How does racial diversity raise income inequality?
Meisenberg, Gerhard
Interest in the determinants of income inequality, most commonly
measured as the Gini index, has been sparked by a trend towards greater
inequality in most of the advanced economies since about 1970 (Alderson
and Nielsen, 2002; Atkinson, 2004). The reasons for this trend are still
unknown. One possibility is that rising income inequality might be
related to the rising cultural or racial heterogeneity of many national
populations.
A recent cross-sectional study did indeed point to population
diversity as a determinant of the Gini index. Using novel measures of
ethnic, religious and racial diversity, it found that high racial
diversity, but not high ethnic or religious diversity, is a robust
predictor of a high Gini index (Meisenberg, 2007). The effect is
approximately linear at low-to-medium levels of racial diversity, but
there is no significant relationship in comparisons of countries at high
to very high levels of racial diversity. For example, within the
category "Latin America + Caribbean", which has the worldwide
highest levels of racial diversity (Table 1), the correlation of racial
diversity with the Gini index is slightly and non-significantly negative
(r = -.247 when racial distances are defined by genetic distances, N =
23).
The empiric relationship between racial diversity and income
inequality is no great surprise. Of the major world regions, racially
diverse Latin America has the highest level of income inequality, and
income inequality is higher in the United States than in the more
homogeneous European and East Asian countries. If racial diversity
favors income inequality, and if advanced postindustrial nations are
becoming more diverse in the wake of replacement migration (Coleman,
2002), we can predict a continuing trend towards greater income
inequality. But which are the causal paths that lead from racial
diversity to income inequality? Two alternative but not mutually
exclusive hypotheses are tested in the following study.
The first hypothesis proposes that racial diversity raises the Gini
index because different racial groups tend to differ in their
intellectual abilities and achievements even when they live in the same
country (Lynn, 2006). Such differences are not unique to racial groups,
but are commonly observed between cultural, national, linguistic and
religious groups of the same racial background living in the same
country (Lynn & Longley, 2006; Verster & Prinsloo, 1988).
Nevertheless, ability differences between racial groups tend to be
larger and more persistent than those between cultural, linguistic,
religious and national groups. If races differ in intellectual ability,
then racial diversity is expected to widen the range of ability levels
in the country. Mental ability measured in childhood or adolescence
predicts adult earnings at the level of individuals (Deary et al., 2005;
Irwing & Lynn, 2006; Murray, 2002). Therefore we can expect that
greater ability differences translate into greater income differences.
A second hypothesis proposes that racial diversity raises the Gini
index because, ultimately as a result of biological evolution, people
are most altruistically inclined toward those who are similar to
themselves (Meisenberg, 2007b; Rushton, 1989; Rushton and Bons, 2005).
This leads to a more individualistic and less altruistic social ethos in
countries with a highly diverse population. Social solidarity is
restricted to groups that are defined on racial, ethnic, religious or
local lines, rather than extending society-wide; economic exploitation
is more extreme; there is less concern for marginalized groups and
individuals; and there is less redistribution of wealth from the rich to
the poor. In the following, these two hypotheses are examined in turn.
General Methods
The Gini index
The primary data source is the World Income Inequality Database
(WIID2a) of the United Nations University, available at
www.wider.unu.edu/wiid/wiid.htm. There are more than 100 results listed
for some countries, together with the type of data and an estimate for
the quality of each study. Only data from 1990 and later were used
except in two cases where data from the 1980s were used for lack of more
recent results. Only data that were based on disposable income, net
income or consumption were included. Data based on gross income were not
used. For each country an average was formed from the results of the
highest-quality data in these categories. Gini indices for 123 countries
could be computed with this procedure, and Ginis for 10 additional
countries were extrapolated from other sources as described in
Meisenberg (2007). A listing of the resulting 133 Ginis can be found in
Meisenberg (2007). Table 1 shows the Gini index together with the
average (country-level) racial-diversity scores for different world
regions.
Racial diversity measures
The construction of the racial-diversity indices is described in
Meisenberg (2007), along with a listing of country-level racial
diversity scores for 198 countries and territories. Racial distances
were weighted either by genetic distance according to Cavalli-Sforza and
Feldman (2003), or by IQ difference according to Lynn (2006). These two
measures are highly correlated (r = .969). To maximize the main effects,
logarithmic transformations were used for analyses spanning the entire
range of countries with available Gini index; and untransformed racial
diversity scores for analyses of country samples that include few
countries with very high racial diversity. Racial diversity weighted by
genes or by IQ were used alternatively in regression models.
Other variables
The following country-level data were used for correlational
studies:
1. lgGDP is the logarithm of gross domestic product adjusted for
purchasing power, averaged for the years 1990-2005. Data are from the
World Development Indicators of the World Bank, which can be purchased
at http://econ.worldbank.org. The logarithmic transformation was used
because of the highly skewed nature of GDP worldwide, which approximates
to a normal distribution in the logarithmic form.
2. Education was calculated by averaging the standardized scores of
4 measures: (1) Average years of schooling of adults over the age of 25
from the Barro-Lee dataset, averaged for the years 19902000. The data
are available at: http://www.cid.harvard.edu/ciddata/Appendix%20Data%20Table s.xls. (2) The school life expectancy (1999-2003 average) from
UNESCO at: http://stats.uis.unesco.org/TableViewer/tableView.aspx. (3)
The combined enrolment ratio for primary, secondary and tertiary schools
in 2002, from the 2005 Human Development Report of the United Nations
(http://hdr.undp.org/reports/global/2005). (4) The arcsine-transformed
averages of the adult literacy rates in 1990 and 2002, from the 2005
Human Development Report.
3. IQ is the average IQ in the country according to Lynn &
Vanhanen (2006) and Lynn (2006). Measured scores are available for 114
countries. Lynn & Vanhanen (2006) also provide estimates for the IQs
of 79 additional countries based on the IQs of neighboring countries
with similar population and culture. The estimates were included in the
present study, yielding a total of 193 countries with IQ scores.
4. Corruption was averaged from the reverse of Transparency
International's Corruption Perception Index, available at
http://www.transparency.org (average for the years 1999-2005), and the
corruption domain of the Heritage Foundation's 2006 Index of
Economic Freedom (http://www.heritage.org/research/)
5. Economic Freedom was averaged from two sources: (1) Areas 2-5 of
the Fraser Institute's economic freedom index (Gwartney, Lawson et
al., 2007) were averaged over the years 1980-2005. Area 1 was excluded
because it is distinct from areas 2-5 both conceptually and factorially
(r = -.015). (2) 9 of the 10 areas of the Heritage Foundation's
2006 Index of Economic Freedom (http://www.heritage.org/research/) were
subjected to principal components analysis with 2-factor varimax
rotation. Corruption was excluded because it was considered conceptually
different from economic freedom. The first principal component of this
factor rotation correlated with areas 2-5 of the Gwartney & Lawson
index at r = .891. These two variables were averaged into one combined
economic freedom index, which correlated with corruption at r = -.829.
To avoid excessive collinearity, corruption and economic freedom were
used alternatively in regression models. Only the variable producing the
better fit was retained.
6. Freedom/Democracy is the average of two measures: Political
Freedom, defined as the scores of political freedom (political rights +
civil liberties) from Freedom House at
http://www.freedomhouse.org/research/freeworld, average 19882005; and
Democracy, defined as Vanhanen's democracy index, average
1990-2004, from the Finnish Social Science Data Archive at
http://www.fsd.uta.fi/english/data/catalogue/FSD1289/. These two highly
correlated measures (r = .847, N = 179 countries), and the average of
the two, were used alternatively in regression models.
7. The square root of the country's land surface was
determined from data in the World Fact Book of the CIA:
www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook. The logarithm of the population
density in 1997 was formed from data in the World Development Indicators
of the World Bank, available from http://econ.worldbank.org.
Results
Relationship between Gini index and racial diversity
Table 2 shows that the Gini index is negatively related to many
development indicators. The strongest relationship is with IQ, but also
high lgGDP, education, democracy and economic freedom are associated
with a low Gini index while high corruption is related to a high Gini
index. As expected, many of the correlations between these predictors
are quite high. The racial diversity measures have substantial positive
correlations with the Gini index although their correlations with most
of the other variables are insignificant.
The independent effects of the predictors were investigated in
regression models. Initial models contained IQ, education, the logarithm
of GDP (lgGDP), corruption, the average of political freedom and
democracy, the logarithm of racial diversity, a categorical measure of
communist history, the square root of the country's surface area,
and the logarithm of its population density. In order to capture
non-linear effects, both the centered linear terms and quadratic terms
were included in the models.
Economic freedom was allowed to substitute for corruption when this
improved the fit of the model, political freedom or democracy were
allowed to substitute for their average, and a categorical measure for
"ex-communist" (for the countries of eastern Europe and the
former Soviet Union) was allowed to substitute for "communist
history." Models were started with the average of "racial
diversity by genes" and "racial diversity by IQ," and one
of these two variables was allowed to substitute for the average if this
improved the fit of the model. Models were developed to maximize the
adjusted R2, and non-predictors were dropped. Table 3 shows the results.
Model 1 shows the prediction of the Gini index in the absence of
racial diversity. The Gini index (measured mainly during the 1990s) is
reduced by high IQ, high GDP, high population density and a history of
communist rule, and raised by high education. IQ and education show
saturation effects at high levels. Countries with extremely high and
extremely low levels of political freedom tend to have a low Gini index.
Model 2 adds interaction effects between the continuously measured
variables in model 1. There is a strong interaction effect between
education and lgGDP. The negative sign of the interaction implies that
the Gini index is lowest in countries in which the average educational
level of the population is congruent with the level of economic
development. Actually, the Gini index is lowest in countries in which
the average educational level is a bit lower than expected for the
country's wealth. High education in a poor country and very low
education in a very rich country both raise the Gini index. This finding
is replicated in models 4 and 6.
Model 3 adds the logarithm of racial diversity to model 1, with a
highly significant effect of racial diversity. Weighting of racial
diversity by IQ produces a marginally better fit than weighting by
genetic distance, but the difference is not nearly significant. Model 4
adds interaction effects to model 3.
Correlational analyses at the country level are subject to spatial
autocorrelation, also known as Galton's problem (Eff, 2004). In
essence, data from different but geographically, culturally and
historically similar countries are not strictly independent of each
other and tend to show similar correlations. This can lead to type 1
errors. To control for spatial autocorrelation, dummy variables for the
major world regions were introduced one at a time to models 3 and 4.
Those showing evidence for effectiveness were then introduced jointly,
and non-predictors were removed. After these manipulations the racial
diversity effect was reduced, especially by the inclusion of Latin
America, but it remained statistically significant. Models 5 and 6 are
equivalent to models 3 and 4, respectively, but limited to the 109
countries outside of Latin America and the Caribbean. The results show
that the worldwide relationship between Gini index and racial diversity
is not merely caused by a coincidence of high Gini index and high racial
diversity in the countries of Latin America and the Caribbean.
Racial diversity and variance in cognitive ability
The spread of mental ability in the national population is measured
as the dispersion of ability levels on standardized mental tests
administered to representative samples of the national population.
The most useful data come from two sets of international
assessments of school achievement: the Third International Mathematics
and Science Study (TIMSS), organized by the International Study Center
of the Lynch School of Education at Boston College; and the Programme
for International Student Assessment (PISA) of the OECD. A recent study
(Lynn et al., 2008) showed that the pooled results of these assessments
correlate at r = .92 with the IQs published by Lynn & Vanhanen
(2006). This shows that at the country level, mental ability tests
("IQ tests") and tests of school achievement measure the same
or nearly the same construct. These measures of intellectual proficiency
have been claimed to be better indicators of "human capital"
than traditional measures of education such as years in school and
educational degrees (Weede, 2004).
TIMSS results for science and mathematics were used from the 1995,
1999 and 2003 assessments. The results of the 1999 assessment are from
Martin et al. (1999) and Mullis et al. (1999), available at
http://isc.bc.edu/timss1999i/math_achievement_report.html and
http://isc.bc.edu/timss1999i/science_achievement_report.html. The
results of the 1995 and 2003 assessments are from exhibits 1.1 and 1.3
in Martin et al. (2004) and Mullis et al. (2004), available at
http://timss.bc.edu/timss2003i/intl_reports.html. These sources contain
the dispersion of scores (5th to 95th percentile) in graphic form.
The 5th and 95th percentile scores of the PISA assessments are
published in numeric form at http://pisacountry.acer.edu.au/ for 2003,
and at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/30/18/39703566.pdf for 2006. The
differences between these scores were calculated for all domains
(mathematics, reading, science and problem solving in 2003; mathematics,
reading and science in 2006).
For all tests of ability or achievement, the dispersion of raw
scores depends on the relationship between the difficulty of the test
items and the performance level of the tested group. For example, the
5%-to-95% performance range of an easy test will be systematically wider
in a low-scoring than a high-scoring group, and the reverse is true for
a difficult test. Therefore the dispersion for each domain in each
assessment was residualized against the mean score, and the residuals
were standardized to a mean of zero and a standard deviation of one. The
correlations between the residuals obtained from different assessments
were small but positive. The correlation between the average dispersion
on all domains of all TIMSS assessments and the average dispersion on
all domains of all PISA assessments was only r = .256, although the
correlations between different assessments within the same program were
substantially higher. This suggests that sampling bias in one or both of
the assessment programs is substantial.
Table 4 shows the correlations of test score variability on each
individual assessment program (vTIMSS and vPISA), and the combined data
from both programs (vTIMSS/PISA), with country-level variables. Overall
the only noteworthy correlations are with racial diversity (especially
when weighted by IQ) in either the untransformed or log-transformed
form, and with the measures of political freedom and democracy.
In order to be a credible mediator of racial diversity effects on
the Gini index, ability dispersion must be predicted by racial diversity
in the presence of other predictors; and ability dispersion must be an
independent predictor of the Gini index in the presence of other
predictors. Table 5 shows the best-fitting regression models for the
prediction of ability dispersion in the two assessments. The procedures
were the same as those used for the models in Table 3. The racial
diversity measures were used either with or without the logarithmic
transformation with the aim of maximizing the main effect.
Table 5 shows that the overall explained variance is modest, and
not all results replicate across the two assessment programs. For
example, effects of the country's size (sqrtArea) and population
density (lgPopDens) are small and inconsistent, and the same is true for
the political indicators of democracy, political freedom and communist
history. This is expected if either the accuracy of the outcome measures
is low or if most of the chosen predictors are genuinely unrelated to
the outcomes. Besides education and corruption, measures of racial
diversity are the only consistent predictors. Racial diversity weighted
by IQ is more predictive than racial diversity weighted by genes, which
is expected if the effect is genuine. Statistical significance levels
for the racial diversity measures are nonetheless moderate: p = .028 for
TIMSS, r = .002 for PISA, and r = .019 for the combined results.
Variance in cognitive ability and income inequality
A greater variance of cognitive ability can mediate the effect of
racial diversity on the Gini index only if greater variance in cognitive
ability leads to a higher Gini index. Table 4 does indeed show a
non-significant trend for a positive association of the Gini index with
ability dispersion. However, Table 2 shows far higher correlations of
the Gini index with several other predictors. Therefore regression
models were examined in which the Gini index was predicted by ability
dispersion along with the other predictors.
Consistent predictors of the Gini index included racial diversity
(positive), lgGDP, and communist history (both negative). However, there
were no significant effects of ability dispersion on the Gini index. In
the PISA assessment (N = 51 countries), the effect of ability dispersion
had a positive sign with p = .282; in TIMSS (N = 46 countries), the
effect had a negative sign with p = .198; and in the combined set (N =
63 countries), it had a positive sign with p = .413. Thus the observed
trends are inconsistent and far from even approaching statistical
significance.
Racial diversity and big government
If a high level of racial diversity reduces social solidarity, and
especially the redistribution of wealth from the rich to the poor, then
we can predict that racially diverse societies have "small"
governments that stay lean and mean by minimizing spending for social
welfare and other redistributive programs. The following analyses
examine whether racial diversity reduces the size of government, and
whether smaller government leads to greater income inequality.
A Big Government variable was formed from two sources: (1) Area 1
of the Gwartney, Lawson et al. (2007) economic freedom index ("Size
of Government") was used directly. (2) The second principal
component of a two-factor varimax rotation of nine of the 10 dimensions
(excluding corruption) of the Heritage Foundation's Index of
Economic Freedom was used. The components loading most strongly on this
principal component are "Fiscal Policy" (low taxes, r = .764),
"Government" (low government expenditures, no state-owned
enterprises, r = .709), and "Labor Freedom" (flexible hours,
no minimum wage, freedom of employers to lay off redundant employees, r
= .561). "Small government" as defined by this factor is also
associated with more corruption (r = .309). This principal component
correlates at r = .605 with area 1 of the Gwartney, Lawson et al. (2007)
index. Before averaging, the two components were standardized and
reversed such that high numbers correspond to "bigger"
government. For those 131 countries for which all relevant variables are
available, correlations of Big Government were r = -.419 with the Gini
index, -.312 with the logarithm of racial diversity by genes, and r =
-.224 with the logarithm of racial diversity by IQ. Big Government is
also positively associated with democracy (r = .405), lgGDP (r = .349),
political freedom (r = .320) and IQ (r = .197), and negatively with
corruption (r = -.429).
The question of whether racial diversity is an independent and
negative predictor of Big Government was explored in regression models
with other plausible predictors. Model 1 in Table 6 shows that racial
diversity reduces the size of the government independent of the other
predictors in the worldwide sample. The size of the government is also
reduced independently by a high level of economic freedom and by high
population density, and increased by excessive economic wealth. Also a
very high level of democratization increases the size of the government,
although a transition from no democracy to some democracy does not have
this effect.
When dummy-coded world regions were added individually to model 1,
Latin America (+ Caribbean) strongly reduced big government while
reducing the racial diversity effect to non-significance (p = .122).
However, when the analysis was limited to the 108 countries outside
Latin America and the Caribbean, the main effect of racial diversity was
again statistically significant (p = .030, model 2 in Fig. 6). The
reason for this result is that within Latin America and the Caribbean
there is no negative but actually a positive relationship between the
logarithm of racial diversity and big government (r = .427, p = .042, N
= 23). Thus the negative relationship between racial diversity and big
government does not apply to comparisons of countries with very high
levels of racial diversity. This is the same pattern that is also
observed for the positive relationship between racial diversity and the
Gini index.
Big government and the Gini index
Table 7 shows three models in which the Gini index is predicted by
Big Government. Model 1 predicts the Gini index with Big Government and
other predictors but without a measure of racial diversity. It resembles
model 1 in Table 3, but shows that Big Government clearly reduces the
Gini index independent of the other predictors. Model 2 includes racial
diversity as an additional predictor. It corresponds to model 3 in Table
3, but with Big Government as additional predictor. Although racial
diversity itself emerges as an independent positive predictor of the
Gini index in this model, it attenuates the effect of Big Government
only to a slight extent. Model 3 includes interaction effects. As in the
models of Table 3, there is a highly significant interaction between
education and lgGDP (but not education and big government). This
interaction does not detract from the independent effects of big
government and racial diversity. The racial-diversity effects in models
2 and 3 are not quite as impressive as those in models 3 and 4 of Table
3, indicating that the Big Government variable does indeed capture some
of the mediating mechanisms between racial diversity and income
inequality.
When dummy-coded world regions were added singly to model 2, Latin
America (+ Caribbean) attenuated the main effect of racial diversity to
borderline non-significance (p = .062) but left the effect of Big
Government intact with p = .001. All other world regions left both the
racial diversity effect at p < .01 and the Big Government effect at p
[less than or equal to] .001. Also in model 3, the addition of Latin
America reduced the racial diversity effect to non-significance (p =
.209) but left the effect of Big Government at p = .002. All other world
regions left the racial diversity effect at p < .05 and the Big
Government effect at p < .005.
lgGDP, which tended to be negatively related to the Gini index in
the models of Table 3, has no effect on the Gini index when Big
Government is one of the predictors. Thus any inequality-reducing effect
of national wealth appears to be mediated by the proportionately greater
government budgets that are typical for wealthy nations. However, the
still intact interaction between education and lgGDP shows that this is
indeed an interaction of education with national wealth, not an
interaction of education with government expenses.
Discussion
Determinants of the Gini index
The regression models of Table 3 give some general insights into
the determinants of income inequality:
1. Rising IQ lowers the Gini index up to an IQ of 90 to 95. Above
this limit, IQ no longer influences the Gini index. A reasonable
explanation is that institutions and procedures of collective bargaining
play a major role in the containment of income inequality, presumably by
reducing the power imbalance between the rich and the poor (Golden and
Londregan, 2006). A certain intelligence is required to create such
institutions and procedures, and to use them for their intended purpose.
2. High education tends to raise the Gini index, presumably because
education enables educated people to acquire wealth at the expense of
those with less education.
3. Education interacts with lgGDP. A well developed educational
system in a poor country is associated with a high Gini index,
presumably because education creates elites that redistribute the
limited national wealth for their own benefit; and countries with low
levels of education but great material wealth usually are poorly
developed but resource-rich countries in which the exploitation of the
country's natural resources enriches a (more or less corrupt)
elite.
4. Both very high and very low levels of political freedom reduce
the Gini index, perhaps because both extremely dictatorial and extremely
democratic societies tend to impose restrictions on the acquisitive
activities of the business elite.
5. Even during the 1990s, when most of the Ginis used in this study
were recorded, a history of communist rule still reduced income
inequality. Although income inequality has been rising fast in many
successor states of the former Soviet Union, most of the ex-communist
countries of Eastern Europe still have fairly low income inequality.
6. The reason for the inequality-reducing effect of high population
density is uncertain. In regression models, a high level of urbanization
fails to reduce the Gini index independent of population density, nor
does it diminish the effect of population density on the Gini index. A
high proportion of agricultural employment raises the Gini index
somewhat, but without substantially reducing the effect of population
density.
7. High racial diversity raises the Gini index. Although racial
diversity weighted by IQ emerged as marginally more predictive than
racial diversity weighted by genetic distance in the models of Tables 3
and 7, the difference is trivial and not nearly significant.
The main limitation of the racial-diversity indices is that they
are based only on the proportions of racial groups from which the
national population was formed after the year 1500. They take no account
of the extent to which these racial groups have merged into a single
gene pool. For example, Paraguay has high racial diversity scores
because the origin of the population is presumed to be 50% European and
50% Amerindian. However, it can be argued that racial diversity in
Paraguay is near-zero because almost everyone is a mestizo. The fact
that many of the countries with the highest diversity of racial origins
(most of them in Latin America and the Caribbean) also have extensive
hybridization between races could be responsible for the observation
that racial diversity no longer predicts small government or a high Gini
index in this group of countries. Besides hybridization, the extent of
race-based privilege and discrimination in the society is a likely
determinant of economic inequalities.
Racial diversity, ability dispersion and income inequality
The "meritocratic" hypothesis proposes that racial
diversity increases the dispersion of mental ability levels in the
population, which in turn raises income inequality through market
forces. The first step of this two-step process finds cautious support
in data from standardized international assessments of student
achievement. In interpreting the results, we must be aware of the
limitations in the TIMSS and PISA assessments. Both assessment programs
include a smallish number of participating countries, most of these
countries have high levels of economic development and low levels of
racial diversity, and the enlistment of a country sample that is
representative not only for the average level but also the variance of
achievement or ability in the country is difficult.
Although the raw correlations reported in Table 4 are weak, the
regression models of Table 5 do show statistically significant effects
of racial diversity. Taken together, the relative congruence of results
from two independently conducted assessment programs argues that the
postulated causal effect of racial diversity on ability dispersion is
genuine.
The translation of ability differences into income differences is
often assumed to be the outcome of market forces, based on the common
observation that higher mental ability leads to higher income in
comparisons between individuals (Deary et al., 2005; Irwing & Lynn,
2006; Murray, 2002). Several authors have proposed that rising income
inequality is caused by a rising demand for complex skills, especially
technical skills (Acemoglu, 2002; Galor and Moav, 2000). However, others
have pointed out that rising income inequality is not driven by
technicians and engineers, whose relative incomes have, if anything,
declined (at least in the United States), but by high-level office
workers (Morris & Western, 1999, p. 635). Thus rising inequality is
not driven by a rising demand for technical skills, but by the rising
skill of corporate management to channel a greater share of their
companies' resources into their own pockets. Whether this
particular skill is closely related to the kind of intellectual ability
measured by IQ tests and school achievement tests is uncertain. The
failure to find independent effects of ability dispersion on income
dispersion suggests it is not. Thus corporate power structures rather
than skill-based market forces appear to be responsible for recent
developments of income inequality. The effect of education in Tables 3
and 7 points to a possible role of educational credentialing systems in
this process, but cognitive ability does not seem to be the decisive
factor.
The failure to find independent effects of ability dispersion on
income inequality might be due to the limitations of data quality.
However, Table 5 shows that data quality is not so poor as to conceal an
effect of racial diversity on ability dispersion. This implies that high
income inequality is not a necessary attribute of
"meritocratic" societies, at least not in comparisons between
the kinds of societies that participate in international school
achievement tests. Functionalist explanations that are based on market
forces and individual differences in achievement are unconvincing.
Conflict theories inspired by Marx or Darwin, which propose that power
imbalances determine the extent of economic inequalities, appear more
fruitful.
Racial diversity, size of government, and income inequality
An alternative explanation for the effect of racial diversity on
the Gini index invokes redistributive policies that are, in turn,
dependent on political values in the society. The inequality-reducing
effect of redistributive policies is well established, at least in
economically advanced societies (Atkinson, 2004). Redistributive
policies express values of distributive justice that are held by the
politically relevant sections of the population. These values vary on
several dimensions, the most important of which appear to be equality,
efficiency, need and merit (Michelbach et al., 2003, p. 524).
Egalitarian motives, in particular, have been demonstrated repeatedly in
laboratory settings (Dawes et al., 2007; Scott et al., 2001).
Distributive justice norms are known to differ between countries. For
example, compared to Americans, Indians give greater weight to need than
to merit (Berman et al., 1985). This might be one reason why the Gini
index is 38.9 in the United States but only 32.3 in India (Meisenberg,
2007).
We do not know what causes distributive justice norms to vary
across countries and time, but racial diversity is one possible
determinant. For example, the movement against federally funded social
welfare programs in the United States during the 1990s was accompanied
by the stereotype of the "black welfare mother." In this case
it is plausible that redistributive policies were cut back or terminated
because the beneficiaries of such policies were perceived as belonging
to a different race. Attitudes to welfare spending in the United States
depend on people's exposure to welfare recipients of their own or a
different race (Luttmer, 2001).
It has been proposed that, as an extension of kin-directed
altruism, people are most altruistically inclined toward those who are
similar to themselves. Empirical evidence has been presented showing
that sympathy and altruism are favored mainly by similarity in traits
with high heritability (Rushton, 1989; Rushton and Bons, 2005). If
genetic similarity is the determining factor, then we must expect that
altruism is reduced specifically toward members of different races but
not necessarily members of different cultural groups. In consequence,
social solidarity and redistributive policies are reduced by racial
diversity but not cultural diversity. Indeed measures of ethnic and
religious diversity from Meisenberg (2007) do not reduce the size of the
government the way racial diversity does, nor do they raise the Gini
index (data not shown). Thus Rushton's theory of genetic similarity
detection is not only a theory of personal preferences, but also a
theory of race prejudice and its societal consequences.
The observation that a measure of "big government" is
negatively related to both racial diversity and the Gini index suggests
that redistributive government policies play a substantial role in the
relationship between racial diversity and income inequality. The second
step of the proposed causal sequence, the reduction of the Gini index by
"big government," is unsurprising, although it contradicts
those who describe the role of the government in the economy as purely
predatory. The first step, which is the reduction of the size of
government in response to high racial diversity, is more interesting. An
effect of racial diversity in reducing social services has been
demonstrated at the community level in the United States (Alesina et
al., 1999), and the present results show that a similar effect also
exists at the country level.
Promising areas for future research include specific institutional
correlates of racial diversity. For example, public expenditures for
health and education benefit, potentially at least, everyone
irrespective of race. Therefore they are unlikely to be reduced by high
racial diversity. However, poverty is more likely to be associated with
race in the public mind, and support for the poor is therefore more
likely to be reduced in racially diverse societies. Also societal traits
that depend on social solidarity, such as collective bargaining and the
unionization of laborers, are predicted to be low in racially diverse
societies. Because political values are the most likely mediators of
these institutional outcomes, survey-derived measures of values and
attitudes should be investigated for racial-diversity effects both at
the country level and the community level. The reported negative
relationship between racial diversity and social participation in
American communities (Alesina and La Ferrara, 2000) points to the
possibility of rather general effects of racial diversity on social
behavior and attitudes.
References
Acemoglu, Daron
(2002). Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal
of Economic Literature 40: 7-72.
Alderson, Arthur S. and F. Nielsen
(2002). Globalization and the great U-turn: Income inequality
trends in 16 OECD countries. American Journal of Sociology 107:
1244-1299.
Alesina, Alberto, R. Baqir and W. Easterly
(1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 114: 1243-1284.
Alesina, Alberto and E. La Ferrara
(2000). Participation in heterogeneous communities. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 115: 847-904.
Atkinson, Anthony B.
(2004). Increased income inequality in OECD countries and the
redistributive impact of the government budget. In: G.A. Cornia (ed):
Inequality, Growth and Poverty in an Era of Liberalization and
Globalization, pp. 221-248. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Berman, John J., V. Murphy-Berman and P. Singh
(1985). Cross-cultural similarities and differences in perceptions
of fairness. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology 16: 55-67.
Cavalli-Sforza, Luigi Luca and M.W. Feldman
(2003). The application of molecular genetic approaches to the
study of human evolution. Nature Genetics Supplement 33: 266-275.
Coleman, David A.
(2002). Replacement migration, or why everyone is going to have to
live in Korea: A fable for our times from the United Nations.
Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London B 357:
583-598.
Dawes, Christopher T., J.H. Fowler, T. Johnson, R. McElreath and O.
Smirnov
(2007). Egalitarian motives in humans. Nature 446: 794-796.
Deary, Ian J., M.D. Taylor, C.L. Hart, V. Wilson, G.D. Smith, D.
Blane and J.M. Starr
(2005). Intergenerational social mobility and mid-life status
attainment: Influences of childhood intelligence, childhood social
factors, and education. Intelligence 33: 455-472.
Eff, E. Anthon
(2004). Spatial and cultural autocorrelation in international
datasets. Department of Economics and Finance Working Paper Series,
Februar 2004. Retrieved February 2006 from:
http://www.mtsu.edu/~berc/working/spatial%20autocorrelation%20z. pdf.
Galor, Oded and O. Moav
(2000). Ability-biased technological transition, wage inequality,
and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 469-497.
Golden, Miriam A. and J.B. Londregan
(2006). Centralization of bargaining and wage inequality: A
correction of Wallerstein. American Journal of Political Science 50:
208-213. Gwartney, James, R. Lawson et al.
(2007). Economic Freedom of the World: 2007 Annual Report,
available at http://www.freetheworld.com/release.html.
Irwing, Paul and R. Lynn
(2006). The relation between childhood IQ and income in middle age.
Journal of Social, Political and Economic Studies 31: 191-196.
Luttmer, Erzo F.P.
(2001). Group loyalty and the taste for redistribution. Journal of
Political Economy 109: 500-528.
Lynn, Richard
(2006). Race Differences in Intelligence. An Evolutionary Analysis.
Augusta (GA): Washington Summit.
Lynn, Richard and T. Vanhanen
(2006). IQ and Global Inequality. Athens (GA): Washington Summit.
Lynn, Richard and D. Longley
(2006). On the high intelligence and cognitive achievements of Jews
in Britain. Intelligence 34: 541-547.
Lynn, Richard, G. Meisenberg, J. Mikk and A. Williams
(2008). National IQs predict differences in scholastic achievement
in 67 countries. Journal of Biosocial Science, in press.
Martin, Michael O., I.V.S. Mullis, E.J. Gonzalez, K.D. Gregory,
T.A. Smith, S.J. Chrostowski, R.A. Garden and K.M. O'Connor
(1999). TIMSS 1999 International Science Report. Chestnut Hill
(MA): ISC.
Martin, Michael O., I.V.S. Mullis, E.J. Gonzalez and S.J.
Chrostowski
(2004). TIMSS 2003 International Science Report. Chestnut Hill
(MA): ISC.
Meisenberg, Gerhard
(2007). Does multiculturalism promote income inequality? Mankind
Quarterly 47: 3-39.
Meisenberg, Gerhard
(2007b). In God's Image. The Natural History of Intelligence
and Ethics. Brighton: Book Guild.
Michelbach, Philip A., J.T. Scott, R.E. Matland and B.H. Bornstein
(2003). Doing Rawls justice: An experimental study of income
distribution norms. American Journal of Political Science 47: 523-539.
Morris, Martina and B. Western
(1999). Inequality in earnings at the close of the twentieth
century. Annual Review of Sociology 25: 623-657
Mullis, Ina V.S., M.O. Martin, E.J. Gonzalez, K.D. Gregory, R.A.
Garden, K.M. O'Connor, S.J. Chrostowski and T.A. Smith
(1999). TIMSS 1999 International Mathematics Report. Chestnut Hill
(MA): ISC.
Mullis, Ina V.S., M.O. Martin, E.J. Gonzalez and S.J. Chrostowski
(2004). TIMSS 2003 International Mathematics Report. Chestnut Hill
(MA): ISC.
Murray, Charles
(2002). IQ and income inequality in a sample of sibling pairs from
advantaged family backgrounds. American Economic Review 92: 339343.
Rushton, J. Philippe
(1989). Genetic similarity, human altruism, and group selection.
Behavioral and Brain Sciences 12: 503-559.
Rushton, J. Philippe and T.A. Bons
(2005). Mate choice and friendship in twins. Evidence for genetic
similarity. Psychological Science 16: 555-559
Scott, John T., R.E. Matland, P.A. Michelbach and B.H. Bornstein
(2001). Just deserts: An experimental study of distributive justice
norms. American Journal of Political Science 45: 749-767.
Verster, J.M. and R.J. Prinsloo
(1988). The diminishing test performance gap between English
speakers and Afrikaans speakers in South Africa. In: S.H. Irvine and
J.W. Berry (eds): Human Abilities in Cultural Context. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Weede, Erich
(2004). Does human capital strongly affect economic growth rates?
Yes, but only if assessed properly. Comparative Sociology 3: 115-134.
Gerhard Meisenberg *
Ross University, Dominica
* Address for correspondence: Department of Biochemistry, Ross
University, Medical School, Picard Estate, Dominica Email
Gmeisenberg@rossmed.edu.dm
Table 1: Mean and standard deviation for Gini index and racial
diversity scores in different world regions. Racial distances are
weighted either by genetic differences or IQ. "Middle East"
includes only the Muslim-majority countries. Greece, Cyprus and
Israel are lumped with "Catholic Europe." N = number of countries.
Region N Gini index
Protestant Europe 7 28.0 [+ or -] 2.9
Catholic Europe 9 32.0 [+ or -] 3.8
English-speaking 6 34.0 [+ or -] 3.0
Ex-Communist 28 34.7 [+ or -] 7.4
Latin America/Car. 23 50.5 [+ or -] 6.7
Middle East 10 37.9 [+ or -] 5.3
South/Southeast Asia 10 39.4 [+ or -] 6.6
East Asia 5 36.3 [+ or -] 6.4
Asian Communist 3 37.1 [+ or -] 1.5
Pacific Islands 1 50.4
Sub-Saharan Africa 31 48.7 [+ or -] 9.7
Total 133 40.9 [+ or -] 10.3
Region Racial diversity
N by genes by IQ
Protestant Europe 8 3.2 [+ or -] 4.1 5.8 [+ or -] 4.5
Catholic Europe 11 2.2 [+ or -] 3.0 5.7 [+ or -] 10.3
English-speaking 6 22.7 [+ or -] 19.7 18.4 [+ or -] 14.7
Ex-Communist 28 2.4 [+ or -] 4.7 2.6 [+ or -] 3.9
Latin America/Car. 37 66.4 [+ or -] 27.7 52.0 [+ or -] 21.0
Middle East 24 13.9 [+ or -] 21.4 7.8 [+ or -] 10.3
South/Southeast Asia 15 19.5 [+ or -] 29.7 15.4 [+ or -] 23.0
East Asia 6 9.3 [+ or -] 14.4 8.0 [+ or -] 13.5
Asian Communist 4 0.1 [+ or -] 0.3 0.1 [+ or -] 0.2
Pacific Islands 14 22.7 [+ or -] 22.6 16.1 [+ or -] 18.7
Sub-Saharan Africa 45 12.6 [+ or -] 19.1 8.5 [+ or -] 15.2
Total 198 21.6 [+ or -] 29.9 16.6 [+ or -] 23.0
Table 2: Correlations of the Gini index with predictors.
N = 131 countries. Educ, education; lgGDP, logarithm of
GDP; Corr., corruption; EcoFr, economic freedom; PolFr,
political freedom; Demo, democracy; RDg, racial diversity,
weighted by genes; RDi, racial diversity weighted by IQ;
lgRDg, lgRDi, logarithm of racial diversity by genes and
IQ, respectively. Correlations above .175 are significant
at p<.05, and correlations above .280 are significant
at p< .001.
Gini IQ Educ. lgGDP Corr. EcoFr
IQ -.587
Educ. -.440 .819
lgGDP -.451 .761 .866
Corr. .440 -.576 -.675 -.813
EcoFr -.403 .617 .691 .779 -.860
PolFr -.301 .514 .655 .748 -.714 .745
Demo -.464 .689 .755 .804 -.705 .721
RDg .372 -.102 -.018 .050 .030 .014
lgRDg .453 -.142 -.032 .026 -.012 .043
RDi .370 -.039 .074 .148 -.045 .080
lgRDi .364 -.015 .113 .185 -.142 .170
PolFr Demo RDg lgRDg Rdi
IQ
Educ.
lgGDP
Corr.
EcoFr
PolFr
Demo .853
RDg .135 -.029
lgRDg .116 -.046 .861
RDi .219 .065 .965 .854
lgRDi .250 .122 .833 .962 .871
Table 3: The best-fitting regression models explaining
the Gini index. The standardized p coefficient is reported.
Models 5 and 6 exclude the countries of Latin America and
the Caribbean. Excom, ex-communist; lgPopDens, logarithm
of population density; Edu, education. For other
abbreviations, see legend of Table 2.
* p<.05; ** p<.01; *** p<.001.
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
IQ -.390 *** -.444 *** -.346 **
IQ2 .194 ** .327 ** .275 ***
Education .378 * .166 .324 *
Education2 -.215 * .501 * -.194 *
lgGDP -.322 * -.261
lgGDP2 -.206 * .248 * -.118
Corr .168
PolFr2 -.257 *** -.302 *** -.194 **
Excom -.391 *** -.416 *** -.281 **
lgPopDens -.272 *** -.265 *** -.251 ***
lgRDi .274 ***
lgRDi2 .092
RDi
IQ x Edu -.313
Edu x lgGDP -.912 ***
N 132 132 132
R2 .618 .637 .675
Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
IQ -.391 *** -.471 *** -.623 ***
IQ2 .403 *** .300 *** .663 ***
Education .214 .446 * .383 **
Education2 .450 * -.188 * .887 ***
lgGDP -.316
lgGDP2 .275 * -.113 .322 **
Corr .220 .193 .239
PolFr2 -.241 *** -.171 * -.211 **
Excom -.344 *** -.281 ** -.272 **
lgPopDens -.254 *** -.241 ** -.185 **
lgRDi .228 ***
lgRDi2 .117 *
RDi .217 ** .136 *
IQ x Edu -.304 -.899 ***
Edu x lgGDP -.768 ** -.776 **
N 132 109 109
R2 .707 .648 .733
Table 4: Correlations of test score variability
(residuals with mean score) on the TIMSS and
PISA assessments (vTIMSS and vPISA), and both
assessments combined (vTIMSS/PISA). Racial
diversity (RD) is weighted either by IQ or by
genetic distance, and is used either directly
in logarithmic transformation. * p<.05; ** p<.01.
vTIMSS vPISA vTIMSS/PISA
RDgenes .136 .204 .212
lgRDgenes .078 .252 .210
RDiq .214 .300 * .292 *
lgRDiq .144 .372 ** .317 **
Gini index .060 .172 .181
IQ .015 .147 .067
Education .052 .281 * .181
lgGDP -.135 .328 * .109
Corruption .171 -.211 -.068
Pol. Freedom .107 .290 * .256 *
Democracy .075 .405 ** .286 *
N 46-51 52-55 64-72
Table 5: Racial diversity as a predictor of ability
dispersion in TIMSS and PISA (vTIMSS and vPISA),
and the combined results from these two assessments
(vTIMSS/PISA). sqrtArea, square root of the country's
surface area; lgPopDens, log-transformed population
density; RDiq and lgRDiq, untransformed and
log-transformed racial diversity, weighted by IQ.
Standardized betas are reported.
* p<.05; ** p<.01; *** p<.001.
vTIMSS vPISA vTIMSS/PISA
predicted predicted predicted
IQ2 .273 .142
Education .427 * .415 .498 **
lgGDP2 .142 .188 .191
Corruption .538 * .669 ** .398
Corruption2 -.508 *** -.244 *
Pol.Freedom2 -.257 -.325 *
Democracy .372 *
Yearscommunist -.362 * -.317 *
RDiq .307 *
lgRDiq .408 ** .275 *
sqrtArea -.241
lgPopDens .146 -.294 *
R2 .410 .550 .396
N 49 53 69
Table 6: Big Government predicted by
racial diversity and other variables.
Model 1 is for all countries with a
Gini index for which complete data are
available. Model 2 is the corresponding
model limited to countries outside
Latin America and the Caribbean. The
standardized p is reported.
* p<.05; ** p<.01; *** p<.001.
Communist: History of communist rule.
RDgenes, racial diversity weighted by
genes. EcoFr, economic freedom. lgPopDens,
logarithm of population density.
Model 1 Model 2
IQ -.317 * -.270 *
lgGDP .863 *** 1.042 ***
lgGDP2 .406 *** .370 ***
EcoFr -.493 *** -.711 ***
EcoFr2 -.233 ** -.311 ***
Democracy .231 .301 *
Democracy2 .207 ** .240 **
Communist .102
lgPopDens -.264 *** -.258 ***
lgRDgenes -.288 ***
RDgenes -.158 *
RDgenes2 .149 *
N 131 108
R2 .513 .579
Table 7: Big Government as a predictor of the Gini
index. lgRDiq, logarithm of racial diversity,
weighted by IQ; lgPopDens, logarithm of population
density; Edu, education; lgGDP, logarithm of GDP.
N = 131. * p<.05; ** p<.01; *** p<.001.
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
IQ -.467 *** -.431 *** -.446 ***
IQ2 .206 ** .258 *** .235 **
Education .354 ** .267 * .276 *
Education2 -.236 ** -.224 **
lgGDP2 .143
Corruption .179 .209 .182
Pol. Freedom2 -.218 *** -.181 ** -.183 **
lgRDiq .189 ** .169 **
lgRDiq2 .075 .086
Excommunist -.332 *** -.245 ** -.292 ***
lgPopDens -.344 *** -.318 *** -.329 ***
Big Government -.299 *** -.232 *** -.214 **
IQ x lgPopDens .086
Edu x lgGDP -.382 ***
R2 .677 .701 .722