Dynamic asset allocation strategies based on unexpected volatility.
Zakamulin, Valerty
Volatility is widely used by both academics and practitioners as a
measure of risk. In a rational expectation model, investors should be
compensated for taking on more risk by receiving a higher expected
excess return. Hence, the excess market return should be positively
related to market volatility (see, for example, Merton [1980]). On the
contrary, the contemporaneous relation between the excess market return
and volatility is found to be negative. For example, using the monthly
data on the S&P 500 index over the period from 1970 to 2012, the
regression results are
[r.sub.t]- [r.sub.f,t] = 0.026-0.502[[sigma].sub.t], (1)
where [r.sub.t] is the return on the S&P 500 index in month t,
[r.sub.f,t] is the risk-free rate of return, and [[sigma].sub.t] is the
monthly volatility of the returns on the index. All regression
coefficients are significantly different from zero at less than 1%
level.
French et al. [1987] propose the resolution of the puzzling
negative relationship between market risk and return. They decompose the
total market volatility into the expected and unexpected components
[[sigma].sub.t]=[[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e] +
[[sigma].sub.t]" where the expected market volatility,
[[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e], is predicted using the generalized autoregres-sive conditional heteroskedasticity (GARCH) model of
Bollerslev [1986], and the unexpected volatility is given by
[[sigma].sub.t]" = [[sigma].sub.t] - [[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e].
In words, unexpected volatility at time t is computed as the difference
between the realized volatility at time t and expected volatility of
time t that was forecasted at time t-1. Using the GARCH(1,1) model to
predict the volatility and the same data as in regression (1), the
contemporaneous relation between the excess market return and both the
expected and unexpected volatility is estimated to be
[r.sub.t] - [r.sub.f,t]=0.021+0.624[[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e] -
0.768[[sigma].sub.t]" (2)
Both the regression coefficients in front of independent variables
are significantly different from zero at less than 1% level. Regression
(2) advocates that the excess market return is positively related to
expected volatility and negatively related to unexpected volatility.
French et al. (1987, page 27) note that the negative relation in
regression (1) can be explained as follows: If the excess market return
is positively related to expected volatility and volatility is highly
persistent, then a positive unexpected change in volatility (and an
upward revision in predicted volatility) increases future expected risk
premiums and lowers. current stock prices (assuming that the future
expected cash flows are unaffected). In other words, when volatility
increases unexpectedly, investors anticipate higher risk in the near
future and, therefore, require higher risk premiums, which causes
current stock prices to fall.
There is a large strand of that explores the predictive abilities
of historical and implied volatility, and proposes how historical and
implied volatility can be used in dynamic asset allocation. For example,
Whaley [2000]; Giot [2005]; and Bann:* et al. [2007] find that the CBOE
volatility index (VIX) predicts returns on stock market indexes.
Copeland and Copeland [1999] propose how to use VIX as a size and style
rotation tool.
Even though there is no statistically significant evidence that
historical volatility is able to predict future stock market returns,
asset allocation strategies with volatility target mechanism are growing
in popularity among practitioners (see, for example, Collie et al.
[2011]; Butler and Philbrick [2012]; and Albeverio et al. [2013]). In
particular, empirical studies usually find that active strategies that
seek to keep volatility at a target level outperform passive
buy-and-hold strategies.
A low volatility anomaly is documented by Ang et al. [2006] and by
Blitz and van Vliet [2007]. These findings report that stocks with high
past volatility have low expected future returns. Where the former
authors focus on a very short-term (one-month) idiosyncratic volatility
measure, the latter authors concentrate on long-term (past three years)
total volatility.
To the best knowledge of this author, the predictive abilities of
unexpected volatility are largely unexplored. Yet there are indications
that at the individual stock level the low volatility anomaly is driven
mainly by unexpected volatility. In particular, Chua et al. [2010]
distinguish between expected and unexpected idiosyncratic volatility and
find a strong negative relation between unexpected idiosyncratic
volatility and expected future returns, while expected idiosyncratic
volatility is positively related to expected future returns.
The first contribution of this article is to document that, at the
aggregate stock market level, unexpected volatility is able to predict
both future excess return and volatility. Specifically, unexpected
volatility is negatively related to expected future returns and
positively related to future volatility. This suggests that when
volatility increases unexpectedly and investors require higher risk
premiums, which causes current stock prices to fall, the adjustment of
stock prices does not happen instantly, but takes some time.
In addition, since volatility is persistent, when volatility
increases it has a tendency to remain increased for some time. This
suggests that the sluggishness of both the processes can be exploited in
dynamic asset allocation strategies.
The second contribution of this article is to test two strategies
that dynamically reallocate between stocks and the risk-free asset,
depending on the value of unexpected volatility. Whereas in the first
strategy the weight of stocks is changed gradually between 0 and 1, the
second strategy involves switching between stocks and the risk-free
asset. We find that both the strategies deliver a substantial
improvement in risk-adjusted performance as compared to traditional
buy-and-hold strategies. In addition, we demonstrate that active
strategies based on unexpected volatility outperform the popular active
strategy with volatility target mechanism, and have some edge over the
popular market timing strategy with 10-month simple moving average rule.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. The second section
describes our data, while the third section outlines how we measure the
actual and unexpected volatility. In the fourth section we investigate
the predictive abilities of unexpected volatility. The fifth section
explores the usefulness of this predictability for dynamic asset
allocation between stocks and the risk-free asset. The final section
presents conclusions.
DATA
In our study we use data on two stock market indexes: the S&P
500 and the Dow Jones Industrial Average. Our sample period begins
January 3, 1950, and ends December 31, 2012. The data for these stock
market indexes come in daily and monthly frequency.
The S&P 500 index is a value-weighted stock index which is
intended to be a representative sample of leading companies in leading
industries within the U.S. economy. Stocks in the index are chosen for
market size, liquidity, and industry group representation. The daily
capital appreciation return series for this index are obtained from
Yahoo Finance.(1)
Dividends on this index are 12-month moving sums of dividends paid
on the S&P 500 index. They are obtained from Robert Shiller's
website.(2) Using capital appreciation return and dividend yield, we
compute the continuously compounded monthly returns on the S&P 500
index, including dividends.
The Dow Jones Industrial Average index is a price-weighted stock
index. Specifically, the DJIA is an index of the prices of 30 large U.S.
corporations selected to represent a cross section of U.S. industry. The
components of the DJIA have changed 48 times in its 1.17-year history.
Changes in the composition of the DJIA are made to reflect changes in
the companies and in the economy. The daily capital appreciation return
series for this index over the total sample period and dividends for the
period 1988 to 2012 are provided by S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, a
subsidiary of the McGraw-Hill Companies.(3)
The dividends for the period 1950 to 1987 are obtained from
Barron's.(4) The dividends are smoothed using 12-month moving sum.
Using capital appreciation return and dividend yield, we compute the
continuously compounded total monthly returns on the DJIA index.
The monthly risk-free rate of return, proxied by the Treasury bill
rate, comes from the data library of Kenneth French.(5) For the purpose
of measuring the performance of alternative strategies, from the data
library of Kenneth French we also obtain the monthly returns on the
market portfolio (which is the value-weighted return on all NYSE, AMEX,
and NASDAQ stocks), the monthly returns on the Small-Minus-Big (SMB) and
High-Minus-Low (HML) Fama-French factors, and the monthly returns on the
momentum (MOM) factor of Jegadeesh and Titnian [1993].
MEASURING ACTUAL AND UNEXPECTED VOLATILITY
The actual (realized) monthly variance of index returns is computed
as the sum of squared daily returns. Specifically, monthly variance is
calculated using the equation
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where N, is the number of trading days in month t and [r.sub.it] is
the return on the ith day of month t. It should be mentioned, however,
that French et al. [1987] suggest using a correction of the formula
above
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where the second term (twice the sum of the products of adjacent
returns) accounts for possible autocorrelation of daily returns. We
tried both these methods of computations of monthly variance and these
experiments showed that a method of computation had little effect on our
results.
The volatility of monthly returns is assumed to evolve according to the GARCH(1,1) model.
In particular, the model is given by
[r.sub.t] = [mu] + [[epsilon].sub.t], [[epsilon].sub.t] ~ N (0,
[[epsilon].sub.t.sup.2])
[[epsilon].sub.t.sup.2] = a + b[[epsilon].sub.t-1.sup.2] +
c[[epsilon].sub.t-1.sup.2]
The reasons for this choice are the following: the GARCH(1,1) model
is simple, robust, popular, and works very well in many practical
applications (see Engle [2001]). The key features of this process are
its mean reversion and its symmetry with respect to the magnitude of
past returns. We also tried two asymmetric GAR.CH models, which are
developed to capture the tendency for volatilities to increase more when
past returns are negative. These models are the GJR-GARCH(1,1) model of
Glosten et al. [1993] and the EGARCH(1,1) model of Nelson [1991]. Our
experiments showed that the type of GARCH model had negligible effect on
our results.
The unexpected volatility for month t is defined as the difference
between. the expected volatility for month t (forecasted at the end of
month t-1) and the actual volatility for month t (computed at the end of
month t): [[^.[sigma]].sub.t]" =
[[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e]-[[sigma].sub.t]. Since the ultimate goal
of this article is to analyze the real-life (that is, out-of-sample).
performance of some dynamic asset allocation strategies based on
unexpected volatility, in order to get rid of the look-ahead bias we
employ the recursive out-of-sample forecasting using the expanding
window estimation scheme to compute the expected volatility
[[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e].
Specifically, out-of-sample forecasting of
[[^.[sigma]].sub.t|t-1.sup.e] is performed as follows. First of all, the
historical data are segmented into in-sample and out-of-sample periods.
The split point between the initial in-sample and out-of-sample periods
is denoted by [tau], 1 < [tau] < T, where
T is the number of months in the total sample. The initial
in-sample period of [1, [tau]] is used to estimate the parameters of the
GARCH(1,1) process. Subsequently, the expected volatility for month
[tau]+1 is forecasted using the estimated parameters of the GARCH(1,1)
process.
We then expand the in-sample period by one month, perform the
estimation of the parameters of the GARCH(1,1) process once again using
the new in-sample period of [1, [tau] +1], and forecast the expected
volatility for month + 2 using the re-estimated parameters of the
GARCH(1,1) process. We repeat this procedure, pushing the endpoint of
the in-sample period ahead by one month with each iteration of this
process, until the expected volatility for the last month T is computed.
Our out-of-sample forecasting period starts in December 1969, which
means that the first computation for the unexpected volatility
[[sigma].sub.t]" is made at the end of this month. Thus, the
composition of the dynamic portfolio is first determined at the end of
December 1969 and, consequently, the first return observation on the
active portfolio is over January 1970.
Observe that our initial in-sample period for forecasting the
volatility is January 1950 through November 1969, which covers almost 20
years. This insures high forecast accuracy because the majority of
studies report that GARCH forecast accuracy increases as the length of
the in-sample period increases (see, for example, Figlewski [1997] and
Brownlees et al. [2012]). In particular, Brownlees et al. [2012] find
that GARCH models perform best using the longest available data series.
Exhibit 1 plots the unexpected volatility of the returns on the S&P
500 index over our total out-of-sample period. The graph of the
unexpected volatility for the DJIA index is basically the same.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
PREDICTIVE ABILITIES OF UNEXPECTED VOLATILITY
In this section we estimate the predictive abilities of unexpected
volatility. Specifically, we regress the monthly excess returns on a
stock index on the lagged unexpected volatility (6)
[r.sub.t] - [r.sub.f,t] = [alpha] + [beta][[sigma].sub.t-1]" +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (3)
For example, if [beta]= 0 in (3), the future excess return is
unrelated to the unexpected volatility. If [beta] <0, then the future
excess return is negatively related to the unexpected volatility. In
this case, a high unexpected volatility would predict a low excess
return. If, on the other hand, [beta] > 0, then the future excess
return is positively related to the unexpected volatility. If this is
the case, a high unexpected volatility would predict a low excess
return.
We also regress the monthly volatility of the returns on a stock
index on the lagged unexpected volatility in order to find out whether
there is a statistically significant relationship between these two
variables
[[sigma].sub.t] = [alpha] + [beta][[sigma].sub.t-1.supll] +
[epsilon], (4)
To check the robustness of our findings, we estimate each
predictive regression not only for our total out-of-sample period
1.970-2012, but also for different subperiods. It is worth noting that
our total out-of-sample period covers four decades, two that can be
characterized as long bull markets (the 1980s and 1990s) and two that
were marked by periods of severe bear markets (the 1970s and 2000s).
First, we split our total period into two (almost) equal subperiod
(1970-1990 and 1991-2012) and estimate the predictive regressions. Each
of these subperiods comprises a decade of a long bull market and a
decade with severe bear markets. Second, we estimate the predictive
regressions for each decade in our sample.
The results of our estimations are reported in Exhibit 2. In
particular, for each predictive regression (3) and (4), stock market
index (S&P 500 and DJIA), and historical period, Exhibit 2 reports
the value of the coefficient in front of the predictor, the P-value of
the coefficient, and the goodness of fit (as measured by R2-statistics).
The P-values are computed using White's
heteroskedasticity-consistent estimator for the asymptotic variance of
the coefficient in front of the predictor (see White [1980]).
EXHIBIT 2
Results of the Estimations of the Predictive Regressions for
the Excess Return on a Stock Index and the Standard Deviation
of Returns on a Stock Index In both cases the predictor is the
lagged unexpected volatility ot returns on a stock index. Coef.
Is the value of the estimated coefficient in front of the
predictor (the value of [^.[beta]]). P-value is the p-value of
the coefficient in front of the predictor. R-square is the value
of the [R.sup.2]-statistics. Bold text indicates values that are
statistically significant at the 5% level.
[r.sub.t] - [r.sub.f,t] [r.sub.t] - [r.sub.f,t]
= [alpha] + [beta = [alpha] + [beta]
[[sigma].sub.t-1.sup.u] [[sigma].sub.t-1.sup.u]
+ [[epsilon].sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
Period Coef. P-value R-squared Coef. P-value K-squared
Panel A: Standard and Poor's 500
1970-2012 -0.300 0.01 0.02 0.645 0.00 0.32
1970-1990 -0.346 0.01 0.02 0.327 0.00 0.09
1991-2012 -0.290 0.06 0.03 0.837 0.00 0.50
1970-1979 -0.498 0.30 0.02 0.653 0.00 0.32
1980-1989 -0.322 0.00 0.03 0.218 0.00 0.04
1990-1999 0.371 0.15 0.02 0.642 0.00 0.28
2000-2012 -0.371 0.02 0.05 0.815 0.00 0.50
Panel B: Dow Jones Industrial Average
1970-2012 -0.221 0.02 0.01 0.570 0.00 0.27
1970-1990 -0.298 0.00 0.02 0.315 0.00 0.09
1991-2012 -0.167 0.24 0.01 0.767 0.00 0.47
1970-1979 -0.386 0.27 0.01 0.655 0.00 0.34
1980-1989 -0.276 0.00 0.02 0.217 0.00 0.04
1990-1999 0.376 0.19 0.02 0.536 0.00 0.21
2000-2012 -0.248 0.09 0.02 0.763 0.00 0.49
The results for both the stock indexes are virtually the same, so
we discuss the results for the S&P 500 index only. First, our
results suggest that unexpected volatility is negatively related to
future excess returns. In particular, the coefficient in front of the
unexpected volatility is negative and statistically significant at the
1% level for the overall sample and the first half of the sample; for
the second half of the sample the coefficient is negative, but it is
statistically significant at the 6% only.
The analysis of the sign of the relation between the unexpected
volatility and future excess returns for each decade in the sample
reveals that the negative relation holds for each decade except the
decade of 1990s. Specifically, during this decade the coefficient in
front of the unexpected volatility is positive, though it is not
statistically significant at the conventional statistical levels. This
suggests that the negative relation between the unexpected volatility
and future excess returns is not very robust; most often the relation is
negative, but sometimes the relation can have the opposite sign.
It should be mentioned, however, that the decade of the 1990s was
not quite a typical one for the stock market. Specifically, this decade
was marked by the outset of the dot-com bubble. It is plausible to
assume that the stock market dynamics during a bubble differ from
"normal" dynamics.
For example, Hsu and Li [2013] study the performance of
low-volatility strategies during the period from 1990 to 2012 and report
that low-volatility strategies consistently outperformed passive
benchmarks in all subperiods except for the second half of the 1990s.
This suggests that during the second half of the 1990s the
low-volatility anomaly was replaced by the high-volatility anomaly,
where high-volatility stocks showed better risk-adjusted performance
than low-volatility stocks. Our result for the decade of the 1990s is
closely related to the findings reported by Hsu and Li [2013]. During
this period, a high unexpected volatility predicted high future excess
returns, where during the other periods the relation was quite the
opposite.
When it comes to the relation between unexpected. volatility and
future volatility, our results suggest that this relation is positive
and highly statistically significant during the overall sample and each
of the subsamples. That is, this relationship is very robust with
respect to the sign of the relationship. Our results also suggest that,
judging by the values of [R.sup.2]-statistics, the unexpected volatility
can explain up to 50% variation in the future volatility.
PERFORMANCE OF DYNAMIC ASSET ALLOCATION STRATEGIES
The results reported in the previous section suggest that at the
aggregate stock market level the unexpected volatility is able to
predict both the future excess return and volatility. Specifically, the
unexpected volatility is negatively related to expected future returns
and positively related to expected future volatility. In this section,
we explore the usefulness of this predictability for dynamic asset
allocation between stocks and the risk-free asset.
The idea is to reduce exposure to stocks when unexpected volatility
increases, and to raise that exposure when unexpected volatility
decreases. The hypothetical advantage of such a strategy over the
passive counterpart comes from two effects: a reduction in volatility
and an increase in excess returns. Both these effects contribute to a
better risk--return trade-off of a dynamic strategy. Even though the
negative relationship between. the future excess return and unexpected
volatility is not especially robust, nevertheless a reduction in
volatility alone can improve the risk--return trade-off of an active
strategy.
Denoting by [a.sub.t] the weight of stocks in the active portfolio
(this weight depends on the value of unexpected volatility), the return
on the active portfolio of stocks and the risk-free asset is given by
[r.sub.t.sup.active] = [a.sub.t][r.sub.l] + (1 -
[a.sub.t])[r.sub.f,l]
We consider two different long-only dynamic asset allocation
strategies based on unexpected volatility. Long-only means that we
impose the borrowing and short-selling constraints that result in the
following restriction on the weight of stocks in the active portfolio: 0
[less than or equal to] [a.sub.t] [less than or equal to] 1.
Unexpected Volatility Responsive Strategy
In the first strategy, the weight of stocks in the active portfolio
is changed gradually between 0 and 1, depending on the value of
unexpected volatility. In order to ensure tha.t the weight of stocks
always lies between the two limits, we compute the weight in the
following manner
[a.sub.t+1] = N([[sigma].sub.t]" -
[E.sub.t][[[sigma].sub.t]"]/[Std.sub.t][[sigma].sub.t]") (5)
where [E.sub.t][[sigma]"] and [Std.sub.t][[sigma]"] are
the mean and standard deviation ofunexpected volatility up to time t,
and N(*) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. That
is, at the end of month t we compute the z-score of
[[sigma].sub.t]" and the standard normal cumulative distribution
function translates the z-score into a percentile value between 0 and 1.
As a result, if the value of unexpected volatility equals its
historical mean, the weight of stocks equals 50%. An increase of, for
example, one standard deviation in the value of unexpected volatility
above its mean leads to a decrease in the weight of stocks in the active
portfolio to 16%. By Contrast, a decrease of one standard deviation in
the value of unexpected volatility below its mean leads to an increase
in the weight of stocks to 84%.
Both the mean and standard deviation of unexpected volatility in
(5) is computed using the data series beginning from January 1950. Since
the first forecasted value for the volatility of stock returns refers to
December 1969, over the period January 1950 to November 1969 the fitted
volatility (instead of forecasted volatility) from the GARCH(1,1) model
is used in the computation of unexpected volatility.
A natural passive benchmark for our active strategy is a fixed
50/50 allocation between stocks and cash. As an additional benchmark
(this time active, not passive) we consider a popular dynamic asset
allocation strategy with volatility target mechanism (see, for example,
Collie et al. [2011], Butler and Philbrick [2012], and Albeverio et al.
[2013]). This strategy is also a natural benchmark for our active
strategy, since the principle that underpins volatility-target asset
allocation is virtually the same: to reduce exposure to stocks when
volatility is high and to increase that exposure when volatility is low.
A typical volatility-target strategy uses the trailing historical
volatility, computed over periods that range from one day to one year,
as a forecast for the future volatility. In addition, in a typical
volatility-target strategy the weight of stocks is computed using
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [[sigma].sup.carget] is the target volatility,
[[^.[sigma]].sub.t+1|t] is the forecasted volatility for month t + 1,
and [a.sup.max] is the maximum allowable exposure to stocks (for
example, Albeverio et al. [2013] use a[a.sup.max] = 200%). Since our
active strategy is a long-only strategy, instead of a volatility-target
strategy we implement a volatility-responsive strategy that performs
similarly to a volatility-target strategy.
In a volatility-responsive strategy the weight of stocks is
computed in a similar manner to (5), specifically
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [E.sub.t][[sigma]] and [Std.sub.t][[sigma]] are the mean and
standard deviation of stock return volatility up to time t, and
[[sigma].sub.t] is the historical volatility over month t. That is, in
this strategy the historical volatility in month t is used A as a
predictor of volatility in month t + 1: [[^.[sigma]].sub.t+1|t] =
[[sigma].sub.t]. As a matter of fact, we varied the length of the
trailing period (over which the historical volatility is computed) and
our experiments showed that the use of one-month a target Ill
historical volatility produced the best performance of the
volatility-responsive strategy.
To measure the performance ot alternative strategies, we use the
following five measures: (1) the Sharpe ratio; (2) the alpha of the
standard one-factor market model (CAPM); (3) the alpha of the
Fama--French three-factor model (FF); (4) the alpha of the
Fama--French--Carhart four-factor model (FFC); and (5) growth of initial
investment of $100 produced by each of the alternative strategies. We
test the null hypothesis that the Sharpe ratio of an alternative
strategy equals the Sharpe ratio of the market portfolio. For this
purpose we apply the Jobson and Korkie [1981] test with the Memmel
[2003] correction. Specifically, given two portfolios, 1 and 2, with
[SR.sub.1], [SR.sub.2], [rho] as their estimated Sharpe ratios and
correlation coefficient over a sample of size T, the test of the null
hypothesis: [H.sub.0] : [SR.sub.1]-[SR.sub.2]= 0 is obtained via the
test statistic
z = [SR.sub.1] - [SR.sub.2]/[square root of (1/T[2(1-[[rho].sup.2])
+ 1/2([SR.sub.1.sup.2] +
[SR.sub.2.sup.2]-2[SR.sub.1][SR.sub.2][[rho].sup.2])]
which is asymptotically distributed as a standard normal. Also for
each alpha we report the P-value of testing the null hypothesis that
alpha is equal to zero..
To check the robustness of our findings, we measure the
performances of alternative strategies not only during our total period
from 1970 to 2012, but in each half of this period (1970-1990 and
1991-2012) as well. Exhibit 3 reports the descriptive statistics and
performance measures of the three alternative strategies simulated using
the returns on the S&P 500 and DJIA indexes. Exhibit 4 shows the
growth of $100 (log scale) invested in each of the three alternative
strategies.
EXHIBIT 3
Descriptive Statistics and Performance Measures of Three
Alternative Strategies; Means and Standard Deviations Are
Annualized and Given as Percentages
Passive Denotes die Passive 50/50 Portfolio of Stocks and Cash.
HistVol Denotes the Volatility-Responsive Active Strategy.
UnexVol Denotes the Unexpected-Volatility-Responsive Strategy.
The Sharpe Ratios are Annualized; The P-values of Testing the
Null Hypothesis of their Equality to the Sharpe Ratio of the
Market Portfolio are Reported in Brackets. The alpha Values
are Annualized and Given as Percentages; The Corresponding
P-values are Reported in Brackets. The bold Text Indicates
Values that are Statistically Significant at the 5% Level.
Standard and Poor's 500
Statistics Passive HistVol UnexVol
Panel A: Period 1970-2012
Mean returns 8.05 7.60 9.00
Standard 7.79 5.38 6.51
deviation
Skewness -0.43 0.26 0.53
Sharpe ratio 0.36 0.43 0.87
(0.95) (0.48) (0.04)
CAPM Alpha 0.04 0.93 1.94
(0.81) (0.10) (0.00)
FF Alpha 0.05 0.92 1.72
(0.65) (0.10) (0.01)
FFC Alpha 0.14 0.44 1.40
(0.17) (0.43) (0.03)
Growth of $100 1,674 2,425 4,297
Panel R: Period 1970-1990
Mean returns 9.53 8.88 10.97
Standard 8.13 5.88 7.48
deviation
Skewness -0.29 0.39 0.58
Sharpe ratio 0.24 0.22 0.45
(0.59) (1.00) (0.08)
CAPM Alpha 0.15 0.30 2.03
(0.54) (0.71) (0.03)
FF Alpha 0.14 0.06 1.38
(0.38) (0.94) (0.15)
FFC Alpha 0.21 -0.19 1.50
(0.20) (0.82) (0.13)
Growth of $100 587 619 936
Panel C: Period 1991-2012
Mean returns 6.46 6.25 6.98
Standard 7.47 4.85 5.40
deviation
Skewness -0.63 -0.08 0.04
Sharpe ratio 0.45 0.66 0.72
(0.66) (0.27) (0.12)
CAPM Alpha -0.07 1.63 2.06
(0.80) (0.03) (0.01)
FF Alpha -0.00 1.72 2.06
(0.98) (0.02) (0.01)
FFC Alpha 0.10 1.24 1.72
(0.43) (0.10) (0.03)
Growth of $100 281 384 448
Dow Jones Industrial Average
Statistics Passive Hist UnexVol
Vol
Panel A: Period 1970-2012
Mean returns 8.29 7.88 8.94
Standard 7.68 5.64 6.65
deviation
Skewness -0.46 0.41 0.49
Sharpe ratio 0.39 0.46 0.55
(0.51) (0.37) (0.08)
CAPM Alpha 0.48 1.22 1.94
(0.27) (0.05) (0.01)
FF Alpha 0.07 1.17 1.72
(0.86) (0.06) (0.01)
FFC Alpha 0.27 0.77 1.32
(0.48) (0.22) (0.06)
Growth of $100 1,764 2,716 4,159
Panel R: Period 1970-1990
Mean returns 9.57 9.12 10.57
Standard 8.07 5.81 7.29
deviation
Skewness -0.39 0.70 0.66
Sharpe ratio 0.25 0.27 0.41
(0.74) (0.79) (0.21)
CAPM Alpha 0.29 0.60 1.75
(0.62) (0.49) (0.09)
FF Alpha -0.31 0.35 1.16
(0.56) (0.69) (0.26)
FFC Alpha -0.17 0.09 0.87
(0.77) (0.92) (0.41)
Growth of $100 590 650 863
Panel C: Period 1991-2012
Mean returns 6.90 6.61 7.25
Standard 7.31 5.48 5.98
deviation
Skewness -0.59 0.06 0.06
Sharpe ratio 0.52 0.65 0.70
(0.54) (0.32) (0.18)
CAPM Alpha 0.70 1.87 2.25
(0.28) (0.04) (0.02)
FF Alpha 0.53 1.91 2.20
(0.31) (0.03) (0.02)
FFC Alpha 0.76 1.52 1.88
(0.15) (0.09) (0.05)
Growth of $100 295 413 472
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The results for the two stock indexes are virtually similar, so we
discuss the results for the S&P 500 index only. The evidence
presented in Exhibit 3 suggests that the
unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy outperforms both the passive
strategy and (historical) volatility-responsive strategy, both over the
total sample and in each half of the total sample. As compared to the
50/50 passive strategy, the unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy
has higher mean returns and lower standard deviation.
While the skewness of the returns to the 50/50 passive strategy is
negative, the skewness of the returns to the
unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy is positive. Thus, the
unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy has both lower total risk and
lower downside risk compared to the passive benchmark. In addition, the
unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy has not only substantially
higher Sharpe ratio and long-term growth of wealth than the passive
benchmark, but also delivers large and statistically significant alphas
in the CAPM, FF, and FFC models (over the total sample and the second
half of the sample). Over the total sample, the Sharpe ratio of the
unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy is statistically significantly
higher than the Sharpe ratio of the market portfolio.
It is worth noting that the volatility-responsive strategy, which
serves as an active benchmark, has virtually no advantage over the
passive buy-and-hold strategy over the first half of the sample. It
could be argued, therefore, that the advantage of the
volatility-responsive strategy over the passive buy-and-hold strategy
appeared mainly over the decade of 2000s. In contrast, the
unexpected-volatility-responsive strategy delivered consistent and
stable outperformance when compared to the passive buy-and-hold
strategy, in all decades in the sample but the 1990s.
Unexpected Volatility Switching Strategy
The second active strategy is the switching strategy. Specifically,
this strategy prescribes investing either all in stocks or all in cash,
depending on whether the unexpected volatility is below or above its
historical average. In particular, the weight of stocks for month t + 1
is determined according to the following rule
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [E.sub.i][[sigma].sup.11] is the historical average of the
unexpected volatility up to time t. Since the mean value of unexpected
volatility is virtually zero, this strategy roughly prescribes investing
all in stocks or all in cash, depending on the sign of unexpected
volatility. For example, if the unexpected volatility is negative, all
should be invested in stocks.
In essence, the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy closely
resembles a market-timing strategy. Hence, besides a passive
buy-and-hold strategy, a market-timing strategy can serve as an
additional benchmark for the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy.
The most popular market-timing strategy is based on using the 10-month
simple moving average rule (SMA10), which prescribes buying stocks
(moving to cash) when the stock price is above (below) the 10-month
simple moving average (see Brock et al. [1992]; Siegel [2002, Chapter
171; Faber [2007]; Gwilym et al. [2010]; and Kilgallen [2012], among
others). More formally, let ([P.sub.1] [P.sub.2], ... , [P.sub.T]) be
the observations of the monthly closing prices of a stock price index. A
10-month simple moving average at month-end t is computed as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The weight .of stocks for month t + 1 is determined according to
the following rule.:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
We use the 75/25 portfolio of stocks and cash as the passive
buy-and-hold benchmark in this case, because over the total sample this
passive portfolio has virtually the same risk (as measured by the
standard deviation) as the active market timing strategy based on the
SMA10 rule.
Exhibit 5 reports the descriptive statistics and performance
measures of the three alternative strategies simulated using the returns
on the S&P 500 and DJIA indexes. Exhibit 6 shows the growth of $100
(log scale) invested in each of the three alternative strategies. The
evidence presented in Exhibit 5 suggests that, over the total sample,
the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy outperforms both the
passive strategy and the SMA1.0 strategy. This is valid for both the
S&P 500 and DJIA stock market indexes. Yet the degree of
outperformance varies over each half of the sample and for each stock
market index. 0 if P, SMA, (10)
EXHIBIT 5
Descriptive Statistics and Performance Measures of Three Alternative
Strategies; Means and Standard Deviations Are Annualized and Given
as Percentages
Passive denotes the passive 75/23 portfolio of stocks and cash.
SIVIA10 denotes the market timing strategy that uses the 10-month
simple moving average strategy. Unexvol denotes the unexpected-
volatility-switching strategy. The sharpe ratios are annualized;
the P-values of testing the null hypothesis of their equality to
the sharpe ratio of the market portfolio are reported in brackets.
The alpha values are annualized and given as percentages: the
corresponding P-values are reported in brackets. The bold text
indicates values that are statistically significant at the 5% level.
Standard and Poor's 500 Dow Jones Industrial Average
Statistics Passive SMAlu UnexVol Passive SMA10 UnexVol
Panel A: Period 1970-2012
Mean 9.44 10.74 10.64 9.80 9.92 10.41
returns
Standard 11,67 11.59 10.00 11.50 11.89 9.70
deviation
Skewness -0.43 -0.69 0.46 -0.46 -0.68 0.72
Number - 58 145 - 68 134
ol'trades
Sharpe 0.36 0.47 0.54 0.39 0.39 0.53
ratio
(0.95) (0.30) (0.17) (0.51) (0.77) (0.23)
CAPM Alpha 0.07 2.42 3.12 0.72 1.70 3.19
(0.81) (0.05) (0.01) (0.27) (0.20) (0.01)
FF Alpha 0.07 2.32 2.76 0.10 1.61 2.87
(0.65) (0.06) (0.02) (0.86) (0.22) (0.02)
FFC Alpha 0.21 0.61 2.34 0.41 0.37 2.08
(0.17) (0.61) (0.06) (0.48) (0.78) (0.10)
Growth of 3,084 7,364 7,656 3,477 5,126 7,029
SI 00
Panel B: Period 1970-1990
Mean 10.51 10.94 13.23 10.58 11.40 11.25
returns
Standard 12.22 12.74 11,36 12.13 13.02 10.87
deviation
Skewness -0.29 -0.82 0.66 -0.38 -0.82 0.89
Number of - 33 76 - 27 75
trades
Sharpc 0,24 0.26 0.50 0.25 0.29 0.34
raiio
(0.59) (0.78) (0.11) (0.74) (0.66) (0.55)
CAPM Alpha 0.22 1.16 3.92 0.43 1.68 2.22
(0,54) (0.51) (0.03) (0.62) (0.39) (0.24)
FF Alpha 0.21 0.76 3.37 -0.47 0.92 1.58
(0.38) (0.67) (0.07) (0.56) (0.64) (0.41)
FFC Alpha 0.31 -1.92 3.20 -0.25 -1.35 0.70
(0.20) (0.28) (0.10) (0.77) (0.50) (0.72)
Growth of 708 830 1,391 716 906 932
S100
Panel C: Period 1991-2012
Mean 8.14 10.53 8.16 8.80 8.50 9.60
returns
Standard 11.18 10.37 8.44 10.93 10.68 8.42
deviation
Skewness -0.62 -0.45 -0.25 -0.58 -0.47 0.27
Number of - 25 68 41 59
trades
Sharpe 0.45 0.72 0.60 0.52 0.51 0.77
ratio
(0.66) (0.15) (0.52) (0.54) (0.83) (0.16)
CAPM Alpha -0.10 4.13 2.85 1.05 2.22 4.49
(0.80) (0.01) (0.06) (0.28) (0.21) (0.00)
FF Alpha -0.00 4.27 2.47 0.80 2.64 4.20
(0.98) (0.01) (0.11) (0.31) (0.13) (0.01)
FFC Alpha 0.16 3.09 2.21 1.14 1.95 3.67
(0.43) (0.05) (0.15) (0.15) (0.27) (0.02)
Growth of 419 893 554 468 569 759
$100
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
First, we consider the performance of the active strategies when
the underlying passive benchmark is the S&P 500 index. In this case,
over the first half of the sample the performance of the SMA10 strategy
is similar to the performance of the passive benchmark, while the
unexpected-volatility-switching strategy produces a Sharpe ratio that is
about 10:0% higher than the Sharpe ratio of either the passive or SMA10
strategy. At the same time, all the alphas are positive and
statistically significant at either the 5% or 10% level. In contrast,
over the second half of the sample the unexpected-volatility-switching
strategy performs better than the passive strategy, yet the SMA10 shows
an even better performance.
The situation is different when the underlying passive benchmark is
the DJIA index. In this case, over the first half of the sample the
performance of the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy is only
marginally better than the performance of the SMA10 strategy, which, in
turn, performs only slightly better than the passive strategy. Over the
second half of the sample, on the other hand, the
unexpected-volatility-switching strategy significantly outperforms the
passive benchmark, whereas the performance of the SM Al0 strategy is
virtually the same as the performance of the passive benchmark.
All in all, while the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy
demonstrates consistent long-term outperformance with respect to the
passive benchmark, the SMA10 strategy produces clear evidence of
outperformance only during the decade of the 20ons and when the passive
benchmark is the S&P 500 index. As a matter of fact, over the past
50+ years the DJIA index is notorious for being practically impossible
to beat using popular market-timing strategies with moving average and
time-series momentum rules (see Zaka-mulin [2013]). In contrast, the
unexpected-volatility-switching strategy works even when the DJIA is
used as the passive benchmark.
Also observe that whereas the returns of the SMA10 are negatively
skewed, the returns of the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy are
most often positively skewed. This means that the return distribution of
the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy has a fat right tail
(higher variation on gains), while the return distribution of the SMA10
has a fat left tail (higher variation on losses). Thus, the return
distribution of the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy most often
has lower downside risk than the return distribution of the SMA10
strategy. It should be noted, however, that the number of trades in the
unexpected-volatility-switching strategy is usually more than double the
number of trades in the SMA10 strategy. That is, the implementation of
the unexpected-volatility-switching strategy requires more frequent
trading and, as a result, incurs more transaction costs.
CONCLUSION
Our research shows that there is usually a negative relationship
between unexpected volatility and future excess returns. That is., most
often increasing unexpected volatility predicts decreasing excess return
on the market in the near term. In addition, our research demonstrates
that there is a strong positive relationship between unexpected
volatility and future volatility. Specifically, increasing unexpected
volatility predicts increasing volatility in the future. These results
hold for both the S&P 500 and IDJIA stock market indexes.
The uncovered relationships between unexpected volatility and
future excess returns and volatility allow the use of unexpected
volatility in an active asset allocation strategy. We test two dynamic
asset allocation strategies based on unexpected volatility and find that
both of them deliver a substantial improvement in risk-adjusted
performance as compared to traditional buy-and-hold strategies. We
demonstrate that active strategies based on unexpected volatility
outperform the popular active strategy with volatility target mechanism
and have some edge over the popular market timing strategy with SMA10
rule.
Using the period from 1970 to 2012, we find that both volatility
targeting and market-timing strategies outperform their passive
counterparts, mainly over the decade of the 2000s. In contrast, active
strategies based on unexpected volatility outperformed the passive
counterparts not only over the 2000s, but over the 1970s and the 1980s
as well.
Last but not least, while market-timing strategies with moving
average and momentum rules do not work when the underlying passive
benchmark is the DjIA index, we find that unexpected volatility can be
used as a timing indicator for the DJIA index as well.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The author is grateful to Hossein Kazemi (the editor), Steen
Koekebakker, and Steve LeCompte for their insightful comments. The usual
disclaimer applies.
REFERENCES
Albeverio, S, V. Steblovskaya, and K. Wallbaum. "Investment
Instruments with Volatility Target Mechanism." Quantitative
Finance, Vol. 13, No. 10 (2013), pp. 1519-1528.
Ang, A., R.J. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang. "The
Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns." Journal of
Finance, Vol. 61, No. 1 (2006), pp. 259-299.
Banerjee, P.S., J.S. Doran, and D.R. Peterson.. "Implied
Volatility and Future Portfolio Returns." Journal of Banking and
Vinance, Vol. 31, No. 10 (2007), pp. 3183-3199.
Blitz, D.C. and P. van Vliet. "The Volatility Effect."
The Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 34, No. 1 (2007), pp. 102-111
Bollerslev, T. "Generalized Au toregressive Conditional
Het-eroskedasticity." Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 31, No. 3
(1986), pp. 307-327.
Brock, W., J. Lakonishok, and B. LeBaron. "Simple Technical
Trading Rules and the Stochastic Properties of Stock Returns."
Journal of Finance, Vol. 47, No. 5 (1992), pp. 1731.1764.
Brownlees, C., R. Engle, and B. Kelly. "A Practical Guide to
Volatility Forecasting Through Calm and Storm." Journal of Risk,
Vol. 14, No. 2 (2012), pp. 3-22.
Butler, A., and M. Philbrick. "Volatility Management for
Better Absolute .and Risk-Adjusted Performance." White paper,
Macquarie Private Wealth Inc., 2012.
Chua, C.T., J. Gob, and Z. Zhang. "Expected Volatility,
Unexpected Volatility, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns."
Journal of Financial Research, Vol. 33, No. 2 (2010), pp. 103-123.
Collie, R., M. Sylvanus, and M. Thomas. "Volatility-Responsive
Asset Allocation." White paper, Russell Investments, 2011.
Copeland, M.M., and T.E. Copeland. "Market Timing: Style and
Size Rotation Using the VIX." Financial Analysis Journal, Vol. 55,
No. 2 (1999), pp. 73-81.
Engle, R. "GARCH 101: The Use of ARCH/GARCH Models in Applied
Econometrics." Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 15, No. 4
(2001), pp. 157-168,
Faber, M.T. "A Quantitative Approach to Tactical Asset
Allocation." Journal of Wealth Management, Vol. 9, No. 4 (2007),
pp. 69-79.
Figlewski, S. "Forecastin.g Volatility." Financial
Markets, Institutions and Instrumeuts, Vol. 6, No. 1 (1997), pp. 1-88.
French, K.R., G. Schwert, and R.F. Stambaugh. "Expected Stock
Returns and Volatility." Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 19,
No. 1 (1987), pp. 3-29.
Giot, P. "Relationships Between Implied Volatility Indexes and
Stock Index Returns." The Journal of Portfolio Management, Vol. 31,
No. 3 (2005), pp. 92-100.
Glosten, L.R., R. Jagannathan, and D.E. Runkle. "On the
Relation Between the Expected Value and the Volatility of the Nominal
Excess Return on Stocks." Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 5
(1993), pp. 1779-1801.
Gwilym, 0., A. Clare, J. Seaton, and S. Thomas. "Price and
Momentum as Robust Tactical Approaches to Global Equity Investing."
Journal of Investing, Vol. 19, No. 3 (2010), pp. 80-91.
Hsu, J., and F. Li. "Low-Volatility Investing." Journal
of Index Investing, Vol. 4, No. 2 (2013), pp. 67-72.
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman. "Returns to Buying Winners and
Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency." Journal
of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 1(1993), pp. 65-91.
Jobson, J.D., and B.M. Korkie. "Performance Hypothesis Testing with the Sharpe and Treynor Measures." Journal of Finance, Vol. 36,
No. 4 (1981), pp. 889-908.
Kilgallen, T. "Testing the Simple Moving Average Across
Commodities, Global Stock Indices, and Currencies." The Journal of
Wealth Management, Vol. 15, No. 1 (2012), pp. 82-100.
Memmel, C. "Performance Hypothesis Testing with the Sharpe
Ratio." Finance Letters, 1 (2003), pp, 21-23.
Merton, R.C. "On Estimating the Expected Return .on the
Market: An Exploratory Investigation.." Journal of Financial
Economics, Vol. 8, No. 4 (1980), pp. 323-361.
Nelson, D.B. "Conditional Heteroske.dasticity in Asset
Returns: A New Approach." Econo-metrica, Vol. 59, No. 2 (1991), pp.
347-370.
Siegel, J. Stocks for the Long Run.. 3rd ed. McGraw-Hill Companies,
2002.
ENDNOTES
(1.) http://finance.yahoo.corn/
(2.) http://www.econ.yale.edu/--shiller/data.htm
(3.) http://www.djaverages.com
(4.) http://online.barrons.com
(5.) http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pagesifaculty/ken.french/data.library.html
(6.) Note that the unexpected volatility appearing in the two
predictive regressions is a function of realized volatility at time t-1
and expected volatility of time t-1 that was calculated at time t-2.
VALERIY ZAKAMULIN is a professor of finance, School of Business and
Law at the University of Agder, Kristiansand, Norway.
valeri.zakamouline@uia.no