首页    期刊浏览 2024年07月18日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The impact of remittances on economic growth and development in Africa.
  • 作者:Fayissa, Bichaka ; Nsiah, Christian
  • 期刊名称:American Economist
  • 印刷版ISSN:0569-4345
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:September
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Omicron Delta Epsilon
  • 摘要:For more than half a century, there have been heated debates on the sources of economic growth of developing economies (Lewis, 1954: Solow, 1956: Chenery and Strout, 1966: Denison, 1967; Myrdal, 1968: Harris-Todaro, 1970: Schultz, 1979: Fields, 1980; Romer, 1986: Lucas, 1988; Barro, 1991: and Easterly, 2001). The perceived sources of economic growth have ranged from surplus labor to physical capital investment and technological change, foreign aid, foreign direct investment (FDI), investment in human capital, increasing returns from investment in new ideas and research and development. Other researchers such as Owens (1987), Sen (1990), and Kaufmann, Kray, and Mastruzzi (2006) have also focused on the impact of institutional factors such as the role of political freedom, political instability, voice and accountability on economic growth and development.
  • 关键词:Economic assistance;Economic growth;Foreign direct investment;Foreign economic assistance;Foreign investments

The impact of remittances on economic growth and development in Africa.


Fayissa, Bichaka ; Nsiah, Christian


I. Introduction

For more than half a century, there have been heated debates on the sources of economic growth of developing economies (Lewis, 1954: Solow, 1956: Chenery and Strout, 1966: Denison, 1967; Myrdal, 1968: Harris-Todaro, 1970: Schultz, 1979: Fields, 1980; Romer, 1986: Lucas, 1988; Barro, 1991: and Easterly, 2001). The perceived sources of economic growth have ranged from surplus labor to physical capital investment and technological change, foreign aid, foreign direct investment (FDI), investment in human capital, increasing returns from investment in new ideas and research and development. Other researchers such as Owens (1987), Sen (1990), and Kaufmann, Kray, and Mastruzzi (2006) have also focused on the impact of institutional factors such as the role of political freedom, political instability, voice and accountability on economic growth and development.

For many developing countries, however, remittances represent a major part of international capital flows, surpassing foreign direct investment (FDI), export revenues, and foreign aid (Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz, 2005). A recent World Bank (2006) study suggests that recorded remittances have grown faster than foreign direct investment, or official development assistance (See Figure 1 below).

Consequently, recent financial flows into developing countries in the form of remittances are receiving increased attention because of their size and impact on the economies of recipient countries. According to Gupta, et al. (2007), estimated official remittances reached a total of $188 billion in 2005 which is twice the amount of development assistance received by emerging economies. Informal and unreported remittances could even easily add another $94 billion to the above figure. Between 2000 and 2005, remittances to Sub-Sahara Africa (SSA) rose 55 percent to nearly $7 billion in comparison to 81 percent increase for all developing countries as a group. In terms of the ratio of remittances to GDP, the top ten countries are: Lesotho (38%), Cape Verde, Guinea-Bissau, Togo, Senegal, Sudan, Swaziland, Comoros, Mali, and Nigeria (about 5%) (See Figure 2 below).

Despite the increasing importance of remittances in total international capital flows, the relationship between remittances and growth, especially in SSA, has not been adequately studied. This study explores the aggregate impact of remittances on the economic growth of African countries within the conventional neoclassical growth model, using panel data spanning from 1980 to 2004 for 36 African countries. (1)

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

We also account for the traditional sources of economic growth using estimation methods that are based on simple fixed-effects and random-effects models which allow us to account for the heterogeneity of African economies and the differences in the traditional sectors' contributions to the economic growth of African economies. The contribution of our work to the empirical literature is that we provide evidence of the extent to which the remittances can spur economic growth while accounting for the conventional sources of economic growth using standard theory. Our empirical results show that remittances have statistically significant contribution to both the current level of gross domestic product and the economic growth rate of African countries as do investments in physical and human capital. Our findings suggest that remittances play a role in the economic growth of African economies by augmenting the dwindling external sources of capital in the form of foreign aid, foreign direct investment, and/or private investments to Africa.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II provides a review of selected literature. In section III, we specify a conventional neoclassical growth model which incorporates remittances as one of the sources of growth. Section IV presents estimation results for both the fixed and random effects regressions accounting for both the country and time effects and the Arellano-Bond (2002) dynamic panel data estimates for reflecting both the dynamic nature of the data and endogeneity of some of the conventional growth sources. The last section summarizes the results, draws conclusions, and makes some policy recommendations for promoting remittances as a growth and development strategy.

II. A Review of Selected Literature

Based on household survey data from various African countries, few empirical studies have investigated the role of remittances in reducing poverty (Lucas and Stark, 1985; Adams, 1991; Sander, 2004; Azam and Gubert, 2005; Adams, 2006). The macroeconomic impacts of remittances, however, may have been overlooked for at least two reasons. One theoretical strand suggests that workers' remittances are mainly used for consumption purposes and, hence, have minimal impacts on productive investment that would spur long-run economic growth (Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz, 2006). In other words, remittances are widely viewed as compensatory transfers between family members who lost skilled workers due to migration with limited or no discernable impact of the national economy.

Nevertheless, Stahl and Arnold (1986) argue that the use of remittances for consumption may have a positive effect on growth because of their possible multiplier effect. Moreover, remittances respond to investment opportunities in the home country as much as to charitable or insurance motives. Many migrants invest their savings in small businesses, real estate or other assets in their own country because they know local markets better than in their host countries, or probably expecting to return in the future. The second reason why empirical macroeconomic impacts of remittances on economic growth have been limited in the literature has to do with the lack of macro-level data. Partly, the availability of macro-level data problem arises from the informality of such transfer of capital from the host to the receiving country since money is typically sent through family members and other friends unlike the formal transfer schemes (e.g. Western Union, Money Gram) which enter the national accounts of the receiving countries (Loser, et al., 2006).

There are two possible motives why migrants might remit money to home country. The first motive may be for altruistic reason, i.e. when the economic condition in the migrant's home country is bad, money is sent as compensatory transfers between family members and they are motivated by welfare and insurance considerations (Lueth and Ruiz-Arranz, 2006). The second motive of remittances is to take advantage of investment opportunities when the economic condition in the home country is healthy. In about two-thirds of developing countries, remittances are mostly profit-driven and increase when economic conditions improve back home (Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz, 2006). Such external monetary flows are particularly used for investment where the financial sector does not meet the credit needs of local entrepreneurs (Ruiz-Arranz, M., 2006). Thus, we cannot, a priori, predict the direction of the impact of remittances ([REM.sub.it]) on the economic growth of African economies based on the above discussions.

III. An Empirical Model of Economic Growth with Remittances

In the economic growth literature, researchers have been interested in the rate at which countries close the gap between their current positions and their desired long-run growth path. To determine the responsiveness of income growth rate to remittances and the traditional sources of economic growth such as investment in physical and human capital, an external source of capital represented by foreign aid, openness of the economy as measured by the ratio of the sum of imports and exports to the GDP, often proxied by terms of trade, foreign direct investment, a measure of an institutional factor often represented by the economic and political freedom index, and the impact of the initial per capita income, we first specify a simple double log-linear Cobb-Douglass production function as:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)

Where in [GDP.sub.it] is the natural log of real GDP per capita and In [REM.sub.it] is log of remittances per capita in US$; In [GCF.sub.it] is the log of gross fixed capital formation as a percent of real GDP used as a proxy for investment in physical capital (2). In [ENR.sub.it] is log of secondary and tertiary enrollment rates used as measure of investment in human capital which is expected to have a positive effect on the economic growth of developing countries (Schultz, 1980; Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988; and Barro, 1990).

The next three variables are used to capture the impact of external sources of capital on economic growth. Proponents of aid argue that overseas capital flows are necessary for the economic growth of developing countries (Chenery and Strout, 1966; Papenek, 1973; Levy, 1987; and Islam, 1992). On the other hand, opponents of foreign aid argue that it has a negative effect on domestic savings and economic growth in less developed countries (see, Heller, 1975 and Boone, 1994). The log of foreign aid (ln [AID.sub.it]) denotes the sum of official development assistance. The log of other official flows (ln [OFI.sub.it]) is used to capture the impact of foreign portfolio investments and other foreign financial flows except foreign direct investment. In [FDI.sub.it] is the log of foreign direct investment used to capture the effect of external sources of capital on growth; In [TOT.sub.it] is the log of the terms of trade for each country under consideration, measured by the ratio of the export to import price indices (See, Table 1 for detailed definitions) to capture the impact of trade, or openness of the economy on economic growth.

In [EFI.sub.it], is log of the economic freedom index. Owen (1987) and Sen (1999) argue that freedom (political, economic, social, transparency and security) is a necessary condition for economic growth and development. Thus, we use the log of the economic freedom index (ln [EFI.sub.it]) to capture the effect of this institutional factor. The EFI is designed to measure the consistency of a nation's institutions and policies with economic freedom in the spirit of La Porta et al. (1997). (3) It ranges from 1 to 10, with higher numbers denoting more freedom. Hence, we expect a positive coefficient for the economic freedom index.

The impact of the initial level of GDP per capita ([INY.sub.it]) on economic growth has been controversial at best. On the one hand, Blomstrom (1996) and Casseli, et al. (1996) have found a positive relationship between growth rate and the initial level of GDP per capita growth rate through its positive impact on capital formation. On the other hand, Barro (1997) has found a negative relationship between the initial GDP per capita and the GDP growth rate in a cross-country empirical study which he interprets to imply a case of conditional convergence. Consequently, we cannot, a priori, predict the sign of the initial level of GDP per capita ([INY.sub.it]) coefficient. TFP is a measure of total factor productivity. It is measured by the log of gross domestic product divided by the logs of the product of gross capital formation and labor force. The more productive an economy is the more per capita income they will observe, thus we expect a positive relationship between productivity and per capita income.

To estimate the parameters corresponding to variables of interest from the data under consideration, we employ a panel data estimation, an empirical exposition of which is provided in equation (2) below.

[Y.sub.it] = [[lambda].sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.t] + ([X.sub.it])[phi] + [[psi].sub.it] (2)

where [Y.sub.it] is the natural logarithm of real GDP per capita in country i at year t, and [X.sub.it] is a vector of the explanatory variables (remittances, investment in physical and human capital, foreign aid, openness, foreign direct investment, economic freedom index, and initial income) for country i = 1, 2..., m and at time t = 1, 2, ..., T, [phi] a scalar vector of parameters of [[beta].sub.1]...., [[beta].sub.7]; [[psi.sub.it] is a classical stochastic disturbance term with E[[[psi].sub.it]] = 0 and var [[[psi].sub.it]] = [[sigma].sub.[??].sup.2], [[lambda].sub.i] and [[gamma].sub.t] are country and time specific effects, respectively. Instead of a priori decision on the behavior of [[lambda].sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.t] different types of assumptions are separately imposed on the model and the one that gives robust estimates is chosen.

If we assume the "country specific" effects to be constant across countries and the "time specific" effects are not present [i.e. [[lambda].sub.i] = [[gamma].sub.t] and [[gamma].sub.t] = 0)], then model (2) is estimated by the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) method, or restricted OLS method. The second estimation technique assumes that the country specific effects are constant, but not equal (i.e. [[lambda].sub.i] = [[gamma].sub.t] and [[gamma].sub.t] = 0 which yields a one-way fixed effects model). The third assumption is a situation where the country effects are not constants, but rather are disturbances: the time effects are not present [i.e. [[lambda].sub.i] = [[gamma].sub.t] + [w.sub.i] and [[gamma].sub.t] = 0] where E[[w.sub.i]] = 0 and var[[w.sub.i]] = [[sigma].sub.w.sup.2] and cov[[psi].sub.i], [w.sub.i]] = 0. In this case, model (2) is estimated by the generalized least squares (GLS) which yields random-effects model.

Given that some of the traditional factors that explain growth are either pre-determined, or endogenous, or both, and current period growth could depend on its values in the past, a dynamic variant of the fixed and random effects provided in Equation (2) above, known as the Arellano-Bond estimation (1991) is specified as follows:

[DELTA][Y.sub.it] = [[alpha].sup.'][DELTA][Y.sub.it-1] + [[beta].sup.][DELTA][X.sub.it-1] + [[gamma].sup.'][Z.sub.it] + [v.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.it] (3)

Where [DELTA][Y.sub.it] is first difference of the natural log of per capita income growth in country i during time t: [DELTA][Y.sub.it-1] is lagged difference of the dependent variable, [DELTA][X.sub.it-1] is a vector of lagged level and differenced predetermined and endogenous variables, [Z.sub.it], is a vector of exogenous variables, and [alpha], [beta], and [gamma] are parameters to be estimated, [v.su.i] and [[epsilon].sub. it] are assumed to be independent over all time periods in country i. The term [v.sub.i] represents "country specific" effects which are independently and identically distributed over the countries while [[epsilon].sub.it] noise stochastic disturbance term and is also assumed to be independently distributed. We estimate the coefficients of the variables using the Arellano-Bond (1991) Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimator to evaluate the joint effects of remittances and the other explanatory variables on economic growth in African countries while controlling for the potential bias due to the endogeneity of some of the regressors including the lagged dependent variable.

All data, except for the economic freedom index (which is taken from the Fraser Institute's Economic Freedom of the World Index), and the foreign financial flow data (which are taken from the UNCTAD Handbook of Statistics) are from the World Bank Development Indicators (WDI, 2006) CD. The definitions and descriptive statistics of each variable included in the model are provided in Tables 1 and 2, respectively.

IV. Empirical Results and Interpretations

Several versions of equation 2 are tested in order to obtain a model which yields robust results and best fits the data. Accordingly, columns 1 and 2 of Table 3 present the estimation results of a quasi fixed-effects panel with heteroskedasticity corrected standard errors, whereas column 3 and 4 present the estimation results for the random effects model with bootstrap standard errors. The correction for heteroskedasticity and the presence of the initial income converts the pooled regression with heteroskedasticity corrected standard errors into a quasi fixed-effects model. Apart from the magnitude of the coefficients, the results reported in models 1 and 2 are comparable. Since the composition of countries receiving remittances in our sample consists of those which may be suspected to be outliers such as Lesotho and Cape Verde, we report regression results in columns 2 and 4 of Table 3 without these outliers for the quasi-fixed and random effect models, respectively. While the results are found to be similar, the magnitude of the impact of remittances on per capita income appears to improve.

A comparison of the consistent quasi fixed-effects model with the efficient random-effects model using the Hausman specification test, rejects the random effects estimates at p < 0.05 in favor of the quasi fixed effects estimates. We thus base the discussion of our findings on the more robust quasi fixed-effects results reported in column 1 of Table 3. Broadly, the results reveal the expected relationship between the GDP per capita income ([GDP.sub.it] and the explanatory variables i.e., the variables representing the sources of growth have the expected signs according to the a priori predictions. All the coefficients represent elasticities since we estimated a double-logarithmic model.

The results from our model of choice indicate that the remittance variable has a positive and statistically significant effect on the GDP per capita (at p < .01) of African countries. Accordingly, we find that a 10 percent increase in the remittances of a typical African economy would result in about 0.4 percent increase in the average per capita income. Similarly, a 10 percent increase in investment in human capital (ENR) increases GDP per capita by 1.1 percent. Consistent with the findings of Solow (1956), Barro (1990), and Temple (1999), we also find that investment in physical capital (GCF) measured by the gross fixed capital formation as a percent of GDP has a positive and statistically significant impact on the real per capita GDP i.e., we observe that a 10 percent increase in investment in the physical capital will lead to about 1.6 percent increase in the GDP per capita, by far the main variable which spurs economic growth.

Our results also indicate that foreign aid (AID) has a negative and statistically significant effect on economic growth, confirming the position of the opponents of aid (Heller, 1975; Boone, 1994). The results also show that the other financial flows (OFI), foreign direct investment (FDI), the terms of trade (TOT), and the total factor productivity measure (TFP) have a positive, but not significant effect on the economic growth of African countries in our sample.

On the other hand, the institutional variable (EFI) used to capture the effect of economic freedom shows that good governance promotes the economic growth performances of African economies. Consistent with arguments made by Sen (1990), Owen (1987), and La Porta et al. (1997), our estimates indicate that a 10 percentage increase the economic freedom index leads to about 1.55 percent increase in per capita income. In their celebrated article, "Africa's Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions," Easterly and Levine (1997) have empirically demonstrated that economic growth is affected by quality of governance (ethnic divisions, political instability), schooling, state of the financial system, exchange markets distortions, high government deficits, and insufficient infrastructure. Finally, we find that the coefficient of the initial per capita income (GDPPC 1980) has a positively and statistically significant effect on the current level of economic growth of countries. In fact, a coefficient value of 0.9 for the initial GDP per capita (INY) implies that a 1 percent increase in INY increases the current GDP per capita by 0.9 percent. This indicates a case of non-convergence, this is to say, the countries with higher per-capita income in 1980 are the ones experiencing higher growth.

While results based on the fixed and random effects models in which we simultaneously account for the heterogeneity and time to time fluctuations in the economic performance of African economies are appealing, we note that some of the explanatory variables of growth are endogenous, thus confounding the results. For example, while FDI and investment in human capital (ENR) have often been credited for their role in the economic growth of a country, there is also ample evidence (Hansen and Rand, 2006; de Mello, 1999) that the level GDP and its growth rate have feedback effects on the amount of FDI a country receives and the rate of investment in human capital formation. Given that we are mainly interested in analyzing the effect of remittances on African economic growth while accounting for the traditional growth explanatory factors that are either pre-determined (e.g., schooling) or endogenous (e.g., FDI), or both, we employ the Arellano-Bond dynamic panel General Method of Moments (GMM) estimator to obtain robust estimates by using levels lagged one period to serve as instruments for the endogenous variables. The Arellano-Bond dynamic GMM estimates are reported in Table 4.

In our case, the Sargan test as treated in the Arellano and Bond (1991) fails to reject the null hypothesis that the over-identifying restrictions are valid while the Arellano-Bond test rejects the null hypothesis of no-first autocorrelation in the differenced residuals AR(1), and accepts the null hypothesis of no second order autocorrelation in the differenced residuals. Consequently, the estimated coefficients reflect the true (efficient and unbiased) relationship between growth in African per capita GDP and remittances (our variable of interests) and the traditional growth determinants that are either pre-determined, or endogenous, or both.

Based on the results from our model, we observe that the coefficients of the lagged values of GDP per capita (PCI) and changes in remittances (REM) have a significant and positive impact on the growth rate of African GDP per capita. Accordingly, a 10 percent increase in remittances would lead to a 0.05 percent growth in the GDP pre capita of African economies. Accounting for the endogenous nature of the traditional growth explaining factors, we find that while foreign direct investment (FDI), the terms of trade (TOT), and the institutional variable proxied by the political rights index (EFI) were not significant, investment in physical capital (GCF), and the lag of human capital (ENR), have significant growth enhancing roles.

V. Conclusion

The main goal of this study is to investigate the effect of remittances relative to the other external sources of capital such as foreign aid and foreign direct investment on the economic growth and development of African countries. The results show that remittances do positively impact the economic growth of African countries. We have found that a 10 percent increase in remittances lead to a 0.4 percent increase in the GDP per capita income.

According to Gupta et al. (2007), remittances are neither a panacea nor a substitute for a sustained and domestically engineered development endeavor for curing the problems of low-income countries. Furthermore, large-scale migration can have a deleterious effect on domestic labor markets in specific sectors such as higher education, government services, science and technology, and the manufacturing and services, especially where those migrating to other countries are largely skilled workers who are difficult and expensive to replace. Migrant transfers in the form of remittances can ease the immediate budget constraints of families by bolstering crucial spending needs on food, health care, and schooling expenses for their children. Such an unharnessed market in money transfers is, not only a source of small scale saving, but it can also be expected to pave a way for the development of a formal financial sector which is essential for the economic growth and development of African countries in line with King and Levine (1993) and Beck, et al. (2000), Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2006), and Gupta, et al. (2007).

In addition, the results show that the conventional sources of growth such as investment in physical and human capital and the ability of households to have the wherewithal of spending on health, housing, nutrition, and other household items can enhance their productivity and spur their economic growth. A policy implication which may be drawn from this study is that African countries can improve their economic growth performance, not only by investing on the traditional sources of growth such as investment in physical and human capital, trade, and foreign direct investment, but also by strategically harnessing the contribution of remittances by ensuring their efficient and reliable transfers and reducing cost of transfers by improving their governance performance.
APPENDIX.
Variable Means by Country in Sample

Country-Name       GDPPC       REM      ENR      GCF       AID

Algeria           1791.248    31.070   77.230   30.721    216.759
Benin              296.854    13.709   17.409   16.377    206.190
Botswana          2243.048    38.041   58.857   29.056     95.694
Burkina Faso       218.344    12.827   10.532   19.528    350.288
Cameroon           669.895     1.450   32.962   19.482    428.166
Cape Verde         927.560   156.548   36.854   26.086     96.526
Comoros            401.250    18.960   27.163   20.974     39.369
Congo, Rep.       1074.509     1.904   42.499   28.066    131.438
Cote d'Ivoire      682.286     5.460   31.310   13.224    502.693
Egypt, Arab       1234.931    61.005   98.384   22.846   2024.138
  Rep.
Ethiopia            97.360     0.400   16.941   15.354    819.509
Gabon             4138.969     0.288   85.995   29.470     76.178
Gambia, The        319.751    10.411   28.451   19.880     64.982
Ghana              224.610     0.996   35.378   15.940    543.388
Guinea-Bissau      167.502     9.885   17.045   25.635     94.423
Kenya              424.471     7.777   20.423   19.963    601.519
Lesotho            405.708   207.451   29.328   43.637     97.084
Madagascar         254.891     0.758   20.857   12.932    381.740
Malawi             144.185     4.252   15.009   17.212    362.108
Mali               197.619     9.069   12.206   20.617    392.485
Mauritania         367.552     2.800   19.491   22.334    223.627
Mauritius         2781.911   110.703   70.546   25.486     38.652
Mozambique         178.140     3.912   12.501   20.378    839.731
Namibia           1802.632     7.003   52.414   21.128     98.621
Niger              178.394     1.485    8.323   12.395    299.505
Nigeria            352.128     5.365   47.880   19.019    181.344
Rwanda             252.161     0.820   20.928   15.603    313.202
Senegal            412.455    18.884   18.943   15.316    525.129
Sierra Leone       230.990     5.122   21.034   10.043    150.843
South Africa      3153.716     4.137   90.198   19.319    389.784
Sudan              313.316    13.855   28.094   16.500    585.466
Swaziland         1208.405    91.131   46.682   23.350     36.695
Togo               264.578     7.028   28.011   18.055    124.216
Tunisia           1674.134    71.502   69.814   27.993    242.610
Uganda             200.429    -5.380   13.968   13.822    545.627
Zimbabwe           601.519     1.589   49.424   16.832    300.343

Country-Name       OFI      FDI      TOT      EFI     TFP

Algeria          240.427   0.443    95.206   3.963   64.593
Benin              6.312   1.430    91.586   5.044   58.624
Botswana           7.630   2.554    89.202   6.164   40.934
Burkina Faso       0.575   0.283   102.115   5.000   60.040
Cameroon          52.543   0.457    87.281   5.682   65.483
Cape Verde         0.149   1.979   105.090   5.198   29.048
Comoros            0.141   0.433    83.929   4.881   33.718
Congo, Rep.       53.944   3.038    83.344   4.748   46.046
Cote d'Ivoire     86.648   1.123   156.881   5.490   77.637
Egypt, Arab      298.971   1.734   131.972   5.387   78.597
  Rep.
Ethiopia           0.204   1.460   116.391   5.698   82.845
Gabon             74.106   0.080   168.186   5.122   39.841
Gambia, The        1.162   3.966   106.115   4.941   39.731
Ghana              7.609   1.141   122.495   4.576   78.773
Guinea-Bissau      1.333   0.905   138.170   3.839   37.323
Kenya             18.646   0.322    90.669   5.690   71.687
Lesotho            5.164   8.668    99.896   5.184   34.816
Madagascar        19.576   0.510    87.634   4.844   75.066
Malawi             0.323   0.755   131.729   5.020   62.919
Mali               2.376   1.339   113.187   5.590   58.877
Mauritania         5.474   2.939    94.508   4.765   44.990
Mauritius          1.550   0.864    90.701   6.502   41.641
Mozambique        27.515   2.321   162.758   5.299   66.418
Namibia           25.670   0.825    93.283   5.587   43.903
Niger              5.470   0.418   158.191   5.191   71.463
Nigeria          342.246   2.926    97.088   4.363   86.378
Rwanda             1.410   0.541    78.835   5.130   61.746
Senegal           24.882   0.830   144.339   5.153   65.862
Sierra Leone       0.772   0.436   103.278   4.511   69.168
South Africa     158.111   0.530   106.502   5.939   83.777
Sudan             38.302   1.370   118.640   4.356   73.781
Swaziland          3.440   4.706    99.313   5.130   36.501
Togo               6.777   1.527   104.470   4.916   53.330
Tunisia          184.406   2.139   106.041   5.484   55.329
Uganda             2.672   1.255   169.218   4.147   78.855
Zimbabwe          32.222   0.600    94.750   4.578   67.976

Country-Name       INY

Algeria          1877.760
Benin             298.331
Botswana         1242.416
Burkina Faso      200.094
Cameroon          747.953
Cape Verde        681.447
Comoros           422.229
Congo, Rep.      1217.315
Cote d'Ivoire     849.253
Egypt, Arab       952.812
  Rep.
Ethiopia          103.111
Gabon            4670.099
Gambia, The       328.563
Ghana             203.932
Guinea-Bissau     161.847
Kenya             423.011
Lesotho           301.762
Madagascar        297.393
Malawi            152.528
Mali              202.367
Mauritania        352.259
Mauritius        1666.669
Mozambique        158.910
Namibia          1940.005
Niger             222.918
Nigeria           350.663
Rwanda            283.166
Senegal           414.549
Sierra Leone      314.398
South Africa     3436.783
Sudan             281.070
Swaziland         947.317
Togo              304.277
Tunisia          1377.847
Uganda            177.806
Zimbabwe          620.412


References

Adams, Richard H., 1991, "The Effects of International Remittances on Poverty, Inequality, and Development in Egypt," IFPRI Research Report 86 (Washington, IFPRI).

--, 2006, "Remittances and Poverty in Ghana" World Bank Policy Research Paper 3838, (Washington: World Bank).

Aretlano, M. and S. Bond, 1991, "Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations," Review of Economic' Studies, 58, 277-297.

Azam, J. and F. Gubert, 2005. "Migrant Remittances and Economic Development in Africa: A Review of Evidence," IDEI Working Papers 354, Institut d'Economie Industrielle (IDEI), Toulouse.

Barro, R.J., 1990, "Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth," Journal of Political Economy, 98: S103-25.

Barro, R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martin, 1992, "Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth," Review of Economic Studies, 54:646-61.

Barro, R., 1991, "Economic Growth in Cross-Section of Countries," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(May): 407-443.

Beck, T., R. Levine, and N. Loayza, 2000, Finance and Sources of Economic Growth," Journal Financial Economics, 58: 263-300.

Blomstrom, Mangnus, Richard Lipsey, and Mario Zejan, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111 (1): 269-276.

Boone, Peter, 1994, "The Impact of Foreign Aid on Savings and Growth," Center Economic Performance, Working Paper, London School of Economics, No. 677, 1994.

Casseli, Francesco, Gerardo Esuivel, and Fernando Lefort, 1996, "Reopening the Convergence Debate: A New Look at Cross-country Growth empirics," Journal of Economic Growth, 1 (September): 363-389.

Chenery, H.B. and A. Strout, 1966, "Foreign Assistance and Economic Development," American Economic Review, 56 (September): 679-733.

de Mello, L.R., 1999, "Foreign Direct Investmentled Growth: Evidence from Time Series Panel Data," Oxford Economic Papers, 51 (1): 133-151.

Denison, E.F., 1967, Why Growth Rates Differ: Post-War Experience for Nine Western Countries, Washington: DC.

Easterly, William and Ross Levine, 1997, "Africa's Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 1203- 1250.

--, 2001, The Elusive Quest for Growth, The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Fields, G.S., 1980, Poverty, Inequality, and Development, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, England.

Giuliano, P. and M. Ruiz-Arranz, 2006, "Remittances, Financial Development, and Growth," IMF Working Papers, WP/05/234, ftp://repec. iza.org/RePEc/Discussionpaper/p2160.pdf

Gupta, Sanjeev, Catherine Pattillo, and Smita Wagh, 2007, "Making Remittances Work for Africa," Finance & Development, 44, No. 2 (June, 2007): 1-9.

Hansen, H. and J. Rand, 2006, "On the Causal Links Between FDI and Growth in Developing Countries," http://www.blackwell-synergy.com/ doi/pdf/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2006.00756.x

Harris, J.R.M. Todaro, 1970, "Migration, Employment, and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis, American Economic Review, 60 (March): 126-142.

Heller, P., 1975, "A Model of Public Fiscal Behavior in Developing Countries: Aid Investment and Taxation," American Economic Review, 65: 429-445.

Islam, N. 1992, "Foreign Aid and Economic Growth: An Econometric Study of Bangladesh," Applied Economics, 24:541-544.

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi, 2007, "Governance Matters VI:

Governance Indicators for 1996-2006," (July 2007), World Bank Policy Research, Washington, DC.

King, R. and R. Levine, 1993, "Finance, Entrepreneurship, and Growth," Journal of Monetary Economics, 32:513-542.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, R. Vishny, 1997, "Legal Determinants of External Finance," Journal of Finance, American Finance Association, 52(3): 1131-1150.

Levine, Roos, and David Renelt, 1992, "A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country growth Regressions," American Economic review, 82, (September): 942-963.

Levy, Victor, 1987, "Aid and economic growth in the sub- Saharan: Africa: The recent experience," European Economic Review, 32; 1777-1795.

Lewis, A.W., 1954, "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor," Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 22, (May): 139-191.

Loser, C., C. Lockwood, A. Minson, and L. Balcazar, 2006, "The Macro-Economic Impact of Remittances in Latin America- Dutch Disease or Latin Cure?" http://www.g24.org/lose0906.pdf

Lueth, E. and M. Ruiz-Arranz, 2006, "A Gravity Model of Workers' Remittances." IMF WorkingPaper WP/06/290, www.imf.org/external/ pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp06290.

Lucas, R.E., 1988, "On Mechanics of Economic Growth," Journal of monetary Economics, 22 (July): 3-42.

Myrdal, G. 1968, Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations, (New York: Twentieth Century Fund).

Owens, E., 1987, The Future of Freedom in the Developing World, Pergamon Press.

Papanek, Gustav, 1973, "Aid, Foreign Private Investment, Savings, and Growth in Less Developing Countries," Journal of Political Economy, 81: 120-130.

Romer, P., 1986, "Increasing Returns and LongRun Growth," Journal of Political Economy, (October): 1002-1037.

Ruiz-Arranz, M., 2006, "Boosting economic growth." Institute of Development Studies http ://www.id21 .org/insight s/insight s60/art03. html

Sander, C., 2004, "Capturing a Market Share? Migrant Remittances and Money Transfers as a Microfinance Service in Sub-Saharan Africa," Small Enterprise Development, 15 (March 2004): 20-34.

Schultz, T.W., 1980, "The Economics of Being Poor," Journal of political Economy, (August): 639-651.

Sen, A., 1999, Development as Freedom, Alfred Knopf Publisher (New York: NY).

Solow, R., 1956, "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(February): 65-94.

Stahl, Charles W. and Fred Arnold, 1986, "Overseas Workers' Remittances in Asian Development," International Migration Review, 20(4): 899-925.

Temple, J.R.W., 1999, "The New Growth Evidence," Journal of" Economic Literature, 37 (March 1999): 112-156.

World Bank, 2006, Global Economic Prospects: Economic Implications and Migration, Washington: DC.

Notes

(1.) We planned to use data for all African countries, however, only 36 countries had data for the variables employed by this study for the time period under consideration.

(2.) Our specification in Eq(1) is based on the empirics in the new growth theory (Lucas, 1988; Barro, 1990; Benhabib and Spiegel, 1994; Grossman and Helpman, 1991; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1992b; Barro and Lee, 1994; and Temple, 1999).

(3.) Whereas La Porta et al. (1997) looked at the "ease of doing business" and how "investor protection" impact capital markets, we use a more general measure of economic freedom (Economic Freedom of the World data) which range from 1-10 with higher numbers indicating more freedom.

Bichaka Fayissa, Corresponding Author: Department of Economics and Finance, Middle Tennessee State University, Murfreesboro, TN 37132, USA, Tel: (615) 898-2385, Fax: (615) 898-5596, Email: bfayissa@mtsu.edu

Christian Nsiah, Department of Accounting and Economics, Black Hills State University, Spearfish, SD-57799, USA, Tel (605) 642-6286, Email: ChristianNsiah@bhsu.edu
TABLE 1.
Variable Description and Source Information

Variable   Description

GDPPC      Gross domestic product per capita, measured
           in constant (2000) US dollars. From the 2007
           World Development Indicators Data Set.

REM        Per capita workers' remittances and
           compensation of employees, received (nominal
           US dollars). From the 2007 World Development
           Indicators Data Set.

ENR        Gross enrollment rate secondary and tertiary
           (%c of gross). From the 2007 World
           Development Indicators Data Set.

GCF        Gross fixed capital formation as a % of
           gross domestic product. From the 2007 World
           Development Indicators Data Set.

AID        Total Official Development Assistance
           (Millions $) includes grants or loans which
           are: (a) undertaken by the official sector;
           (b) with promotion of economic development
           and welfare as the main objective; (c) at
           concessional financial terms (if a loan, have
           a grant element of at least 25 per cent).
           From the United Nations Conference on Trade
           and Development (UNCTAD) Handbook of
           Statistics.

OFI        Other Official Flows (Millions $) are
           transactions by the official sector whose
           main objective is other than development
           motivated, or, if development motivated,
           whose grant element is below the 25%
           threshold which would make them eligible to
           be recorded as ODA. The main classes of
           transactions included here are official
           export credits, official sector equity and
           portfolio investment, and debt reorganization
           undertaken by the official sector at
           non-concessional terms (irrespective of the
           nature or the identity of the original
           creditor). From the United Nations Conference
           on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Handbook of
           Statistics.

FDI        Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of
           GDP). From the 2007 World Development
           Indicators Data Set

TOT        Net barter terms of trade (2000 = 100). From
           the 2007 World Development Indicators Data
           Set.

EFI        Economic Freedom Index obtained from Economic
           Freedom of the World project data the ranges
           from 1 to 10 with higher numbers denoting
           more freedom. It is designed to measure the
           consistency of a nation's institutions and
           policies with economic freedom. From the
           Fraser Institute.

TFP        Total factor productivity, measured as the
           log of GDP divided by the product of labor
           force and gross capital formation. From the
           2007 World Development Indicators Data Set.

INY        Initial Per Capita Income (GDPPC 198(1)
           measured in constant U.S. dollars. From the
           2007 World Development Indicators Data Set.

TABLE 2.
Descriptive Statistics

Variable     Mean   Std. Dev.      Min       Max

GDPPC      828.25      950.83    85.79   4670.10
REM         27.72       48.46     0.00    250.01
ENR         36.63       25.06     5.85    117.11
GCF         20.86        7.84     4.84     59.00
AID        352.44      407.51     0.01   3817.46
OFI         48.91      158.25     0.00   1096.55
FDI          1.52        2.77     0.00     26.75
TOT        111.26       37.38    44.40    320.94
EFI          5.09        0.78     2.89      7.43
EFI         59.63       17.44    26.44    117.48
INY        777.82      926.49   103.11   4670.10

Notes: All data are transformed into logs for our analysis.
Data is averaged over 5 year periods between 1980
and 2004 for 36 countries.

TABLE 3.
Results for Random Effects and Quasi-Fixed Effects Models

                Model 1                      Model 2

Variables       Whole-Sample   Sub-Sample    Whole Sample   Sub-Sample

Constant         -0.664 **      -0.619 *      -0.786 **      -0.726 *
                 (0.333)        (0.338)       (0.373)        (0.377)

REM               0.039 ***      0.042 ***     0.037 ***      0.039 ***
                 (0.008)        (0.008)       (0.011)        (0.011)

ENR               0.111 ***      0.115 ***     0.109 ***      0.113 ***
                 (0.032)        (0.032)       (0.040)        (0.041)

GCF               0.174 **       0.177 **      0.211 ***      0.196 **
                 (0.075)        (0.081)       (0.075)        (0.082)

AID              -0.022 ***     -0.024 **     -0.028 **      -0.028 **
                 (0.010)        (0.010)       (0.012)        (0.013)

OFI               0.007          0.009         0.007          0.009
                 (0.006)        (0.006)       (0.009)        (0.009)

FDI               0.007          0.006         0.003          0.002
                 (0.013)        (0.014)       (0.010)        (0.010)

TOT               0.053          0.050         0.052          0.052
                 (0.042)        (0.042)       (0.049)        (0.049)

EFI               0.155 *        0.162 *       0.185 *        0.189 *
                 (0.091)        (0.092)       (0.109)        (0.110)

TFP               0.011          0.011         0.015 *        0.014
                 (0.007)        (0.007)       (0.008)        (0.009)

INY               0.857 ***      0.846 ***     0.849 ***      0.843 ***
                 (0.027)        (0.030)       (0.035)        (0.037)

Number of       180            170           180            170
Observations

Number of        36             34            36             34
countries

R-Squared         0.980          0.981         0.979          0.981

Notes: Model 1 presents estimates for the quasi-fixed model with
panel specific heteroskedasticity corrected standard errors;
Model 2 presents estimates for random effects with bootstrap
standard errors; The sub-sample leaves out Lesotho, and Cape
Verde. The standard Errors In Parenthesis; and * indicate
significance at p < 0.01, p < 0.05, and p < 0.1 levels,
respectively.

TABLE 4.
Arellano-Bond Dynamic Panel-Data Estimation-Results

                            (1)             (2)
                       Whole Sample     Sub Sample
                         Estimates       Estimates
                       (One-Step and   (One-Step and
Variables              One-Year Lag)   One-Year Lag)

GDP (LD)                 0.8671 ***      0.8698 ***
                        (0.0120)        (0.0110)

REM (D(1))               0.0050 **       0.0060 ***
                        (0.0022)        (0.0019)

ENR (D(1))               0.0077 ***      0.0064 ***
                        (0.0025)        (0.0012)

ENR(LD)                  0.0053 ***      0.006l ***
                        (0.0014)        (0.0020)

GCF (D(1))               0.0165 ***      0.0131 *
                        (0.0060)        (0.0074)

AID (D(l))               0.0009 *        0.0006
                        (0.0005)        (0.0006)

OFI (1)(1))             -0.0003 **       0.0000
                        (0.0001)        (0.0001)

OFI (LD)                 0.0006 ***      0.0006 ***
                        (0.0001)        (0.0001)

FDI (D(1))              -0.0012         -0.0010
                        (0.0008)        (0.0003)

FDI (LD)                 0.00121 ***     0.0002 ***
                        (0.0003)        (0.0002)

TOT (D(l))               0.0247 ***      0.0271 ***
                        (0.0050)        (0.0027)

EFI (D(1))               0.07021 ***     0.0684 ***
                        (0.0108)        (0.0052)

PRO (D(1))               0.0023 ***      0.0025 ***
                        (0.0006)        (0.0007)

Constant                 0.6039436       0.6979399
                        (0.4165)        (0.4389)

Number of              900             850
Observations

Number of               36              34
Countries

Arellano-Bond Test      -2.279 **       -2.412 **
of the null of No
AR(1) Residual
Errors

Arellano-Bond test       0.651           1.401
of the null of No
AR(2) Residual
Errors

Sargan Test of the      22.072          17.258
Validity of the null
of over-identifying
Restrictions

Notes: Standard Errors In Parenthesis; ***, **, and * indicate
significance at 1) < 0.01, h < 0.05, and h < 0.1 levels,
respectively. While the suffix D(1) after each variable denotes
the number of times the specific variable was  differenced. LD
denotes the lagged difference. The variable ENR is treated as
predetermined, while FDI and OFI  are treated as endogenous
variables. The sub-sample model excludes the countries of Lesotho
and Cape Verde.

FIGURE 1. International Capital Flows to Africa.

Millions of Dollars

Workers Remittances                 1994    2004
Foreign Direct Investment           1994    2004
Official Development Assistance     1994    2004

Source: World Development Indicators Dataset 2007, and
UNCTAD Handbook of Statistics

Note: Table made from bar graph.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有