Female householding in late eighteenth-century America and the problem of poverty.
Smith, Daniel Scott
Families in early modem England were more than twice as likely to be
headed by woman as were white households in late eighteenth-century
America. On average, in a preindustrial English community, women headed
between one-sixth and one-fifth of all households. In the United States in 1790, by contrast, less than one-thirteenth had female household
heads or householders.(1) The incidenc of female householding provides
an important window on preindustrial American society. Its magnitude and
ramifications deserve analysis and discussion for at least four reasons.
First, householder was a significant status, particularly because
households were very important units of social and economic life in the
preindustrial era. Householders served as the directors of the
predominant institution of economic production. While not a primary
category in thinking about the family, house-holding nevertheless was a
consequence of other statuses that mattered more centrally, at least for
men. Since newlywed couples established households becoming a head (and
wives were considered co-heads, especially with respect to matters that
were internal to the household) conveyed independence from the control
of parents. Indeed, the contrast between autonomy and dependence was at
the heart of legal definitions and other perceptions of social roles in
early modern Anglo-America. The category of female household heads thus
is crucial fo assessing one critical arena of social autonomy for
women.(2)
Second, like their current counterparts, women who were particularly
likely to head households in preindustrial England and America also were
disproportionately prone to be impoverished. Consequently they were
subjects fo support from and intervention by agents beyond the
household: informal aid from kin, charity from private individuals or
voluntary groups, and poor relief from public authorities. As the wages
and assets of these female household heads wer lower than those enjoyed
by male family heads, on average they were closer to poverty.
Additionally, as women householders frequently had responsibility for
the support of minor children, they shared their meager incomes with
others, increasing the numbers facing poverty.
A heterogeneous group, women who headed households had some stability
of residence and thus status in the community. Some were even
"widows of means," who had the inherited resources and
practical skills to support themselves and their families comfortably.
But for many women familially unattached to the households of husbands
or fathers, private troubles became, in many instances, public problems.
The study of the incidence of female-headed households provide an
indirect entry into the analysis of one large segment of the population
of the poor of preindustrial society, a portion that was relatively
larger in England than in America.
Third, historians need to provide a temporal perspective on the rapid
growth in the number and percentage of female householders in both
countries in recent decades, a phenomenon that is closely associated
with the "feminization of poverty." The number of female
householders, women enumerated first in both family and non-family
living arrangements, increased by 98% in the United State between 1970
and 1990, and the share of such units expanded from 21% to 28% of all
American households over that interval. In 1940, by contrast, only 15%
of householders were women. During the last two decades, as Figure 1
shows, the absolute percentage increase was roughly that of the
preceding three decades an also that of the entire century and a half
between 1790 and 1940. A family form that was once unusual is no longer
so, and historians cannot ignore major differences between past and
present.(3)
Finally, as is the case for many areas of social history, the
historiography of female-headed families critically needs comparative
and analytical perspectives While demographic, urban, labor, welfare,
and women's historians have contributed to the study of this
subject, they have characteristically focussed on a single locality. At
most, the geographic scope of these researches has extended to a handful
of places within a region. Cities have been the focus of historians of
poverty in preindustrial America, even though nearly 95% of the
population lived outside of the handful of American urban places. While
the local history approach has value, and is nearly irreplaceable for
the reconstruction of the biographies of ordinary individuals, the
typicality of findings unearthed by these local inquiries remains
problematic.(4)
Even more important than the absence of a comprehensive geographic
picture has been the neglect of a larger theoretical perspective that
links familial and demographic outcomes to economic structure. Not only
does social history need t establish variations, it also requires a
framework that organizes a pattern among the differences.
I
An analytical extension of the demographic and economic framework
used by late eighteenth century American and English writers provides
the basis for understanding the Anglo-American difference in the
incidence of female-headed households. Contemporaries in what may be
called the Malthusian-frontier school were correctly impressed by the
extremely high rate of population growth in eighteenth-century America,
and they fitted this observation into a larger conceptual framework.(5)
The rate of population growth, they theorized, was positively related
to the availability of land and consequently inversely related to
population density. Compared to Europe, the components of more rapid
American population growth included both differentials in natural
increase, driven by the mechanisms of early marriage made possible by
the availability of land that facilitated famil formation in the New
World environment, and migration, as people moved from mor to less
densely settled areas--both from Europe to America and toward the
frontier within North America.
The framework of these commentators was highly parsimonious. Nothing
else--whether technological change or productivity growth, the
preventive check that limited the number of births by cheating nature
within marriage, or the incidence of disease independent of economic
conditions--determined the rate of population growth. Neither did more
complex cultural, institutional, or historical conditions matter unless
they could be tied to the sinews of their economic-demographic
framework. Eighteenth-century writers on population were certainly not
pure theorists, as they tended to focus on selected issues that were
frequently related to immediate political problems.(6)
Following from the analysis of the sources of population growth,
eighteenth-century writers also argued that economic and social
organization were tied to density. Higher population densities lowered
wages which in turn led to the development of manufacturing.
Urbanization too was spurred by the demographic expansion that caused
the countryside to become over-populated and pressured individuals to
seek opportunities elsewhere. Poverty--in both the sense of the absence
of access to the means of production by individuals and th sense of a
supply of labor that exceeded demand in the aggregate--also was strongly
related to density.(7) Consequently, poverty was less common in Americ
than in England or western Europe, but this favorable situation was,
many writers thought, necessarily transitory. Geographic expansion of
the territory of the United States could, however, delay that
development, which had ominous political ramifications for republican
institutions, into the future.(8)
The optimism of political economists of the early Republican era
concerning the short-run prospects for avoiding poverty persisted over
the longer run in the United States. As one comparative historian has
put it, the distinctive America assumption about poverty among the able
bodied has been that there is none. American wages were too high and
opportunities for employment too great for poverty to be a serious
problem. Before American reformers could get a hearing for schemes to
deal with poverty, they first had to demonstrate that it existed at all,
a task that was unnecessary for their European counterparts.(9)
Commentators on poverty, both in the eighteenth century and later,
neglected th large numbers of "life cycle" poor--orphans,
widows, and the aged, who were grouped with the sick and physically
disabled into the normative category of "worthy." Women at
some risk to be heads of families were a only a potential segment of
this non-controversial group of the poor. Despite their numbers, the
were not seen within the socially constructed "problem" of
poverty that was articulated by social and moral commentators. They were
not blameworthy, as the proximate origin of the poverty of widows was,
of course, the deaths of their husbands. Older widows were typically
classified with the dependent rather than with the laboring poor: that
is, as unable to work rather than unwilling to work, which meant, by an
alternative interpretation, that they were unable to find work.(10)
Deserted wives and especially mothers of illegitimate children were not,
of course, viewed so sympathetically. By contrast, the able-bodied or
labor-market poor faced two difficulties in garnering public support or
charitable sympathy. As individuals, they mainly had only themselves to
blame for their unfortunate situations. Collectively, it was feared, the
numbers of labor-market poor would expand precipitately if relief were
offered.
Women who headed households never slipped into membership of the
"dangerous classes," whose criminal activity menaced the
respectable. And as women, they were not generally considered to be
potential political actors, either legally as voters or illegally as
rioters or armed rebels. Central governments passed laws to compel units
of local administration and close kin to do their duty in providing for
these traditional needy.(11) Widowed women of all ages were particularly
suited for small amounts of outdoor relief such as the provision o wood
in winter. When local authorities institutionalized the poor, they
attempted to compel the able-bodied of both sexes to work.
Even if legal sanctions and informal community pressure successfully
privatized support for these poor, historians still need to incorporate
life-course povert into their analyses of the general problem of the
poor in preindustrial societies. For these traditional sources of
poverty accounted for a substantial segment of the total population on
public relief. These poor were the most morally entitled of all
potentially dependent groups. Everywhere in early moder Europe the
life-cycle poor were recognized as being worthy of support.(12)
Typically, the limited evidence suggests, about one-third of widows
in England and America received such aid.(13) And they contributed a
large proportion of the total welfare cases in both societies.(14)
Quantitatively, then, the relative incidence of female-headed households
can be regarded as an indirect measure of the economic burden of life
cycle poverty on local government.
Later scholars also have neglected consideration of female-headed
household and other groups in the ranks of the worthy poor. If politics
as conventionally understood is the core of history, then these subjects
are admittedly marginal. For example, an important, controversial
interpretation of the growth and decline of the welfare rolls in
American history excludes life cycle poverty an focuses solely on the
relationship between work and welfare for the able-bodied poor.(15)
Further, historians who were attracted by the relevance of the
Malthusian-frontier perspective to American history have neglected the
study of both poverty and women. Until very recently, emphasis on the
low "man-land" ratio in early America, exemplified most
famously by the frontier theory of Frederick Jackson Turner, coincided
with an optimistic evaluation of the environmental conditions underlying
that experience. The frontier, by this theory, meant that there were
relatively fewer poor in America than in Europe; to dwell on the
unfortunate circumstances of the small group of impoverished wa beside
this central comparative point. However, the effects of the frontier on
social experience do not all run in a single direction. Historians now
emphasiz that the frontier was an environmental context that produced
outcomes that were extreme.(16)
II
In this article I marshall the best available early American evidence
on the incidence of female householding. Description and analysis focus
on three large data sets: (1) for spatial variation, a sample of
household heads from the 1790 U.S. census, the first enumeration of the
entire population; (2) for variation by age, the extant document with
the largest number of cases, the Maryland census of 1776; and (3) for an
economic profile, the largest available computerized tax record, the
Massachusetts valuation of 1771.
Results from a study of the 1790 printed census returns and an
analysis of the variations in the incidence of female-headed families
among the places in the sample provide a framework and context for local
inquiries. The sex of some 27,854 white heads of families in this
national sample of 79 places with surviving lists was inferred from the
forename. When weighted to correspond to the number of white households
in each sampled stratum, the percentage of white households headed by
women fell between 6.88% and 7.64%. The higher estimate incorporates
corrections for the possible misclassification of names of ambiguous
gender and for the use of lists of taxables rather than of family heads
for thirteen of the Southern counties in the national sample.(17)
White American female-headed households were distinctive in ways
other than the gender of their head. As Table 1 shows, their size and
composition reflect the likely effects of their later than average stage
in the family cycle. Their households contained fewer males under 16 and
a larger number of slaves compare to households headed by men. Older
persons naturally were less likely to have minor children, and they had
a longer period in which to accumulate slaves. Bot daughters and widows
were less likely to receive inheritance bequests of land than of slaves,
which were classified as personalty.(18) If a higher fraction o women
family heads held slaves than did men, at the same time the shortage of
family labor indicated by the smaller average numbers of whites in these
households suggests a higher level of economic vulnerability. Solitary
residenc was very uncommon in the United States before the second half
of the twentieth century. But one-ninth of white women heading
households in 1790 lived alone, compared to only three percent of
households headed by men; over three-fifths o women family heads in that
year had no white male over age 16 present in their households.
Table 1
Composition of white female- and male-headed households in the United States in
1790: Area with extant census listings(a)
Category Female-headed(b) Male-headed(c) Total
Total mean household size 5.09 (100) 6.64 (100) 6.54
Whites per household 3.86 (75%) 5.85 (88%) 5.70
Males aged 16 and older 0.56 (11) 1.54 (23) 1.47
Males under age 16 0.80 (16) 1.46 (22) 1.42
Total females 2.50 (49) 2.84 (43) 2.82
Nonwhites per household 1.23 (24%) 0.80 (12%) 0.83(a)
Slaves 1.17 (23) 0.77 (12) 0.80
Free blacks 0.059 (01) 0.032 ( 0) 0.034
With no other free person
present: 11.2% 3.2% 3.7%
With one or more non-whites
present: 19% 12% 12%
With no males under age 16
present: 53% -- --
With no males over age 16
present: 61% -- --
Notes:
a Included were the New England states, New York, Pennsylvania, South Carolina,
and all but three counties each in Maryland and North Carolina.
b Sample post-weighted to reflect varying distribution of female householders
relative to total white population. Data for female-headed households based on
actual count.
c Figures for households headed by males obtained by subtraction from totals
reported in W.S. Rossiter, A Century of population Growth: From the First Censu
of the United States to the Twelfth, 1790-1900 (Washington, D.C., 1909; 1966
reprint): Table 27, p. 98; Table 30, p. 100; Table 104, pp. 188-200. Table 105,
pp. 201-207; Table 114, pp. 276-291.
The purely demographic ramifications of the Malthusian-frontier
theory can account for a substantial part of the smaller American
incidence of female-headed households and the smaller share of its white
population that was compared to England, potentially dependent. Although
not all of the pieces of data are available, an accounting framework is
useful for framing the problem and pointing toward the major elements of
the solution. Definitionally, the female householder ratio is simply the
number of female householders divided by the sum of the numbers of male
and female householders. Since this ratio is a fraction, it is obvious
that it may be made smaller by decreasing the number of female
householders in the numerator, or by increasing the number of male
householders, who appear only in the denominator. Marriage is the
demographic event that does both. Almost by definition, spouse-present
wives were not listable as household heads, and their measurable
headship rate was zero, or nearly so. In the "western family
pattern" or the "northwest European household formation
system," nearly all households originated in a marriage.(19)
Married men were listed as the heads of these households. Hence a high
proportion of married people in the adult population, a result of early
and nearly universal marriage, simultaneously reduces the numerator and
increases the denominator.(20)
It is also unlikely that more than a small percentage of
never-married women headed households. Widows were the only group among
women who had much of a chance to be recorded as heads of households.
Consequently, the share of widows in the adult female population or the
number per household are very pertinent figures for understanding the
overall female household headship rate and the share of female
householders among all householders in a population.(21)
Compared to England, a considerably higher fraction of adult
Americans had been married. Widows were a smaller percentage of the
ever-married, and there were substantially fewer widows per household in
America than in England. New Hampshire was the only early American
locale to report its population by detailed marital status. Averaging
the results from the 1767 and 1773 censuses, some 27%, 64% and 9% of
females over age 15 were single, married and widowed respectively. In
the English parishes with extant listings, the comparable figures are
37%, 49%, and 13%. In New Hampshire, however, female householding was
low, even by American standards. Only four percent of households in the
Granite State in 1790 were headed by females and only three percent of
females over age 16 headed households, figures substantially lower than
the national averages for 1790. Elsewhere, I have estimated that only
27% of colonial New Hampshire widows were householders, a figure
radically below that of 76% for th three English parishes with available
data.(22)
The only large-size extant nominal listing of an American population
by age before the seventh U.S. census of 1850 covers parts of Maryland
in 1776. In three Maryland counties in that year, 6.8% of females over
15 headed households a higher rate than that estimated for the white
population nationally in 1790 (5.3%). In 1790, some 9.7% of white
households in Maryland were female-headed, and 7.1 % of females over age
15 were household heads.
Table 2 compares age-specific female householder rates for parts of
three Maryland counties in that year with those for nine preindustrial
English parishes, seven rural and two urban, and national figures for
the United States in 1900. Although female household heads were more
common in Maryland than in America generally, the headship rate of 11.1%
in England was more than 60% higher than that of Maryland in 1776.
In both countries female householder rates increased sharply with
age, and the climb was especially steep in England. Women under age 35
in Maryland in 1776 were actually more likely to be householders than
their counterparts in preindustrial England (3% versus 2%). Middle-aged
women, those aged 35 to 54, were somewhat less likely to head households
in Maryland (12%) than in England (15%). Older women in Maryland, those
aged 55 and older, however were substantially less likely to head
households (19%) compared to older English women (32%).
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
Reflecting a lower level of fertility in the past, English women were
older tha women in Maryland. Some 16% of those over age 15 in these
English parishes were aged 55 and older compared to 8% of those in
Maryland; likewise, fewer adult women in England (53%) were under 35
than in Maryland (66%). Standardization reveals that nearly half (45%)
of the difference in the overall headship rates between Maryland and
England may be attributed to the older age distribution in the latter
population, while the other half is due to the higher age-specific
female householder rates in England.(23)
For understanding the burden of poverty, the fraction of
female-headed households is a proxy for the percentage of the
potentially-dependent among all households. But demographic factors are
also important in dividing the non-dependent population into those who
might (or might be forced) to contribut to the dependent because of kin
relationships, and those unrelated households and individuals that could
only be taxed to support the poor.
The higher rates of natural population increase in America compared
to England meant that old people had more children and other kin
available. In Maryland in 1776, for example, about 60% of those over age
65 lived with a child. In preindustrial England, by contrast, this
figure was just under 50%, a small gap that likely can be accounted for
the differential in the availability of children.(24) The higher
householding rate of older white women in England than Maryland is
probably attributable to a lesser incidence of widows living in the
households of their children than was case in America.
Furthermore, there were more kin available in the neighborhood and
community in America than in England. Nearly three in ten white American
households in 1790 were located within five households of another that
was headed by a person with the same surname, compared to only one in
twenty in three English parishes. In these English locales, some 73% of
householders had no other same-surname head within a cluster of 50
households; in America in 1790, only 58% were missing such a
same-surname household head within a group of 50.(25) In America the
greater availability of kin living in close proximity reduced the
demands place on the public welfare system.
III
Early and nearly universal marriage was the proximate demographic
force driving the Malthusian-frontier system. Compared to England, it
produced fewer widows relative to the numbers of married householders
who could provide assistance, acting in the roles of kin, neighbors, or
rate payers. The factor of density supplies the substantive mechanism in
the Malthusian-frontier theory.
Table 3 confirms that areas of higher density had a higher female
householder rate and ratio. The adjusted rate increased from 4.8% for
places under 10 persons per square mile to 6.0% for places with a
density greater than 50; the respective ratios are 6.1% and 9.0%. The
female headship rate and ratio were considerably higher in areas with
lower sex ratios, child-woman ratios, numbers of children per household,
and average household sizes. All of these indicators capture the stage
of demographic development of communities.
Table 3
Description of patterns in female householder ratio, and male and female
headship rates, U.S.A. 1790
Female Householder Male Householder
Ratio Rate Adjusted
Variable and Categories Raw Adjusted Adjusted Rate
Grand Mean 6.88% 7.64% 5.49% 63.32%
Main Regions
South 7.5 9.2 7.0 62.7
Middle states 5.2 5.4 4.0 63.1
New England 7.5 7.7 5.0 64.1
[Eta.sup.2] .04 .09 .12 .01
F-value 1.7 3.6 5.4 0.4
Significance level .19 .03 .01 .69
Detailed Region
Rural:
Carolinas 8.3% 8.8% 6.8% 66.8
Chesapeake 6.6 9.2 6.9 60.3
Middle states 4.5 4.6 3.7 63.8
Southern
New England 8.6 8.8 5.6 64.2
Northern
New England 3.4 3.5 2.5 64.1
Largest cities 18.4 18.9 11.7 56.4
[Eta.sup.2] .38 .39 .33 .16
F-value 8.7 9.4 7.3 2.8
Significance level .001 .001 .001 .02
White Sex Ratio,
Ages 16+
Under 100 10.7 11.3 7.4 64.1
100 to 104.9 5.2 6.2 4.7 64.1
105 to 109.9 5.2 5.9 4.6 62.4
110.0 and above 4.7 5.5 4.6 62.2
[Eta.sup.2] .39 .24 .14 .02
F-value 10.2 8.0 4.0 0.5
Significance level .001 .001 .01 .68
Density Per
Square Mile
Under 10 5.7 6.1 4.8 65.5
10 to 30 5.4 6.6 5.1 63.2
30 to 50 6.9 7.6 5.4 61.8
Over 50,
except urban 8.8 9.0 5.9 64.6
Cities 18.4 18.8 11.7 56.4
[Eta.sup.2] .29 .23 .14 .10
F-value 7.4 5.6 3.0 2.1
Significance level .001 .001 .02 .09
Notes:
For a description of the sample, see Smith, "'All in Some Degree Related'"
American Historical Review 94 (1989): 74-79. The sample was retrospectively
re-weighted so that the number of cases reflect the number of white households
in each area, rather than the white population.
The adjusted female householding ratio is an estimate of maximum fraction of al
white households headed by women; it compensates for omitting names of ambiguou
gender from recording as women and for the use of tax lists in Virginia and one
North Carolina county rather than the 1790 census listings.
The adjusted female householding rate is a maximum estimate of the fraction of
women over age 16 who were householders. The adjusted male householding ratio i
a minimum estimate of the fraction of men over age 16 who were householders.
The categorization of places by density statistically accounts for a
modest percentage of the variation in the rates and ratios. Only New
England seems to have been an exception to this weak pattern,(26) and
the correlation of a dichotomous indicator of densities above and below
40 per square mile with the rural female headship ratio (.66) and rate
(.63) was substantial only in that region. As Franklin optimistically asserted and later American commentators hoped, the dire,
characteristically "Malthusian" implications of higher
densities were not applicable to American conditions: there was simply
too much land for expansion in the frontier economy of early America.
The distribution o densities among places in rural America in 1790 was
missing cases with a high enough level of density that signified a
complete occupation of economic resources.
In multiple regression and multiple classification analyses of the
female householder ratio and rate in 1790, variation in density among
rural areas did not prove to be a statistically significant predictor.
However, the interaction of density with location in New England
remained statistically significant with the inclusion of a regional
variables and two other demographic indicators of the stage of
development (the adult sex ratio, and the mean number of children per
household, an indicator that was negatively related to density) in the
analysis.(27) Although a useful first approximation, density as the
operative mechanism in the Malthusian-frontier theory is an imperfect
indicator and not the only discernable source of variation.
Regional location and especially urban-rural residence more
forcefully shaped the incidence of female householding. Cities exhibited
an especially large ratio, for they were also characterized by a low
male householder rate. In the seven large American cities, females
headed some 18.8% of all white households, a figure more than double
that for rural areas. Cities in New England, with Boston leading with
30.4%, had the highest incidence of households headed by females, while
Baltimore was lowest at 13.6%. While higher urban mortality is doubtless
one source of the greater incidence of female householding in cities,
the more influential cause was the migration of unmarried householders
and the poor toward the greater economic opportunities in cities. In
1708, for example, the mayor of Philadelphia complained that his city of
brotherly love took care not only of its own poor "but almost all
the poor of the province, most of them when distressed in the Countrey,
repairing to the town for relief."(28)
The female householding rate and ratio were highest in the South and
lowest in New York and Pennsylvania (see the bivariate results under the
"none" column of Table 4). Controlling for the effects of
demographic variables, however, the middle states are very close to the
national average. New England had the lowes female householding rate and
ratio, while the South remained the region with th highest incidence.
Assuming that the adjusted results sufficiently control for demographic
differences and therefore reflect variations in propensity, there i no
obvious reason why the level of New England female householding should
be lower than elsewhere in America.(29)
As noted previously in the discussion of Maryland patterns in 1776,
slavery is the likely reason that white southern unmarried women were
more able to be householders. Domestic slaves could provide the services
needed for the maintenance of independent households, and field slaves,
some of whom presumabl were rented out to other masters, the income.
Table 4
Multiple classification analysis of adjusted female householder ratio for place
in the United States in 1790
Deviations from grand mean:
Weighted Adjusted for:
Factor & Categories (N) None Factors only All variable
Density per square mile
Under 20 (31) -2.1 -2.0 -1.1
20 to 40 (22) -0.6 0.3 -0.1
Over 40 (23) 1.9 0.7 0.4
Cities (3) 11.2 13.0 9.0
Eta and beta .55 .57 .38(***
Regions
South (30) 1.5 3.1 2.7
Middle states (22) -2.2 -1.9 -1.2
New England (28) 0.1 -1.9 -2.0
Eta and beta .29 .47 .42(***
Interaction Term
Rural New England/
over 40 p.s.m. (14) 2.9 4.0 1.5(**)
Other (65) -0.6 -0.9 -0.3
Eta and beta .26 .36 .13(**)
Regression coefficients:
Sex ratio over age 16 -10.5(**)
Children per household -4.1(**)
Grand Mean=7.64% Multiple R-Square=0.63
* Sig. at .05; ** Sig. at .01; *** Sig. at .001
IV
An advantage of an accounting framework for the study of householding
is that the scheme must "account" for everyone, whether or not
they would qualify by current or past definitions. This framework
focuses directly on different elements in the entire population and what
role each played in family organization. Two groups--slave women around
whom dwelling units within the enslaved population were organized and
white women who were perceived to function in some respects as co-heads
of their households--need to be evaluated Neither group, albeit for
quite different reasons, would be listed in an enumeration as household
heads. Any framework that omits the some 18% of Americans who were
enslaved in 1790 is obviously incomplete. Further, slavery intertwined
with welfare provisions for whites in ways beyond facilitating
independent householding by white widows. In colonial Charleston, South
Carolina, for example, the workhouse was filled with runaway slaves and
outdoor relief was provided for white paupers.(30) In addition to
slaves, wives of whit men are an ambiguous group in relationship to the
status of headship. When thes groups are considered, the
Malthusian-frontier model can explain why the state or collectivity in
America had an even lower burden of poverty to deal with tha has already
been argued in this article. This is true even though the overall
fraction of female-headed households in America, as measured by the
expanded perspective provided by the accounting construct, may have been
quite similar t that in England.
First, a cultural norm in both societies regarded wives as deputy
husbands or co-heads of their households.(31) Certainly a wife was more
of a householder than was a daughter or a servant of the head. An upper
limit of one-third can b placed on the extent of co-headship of
wives.(32) Some 63% of adult women in Ne Hampshire around 1770 were
married compared to only 49% in late eighteenth-century England.(33)
Thus, compared to England, the early American female headship ratio
needs to be raised by nearly five points to account for the phenomenon
of co-headship by wives.
Estimates of the incidence of female householding among the
African-American population must be approximate. While of interest, data
for free blacks in 1790 do not provide a good guide for an estimate for
the entire population. Only a little more than a tenth of blacks in
areas with extant census listings were free in that year. The female
householder ratio for blacks in that year was about twice as high as it
was for whites in the same distribution of places where free blacks
lived.
About one-fifth of free black householders were women, and about half
of free blacks lived in households with no white members. Interestingly,
in light of patterns since the Civil War, there was, except in the
South, no marked urban-rural difference in the incidence of
female-headed families in the black population.(34)
If one-half of the households of the enslaved were organized around
an adult woman, then both America and England in the late eighteenth
century would have nearly identical proportions of female-headed
households. Yet this guess TABULA DATA OMITTED about the gender of
householders among slaves is almost surely too high. Almost exactly a
quarter of nearly 4,000 units in rural Louisiana between 1810 and 1860
were organized around an enslaved woman, although over half of these
female-headed households contained only a solitary woman.(35)
It must be remembered that the accounting framework does not match
the structur most suited to the understanding of poverty. Taking into
account the families o slaves and co-headship by white wives, the former
gets at the fraction of adult women who performed the householding role.
Neither of these categories fails into the population that would be
aided by the collectivity, either formally or informally. As co-heads,
wives were in the segment of the population that serve normally as
providers of welfare to the poor, either as rate-paying households or
informally to neighbors. In principle, masters took care of the welfare
need of slaves. In practice, slave owners sometimes shirked their duty.
In 1752, the Maryland legislature complained in an act that "sundry Persons in this Province have set disabled and superannuated Slaves free
who have either perished throug want or otherwise have become a Burthen
to others."(36) Although the accounting framework yields a
perspective that should not be overlooked, only white female
householders are relevant to the poverty problem as defined by early
American institutions.
V
Not all white female householders were poor. But more needs to be
known about the economic circumstances that allowed or forced women to
become householders. In particular, data on wealth or income are needed
to evaluate the relationship of female householders to the threat of
poverty. Unfortunately, the available sources are not readily helpful
because they incompletely cover the relevant populations. Not all
currently unmarried women appear in probate records after death or on
tax lists while alive; for that matter, neither do all men, althoug the
coverage is substantially higher for males. For comparison we need to
know the relationship of those for whom information on wealth is
available to the larger population of each group.
Certainly direct comparison of those appearing in a record can be
misleading, a results from the largest extant computerized tax list,
that for Massachusetts i 1771, reveal.(37) For this investigation, the
1,562 women (4.01% of the total) who could be identified were compared
with a random sample of men of the same size.(38) As was the case of
female householding nationally in 1790, female taxpayers in
Massachusetts in 1771 were more frequently found in cities: 8.5% o the
total in Boston, 5.7% in Salem, and 17.2% in Charlestown.
Comparing the wealth of men and women on the list yields a temporary
surprise. Women appear to be richer than men, as the former possessed an
average of [pounds]72 compared to [pounds]49 for the latter. Women had
even more of an advantage in categories other than real property, owning
[pounds]42 compared to the [pounds]20 of men.(39) Real property was more
evenly distributed, with wome holding [pounds]29 and men [pounds]31.
In 1790, however, an adjusted estimate of 8.56% of household heads
enumerated i Massachusetts (including Maine) were women, more than twice
the fraction of females on the 1771 tax lists. One reason for the
deficiency in the numbers of women on the 1771 document is the inclusion
of a poll tax, which allows more me without other property to appear on
the tax valuations. By Pruitt's definition of wealth, some 19% of
men named on the list had none, compared to only 6% of the women. Some
84% of women taxpayers had no rateable polls compared to only 14% of the
men on the 1771 document.
Two simple, plausible assumptions produce an estimate that there were
some 55.4 of female household heads had no property of any sort that was
valuated in 1771.(40) Women householders were, after this adjustment,
poorer than men; thei total wealth was only two-thirds of that of their
male counterparts.(41) The implied estimate of the share of women's
wealth in all wealth is below that found in early American probate
inventories.(42)
The comparison of the unadjusted figures underscores the undeniable
economic heterogeneity among female householders. Indeed, the variation
in wealth among female taxpayers was greater than among male taxpayers.
As the coefficients of variation (the ratio of standard deviation to the
mean) show, this was primaril because women disproportionately held
non-real wealth that was more dispersed i its distribution than real
property.
Another distinctive feature of the assets of Massachusetts female
taxpayers in 1771, like the households of female heads nationally in
1790, was that slaves were more likely to be included than was the case
for men. It is possible that more of the slaves of female householders
were female household servants, provided by their husbands as part of
provision for old age. However, neither the 1771 tax lists nor the 1790
census indicates the sex of slaves.(43)
Table 6
Comparison of wealth profiles of male and female taxpayers on 1771 Massachusett
provincial evaluation
"Taxed" "Heads"
Observed Corrected
Category Males Females Females
Total Wealth 48.9 (1522) 73.7 (1522) 32.9
Coeff. of variation 2.89 4.48 --
Real Wealth 29.3 31.2 13.9
Coeff. of var. 1.53 1.55 --
Other Wealth 19.6 42.4 18.9
Coeff. of var. 6.25 7.30 --
Pct no wealth 19.0 5.9
Pct no rateable polls 13.7 84.4
Pct with slave 1.6 4.3 1.9
Pct Lenders 5.9 13.9 6.2
Pct Merchants 4.7 3.9 1.7
Pct Manufacturers 4.3 2.6 1.1
Pct with cow 58.5 53.3
Urban 6.3 (143) 5.1 (356)
Rural 63.9 (1379) 68.1 (1166)
Notes: Wealth is in pounds, and is the sum of [(horses + oxen) * 2], (cows *
1.5), [(goats + sheep) * 0.015], (swine * 0.4), (annual value of real wealth *
6), and the values of stock-in-trade, factorage, and money at interest. Lenders
are defined by Pruitt as those having any money at interest. Merchants are thos
with any stock-in-trade. Manufacturers are those owning any part of a works or
still. See Pruitt, "Agriculture and Society in the Towns of Massachusetts, 1771
A Statistical Analysis," (Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Boston University, 1981),
185. Only 3 places--Boston, Salem, and Charlestown--were classed as urban.
Additionally, there is evidence, at least in relative terms, for what
one historian of widowhood in England has pointed out as "the most
prominent economic function of the widow in English rural society
between 1500 and 1900"--money lending.(44) Some 14% of women on the
list (6.2% after the adjustment) were money lenders, having
money-at-interest reported, compared to 5.9% of men. However, nearly 90%
of the outstanding credit provided by Massachusetts taxpayers in 1771
was supplied by men, although women participate disproportionately in
this activity. As for the other, more mundane stereotype, rural female
taxpayers were slightly more likely (68%) to own a cow than were male
taxpayers (64%).
Despite the diversity in wealth, most American female householders
were poor. I is unknown whether the fraction was higher or lower than in
England. But even i the poverty rates of female householders were
identical, this aspect of the social burden of life-cycle poverty was
reduced in America for the demographic reasons discussed previously. The
female headship ratio was less because of the higher householding rates
for men, because of the younger age structure of the population, and
because of the lower proportion of the widowed in the adult female
population. The American inputs into the Malthusian-frontier model
reduced poverty for demographic as well as economic reasons.
VI
SUMMARY AND SPECULATIONS ABOUT IMPLICATIONS
The Malthusian-frontier model can subsume under its themes all of the
sources o the collective problem of poverty:
(1) the familiar "frontier model" that emphasizes the cheap
land and high wages of America, and a low incidence of labor-market
poverty--in short, America as "the best poor man's country."
(2) the comparative advantage of agriculture over commerce and
especially manufacturing led to a very low incidence of urbanization.
Both life-cycle and labor-market poor were more prevalent in cities.
(3) the purely demographic effects of early marriage and high male
house-holdin rates, young age structure and low incidence of widowhood
that have been documented in this paper. At any point in time, a smaller
proportion of white adults in America faced the problem of life-cycle
poverty.
(4) finally slavery, an institution also built on the economic facts
of cheap land and high wages for free labor, also reduced the collective
burden of poverty. Although it radically altered patterns of household
organization, slavery simultaneously privatized the resulting poverty
problem.(45)
The lesser incidence of poverty, both labor-market and life-cycle,
had larger and longer lasting implications. Many eighteenth- and even
nineteenth-century American communities were too small in population to
justify the construction o almshouse or workhouse for their poor. Such
facilities for indoor relief, which advocates thought compensated for
their expense by their deterrent value, appeared first in cities, then
in smaller cities and towns, and finally in consolidated poor farms in
rural counties.
If a harsh method for dealing with the poor was delayed by their
scarcity in th populations of American communities, so too was the
English experiment with a more generous and extensive one, that of
family allowances. Inasmuch as early modern societies first learned to
deal with poverty primarily as life-cycle phenomena, societies with a
larger share in the total population of those who were unable to work
developed means of support that eventually could be extende to others in
unfortunate circumstances for other reasons. In other words, by this
admittedly speculative hypothesis, the substantial magnitude of the
welfar burden of the worthy poor paved the way for entitlement of those
unworthy by traditional definition.(46) However, with the important
exception of veterans and their widows, first of the War for
Independence and then of the Civil War, such a transformation from poor
relief to more extensive entitlements did not happen in the United
States until well into the twentieth century.(47)
As in England, nineteenth-century American public discourse about
poverty continued to ignore the "impotent" or life-cycle poor
and focused on the able-bodied poor. Despite differences in economic
situation and in the analysis of the causes of poverty, American
thinking about the effects of public policy on the problem followed that
in England to a remarkable degree.(48) After the repeal of the Old Poor
Law in England in 1834, reformers in both societies, armed with the
doctrines of liberal political economy, stressed deterrence and fought
against outdoor relief, even for the worthy poor.(49)
Experience, however, did not closely follow ideology. Outdoor relief
remained important, especially for the life-cycle poor. In Philadelphia
in 1830, for example, 498 out of 549 paupers on outdoor relief were
women who were either aged or had young children; of the total, 406 were
widows.(50) Indeed, even in the century of the poorhouse, more people
were given outdoor relief than entere that detested institution. Outdoor
relief tended to be given in small amounts, often only in kind rather
than cash, for short periods and for what seemed to b special cases of
need for those who were deemed to be worthy.(51)
Nineteenth-century demographic developments helped to perpetuate the
distinctio between the populations of life-cycle and labor-market poor.
The former tended to be old, rural, and native-born. The latter, on the
other hand, were younger, urban, and increasingly over time,
foreign-born.(52) This ethnic difference was probably most important in
its implications for policy, as the American reform impulse, both in
antebellum and Progressive eras, was distinctively located among
Protestant, middle-class groups, and especially women in this milieu.
Fro their perspective, the life-cycle poverty of widows could easily be
identified as something that happened to "us" rather than to
"them"--the urban, immigrant, Catholic working classes.(53)
Although marriage ages increased over time and a larger fraction
remained unmarried relative to the incidence of celibacy in northwestern
Europe, America retained its distinctive pattern of high nuptiality. The
number of widows relative to all householders made the financial burden
of assistance to them relatively small. Compared to England and western
Europe, private charity playe a larger role in American assistance to
the poor. The impotent poor who were in need for reasons beyond their
control (e.g., widowhood) were not socially constructed into the
"poverty problem" that was ideologically problematic.
Recent scholars of the twentieth-century welfare state have argued
that America developments have been maternalist in orientation,
favoring, for example, mothers' pensions over unemployment
insurance. Focussed on understanding the present, social welfare
historians have emphasized mothers' pensions, enacted b twenty
states between 1911 and 1913 and by forty by 1920, as a turning point in
the creation of the modern welfare state. State rather than local in
creation and based on a status rather than a situation, mothers'
pensions removed the stigma of poor relief. This program can be seen as
a precursor of the kind of entitlements that became common in welfare
policy during the New Deal and thereafter.(54) Similarly, feminist
scholars have emphasized the inadequacy of the program by the less
moralistic and more humane standards of current welfare policies.(55) In
her comprehensive study of the American welfare state in comparative
perspective, Theda Skocpol also has emphasized the novelty and
distinctively American attributes of the mothers' pensions program.
She particularly stresses the crucial role of women's organizations and publication for women in the sudden emergence of the issue and its
equally swift passage by state legislatures in the 1911-13 period.(56)
To be sure, novelties and antecedents of later developments may be
discerned in the maternalist orientation of early twentieth-century
American welfare. This explanation is, however, incomplete. It focuses
too much on the sources of reform and not enough on the size and
character of those who composed the problem in need of amelioration. It
also neglects the orientation of the male legislators who voted for
mothers' pensions by overwhelming majorities. The distinctively
maternalist orientation in the belated building of the modern American
welfare state may also be seen as an ongoing legacy of the peculiar
structuring of poverty in the preindustrial, Malthusian-frontier era
that persisted into the nineteenth century.
First, mothers' pensions were really widows' pensions, as
only three states as late as 1931 allowed never-married women to be
aided. The test for eligibility for these pensions was not simply the
status of being a widowed mother. Officials also assessed the moral
character and behavior of the potential recipients. Second, although the
program was enacted by states, it was primaril funded by cities and
counties and also administered locally, by juvenile court judges or
other local officials. Its administration thus did not represent a ne
departure toward the creation of a centralized welfare state.
Third, the amounts appropriated not surprisingly fell far short of
the total needed to meet the novel goal of the program. One of its major
aims to provide funds so mothers could stay out of the labor force and
their children in school.(57) In fact, in most states the stipends were,
as outdoor relief had been in the preceding centuries, small supplements
to income. Much of the refor legislation that expanded the role of
American governments in the late nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries was successful because its substance dealt with small,
manageable problems. For example, variation in the timing of compulsory
school attendance by states followed rather than preceded the attainment
of nearly universal attendance in the relevant age groups. The law
served to compel a small group of deviant children and their parents to
comply.(58) Perhaps legislators originally hoped that the size of group
being aided was small enough to be easily assisted. In effect, since the
initial legislation was not tied to the appropriation of funds,
legislators were making only a symbolic statement that reflected a
perception that widowed mothers were worthy.
Mothers' pensions, then, were part of a historical context in
which both labor-market poverty and life-cycle poverty were rarer than
in England or western Europe. The economic problems of widows and other
dependent poor remained visible to those who provided informal aid,
private charity, and publi outdoor relief. Given the relatively small
numbers involved and the small amounts of aid provided to each
recipient, this "invisible" poverty problem was visible enough
when it was perceived, as indeed it was, as close up rather than
distant. A legislative innovation in the second decade of the twentieth
century mothers' pensions in practice were more noteworthy for
their continuity with past experience. The details of their
implementation demonstrate the legacy of distinctive past on a seemingly
innovative policy.
More generally, social historians need to explore further the
implications of the important distinction developed in this article
between the life-cycle and the labor-market poor. Both contemporary
writers on poverty and later historian of the subject have neglected the
former group. Their very worthiness has condemned them to obscurity.
Yet, in terms of the economic burden of poverty on the non-poor and on
the collectivity and, more especially, in terms of the numbers of people
who were assisted, the life-cycle poor loom very large indeed
Department of History, M/C 198 851 South Morgan Street Chicago, IL
60607-6377
ENDNOTES
An earlier version of this paper was presented at a conference,
"Lois Green Carr: The Chesapeake and Beyond--A Celebration,"
at the University of Maryland, College Park, May 22-23, 1992. The author
is indebted to Mary Lynn Dietsche for research assistance with the 1790
sample and to Richard John, Steven Ruggles, Peter Stearns and Steven
Wiberley for helpful suggestions for revision.
1. Unless otherwise stated, the terms female householder ratio and
female headship ratio are used synonymously to refer to the ratio of
female householders or heads to all householders or heads. The female
householder or headship rate is the ratio of female householders to all
females aged 16 and older; the denominator of the male rate is the
number of males aged 16 and older. The English female householder ratio
of 16.5% is the average for 70 communities enumerated between 1574 and
1821. Peter Laslett, "Mean Household Size in England since the
Sixteenth Century," in Laslett, ed., Household and Family in Past
Time (Cambridge, Eng., 1972), Table 4.9, p. 147. However,
"Introduction: the History of the Family," Table 1.8, p. 78,
yields a figure of 20.1%.
2. Mary Beth Norton, Liberty's Daughters: The Revolutionary
Experience of American Women, 1750-1800 (Boston, 1980), 40-51, 125-38.
Daniel Scott Smith, "The Meanings of Family and Household: Change
and Continuity in the Mirror of the American Census," Population
and Development Review 18 (1992): 421-456.
3. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Current Population Reports, Series
P-20, No. 447 Household and Family Characteristics: March 1990 and 1989
(Washington, D.C., 1990), Appendix Table A-2, pp. 200-203.
4. Recently, for example, Waciega and Gough have disagreed about the
extent of economic independence possible for widows in Philadelphia and
several counties in southeastern Pennsylvania in the eighteenth and
early nineteenth centuries. Lisa Wilson Waciega, "A 'Man of
Business': The Widow of Means in Southeastern Pennsylvania,
1750-1850," William and Mary Quarterly, 3d Ser., 44 (1987): 60-64
Deborah Mathias Gough, "A Further Look at Widows in Early
Southeastern Pennsylvania," William and Mary Quarterly, 3d Ser.
(1987): 829-835; Waciega, "Reply," ibid., 835-839. A rare
exception to concentration on a single locality is Lynne E. Withey,
"Household Structure in Rhode Island, 1774-1800," Journal o
Family History 3 (1978): 37-50. In Rhode Island, Withey notes, the
percentage o female-headed households increased from 5% in subsistence agricultural towns, t 6-7% in commercial towns and 7-11% in smaller port
towns, and finally to 17-20% in cities.
5. J.J. Spengler, "Malthusianism in Late Eighteenth Century
America," American Economic Journal 25 (1935): 691-707; reprinted
in John Cunningham Wood, ed., Thomas Robert Malthus: Critical
Assessments (London, 1986), I, 72-89. Daniel Scott Smith, "A
Malthusian-Frontier Interpretation of United States Demographic History before c. 1815," in Woodrow Borah, Jorge Hardoy and Gilbert A.
Stelter, eds., Urbanization in the Americas: The Background in
Comparative Perspective (Ottawa, Canada, 1980), 15-24.
6. Dennis Hodgson, "Benjamin Franklin on Population: From Policy
to Theory," Population and Development Review 17 (1991): 639-661.
Greater complexity appear in the frameworks of early nineteenth-century
American writings on population. See James R. Gibson, Jr., Americans
versus Malthus: The Population Debate in th Early Republic (New York,
1989). For the use of the framework as a periodizatio scheme, see Walter
Nugent, Structures of American Social History (Bloomington, IN, 1981).
7. "Populous places have all times, been burthened with a larger
proportion of paupers, than places where a thin or scattered population
is found." J.V.N. Yates, "Report of the Secretary of State in
1824 on the Relief and Settlement o the Poor," reprinted from the
Thirty-Fourth Annual Report of the New York State Board of Charities,
January 28, 1901, p. 989, and in David J. Rothman, ed., Poverty, U.S.A.:
The Almshouse Experience, Collected Reports (New York, 1971)
8. Drew R. McCoy, "James Madison and Visions of American
Nationality in the Confederation Period: A Regional Perspective,"
in Richard Beeman, Stephen Botein, and Edward C. Carter, II, Beyond
Confederation: Origins of the Constitution and American National
Identity (Chapel Hill, 1987), 226-258.
9. Daniel Levine, Poverty and Society: The Growth of the American
Welfare State in International Comparison (New Brunswick, NJ, 1988), 15.
10. For distinctions among types of poor, see Stephen Edward
Wiberley, Jr., "Four Cities: Public Poor Relief in Urban America,
1700-1775," (Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1975),
8-10. Conrad Edick Wright, The Transformation of Charity in
Postrevolutionary New England (Boston, 1992), 28-29.
11. For a summary of early nineteenth-century laws, see Yates,
"Report of the Secretary of State," 1068-1110.
12. Stuart Woolf, The Poor in Western Europe in the Eighteenth and
Nineteenth Centuries (London, 1986), 32-33.
13. For example, in Aldenham, Hertfordshire, 34% received public
support in the period 1641-1681. W. Newman Brown, "The receipt of
poor relief and family situation: Aldenham, Hertfordshire,
1630-1690," in Richard Smith, ed., Land, Kinship, and Life-Cycle
(Cambridge, 1984), Table 12.4, p. 412. About 30% of the recently widowed
received outdoor relief in the period 1808-1812 in Newburyport
Massachusetts. Susan Grigg, The Dependent Poor of Newburyport: Studies
in Socia History, 1800-1830 (Ann Arbor, 1984), 19.
14. In nine seventeenth-century Norfolk, England, parishes, widows
comprised 48 of all those receiving relief, and all categories of women
supplied 61% of all pauper households. In many American communities,
widows and single women living alone comprised a majority of those
receiving relief. Tim Wales, "Poverty, poor relief and the life
cycle: some evidence from seventeenth-century Norfolk," in Smith,
ed., Land, Kinship, and Life Cycle, Table 11.3, p. 360. More generally
see Richard Smith, "Some issues concerning families and their
property in rural England 1250-1800," in Ibid., 72-86. In Women and
the Law of Property in Early America (Chapel Hill, 1986), 184, Marylynn
Salmon does not document the assertion that widows and single women
comprised a majority of welfare cases.
15. Frances Fox Piven and Richard A. Cloward, Regulating the Poor:
The Function of Public Welfare (New York, 1971). For a statement
limiting the scope of their study to those not exempted from the
necessity of working, see Piven and Cloward, "Humanitarianism in
History: A Response to Critics," in Walter I. Trattner, ed., Social
Welfare or Social Control?: Some Historical Reflections o Regulating the
Poor (Knoxville, TN, 1983), 138.
16. Evsey D. Domar, "The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A
Hypothesis," Journal o Economic History 30 (1970): 18-32. William
H. McNeill, The Great Frontier: Freedom and Hierarchy in Modern Times
(Princeton, 1983). Howard Lamar, "From Bondage to Contract: Ethnic
Labor in the American West, 1600-1890," in Steven Hahn and Jonathan
Prude, The Countryside in the Age of Capitalist Transformation: Essays
in the Social History of Rural America (Chapel Hill, NC, 1985), 293-324.
17. For a description of the sample, see Daniel Scott Smith,
"'All in Some Degree Related to Each Other': A
Demographic and Comparative Resolution of the Paradox of New England
Kinship." American Historical Review 94 (1989): 74-79. The sex of
the head was not explicitly recorded by the census and thus had to b
inferred from the forename. For two regions--the Carolinas and southern
New England--the forenames of householders that contained white females
and no male over age 16 were separately examined. It was assumed that
females were the head of these households. In the former region, a
maximum of 16 of 168 names of family heads (9.5%) that almost certainly
belonged to women by the above rule were ambiguous and not easily
spotted as those of females: Christian/Chritian, Desy, Frank, Frans,
Jude, Love, Maple, Massey, Oma, Uley, Sillah, Sande (2), Tener, and
Tamar. In southern New England, out of 365 heads, a minimum of 13 names
[Alatheus, Allin (2), Damarus, Elliot, Elijah, Juda, Lewis (2), Prince,
Rob't, Sam'l, and Subinet] appeared to be masculine and eight
others (Asenath, Bethiah, Easter, Meriam, Noami, Robin, Toby, and
Zilpha) were judged unusual enough not to be picked up as female while
scanning the lists. By the lower estimate, some 3.5% of female heads
would be miwsed, and by the higher, 5.2%. I order to obtain a maximum
estimate, the percentage of female householders in households that
contained no males over 16 was assumed to be correct. However, in
households that had males over age 16, the percentage of female
householders was multiplied, somewhat arbitrarily, by 8.25%.
A more serious defect arises from the loss of the original schedules
of the 179 census for some states or counties. Printed versions of the
original documents exist for all of New England, New York and
Pennsylvania, Maryland, and the Carolinas. The compilers of the printed
volumes substituted names and data from tax lists from the 1780s for
Virginia and for a few counties elsewhere. In this study, data for one
North Carolina county (Orange) and for all twelve counties in Virginia come from tax rather than census lists. In the southern sampling units
with extant 1790 census listings, women headed over 75% more households
than in the 13 counties with only tax records available.
To arrive at an upper estimate of female householders, their numbers
were increased in the 13 southern places with tax list data. In making
the correction, the more important assumption is that the overall
averages in both tax- and census-record southern places would be
identical if the areas in both categories were at the same stage of
demographic development. Of lesser quantitative importance is the
adjustment for the developmental stage that was assumed to be captured
by the estimated sex ratio of the white population aged 16 and older.
For counties where tax lists were used instead of the census records,
the percent of female headed households was multiplied by 1.754.
18. Jean Buttenhoff Lee, "Land and Labor: Parental Bequest Practices in Charles County, Maryland, 1732-1783," in Lois Green
Carr, Philip D. Morgan and Jean B. Russo, eds., Colonial Chesapeake
Society (Chapel Hill, 1988), 330-38. Virginia and especially South
Carolina limited the rights of widows to inherit slaves. Salmon, Women
and the Law of Property, 149-160.
19. Peter Laslett, "Characteristics of the Western Family
Considered over Time, Journal of Family History 2 (1977): 89-115. John
Hajnal, "Two Kinds of Pre-Industrial Household Formation
System," in Richard Wall, ed., Family Forms in Historic Europe
(Cambridge, Eng., 1983), 65-104. Daniel Scott Smith, "American
Family and Demographic Patterns and the Northwest European Model,"
Continuity and Change 8 (1993): 389-415.
20. In the public use sample from the U.S. manuscript census of 1900,
nearly al (97%) of spouse-present married men were listed first in the
census household. Some 42% of post-married men aged 16 and older headed
households compared to 9% of never-married men.
21. In the 1900 public use sample, some 51.4% of post-married (mostly
widowed) women aged 16 and older headed households compared to 3.5% of
never-married women. Only 0.1% of spouse-present married women were
listed first in the censu household.
22. A complete count of the 1790 listings for the entire state
reveals that 3.8 of all householders were females, and that 2.6% of
females over age 15 were householders. Smith, "The Demography of
Widowhood in Pre-Industrial New Hampshire," in David L. Kertzer and
Peter Laslett, eds., Aging in the Past: Demography, Society, and Old Age
(Berkeley: University of California Press, forthcoming). The English
figure is from Wall, "Women Alone," Table 4, p. 313.
23. Controlling simultaneously for both age and marital status, if
such data were available, would provide a better fix on the separate
roles of age and marital distribution.
24. Daniel Scott Smith, "Historical Change in the Household
Structure of the Elderly in Economically Developed Societies," in
Robert Fogel et al., eds., Aging: Stability and Change in the Family
(New York, 1981), Table 5.1, p. 100. Also see Steven Ruggles, "The
Transformation of American Family Structure," American Historical
Review 99 (1994): 118-120.
25. Smith, "'All in Some Degree Related'," 44-79.
26. Density was measured for towns in New England but for counties
elsewhere in the country. In general, better measurement produces higher
correlations. Also see the results for the relationship of these
indicators to density variations among New Hampshire towns. Smith,
"Demography of Widowhood," Tables 3 and 4.
27. Together the predictors accounted for 56% of the variance in the
adjusted female ratio, 51% of the adjusted female ratio but only 16% of
the adjusted mal ratio.
28. Quoted by Jill S. Quadagno, "The Transformation of Old Age
Security," in David Van Tassel and Peter N. Stearns, eds., Old Age
in a Bureaucratic Society: The Elderly, the Experts and the State in
American History (Westport, CT, 1986) 132.
29. By propensity is meant the disposition to engage in an action
given the opportunity. For example, only old people who have children
have a non-zero propensity to live with a child. It is possible that
this assumption is wrong; the lower figure for New England might be
attributed to the small proportion of non-American born in that region
or some other inadequately measured demographi factor.
30. Wiberley, "Four Cities," 80-85.
31. See especially Laurel Thatcher Ulrich, Good Wives: Image and
Reality in the Lives of Women in Northern New England, 1650-1750 (New
York, 1982).
32. This was the fraction of married men and women who indicated
their belief i joint headship in responses to a special inquiry of the
Census Bureau in September 1975. Unpublished Census Bureau memo of
October 17, 1975, cited in Smith, "Meanings of Family and
Household," 447-448. The calculation assumes tha the subjective
status of married women within the household was not lower in 1975 than
it had been in 1790.
33. Smith, "Demography of Widowhood," Table 1.
34. Charleston, South Carolina, and Baltimore, Maryland, are the two
southern cities above 8,000 population.
35. Ann Patton Malone, Sweet Chariot: Slave Family and Household
Structure in Nineteenth-Century Louisiana (Chapel Hill, 1992), Table
1.1, p. 15. Also see, Stephen Crawford, "The Slave Family: A View
from the Slave Narratives," in Claudia Goldin and Hugh Rockoff,
eds, Strategic Factors in Nineteenth-Century American Economic History
(Chicago, 1992), 331-350.
36. In 1755, 20% of all free blacks in Maryland were "past
labour or cripples" compared to only 2% of white men. Allan
Kulikoff, "The Beginnings of the Afro-American Family in
Maryland," in Aubrey C. Land et al., eds., Law, Society and
Politics in Early Maryland (Baltimore, 1977), 189.