首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月25日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Does inequality matter for poverty reduction? Evidence from Pakistan's poverty trends.
  • 作者:Jamal, Haroon
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2006
  • 期号:September
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics

Does inequality matter for poverty reduction? Evidence from Pakistan's poverty trends.


Jamal, Haroon


1. INTRODUCTION

Inequality has been brought out of the cold and now has re-entered the mainstream development policy agenda in many developing countries. This is the consequence of a deep-rooted disillusionment with the development paradigm which placed exclusive emphasis on the pursuit of growth. Growth-optimists believe in "trickle-down" (1), i.e. the notion that growth in average incomes automatically sinks down to and benefit the poor. However, the premise of 'trickle-down' that higher investment would alleviate poverty through higher employment and real wages did not work. In many situations the pro-growth development agenda was accompanied by rising inequality.

During the 1990s, the proliferation of quality data on income distribution from a number of countries has allowed rigorous empirical testing of standing debates on the relative importance of growth and redistribution in poverty reduction. While the debate is still inconclusive, the majority of development economists emphasised, based on empirical cross-country data, that an unequal income distribution is a serious impediment to effective poverty alleviation [Ravallion (1997)]. Many researchers suggested that growth is, in practice the main tool for fighting poverty. However, they also reiterated that the imperative of growth for combating poverty should not be misinterpreted to mean that "growth is all that matters". Growth is a necessary condition for poverty alleviation, no doubt, but inequality also matters and should also be on the development agenda.

The purpose of this paper is to supplement the debate by providing empirical evidence from Pakistan's poverty trends. The paper estimates the poverty elasticity with respect to growth and inequality. It also explores the macroeconomic and structural proximate determinants of inequality. Section 2 presents a short review of research conducted during last two decades on poverty, inequality and growth. However, the focus of this section is to highlight the links of inequality with growth and poverty. Previous attempts to model poverty trends in Pakistan are summarised in Section 3. The methodology used for this research is also furnished in this section. Traditionally, Household Income and Expenditure Surveys (HIES) are used to compute poverty and inequality in Pakistan. Comparable poverty figures (headcount) are available upto 1992-93 based on consistent methodology. Using the same methodology, this consistent series is updated upto 2001-02. Household surveys are not conducted regularly; therefore to fill the gap interpolation is necessary. The estimated and interpolated series of headcount and Gini coefficients are provided in Section 4. Empirical findings are presented in Section 5, while the last section gives concluding remarks.

2. RELEVANCE OF INEQUALITY FOR GROWTH AND POVERTY REDUCTION

Income inequality (2) and poverty affect each other directly and indirectly through their link with economic growth. These interact with one another through a set of two-way links (see Figure 1). Some of these links can be explored separately, but often one influences another causing indirect effects. For instance inequality can indirectly influence poverty as inequality affects growth and growth in turn influences poverty.

Small changes in income distribution can have a large effect on poverty. A simple arithmetic example can help visualize this. Imagine that the share of national income that goes to the poorest 20 percent of the population of Pakistan increases from 7 percent to 7.25 percent. A change in income distribution of one quarter of one percent would barely affect the Gini coefficient, but for the poor this represents about 4 percent increase in their total income. Such a small redistribution would have the same effect on poverty as doubling the annual growth (distribution neutral) of national income from 4 percent to 8 percent.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Cross-country studies have argued that, on average, within country inequality is stable over time, or changes too slowly to make a significant difference in poverty reduction [Deininger and Squire (1998)]. Recent country and regional studies have looked beyond the 'average' and refuted the initial cross-country evidence. Large distributional changes can occur even over relatively short periods of time--for example, in sub-Saharan African; in Latin America where income distribution improved during the expansion in the 1970s and deteriorated during the recession of the 1980s; in China; and, in the transition economies of Eastern Europe and Central Asia over the 1990s. While the rapid increase in inequality in the latter region is a special case, it very much confirms the importance of distribution changes for poverty reduction. Gini coefficients for the majority of these countries increased by between 5 and 20 percentage points, in some by even more than that, greatly exacerbating the effects of negative growth on poverty [Kanbur and Lustig (1999)]. Policies and growth patterns that improve distribution are, therefore, a potentially significant additional tool in the fight against poverty. Past changes in distribution occurred without active policy intervention, as the focus of development policy and research was on growth, rather than distribution issues. If, in future, development policy makes inequality an explicit target, it will greatly enhance the poverty reducing effect of growth. Of course the big question is how best to improve the distribution of income?

In addition to its direct effect on poverty, inequality also affects poverty indirectly through its impact on growth. A resurgence of work on inequality in the 1990s has reconfirmed the classical view that distribution is not only a final outcome, but also a determinant of economic growth. Initial cross-country studies, including Birdsall, et al. (1995), found that greater initial income inequality actually reduces future growth even after controlling for initial levels of GDP and human capital. The robustness of these findings has been the subject of much debate, (3) however recent analysis using an updated and more comparable inequality data reconfirms the negative effects of inequality on growth [Knowles (2001)]. Low inequality can, therefore, benefit the poor in two ways: by increasing overall growth and average incomes, and by letting them share more in that growth.

Is there any inherent link in the other direction--from growth to inequality? The seminal Kuznets hypothesis predicted increases in inequality during early periods of growth and reduction in inequality during subsequent periods [Kuznets (1955)]. However, the recent evidence has rejected this pattern. Deininger and Squire (1996, 1998), for example, detect no statistically significant link between income and distribution in 80 percent of cases, with the rest being evenly split between a positive and a negative effect. They confirmed their findings using a larger cross-country data set.

Only in Eastern Europe and Central Asia has there been a significant positive correlation (though not necessarily causality) between incomes and inequality, but this was during a period of negative growth coinciding with increasing inequality--the structural transformation in this region clearly makes it a special case. The consensus is that inequality is no more likely to rise than it is to fall in periods of economic growth and increasing inequality is not an inevitable consequence of early growth. It is not the rate of economic growth or the stage of economic development but the kind of economic growth which affects inequality. Overall, there is no trade-off per se between growth and inequality, so distribution can be pursued as an additional policy objective to enhance the poverty reducing effect of growth. In countries where distortions are causing inequalities, distribution policies would have a doubly beneficial effect on poverty reduction. However, in other countries where distortions have kept inequalities low there is likely to be a trade-off between distribution and growth. There is a gap in current knowledge about which countries fall into which category and, where appropriate, about how to make tradeoffs to maximize poverty reduction.

Another avenue of the recent research is to determine the relative importance of growth and inequality in reducing poverty. The major empirical finding is that "overall the growth effect dominates". However, this is not true in all cases or for all groups of countries. Inequality has been more important in reducing poverty than growth in a quarter of the case studies cited in White and Anderson (2001). The dominance of growth overall may also be partly due to the growth focus of policies over the last 20 years and the weight given to cross-country studies looking at average effects across countries (the lack of time-series analysis has largely been due to insufficient data over time). Arguably there is unused potential for reducing poverty in implementing distribution policies.

Further, growth is less effective in reducing poverty in high inequality countries. This should come as no surprise as what matters for poverty reduction is not the rate of growth, but the distribution-corrected rate of growth [Ravallion (2001)]. In some high inequality countries, particularly those with low rates of growth, this means that changes in income distribution may be more effective in reducing poverty than growth.

To recap the above discussion regarding the relevance of re-distribution for growth and poverty reduction, the following major conclusions (4) emerge, based on cross-country research during last decade:

* Poverty and inequality are intrinsically linked. Poverty reduction--especially for the poorest--can be greatly enhanced through distributional policies. All the evidence confirms that distribution is central to fighting poverty. Distribution objectives should be an integral part of the poverty reduction agenda.

* There is no inevitable trade-off between equity and efficiency. On the contrary growth and better distribution are complementary, rather than competing objectives in the fight against poverty. More equal distribution of income and assets can foster growth, whereas high inequality can retard it. Thus, reducing inequalities can be doubly beneficial for the poor.

* Distribution policies should be pursued (a) where they remove redundant/dysfunctional inequalities, and (b) in countries where the inequality effect on poverty is greater than the growth effect.

* The relative importance of growth and distribution varies across countries. The growth effect dominates in the majority of cases, but in a significant number of cases distribution can have a larger impact.

* Small changes in distribution can have a very large effect on poverty reduction. There are cases where inequality levels have changed relatively quickly. Moreover, the lack of knowledge of the determinants of inequalities and the relative neglect of distribution issues in recent decades may mean that there is untapped potential for reducing poverty through distribution changes.

* It is not possible to separate poverty and inequality. No commonly used measure of poverty is entirely absolute. The difference lies in the extent to which they incorporate relative measures. The choice of poverty measure, therefore, makes an implicit judgment about how much the poor should benefit from increases in national income. Development policy could make this explicit, even if it stops short of an internationally accepted standard for income distribution.

* Knowledge of the effects of non-income dimensions of inequality is very limited and the evidence somewhat anecdotal. Even the determinants of income inequality are insufficiently understood. There is a need for further country-based work on the nature, extent and determinants of various dimensions of inequality, and their effects on different dimensions of poverty.

3. MODELING PAKISTAN'S POVERTY TRENDS

The first attempt to explain poverty trends in Pakistan with the help of macro determinants was made by Amjad and Kemal (1997). They operationalised various macro explanations of poverty into observed variables and empirically tested a prior impact of macro policies on poverty in Pakistan. Given the very small number of observations the authors employed simple one variable regression. Using a double log transformation they regressed one exogenous variable at a time on poverty incidence (headcount) series. Real per capita GNP, real remittances per capita, real wages in manufacturing, total labour force as percent of total population and real subsidies per capita were statistically significant and had the expected signs.

Using simple econometric techniques Akhtar and Ahmed (1999) extended the work of Amjad and Kemal (1997) conceptually and empirically to a multi-variable framework and quantified relative contribution of various correlates in explaining trends in overall poverty in Pakistan. They concluded that the estimates of various versions of the reduced multi-variate model on explaining poverty trends during 1979-93 confirm that per capita income, remittances, and unemployment not only impact independently, but also impact jointly. In addition they verified that inflation in food prices exacerbates poverty. The household endowment, proxied at macro level by aggregate human capital index, in explaining poverty trends is also tested and found statistically significant. They estimated that one percent increase in income will result in a 1.58 percent decline in poverty incidence.

The previous attempts to model Pakistan's poverty trends did not incorporate the dependence of poverty on the degree of inequality. It is fairly well-known that the poverty elasticity of growth depends on the specific poverty measure being used [Kakwani (1993)], the degree of inequality of the income distribution [Ravallion (1997)] as well as the specific characteristics of growth episodes (inequality increasing or decreasing). Therefore, this paper proposes that the degree of poverty in any given country depends upon two factors: the average income level of the country and the extent of income inequality. Formally,

P = f(Y, L(p)) (1)

Where P is a poverty measure, Y is per capita income and L(p) is the Lorenz curve measuring the relative income distribution.

Changes in poverty can be decomposed into a growth component and an inequality component. In general, increases in average income (growth) will reduce poverty. Thus, denoting by [lambda] the growth elasticity of poverty one could write:

[lambda] = [[partial derivativeP/[partial derivative]Y * Y/P] < 0 (2)

Measuring the effect on inequality on poverty is slightly more complex because inequality can change in an infinite number of ways. It is difficult to say anything general about the growth-poverty relationship when the distribution is allowed to change during growth. Although intuitively progressive distributional change is likely to reduce poverty, this rest, It cannot be generalised without additional assumption regarding the distribution. Kakwani (1993) developed a formula for the inequality elasticity of poverty under the assumption of an equal proportionate change in the Lorenz curve. Under this assumption it is possible to express the inequality elasticity of poverty co as the elasticity of poverty with respect to the Gini index G:

[omega] = [[partial derivative]P/[partial derivative]G * G/P] > 0 (3)

This framework may be used to observe the impact of macroeconomic policies on poverty and inequality. Formally one can write,

dP/dX X/P = dY/dX X/Y x [lambda] + dG/dX X/G x [omega] (4)

Equation (4) reads that the impact that a change in policy X will have on poverty will depend on: (i) the impact that the policy has on growth; (ii) how growth is translated into poverty reduction; (iii) the simultaneous impact that the policy has on inequality, and finally (iv) how inequality changes are translated into poverty reduction.

Since the purpose of this paper is to estimate poverty elasticity and not to analyse the impact of various policies on poverty reduction, the analysis is restricted to estimating Equation (1) with the following specification,

Log (Headcount) = [alpha] + [lambda] Log (Per Capita GDP) + [omega] Log (Gini) + [mu] (5)

However, an attempt is also made to explain the variation in inequality with the help of various macroeconomic and structural policies. Besides income (per capita GDP), following determinants were considered in modelling inequality.

There is widespread consensus that macroeconomic stability is a prerequisite for pro-poor growth. In particular, it has been found repeatedly that high inflation (particularly above a level of about 10 percent) hurts the poor and economic growth. Low inflation rate is considered a good indicator for macroeconomic stabilization in an economy; therefore it is included in the equation as a determinant of inequality. A negative relationship is hypothesised between development expenditure, especially on social services (as a percent of GDP) and income distribution. More public expenditure on health and education certainly increases the human capital endowment of the poor and hence affects on their empowerment. A major redistribution policy is to make the tax structure pro-poor. Therefore, it is hypothesised that there is a direct link between progressive tax structure (proxied by the rate of direct to indirect taxes) and equity. Investments, especially in infrastructure have a major impact on making economic growth pro-poor. Growth in investments is essential for reducing rate of unemployment and under-employment in the economy. Public investments by providing infrastructure play an important role in reducing poverty and increasing the share of people at the bottom of the income distribution. (5)

Two elements of economic structure are considered in the analysis: first, the manufacturing to agriculture wage (6) gap and secondly, the manufacturing to agriculture terms of trade. (7) Keeping the economic structure of the country in view, it is expected that the increase in these ratios will worsen the income distribution and will have a positive relationship with the Gini coefficient.

4. GENERATING AN INTERPOLATED POVERTY SERIES

Malik (1988) generated five poverty observations during the period 1963-64 to 1984-85 based on household surveys. They have applied a consistent methodology (8) to compute poverty lines for these particular years. Amjad and Kemal (1999) inflated the poverty line for 1984-85 by the consumer price index and using the same methodology added three more observations for the years 1987-88, 1990-91 and 1992-93. Three more observations were added for the year 1996-97, 1998-99 and 2001-02 by this author. Consumer prices indices are used to inflate the poverty line and poverty incidences were estimated using the same methodology for these years. These estimates along with the Gini coefficients (9) and share of bottom 20 percent of population in national income are reported in Table 1.

A simple interpolation technique is to take the decline or growth in trend between two points in time and fill the data gaps between successive observations. However, a slightly more sophisticated method is applied to generate an interpolated series for poverty and inequality measures. (10) A quadratic curve was fitted on the actual observations by regressing log of poverty measure (or log of Gini coefficient) on time and time square variables. The estimated series for poverty incidence (headcount) and Gini coefficient are provided in Annexure (Table B-l, Appendix - B) and are also plotted in the following Figure 2.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

5. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS

The following three tables (Table 2 through Table 4) summarise the main findings of this study. Detail results (11) and summary statistics of various equations are provided in the annexure (Table B-2 through Table B-9, Appendix - B).

For the purpose of comparison with earlier research, poverty is regressed, first on growth and some other explanatory variables. This specification did not incorporate inequality explicitly in the equation. The growth elasticity estimate from this specification (12) turned out to be -2.1 (Table 2) as against -1.6 of Akhtar and Ahmed (1999). Apparently, it is due to the inclusion of new data and also because of different exogenous variables.

Table 2 also presents the estimates of poverty elasticity (Equation 5) with respect to growth and inequality. The equation is estimated with two different methods: OLS (13) and 2SLS, (14) treating inequality both as an exogenous variable and as a pre-detennined variable. Interestingly, both methods estimated very similar magnitudes for poverty elasticity with respect to per capita GDP (-3.51 versus -3.54) and Gini (8.37 versus 8.44).

A few observations emerge from Table 2. First, the magnitude of inequality elasticity measures is quite high as compared with the growth (per capita GDP) elasticity. Second, the magnitude of poverty elasticity of growth is more than doubled as compared with the earlier research. (15) This is partly due to inclusion of new data and partly because of ignoring the dependence of poverty on inequality in earlier attempts. Third, the poverty elasticity is sensitive with the choice of inequality measure. The growth, as well as inequality, elasticity reduces if the share of bottom 20 percent is replaced with Gini coefficient. The results seem plausible. The cross-country research indicates that lower growth elasticity is associated with higher inequality. Similar phenomenon is, perhaps working here. To address the lower tail of distribution, relatively high elasticity of growth is required.

As for the empirical model for inequality (Gini coefficient), Table 3 presents (16) the elasticities with respect to various macroeconomic and structural variables. Food prices are dominating in term of elasticity and are highly significant. Progressive taxation and development expenditure on social services also appear as important determinants of inequality. The magnitude of the effect of development expenditure is, however quite low. Public investment is considered pro-poor by directly providing employment through public works and indirectly crowding-in private investment. However, it did not appear as statistically significant. Total investment, (17) therefore tried and it turned out an important determinant. The negative relationship between inequality and investment demands further assessment and research, as it is expected that the investment (especially private investment) in Pakistan works as an instrument for raising inequality. One possible explanation however, lies in the argument that informal economy is pro-cyclical with respect to trends in investment. This would imply that during period of higher investment and growth of the formal economy, the informal economy would also exhibit higher growth. Informal economy, in fact is supposed to be pro-poor as it provides unskilled jobs.

Two proxies for structural elements were incorporated in modelling inequality, i.e. manufacturing to agriculture wage gap and manufacturing to agriculture terms of trade. Both turned out significant and exhibited a positive relationship with inequality. Their significant clearly indicates rural versus urban income disparities and highlights the need for policy intervention in agriculture sector and rural economy.

The positive relationship between average income (per capita GDP) and level of inequality (Gini coefficient) again confirms some of the cross-country research that higher growth is accompanied with higher inequality. The seminal Kuznets hypothesis is therefore tested (18) by incorporating the square term of per capita GDP in the Gini equation. The coefficients associated with per capita GDP and the square of per capita GDP were not statistically significant. However, the negative sign of square term did indicate an inverted U-shaped curve.

Another inequality measure (share of bottom 20 percent of population) is modelled with the same explanatory variables. The results (19) are displayed in Table 4. Except the income (GDP per capita) variable, all variables exhibited the similar trends. Income did not turn out as statistically significant. Again, the findings are plausible. Average growth is distributional neutral and explicit distribution policies are required to address the poor 20 percent population.

6. CONCLUDING REMARKS

Poverty reduction has always been a priority of development policy, albeit sometime only at the rhetorical level. The end of the 1990s brought increased emphasis on bringing the benefits of growth to the poor. However, growth alone is a rather blunt instrument for poverty reduction, since the consensus of empirical work suggests that it is distribution neutral. Along with emphasis on poverty reduction, a shift occurred in the policy literature towards a moire favourable view of policies to redistribute income and assets. An integration of distributional concerns and a priority on poverty reduction could be the basis for a new policy agenda to foster growth with equity.

This paper highlights the importance of distribution policies in poverty reduction using Pakistan poverty trends during the period 1979 to 2002. Summing up, the conclusions of this research are the following: First, the poverty elasticity with respect to various inequality measures is statistically significant and also the magnitude is relatively high as compared with poverty elasticity of growth. Second, as compared with earlier efforts in Pakistan, the magnitude of poverty elasticity of growth is quite high. This is partly due to inclusion of new data and partly because of ignoring the dependence of poverty on inequality in earlier attempts. Third, the study found inflation, sectoral wage gap, and terms of trade in favour of manufacturing as the significant positive correlates of inequality, while progressive taxation, investment and development expenditure on social services are negatively impacting on inequality.

Finally, it is true that redistribution often has limited potential and that growth is a necessary condition for poverty reduction. Yet the level of inequality and change therein, still matters. This is because the level of inequality affects the degree of poverty as well as growth elasticity of poverty. Further, low level of inequality contributes for an acceleration of poverty reduction for a given level of growth. For these reasons, inequality still matters, and the search for effective policies for reducing inequality, or at least prevent them from rising, should be an integral part of the development agenda.

Appendices

APPENDIX- A

SENSITIVITY OF INTERPOLATION TECHNIQUES Poverty and inequality are estimated from occasional household surveys, therefore smoothing is not irrational to control, for instance exceptionally good or bad survey years in terms of national growth.

Three interpolation techniques (Linear, Exponential Growth and Quadratic) were applied to check the robustness and sensitivity of poverty and inequality measures. The summary results of these models (regression equations) for poverty measures are furnished below. For visual demonstration of proximity, the predicted values are also plotted vis-a-vis the observed poverty figures in Chart-A1.

Clearly the values predicted through quadratic model are very close to the observed poverty figures. It is also plausible to argue that the predicted poverty incidences with 0.9 adjusted [R.sup.2] will produce alike correlation with the other economic variables. Following charts, which show the relationship between actual and predicted poverty with GDP growth confirm this hypothesis.

[GRAPHIC OMITTED]

[GRAPHIC OMITTED]

Instrumental Variables (for Tables B-8, B-9, and B-10):

GDP Per capita

Inflation (Food)

Wage Gap

Direct to Indirect Tax Ratio

Development Expenditure on Social Services

Investment.

Terms of Trade

Dummy Variable (i 985, 1986,1987,1988 = 1)

Constant

REFERENCES

Adams, R. H. Jr. (2004) Economic Growth, Inequality and poverty: Estimating the Growth Elasticity of Poverty. World Development 32:12, 1989-2014, December.

Akhtar, Sajjad, and Mansoor Ahmed (1999) Modelling Poverty Trends in Pakistan: Some additional Empirical Evidence. Social Policy and Development Centre, Karachi. (Social Policy and Development Centre Research Report Number 27.)

Amjad, Rashid, and Abdul Razzaq Kemal (1997) Macroeconomic Policies and their Impact on Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 36:1, 39-68.

Birdsall, Nancy, David Ross, and Richard Sabot R. (1995) Inequality and Growth Reconsidered: Lessons from East Asia. World Bank Economic Review 9:3, 477-508.

Deininger, Klaus, and Lyn Squire (1996) A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality. World Bank Economic Review 10:3, 565-91.

Deininger, Klaus, and Lyn Squire (1998) New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality and Growth. Journal of Development Economics 57:2, 259-287.

Kakwani, Nanak (1993) Poverty and Economic Growth with an Application to Cote d'lvoire. Review of Income and Wealth 39:2, 121-139.

Kanbur, Ravi, and Lustig Nora (1999) Why is Inequality Back on the Agenda? Paper prepared for the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Knowles, Stephen (2001) Inequality and Economic Growth: The Empirical Relationship Reconsidered in the Light of Comparable Data. Paper for UNU/Wider Development Conference on Growth and Poverty, WIDER, Heisinki.

Kuznets, Simon (1955) Economic Growth and Income Inequality. American Economic Review 45, 1-28.

Malik, Muhammad Hussain (1988) Some New Evidence on the Incidence of Poverty in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 27:4, 509-16.

Naschold, Felix (2002) Why Inequality Matters for Poverty? UK Department for International Development (DFID), UK. (Briefing Paper No. 2.)

Ravallion, Martin (1997) Can High Inequality Developing Countries Escape Absolute Poverty? World Bank, Washington, D.C. (World Bank Working Paper No. 1775.)

Ravallion, Martin (2001) Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages. World Development 29:11, 1803-1815.

White, Howard, and Edward Anderson (2001) Growth versus Distribution: Does the Pattern of Growth Matter? Development Policy Review 19:3, 267-289.

(1) Trickle-down was the dominant development thinking in the 1950s through 1980s. It implies a vertical flow from the rich to the poor that happens on its own accord. The benefits of the economic growth go to the rich first, and then in the second round the poor begin to benefit when the rich start spending their gains. Thus, the poor benefit from economic growth only indirectly through a vertical flow from the rich. It implies that the proportional benefits of growth going to the poor will always be less.

(2) Knowledge about the links between non-income inequality and poverty remains very limited. The studies that do exist generally focus on the effect of non-income inequality on income rather than other dimensions of poverty and suggests that income inequality also acts as a proxy for asset inequality.

(3) Some critics quote the argument of trade-off between equity and efficiency. It is often hypothesised that distribution policies give rise to distortions in the economy, resulting in inefficiencies or loss of growth. Such loss of growth may be so much that the overall well-being of society falls. It is not certain that policies for equity necessarily create inefficient outcomes. The issue of trade-off is closely related to the choice of a social welfare function. If the concern is more about the well-being of the poor, then greater weight must be given to those at the bottom of the distribution than those at the top. Nevertheless, the magnitude of its impact on social welfare compared with the gains that results form improved equity needs to be assessed. It should be pointed out that the removal or correction of the various anti-poor institutional constraints and policy-induced biases might actually improve market efficiency besides promoting equity. For instance, social policy ensuring adequate provision of education and health services to the poor will improve their productivity and contribution to the economy.

(4) Reproduced from Naschold (2002).

(5) Other possible candidates for explaining inequality, like economic and food subsidies, remittances, unemployment rate etc. were also tested, hut turned out not to be statistically significant.

(6) Sectoral wage is computed as the sectoral value added divided by sectoral labour force.

(7) This is the ratio of manufacturing implicit GDP deflator to that of agriculture implicit GDP deflator.

(8) They defined a poverty line based on calorie requirement of 2550 per day plus 'other basic needs of a person'. In the estimation of the non-food consumption, he used the average ratio of food to non-food consumption of the poor.

(9) The estimates of Gini coefficients and share of bottom 20 percent are available in the Pakistan Economic Survey upto 1996-97. The author estimated these for the last two years from the raw data of household surveys.

(10) Various techniques are applied to interpolate poverty measure in order to check the robustness, sensitivity and consistency with economic growth. See the Appendix A.

(11) Although the interpolated poverty and inequality series are for the period 1973 to 2003, however due to some econometric problems equations were estimated for the period 1979 to 2002.

(12) The detail results and summary statistics for this specification are provided in annexure, Table B-2 (Appendix-B).

(13) For Gini, share of bottom 20 percent of population and quintile ratio treated as exogenous, see Tables B-3, B- 4 and B-5 respectively in the Appendix B.

(14) For Gini, share of bottom 20 percent of population and quintile ratio treated as pre-determined, see Tables B-8, B-9 and B-10 respectively in the Appendix B.

(15) Using cross-country data and dollar-a-day poverty line, Richard H. Adams recently estimated poverty elasticity as -2.79 and -2.27 for survey mean and per capita GDP respectively after controlling for changes in income inequality. For results and specification see "Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Estimating the Growth Elasticity of Poverty", World Development, December 2004, 32(12), pp. 1989-2014.

(16) Detailed results and summary statistics are provided in annexure, Table B-6 (Appendix-B).

(17) The collinearity between per capita GDP and investment is tested through Auto Regressive Conditional Hetroschadasticity (ARCH). According to the statistic. No evidence of presence of ARCH was found.

(18) Results arc not explicitly reported here.

(19) Detailed results and summary statistics are provided in annexure, Table B-7 (Appendix B).

Haroon Jamal <haroonjamal@hotmail.com> is Principal Economist, Social Policy and Development Centre, Karachi.

Author's Note: The views expressed in this paper arc those of the author and do not necessarily represent those of the Social Policy and Development Centre (SPDC). Adjusted Significance Models [R.sup.2] F-value of F-value Linear 0.20 3.037 0.125 Growth 0.11 1.978 0.202 Quadratic 0.90 37.475 0.000 APPENDIX-B Table B-1 Poverty and Inequality Trends (Interpolated) Gini Coefficient Population Below the Poverty Year (%) Line Headcount (%) 1973 30.6444 45.75 1974 31.1047 43.00 1975 3l.5586 40.41 1976 32.0062 37.98 1977 32.4473 35.71 1978 32.8821 33.60 1979 33.3105 31.65 1980 33.7325 29.86 1981 34.1482 28.23 1982 34.5575 26.76 1983 34.9603 25.45 1984 35.3569 24.30 1985 35.7470 23.31 1986 36.1307 22.47 1987 36.5081 21.80 1988 36.8791 21.29 1989 37.2438 20.94 1990 37.6020 20.74 1991 37.9539 20.71 1992 38.2994 20.84 1993 38.6385 21.13 1994 38.9712 21.57 1995 39.2976 22.18 1996 39.6175 22.94 1997 39.9312 23.87 1998 40.2384 24.96 1999 40.5392 26.20 2000 40.8337 27.61 2001 41.1218 29.17 2002 41.4035 30.90 2003 41.6788 32.78 Source: Author's Estimates (Based on Table 1 in the Text). Table B-2 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: OLS) t- Explanatory Variables Coefficient statistic Significance GDP Per Capita -2.117 -6.93 0.0000 Inflation (Food) 0.603 5.17 0.0001 Development Expenditure -0.243 -5.09 0.0001 on Social Services Private Investment -0.492 -3.30 0.0039 Direct to Indirect -0.073 -1.13 0.2693 Tax Ratio Terms of Trade 0.688 2.79 0.0120 Constant 15.49 7.13 0.0000 R-squared 0.955 F-statistic 64.95 Adjusted R-squared 0.941 Probability 0.00 (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.497 Number of 24 Observations Notes: All variables are used after Logarithmic transformation LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation Except Direct to Indirect Tax Ratio, all variables are statistically significant. Table B-3 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: OLS) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita -3.505 -12.83 GINI Coefficient 8.365 12.68 Dummy Variable (1985, -0.059 -2.95 1986, 1987,1988 =1) Constant 2.147 4.48 R-squared 0.911 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.897 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.645 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.0000 GINI Coefficient 0.0000 Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0078 1986, 1987,1988 =1) Constant 0.0002 R-squared 0.911 68.09 Adjusted R-squared 0.897 0.00 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.645 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table B-4 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: OLS) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita -2.50 -20.73 Share of Bottom 20 -6.66 -18.92 Percent of Population Dummy Variable (1985, -0.036 -2.06 1986,1987,1988=1) Constant 67.73 20.66 R-squared 0.960 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.954 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson slat 1.776 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.0000 Share of Bottom 20 0.0000 Percent of Population Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0522 1986,1987,1988=1) Constant 0.0000 R-squared 0.960 160.81 Adjusted R-squared 0.954 0.00 Durbin-Watson slat 1.776 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table B-5 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: OLS) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita -2.362 -22.40 Quintile Ratio (Top 20 3.718 20.40 Percent / Bottom 20 Percent Population) Dummy Variable (1985, -0.032 -1.99 1986,1987, 1988 =1) Constant -1.255 -2.76 R-squared 0.965 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.960 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.805 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.0000 Quintile Ratio (Top 20 0.0000 Percent / Bottom 20 Percent Population) Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0601 1986,1987, 1988 =1) Constant 0.0121 R-squared 0.965 186.53 Adjusted R-squared 0.960 0.0000 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.805 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates Table B-6 Determinant of Inequality (Dependent Variable: Gini Coefficient-Percentage) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per capita 0.081 3.59 Inflation (Food) 0.088 10.49 Wage Gap 0.023 3.71 Direct to Indirect -0.024 -5.20 Tax Ratio Development Expenditure -0.015 -2.07 on Social Services Investment -0.037 -2.35 Terms of Trade 0.046 1.90 Dummy Variable (1985, 0.006 2.78 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 2.317 14.29 R-squared 0.998 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.998 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.683 Number of Observations Significance GDP Per capita 0.0027 Inflation (Food) 0.0000 Wage Gap 0.0021 Direct to Indirect 0.0001 Tax Ratio Development Expenditure 0.0566 on Social Services Investment 0.0329 Terms of Trade 0.0768 Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0140 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 0.0000 R-squared 0.998 1543.25 Adjusted R-squared 0.998 0.00 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.683 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table B-7 Determinants of Inequality (Dependent Variable: Share of Bottom 20 Percent of Population-Percentage) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita 0.046 1.03 Inflation (Food) -0.121 -8.62 Wage Gap -0.018 -1.84 Direct to Indirect 0.027 3.85 Tax Ratio Development Expenditure 0.024 6.04 on Social Services Investment 0.051 3.65 Terms of Trade -0.078 -2.45 Dummy Variable (1985, -0.006 -2.57 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 7.054 23.71 R-squared 0.997 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.996 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.608 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.3166 Inflation (Food) 0.0000 Wage Gap 0.0837 Direct to Indirect 0.0014 Tax Ratio Development Expenditure 0.0000 on Social Services Investment 0.0021 Terms of Trade 0.0258 Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0205 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 0.0000 R-squared 0.997 926.46 Adjusted R-squared 0.996 0.000 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.608 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. Except GDP per capita, all variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table B-8 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: TSLS) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita -3.537 -13.07 GINI Coefficient 8.435 12.11 Dummy Variable (1985, -0.058 -2.31 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 2.115 3.77 R-squared 0.911 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.897 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.659 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.0000 GINI Coefficient 0.0000 Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0312 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 0.0012 R-squared 0.911 67.39 Adjusted R-squared 0.897 0.0000 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.659 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table B-9 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: TSLS) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita -2.482 -20.21 Share of Bottom 20 -6.601 -18.39 Percent of Population Dummy Variable (1985, -0.037 -2.11 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 67.136 20.09 R-squared 0.960 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.954 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.761 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.0000 Share of Bottom 20 0.0000 Percent of Population Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0473 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 0.0000 R-squared 0.960 154.14 Adjusted R-squared 0.954 0.0000 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.761 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table B-10 Determinants of Poverty Dependent Variable: Poverty Incidence (Headcount) (Method: TSLS) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic GDP Per Capita -2.344 -21.79 Quintile Ratio (Top 20 3.679 19.78 Percent / Bottom 20 Percent Population) Dummy Variable (1985, -0.033 2.05 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant -1.179 -2.55 R-squared 0.965 F-statistic Adjusted R-squared 0.960 Probability (F-statistics) Durbin-Watson Stat 1.787 Number of Observations Explanatory Variables Significance GDP Per Capita 0.0000 Quintile Ratio (Top 20 0.0000 Percent / Bottom 20 Percent Population) Dummy Variable (1985, 0.0534 1986,1987,1988 =1) Constant 0.0187 R-squared 0.965 178.12 Adjusted R-squared 0.960 0.0000 Durbin-Watson Stat 1.787 24 Notes: Variables (except dummy) are used after Logarithmic transformation. All variables are statistically significant. LM and ARCH tests are applied and found no evidence of serial correlation. The dummy variable helps to captures the extreme point estimates. Table 1 Poverty and Inequality (Consistent Estimates) Percentage of Share (%) of Population Below Gini Bottom 20 Percent Survey Years the Poverty Line Coefficient of Population 1963-64 40.24 0.386 6.4 1966-67 44.50 0.355 7.6 1969-70 46.53 0.336 8.0 1979 30.68 0.373 7.4 1984-85 24.47 0.369 7.3 1987-88 17.32 0.348 8.0 1990-91 22.11 0.407 5.7 1992-93 22.40 0.410 6.2 1996-97 27.72 0.400 7.0 1998-99 24.31 0.410 6.2 2001-02 29.71 0.399 6.7 Sources: Amjad and Kemal (1997). Pakistan Economic Survey (Various Issues). Pakistan Integrated Household Surveys (1996-97, 1998-99, 2001-02). Table 2 Poverty Elasticity Elasticity with Respect to Period Covered Growth Inequality Amjad and Kemal (1997) 1963 to 1993 -1.01 -- Akhtar and Ahmed (1999) 1979 to 1993 -1.58 -- This Paper: With no explicit 1979 to 2002 -2.12 -- Inequality Variable With Gini Coefficient 1979 to 2002 -3.51 8.37 With Share of Bottom 20 1979 to 2002 -2.50 -6.66 Percent With Quintile Ratio 1979 to 2002 -2.36 3.72 (Share of Top 20 Percent / Share of Bottom 20 Percent) Table 3 Determinants of Inequality (Gini Coefficient) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic Significance GDP Per Capita 0.081 3.59 0.0027 Inflation (Food Prices) 0.088 10.49 0.0000 Manufacturing to 0.023 3.71 0.0021 Agriculture Wage Gap Direct to Indirect -0.024 -5.20 0.0001 Tax Ratio Development Expenditure -0.015 -2.07 0.0566 on Social Services Investment -0.037 -2.35 0.0329 Manufacturing to 0.046 1.90 0.0768 Agriculture Terms of Trade Table 4 Determinants of Inequality (Share of Bottom 20 Percent of Population) Explanatory Variables Coefficient t-statistic Significance GDP Per Capita 0.046 1.03 0.3166 Inflation (Food) -0.121 -8.62 0.0000 Manufacturing to -0.018 -1.84 0.0837 Agriculture Wage Gap Direct to Indirect 0.027 3.85 0.0014 Tax Ratio Development Expenditure 0.024 6.04 0.0000 on Social Services Private Investment 0.051 3.65 0.0021 Manufacturing to -0.078 -2.45 0.0258 Agriculture Terms of Trade
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有