instrument. Oxford: James Currey.
Chang, Joon H.A. 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder: Development
Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem.
Chambers, R. and Conway, T. 1991. Sustainable Rural Livelihood:
Practical Concepts for the 21st Century. IDS Discussion Paper 296, IDS,
Brighton.
Collier, P. 2001. The Macro-Economic Repercussions of Agricultural
Shocks and Their Implications for Insurance. Washington, D.C.: World
Bank, draft, 8 October.
Conveys, D. 1974. Decentralization: the Latest Fashion in
Development Administration? Public Administration and Development 3:
97-109.
Cooke, B. and Kothari, U. (eds.) 2001. Participation: The New
Tyranny. London and New York: Zed Books.
Creevey, L., Vengroff, R. and Gaye, I. 1995. Devaluation of the CFA
Franc in Senegal: The Reaction of Small Businesses. The Journal of
Modern African Studies 33 (4): 147-151.
Deng, L. 1999. Rethinking African Development. Trenton, N.J.:
Africa World Press.
Ellis, F. 2000. Rural Livelihoods and Diversity in Developing
Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ellis, F. and Freeman, H.A. 2004. Rural Livelihood and Poverty
Reduction Strategies in Four African Countries. Journal of Development
Studies 40 (4): 1-30.
Ezeani, O.E. 2004. Local Government Administration. Enugu:
Zik-Chuks Printing Press.
Green, M. 2000. Participatory Development and the Appropriation of
Agency in Southern Tanzania. Critique of Anthropology 20 (1): 67-89.
Haggblade, S., Hazell, P. and Reardon, T. (eds.) 2006. Transforming
the Rural Nonfarm Economy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Harbeson, J. Donald, R. and Naomi, C. 1994. Civil Society and the
State in Africa. Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner.
Harris, J. 2002. Politicizing Development: The World Bank and
Social Capital. London: Anthem Press.
IMF 1997. IMF Builds on Initiatives to Meet Challenges of
Globalization. IMF Survey 26 (September).
IMF 1997. IMF Acts in Changing Economic Environment to Strengthen
Global Monetary System. IMFSurvey27 (September).
Joseph, R. 2003. Africa: States in Crisis. Journal of Democracy 14
(3): 161-70 (July). Khalil Timamy, M.H. 2005. African Leaders and
Corruption. Review of African Political Economy32 (5): 383-93.
Khalil Timamy, M.H. 2007. The Political Economy of Technological
Underdevelopment in Africa. Lagos and Addis Ababa: Centre for Black and
African Arts and Civilization (CBAAC) and Development Policy Management
Forum (DPMF).
Kasfir, N. 1998. The Conventional Notion of Civil Society: A
Critique. Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Studies 36 (2): 1-20.
Korten, D. 1990. Getting to the 21st Century: Voluntary Actions and
the Global Agenda. West Hatfold: Kumarian.
Kuhn, T. 1996. The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (3rd ed.).
Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press.
Lemarchand, R. 1992. Uncivil States and Civil Societies: How
Illusion became Reality. Journal ofModern African Studies 3 (2): 177-91.
McLean, S. 1993. North-South NGO Relations and Sustainable
Development in Africa: Toward a Study of Canadian and African
Partnerships. Boston, ASA Conference.
Ndegwa, S. 1996. The Two Faces of Civil Society. West Hartford,
Connecticut: Kumarian Press. North, D. 1994. Economic Performance
through Time. The American Economic Review 84 (3): 359-68 (June).
Nyang'oro, J. 1993. The Receding Role of the State and the
emerging Role of NGOs in African Development. Nairobi: AACC.
Nyerere, J.K. (1972). Decentralization in Dar es Salaam. Dar es
Salaam: Government of Tanzania.
O'Brien, F.S. and Ryan, T.C.I. 2001. Kenya. In: Shantayanan,
D. et. al., (eds.) Aid and Reform in Africa: Lessons from Ten Case
Studies. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Osaghae, E. 1995. The Study of Political Transition in Africa.
Review of African Political Economy64: 183-97.
Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern
Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Rahman, M.A. 2002. The Politics of Uncivil Society in Egypt. Review
of African Political Economy 191: 21-36.
Rondinelli, D.A. 1981. Government Decentralization in Developing
Countries. International Review of Administrative Sciences XLVII (2).
Shaw, T.M. and McLean, S.J. 1996. Civil Society and Political
Economy in Contemporary Africa, what Prospects for Sustainable
Democracy? Journal of Contemporary African Studies 14 (2): 247-64.
Treisman, D. 2000. The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National
Study. Journal of Public Economics 76 (3): 399-457 (June).
Walzer, M. 1991. The Idea of Civil Society. Dissent 38 (2):
293-304.
Wellard, K. and Copestake, J. (eds.) 1993. NGOs and the State in
Africa: Rethinking Roles in Sustainable Development. London: Routledge
for ODI.
by
Ezeanyika, Samuel Ezeanyika
Senior Lecturer in Political/Social Economy, Unit of Development
Studies, Department of Political Science and Public Administration, Imo
State University, Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria esezeanyika@yahoo.com
Okorie, Hilarie Anyanwu
Senior Lecturer and Head, Department of Crop Science and
Biotechnology, Faculty of Agricultural Science and Veterinary Medicine,
Deputy Director, Development Studies Research Group, Imo State
University, Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria
Agnes Osita-Njoku
Senior Lecturer, Department of Sociology, Imo State University,
Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria
Edith Chinwe Pat-Mbano
Senior Lecturer, Department of Urban and Regional Planning, Imo
State University, Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria
&
Opurum, Innocent Okwu
Research Fellow, Development Studies Research Group
Imo State University, Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria
Ezeanyika, Samuel Ezeanyika (esezeanyika@yahoo.com) is a senior
lecturer in Political/Social Economy in the Unit of Development Studies,
Department of Political Science and Public Administration at Imo State
University in Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria. He is also a senior research
fellow and director of the Development Studies Research Group at Imo
State University, Owerri. His articles have been published in
International Studies Review, African Journal of Rural Studies, African
Journal of Democracy and African Journal of Communication and
Development. He is author of The Politics of Development Economy in the
South (Owerri: Gabtony International, 2006) and Introduction to African
Politics (Owerri: Gabtony International, 2007). He is also co-author
(with K.O. Nworgu and I.O. Oprurum) of Understanding the Nexus between
Communication and Globalization (forthcoming).
Okorie, Hilarie Anyanwu is a senior lecturer and head of the
Department of Crop Science and Biotechnology with the Faculty of
Agricultural Science and Veterinary Medicine at Imo State University in
Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria and the deputy director of the Development
Studies Research Group at Imo State University.
Agnes Osita-Njoku is a senior lecturer specializing in gender
issues and the sociology of development in the Department of Sociology
at Imo State University in Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria. Her articles have
been published in several volumes of Journal of Women Academics. She
also contributed a chapter in the Issues in Substance Use and Abuse in
Nigeria.
Edith Chinwe Pat-Mbano is a senior lecturer specializing in
Environmental Sustainability int the Department of Urban and Regional
Planning at Imo State University in Owerri, Imo State, Nigeria. She has
published major articles in Journal of Women Academics and International
Journal of Development and Management Review.
Opurum, Innocent Okwu is a research fellow in the Development
Studies Research Group at Imo State University in Owerri, Imo State,
Nigeria. His is the author of Classical Political Thought (Owerri: Imo
State University Press, 2007) and the co-author (with E.S. Ezeanyika and
K.O. Nworgu) of Understanding the Nexus Between Communication and
Globalization (forthcoming).