Sources of Pakistan's economic growth.
Burney, Nadeem A.
INTRODUCTION
Economic growth is one of the most important objectives of development policy in almost every country. It depends on the historical accumulation of primary factors of production, e.g. labour and capital, and on technological progress and a combination of socio-political and institutional factors. Owing to interactions among these different factors, it is difficult to delineate the role of each factor in economic growth. It is precisely because of this that a systematic and quantitative study of the sources of growth is indispensable. The growth-accounting framework, introduced by Solow [15] to measure productivity change and subsequently extended by Jorgenson and Griliches [5], Christensen and Jorgenson [1], Hulten [4] and Denison [2], provides an important method with which to study the growth experience of a country.
In developed countries a proportionately higher percentage of GDP growth is attributable to productivity change. In less developed countries (LDCs), however, increased use of factor inputs is the dominant source of economic growth) In LDCs, typically, two-thirds of the factor input contribution in GDP growth is due to capital. The estimates obtained, using the growth-accounting framework, can thus be taken as crude indicators of the level of development.
The main purpose of this paper is to apply the growth-accounting approach in order to analyse the sources of growth in Pakistan from 1959-60 to 1984-85. Following McCarthy, Hanson and Kwon [10], growth during the period under study will be analysed over different subperiods. The GDP growth over each subperiod will be decomposed according to: (i) factors of production, viz. labour and capital; (ii) components, e.g. consumption, investment, etc.; and (iii) sectors, e.g. agriculture, manufacturing, etc. The factor decomposition of GDP growth gives an estimate of the overall productivity change in the economy. The component- and sector-wise decomposition, on the other hand, shows the contribution of each component and sector in the overall GDP growth.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section I1 explains the analytical framework. Section III discusses methodology and data sources. In Section IV, we discuss our estimates of the sources of growth in Pakistan. Finally, Section V summarizes the results.
II. THE ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
The measurement of technological change, as defined by Solow [15], depends critically on the existence of an aggregate production function for the economy and homogeneous factor inputs. Therefore, an explicit consideration of a well-behaved constant-returns-to-scale (CRS) production function forms the basis of the analysis. Let Y represent net real output produced. If one makes the rather heroic assumption that capital (K) and labour (L) are the only factors of production, and, additionally, that both factors are homogeneous, (2) then the aggregate production function can be written as
Y = F(K, L, t) ... ... ... ... ... (1)
where t allows F to change over time. Assuming CRS and Hicks-neutral technological change, we can write the aggregate production function as
Y = A(t)f(K, L) ... ... ... ... ... (2)
Where A(t) represents the Hicksian efficiency parameter. (3) Differentiating Equation (2) with respect to t. we get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
where the dot over the variable indicates its derivative with respect to time. Equation (3) shows that the growth in real output is the sum of growth in the Hicksian efficiency parameter and the weighted sum of growth in capital and labour. The weights [[theta].sub.k] and [theta].sub.L] are the output elasticities of capital and labour, respectively. The term A/A represents shifts in the production function and the expression within the brackets of Equation (3) indicates a movement along the function. Thus, the growth in the aggregate output of the economy, i.e. Y/Y, is the sum of the shift in, as well as the movement along, the production function.
Under the assumption that the economy is in a competitive equilibrium, output elasticities in Equation (3) become equivalent to the income shares of the respective factors of production in total output. Equation (3) can then be rewritten as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
where [alpha] = cK/pY and [beta] = wL/pY, are shares of capital and labour in total output, respectively The prices of output, capital and labour are denoted by p, c and w, respectively. Equation (4) indicates that the growth in the Hicksian efficiency parameter (or technological change) can be measured as the difference between the growth in aggregate output and the growth in total factor inputs (which is the weighted sum of growth in all productive inputs).
We know from the national income identity that the total value of output produced in an economy, in a particular year, is either consumed, saved (invested), or exported, i.e.
[Y.sub.t] = [C.sub.t] + [I.sub.t] + ([X.sub.t] - [M.sub.r]) ... ... ... ... (5)
where [Y.sub.t], [C.sub.t] [X.sub.t], and [M.sub.t] are, respectively, total value of output produced, total consumption, total investment, exports, and imports, in year t. Taking first-order difference and dividing both sides of the equation by [Y.sub.t-1], we get
[DELTA]Y/[Y.sub.t-1] = [[gamma].sub.1] [DELTA]C/[C.sub.t-1] + [[gamma].sub.2] [DELTA]I/[I.sub.t-1] + [[gamma].sub.3] [DELTA]X/[X.sub.t-1] -[[gamma].sub.4] [DELTA]M/[M.sub.t-1] ... ... (6)
where [DELTA] represents the first-order difference of the variable with which it appears and [[gamma].sub.1], [[gamma].sub.2], [[gamma].sub.3], and [[gamma].sub.4] are shares of consumption, investment, exports and imports, respectively, in total GDP in period t-1. Equation (6) indicates that growth in GDP over a period is the weighted sum of growth in its components. The weights are the shares of each component.
The total value of output produced in an economy, i.e. GDP in period t, is also the sum of value added in each sector, e.g. agriculture, manufacturing, etc. Thus. the growth in GDP over a period can also be expressed as the weighted sum of growth in each sector. The weights, in this case, are the shares of each sector in total GDP in period t-1.
III. DATA SOURCES AND METHODOLOGY
Except those for capital stock and factor shares, all the data are obtained from the Pakistan Economic Survey, 1985-86 [14] and are at constant prices of 1959-60. There is no official capital-stock series available for Pakistan. However, an official investment series is available. These data were used to generate a capital-stock series using the first-order difference equation
[K.sub.t] = (1-d) [K.sub.t-1] + [I.sub.t]
where
[K.sub.t] is capital stock in year t;
[K.sub.t-1] is capital stock in year t-1,
[I.sub.t] is gross investment in year t; and d is the depreciation rate.
Capital stock for the starting year, viz. 1959-60, was estimated with the Harrod-Domar formula. This further required knowledge about the overall capital-output ratio. Estimates of both the capital-output ratio and the depreciation rate were obtained from Khilji [8], who, by using coefficients from Khan and MacEwan [7], generated capital-stock series for different sectors and the overall economy of Pakistan from 1956 to 1978. The estimates of the capital-output ratio for 1959-60 and the depreciation rate derived from Khilji's aggregate capital-stock series are 2.75 percent and 4 percent, respectively.
There are no official data on factor shares in GDP for the overall economy. However, the distribution of household monthly income by source, e.g. wages and salaries, self-employment, property, etc., is given in HousehoM Income and Expenditure Surveys (HIES) [13] for different years. This information was used to estimate factor shares in GDP. As the. income of the self-employed also includes wages, the share of wages and salaries given in the HIESs are underestimated. Thus labour's share in GDP was obtained by adjusting the share of wages and salaries, assuming that 40 percent of the income of the self-employed is wages and the remaining 60 percent is return on their capital. The share of capital in GDP is simply one minus the share of labour. The resulting estimated shares are presented in Table 1. (4)
IV. SOURCES OF GROWTH
Factor Decomposition
A change due to a factor of production is composed of two parts: the gross component, which reflects change in the quantity of the factor, and the quality component, which, say for labour, takes account of change in education, sex composition, age composition, etc., of the labour force. Because of data constraints, it was not possible to adjust our estimates of the factor contribution in GDP growth for the qualitative changes. As a result, our estimates of the residual, or productivity, are biased upwards.
The decomposition of GDP growth by the contribution of factor inputs, viz. labour and capital, over each sub-period, is given in Table 2. Overall, the performance of GDP growth has been reasonable during the period under study. It grew at an average rate of well over 6 percent during the Sixties and Eighties. In the Seventies, however, the growth was slower but was well over 4 percent. Although this, as noted by Naqvi and Sarmad [12], is a fairly healthy rate compared with that of the Sixties and Eighties, the performance is relatively weak. This can partly be attributed to exogenous shocks, e.g. secession of East Pakistan and the sharp rise in oil price during the period.
Both in absolute terms and as a percentage of GDP growth, the contribution of labour increased consistently during the Sixties and Seventies but declined during the Eighties. During the 1975-80 period, one-third of the growth in GDP was due to labour. The increase in the contribution of capital had not been smooth. However, as a percentage of GDP growth, it had been close to 40 percent in all but one subperiod. The residual, which also represents aggregate productivity, accounted for over 55 percent of the growth in GDP during the Sixties. Its share dropped to only 23 percent during the 1975-80 period. However, there has been a significant improvement since then. (5)
The analysis of productivity will be considered in more detail later. Firstly, for comparison across countries, in Table 3 we reproduce estimates of factor inputs and productivity contribution in GDP growth for some Latin American countries and Malaysia, obtained by Elias [3] and McCarthy and Burney [9], respectively. It is evident from the estimates that, as compared with other countries, most of which are better endowed in terms of resources, Pakistan has done reasonably well.
Our estimates in Table 2 indicate that during the Sixties, productivity was the main source of growth in GDP, whereas during the Seventies and Eighties, factor inputs were the major contributors. In order to explore what might have gone wrong, we examine average labour productivity (ALP) in different sectors. ALP is taken as value added per worker. Growth in ALP depends on the rate of technical change and the growth rate of the capital-labour ratio. In Table 4, we give estimates of aggregate ALP, and ALP in different sectors. It is important to note that throughout the period, ALP is the lowest in agriculture. During 1965-70 and 1980-85 periods, aggregate ALP grew at an average rate of 5.3 percent and 4.8 percent, respectively. The capital-labour ratio in the corresponding periods grew at an average rate of 2.5 percent. During 1970-75 and 1975-80 periods, however, when aggregate ALP grew at an average rate of 2.5 percent and 1.3 percent, the growth in the capital-labour ratio was not more than 0.8 percent. This indicates that one possible reason for slower productivity change during the Seventies was the slow growth in capital per capita. This is further supported by the fact that during the 1960-85 period, the capital-output ratio dropped from 2.75 to 1.72. This reasoning can also be true for agriculture where, during the 1970-75 period, the average growth rate of ALP was negative and has subsequently been less than one percent.
Demand Decomposition
The GDP growth for each sub period is decomposed into principal aggregates of consumption, investment and trade. (6) Consumption and investment are further divided into private and public components. The estimates of the contribution by each component are given in Table 5. Consumption provided the main source of growth in all subperiods. Excluding the first subperiod, it accounted for more than 85 percent of GDP growth. More than 80 percent of this has been from the private sectors. Since the mid-Sixties, however, the contribution of public consumption has been rising gradually. Except for the first sub period, i.e. 1960-65, the contribution of investment in GDP growth has never been more than 18 percent of GDP growth. Both private and public sectors have contributed more or less equally. Some of the contribution made by consumption and investment had been offset by the negative effect of trade. The contribution of trade, however, was never more than 20 percent and has declined significantly since 1970-75. Within trade, the contribution of both exports and imports does not show any consistent pattern.
Sectoral Decomposition
Estimates for the sectoral contribution in the GDP growth are given in Table 6. First, note that the role of different sectors in GDP growth has more or less remained the same during the period under study. This is despite the fact that in GDP the shares of different sectors have changed sharply over time [12]. Except for the 1970-75 subperiod, when public administration and defence contributed 25 percent of growth in GDP, the commodity-producing sectors, viz. agriculture plus manufacturing, had contributed more than 40 percent to the growth. Agriculture faced major problems in the early Seventies. Its performance in the Eighties is also not all that impressive, especially if we take into account the fact that investment in this sector, in nominal terms, increased by 54 percent during the period. It is evident from the estimates that the difference in the performance of agriculture during different sub periods is mainly due to the strong or weak performance of the major crops. Manufacturing contributed 23 percent of growth in GDP during the early Sixties. Its share dropped gradually to 17 percent during the 1970-75 subperiod, but since then has increased significantly. This increase is largely due to the role of large-scale manufacturing.
Besides agriculture and manufacturing, the contribution of wholesale and retail trade had been significant. It was around 15 percent of GDP growth in all subperiods. Other important sectors, in order of their significance, are public administration plus defence, transport plus communication, and construction. In view of sharp increases in investment in this sector during different sub periods, one might have expected an even bigger contribution from the construction sector but it seems that much of the gains were not captured by the domestic sector.
V. CONCLUSIONS
In this paper we have analysed the sources of economic growth in Pakistan during the period from 1959-60 to 1984-85. The GDP growth is decomposed according to the contributions made by factors of production, components and sectors. The main finding is that during the Sixties productivity was the main source of GDP growth. During the Seventies and Eighties, however, factor inputs were the major contributors. This shift is partly due to a slower increase in capital per capita and decline in capital-output ratio. This is further supported-by the evidence that the contribution of investment in GDP growth is small. On the demand side, consumption has been the major source of growth in GDP. The sectoral decomposition of GDP growth indicates that the commodity-producing sector has accounted for more than 40 percent of the growth in GDP. The major crops are the main source of the varying contribution of agriculture. In the case of manufacturing, large-scale sector's output accounts for more than 60 percent of the contribution.
Comments on "Sources of Pakistan's Economic Growth"
Any empirical work, undertaken to identify the sources of economic growth for Pakistan's economy, is hampered by an acute paucity of reliable statistical data. Dr Burney's paper should, therefore, be examined in this perspective.
I would have no serious reservations about the theoretical underpinnings: It is a standard formulation for an aggregate production function with two factors of production--capital and labour. A time variable allows the function to shift parametrically over time, which signifies a constant-returns-to-scale production function with neutral (a la Hicks) technological change. Equation (3), thus, measures the growth of "real output" as the sum of growth of the "Hicksian efficiency parameter A/A" plus the weighted sum of growth in output elasticities of capital and labour".
In the case of Pakistan, one would seriously question the assumption of "competitive equilibrium" and consequently the equality between the output elasticities of Equation (3) and their corresponding income shares as stipulated in Equation (4). For the period in question, any observer of the economic scene in Pakistan would rather point to the monopolistic/quasi monopolistic market conditions of the economy. Viewed thus, the estimation of [alpha]'s and [beta]'s is clearly suspect and does not follow the marginal productivity criteria for the determination of factor shares. Furthermore, there is still a very large "residual" left to be explained.
It is not quite clear whether the author is trying to measure total factor productivity, multifactor productivity or technological change (as measured by changing techniques of production). For example, it is not clear whether the author is determining gross output prices, net output prices, or prices of particular capital goods. It is also confusing to ascertain whether the total wage rate of the economy has been measured or not.
I think there is an error in the formulation when it is said that the total value of output equals the GDP. The latter is the difference between the total gross outputs and the total intermediate inputs.
The following specific comments are offered with a view to overcoming some of the shortcomings of the paper:
Capital Stock Series: Since there exist no such data, they have to be estimated. The author uses some depreciation rates but he does not discuss what depreciation procedures have been employed--i.e. whether the straightline depreciation rate or the Perpetual Inventory Method is used.
Gross Investment: Is it total investment or does it refer to both private and public investments separately? Each component has its own peculiarities and the rates at which each would be depreciated would certainly differ.
Inter-country Comparison: Comparison of the results obtained for Pakistan's economy with corresponding results for other countries is unwarranted unless the countries in question follow the same path of economic growth or, at least, depict similar characteristics. No such explanation about the countries compared has been provided.
Table 4: Some explanation as to what is the source of employment data, with all its sectoral disaggregation, is required.
Given the lack of statistical information, I would suggest that the sources of structural change for Pakistan's economy be best studied within an input-output framework. Two such tables are available for Pakistan's economy. A given level of final demand can be assumed to be produced by two (given) technologies and the sources of change in the gross output levels be quite easily decomposed.
Aftab A. Syed
Input-Output Division, Statistics Canada, Ottawa, Canada
REFERENCES
[1.] Christensen, L. R., and D. W. Jorgenson. "U.S. Real Product and Real Factor Input: 1927 to 1967". Review of Income and Wealth. Series 16, No. 1. 1970. pp. 19-25.
[2.] Denison, E. F. Accounting for United States Economic Growth: 1929-1969. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution. 1974.
[3.] Elias, V. J. "Sources of Economic Growth in Latin American Countries". Review of Economics and Statistics. Vol. LX, No. 3. 1978. pp. 362-372.
[4.] Hulten, C. R. The Measurement of Total Factor Productivity in United States Manufacturing: 1948-1966. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of California, Berkeley, (U.S.A.). 1973.
[5.] Jorgenson, D. W., and Z. Griliches. "The Explanation of Productivity Change". Review of Economic Studies. Vol. XXXIV, No. 3. 1967. pp. 249-283.
[6.] Kernal, A. R. An Analysis of Industrial Efficiency in Pakistan: 1959-60 to 1969-70. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Manchester (U.K.). 1978.
[7.] Khan, A. R., and Arther MacEwan. "A Multisectoral Analysis of Capital Requirement for Development Planning in Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. VII, No. 4. 1967. pp. 445-484.
[8.] Khilji, N. M. Growth Prospects of a Developing Economy: A Macro-economic study of Pakistan. Ph.D. Dissertation, McMaster University, Hamilton (Canada). 1982.
[9.] McCarthy, F. D., and N. A. Burney. "Malaysia: Endowment, Growth and Development". Country Policy Department, the World Bank, Washington, D.C. (U.S.A.). 1985.
[10.] McCarthy, F. D., J. A. Hanson and S. Kwon. "Sources of Growth in Colombia". Journal of Development Economics. (Forthcoming)
[11.] Nadiri, M. I. "Some Approaches to the Theory and Measurement of Total Factor Productivity: A Survey". Journal of Economic Literature. Vol. VIII, No.4. 1970. pp. 1137-1177.
[12.] Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider, and Khwaja Sarmad. Pakistan's Economy through the Seventies. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. 1984.
[13.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Statistics Division. Household Income and Expenditure Survey. Karachi. (Various issues)
[14.] Pakistan. Finance Division. Economic Adviser's Wing. Pakistan Economic Survey 1985-86. Islamabad. 1986.
[15.] Solow, R. "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function". Review of Economics and Statistics. Vol. XXXIX, No. 3.1957. pp. 312-320.
(1) See, for example [2], [3] and [10].
(2) Homogeneous labour and capital are aggregates of heterogeneous elements. Capital equipment varies in type, life span. productive quality, etc., while labourers differ in skill, education, age, sex, etc. Since the aggregation problems are elaborated elsewhere in the literature, they are not discussed in this paper.
(3) productivity change can also be labour-saving or capital-saving. There are three definitions of productivity (or technical) change: (i) Hicksian, which measures bias along constant capital-labour ratio; (ii) Harrodian, which measures bias along constant capital-output ratio; and (iii) Solow's, which measures bias along constant labour-output ratio. See Nadiri [11] for detailed discussion.
(4) The Household Income and Expenditure Surveys (HIES)available do not necessarily correspond with all the years given in the Table. For the years for which HIESs are not available, the factor shares were interpolated, using average annual growth rates.
(5) See Kemal [6] for a detailed analysis of the productivity change in the manufacturing sector of Pakistan.
(6) Kemal [6] decomposed growth in manufacturing into domestic demand, export expansion, and import substitution. The evidence presented shows that during the Sixties, Pakistan was not heavily dependent on import substitution for its growth.
NADEEM A. BURNEY, The author is Staff Economist at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad (Pakistan). Table 1 Estimated Factor Shares Years Labour Capital 1959-60 0.400 0.600 1964-65 0.446 0.554 1969-70 0.454 0.546 1974-75 0.463 0.537 1979-80 0.486 0.514 Source: Author's estimates. Table 2 Factor Decomposition of GDP Growth (Percentage) 1960-65 1965-70 1970-75 1975-80 1980-85 GDP Growth (Factor Cost) 5 years 38.83 38.43 23.48 29.79 37.73 Average Annual Growth Rate 6.78 6.72 4.31 5.35 6.61 Factor Inputs 17.66 16.09 15.60 22.87 21.34 Labour 3.08 3.91 6.34 9.94 6.84 Capital 14.58 12.18 9.26 12.93 14.50 Residual 21.17 22.34 7.88 6.92 16.39 Percentage Distribution of GDP Growth Factor Inputs 45.48 41.87 66.44 76.77 56.56 Labour 7.93 10.18 27.00 33.37 18.13 Capital 37.55 31.69 39.44 43.40 38.43 Residual 54.52 58.13 33.56 23.23 43.44 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 Source: Author's estimates. Table 3 Factor Decomposition of GDP Growth in Various Countries Percentage Distribution of GDP Growth 1960-65 1965-70 1970-75 Factor Inputs 51.91 119.0 78.30 Argentina Labour 7.43 38.0 27.64 Capital 44.48 81.0 50.66 Residual 48.09 -19.0 21.7 Factor Inputs 87.44 56.25 70.00 Brazil Labour 53.4 22.66 16.13 Capital 34.04 33.59 53.87 Residual 12.56 43.75 30.00 Factor Inputs 68.60 64.90 90.89 Chile Labour 18.06 15.77 32.32 Capital 50.54 49.13 58.57 Residual 31.40 35.10 9.11 Factor Inputs 65.10 63.51 57.01 Colombia Labour 23.50 21.93 12.92 Capital 41.70 41.58 44.09 Residual 34.90 36.49 42.99 Factor Inputs 60.60 105.0 72.00 Malaysia Labour 19.60 32.7 13.60 Capital 41.00 72.3 58.40 Residual 39.4 -5.0 28.0 Factor Inputs 77.05 76.45 98.14 Mexico Labour 16.44 12.11 20.51 Capital 60.61 64.34 77.63 Residual 22.95 23.55 1.86 Factor Inputs 62.34 77.35 -- Peru Labour 18.48 27.95 -- Capital 43.86 49.40 -- Residual 37.66 22.65 -- Factor Inputs 38.36 118.86 128.57 Venezuela Labour 23.29 44.29 31.43 Capital 15.07 74.57 97.14 Residual 61.64 -18.85 -28.57 1975-80 1980-83 Factor Inputs -- -- Argentina Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Factor Inputs -- -- Brazil Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Factor Inputs -- -- Chile Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Factor Inputs -- -- Colombia Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Factor Inputs 86.3 121.1 Malaysia Labour 11.7 13.4 Capital 74.6 107.7 Residual 13.7 -21.1 Factor Inputs -- -- Mexico Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Factor Inputs -- -- Peru Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Factor Inputs -- -- Venezuela Labour -- -- Capital -- -- Residual -- -- Source: [3], [9]. Table 4 Capital-output Ratio, Capital Labour Ratio, and Average Labour Productivity Output-employment Ratio Years Agriculture Manufactur- Construc- Electricity ing Mining tion and Gas 1964 897.45 1497.29 3900.00 2366.67 1965 946.53 1580.87 3548.28 2866.67 1966 952.76 1645.42 3082.86 3283.33 1967 1008.1 1659.36 2416.28 3450.00 1968 1128.67 1695.79 1956.60 3733.33 1969 1182.08 1764.71 2057.81 4183.33 1970 1241.26 1936.23 1938.57 9128.57 1971 1151.98 2027.50 2106.06 14820.00 1972 1186.36 2395.42 1846.03 11142.86 1973 1180.57 2456.30 1922.86 11287.50 1974 1215.38 2497.74 1935.06 11866.67 1975 1175.72 2385.36 2063.53 9490.00 1976 1193.97 2292.54 2276.09 8954.55 1977 1190.82 2222.83 2076.00 8792.31 1978 1190.98 2324.09 2081.48 8293.33 1979 1194.29 2383.24 2043.96 8035.29 1980 1244.18 2628.24 2240.68 7655.00 1981 1260.95 2908.05 2290.83 7382.61 1982 1275.68 3300.29 2324.59 6834.62 1983 1293.98 3528.86 2560.48 6606.90 1984 1178.59 3768.08 2934.65 6815.15 1985 1200.00 4051.40 2949.23 6171.05 Output-employment Ratio Years Transport Trade Other Aggregate 1964 3563.64 2386.18 1737.87 1638.41 1965 3970.00 2380.45 1962.01 1769.20 1966 3516.67 2405.59 2490.87 1876.46 1967 3036.21 2336.13 2575.12 1831.76 1968 2651.43 2247.90 2877.01 1865.72 1969 2339.29 2233.33 3470.99 1999.41 1970 2411.90 2532.39 3960.00 2291.94 1971 2201.11 2283.00 4455.40 2499.89 1972 2254.44 2549.73 3108.61 2276.12 1973 2536.56 2491.41 3351.40 2391.52 1974 2571.88 2663.98 3589.86 2541.04 1975 2604.04 2575.11 4156.16 2589.32 1976 2556.86 2518.80 4011.30 2520.60 1977 2526.67 2417.70 4023.55 2511.42 1978 2804.63 2563.49 4229.64 2629.49 1979 2924.11 2625.95 4254.72 2669.38 1980 3092.92 2710.26 4341.54 2767.76 1981 3283.48 2786.27 4486.02 2891.45 1982 3454.70 2961.15 4604.21 3027.19 1983 3660.50 3018.12 4835.74 3172.47 1984 3984.30 2987.65 5089.97 3378.51 1985 4114.52 3149.56 5306.51 3496.47 Capital- Capital- Years Labour Output Ratio Ratio 1964 3116.16 2.37 1965 3278.94 2.31 1966 3402.45 2.26 1967 3514.83 2.30 1968 3581.18 2.22 1969 3631.74 2.15 1970 3711.53 2.04 1971 3720.65 2.09 1972 3795.61 2.10 1973 3764.35 2.03 1974 3777.64 1.94 1975 3795.93 1.93 1976 3818.17 1.95 1977 3860.32 1.99 1978 3885.24 1.93 1979 3892.84 1.91 1980 3958.84 1.84 1981 4022.86 1.80 1982 4134.44 1.77 1983 4262.67 1.75 1984 4355.72 1.77 1985 4460.64 1.72 Source: Author's estimates. Table 5 Demand Decomposition of GDP Growth (Percentage) 1960-65 1965-70 1970-75 1975-80 1980-85 GDP Growth (Market Prices)--5 Years 36.37 65.56 1935 33.81 36.78 Average Annual Growth Rate 6.40 10.61 3.60 6.00 6.46 Consumption 24.14 58.86 22.48 34.45 31.09 Private 19.05 54.57 21.16 29.12 24.61 Public 5.09 4.29 1.32 5.33 6.48 Investment 19.03 -0.93 0.50 4.57 6.60 Private 12.23 -1.52 -2.47 2.33 2.77 Public 8.22 -0.46 2.53 2.86 2.50 Change in Stock -1.42 1.05 0.44 -0.62 1.33 Trade -6.80 7.63 -3.63 -5.21 -0.91 Exports 3.50 8.26 -1.38 2.63 2.14 Imports 10.30 0.63 2.25 7.84 3.05 Percentage Distribution of GDP Growth Consumption 66.37 89.78 116.18 101.89 84.53 Private 52.37 83.24 109.35 86.13 66.91 Public 14.00 6.54 6.83 15.76 17.62 Investment 52.33 -1.42 2.58 13.52 17.94 Private 33.63 -2.32 -12.76 6.89 7.53 Public 22.60 -0.70 13.07 8.46 6.80 Change in -3.90 1.60 2.27 -1.83 3.61 Stock Trade -18.70 11.64 -18.76 -15.41 -2.47 Exports 9.62 12.60 -7.13 7.78 5.82 Imports -28.32 -0.96 -11.63 -23.19 -8.29 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 Source: Author's estimates. Table 6 Sectoral Decomposition of GDP Growth (Percentage) 1960-65 1965-70 1970-75 1975-80 1980-85 GDP Growth (Factor Cost) 5 Years 38.83 38.43 23.48 29.79 37.73 Average Annual Growth Rate 6.78 6.72 4.31 5.35 6.61 Agriculture 9.30 14.11 1.55 6.88 5.27 Major Crops 5.96 1139 -0.3 4.14 2.36 Minor Crops 1.41 0.99 0.97 1.02 0.56 Livestock 1.69 1.37 1.11 1.53 2.22 Fishing & Forestry 0.24 0.36 -0.23 0.19 0.13 Mining & Quarrying 0.30 0.15 0.08 0.19 0.25 Manufacturing 8.90 7.16 4.04 5.95 10.14 Large-scale 8.12 6.51 2.56 3.87 7.48 Small-scale 0.78 0.65 1.48 2.08 2.67 Construction 3.52 1.40 1.23 2.23 2.30 Electricity & Gas 0.49 1.90 0.97 1.47 1.60 Transport & Communication 3.81 1.88 1.72 2.31 3.08 Wholesale & Retail Trade 6.30 5.56 4.14 4.02 6.46 Banking & Insurance 1.00 1.14 1.33 0.73 1.70 Ownership of Dwellings 0.83 0.60 0.64 0.64 0.58 Public 2.47 2.65 5.82 3.11 4.04 Administration & Defence Services 1.91 1.88 1.96 2.26 2.31 Percentage Distribution of GDP Growth Agriculture 23.95 36.72 6.60 23.09 13.97 Major Crops 15.35 29.64 -1.28 13.90 6.25 Minor Crops 3.63 2.58 4.13 3.42 1.48 Livestock 4.35 3.56 4.73 5.14 5.88 Fishing & Forestry 0.62 0.94 -0.98 0.63 0.34 Mining & Quarrying 0.77 0.39 0.34 0.64 0.66 Manufacturing 22.92 18.63 17.21 19.97 26.88 Large-scale 20.91 16.94 10.90 12.99 19.83 Small-scale 2.01 1.69 6.31 6.98 7.08 Construction 9.07 3.64 5.24 7.49 6.10 Electricity & Gas 1.26 4.94 4.13 4.93 4.24 Transport & Communication 9.81 4.89 7.33 7.75 8.16 Wholesale & Retail Trade 16.22 14.47 17.63 13.49 17.12 Banking & Insurance 2.58 2.97 5.66 2.45 4.51 Ownership of Dwellings 2.14 1.56 2.73 2.15 1.54 Public Administration & Defence 6.36 6.90 24.79 10.44 10.71 Services 4.92 4.89 8.34 7.60 6.11 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 Source: Author's estimates.