Gaining through Corporate Bankruptcy: Evidence from Competitors.
Kolay, Madhuparna
Gaining through Corporate Bankruptcy: Evidence from Competitors.
I. INTRODUCTION
In this study, we examine the effect of corporate bankruptcy on a
rival firm's equity. Corporate bankruptcy has many effects on its
various stakeholders such as its bondholders, stockholders, employees
and its industry i.e. its competitors. In general, bankruptcy conveys
negative news about the filing firm and therefore, adverse effects are
expected on the various groups. An exception however may arise in the
case of a bankrupt firm's competitor since the peer firm may
benefit due to increased market share from the potential removal of the
distressed firm. On the other hand, sources of cash flow in industry
rivals are likely to be correlated and therefore, corporate bankruptcy
may convey bad news about the filing firm's peers as well. Even
without actually conveying new information about the industry, the
anticipation of related bad news due to the bankruptcy may lead peer
firms to suffer from contagion (Lang and Stulz, 1992).
An interesting question in this area is: when does a firm gain from
a rival's bankruptcy and when does it lose? Lang and Stulz (1992),
who examine the effect on the equity of the filing firms' rivals,
posit that the competitive effects are likely to arise when firms
operate in concentrated industries and a rival is relatively less
levered and therefore, in a stronger financial position to take
advantage of the market share increase. In contrast, firms operating in
competitive industries do not have much scope for market share gains and
are more likely to be affected negatively. Lang and Stulz find
corroborating evidence in their study of 59 bankruptcies between 1970
and 1989. They found evidence of competitive effects for those rivals
which had lower leverage and operated in concentrated industries, though
these effects were smaller than observed contagion effects. However,
subsequent research has not been able to provide direct evidence about
the existence of such competitive effects. In a study similar to that of
Lang and Stulz, but using an expanded sample, Ferris, Jayaraman, and
Makhija (1993) were not able to find any significant competitive
effects. They concluded that it was likely that news about the
bankruptcy was already incorporated into market prices at the time of
filing. Other studies find indirect evidence of competitive effects.
Jorion and Zhang (2007) study jumps in the prices of CD swaps to
investigate competitive and contagion effect in both Chapter 7 and
Chapter 11 bankruptcies. They find that competitive effects are
relatively more evident in their Chapter 7 sample. Intuitively, these
firms are filing with the aim of liquidation, and not in order to
restructure, and therefore, rivals' probability of gain is higher.
Filing for Chapter 11 may weaken a firm and therefore, benefit the
rivals. On the other hand, a filing firm may reemerge with lower
leverage and less contractual obligations. Zhang (2010) examines this
question and finds that when rivals emerge from the Chapter 11 process,
firm experience significantly negative competitive effects (-6%) over
200 days following the emergence date.
Conceptually, a rival stands to gain the most market share only if
the bankrupt rival is completely eliminated from the market. Therefore,
from an intuitive standpoint, the ex-ante probability that a filing firm
emerges successfully from the Chapter 11 process and remains a rival in
the long run ought to play a major role in determining the wealth
effects on rivals at the time of filing. In this study, we examine this
issue in a sample of 219 Chapter 11 filings which took place between
1980 and 2009 by accounting for various factors which directly affect
the probability of successful reorganization of a filing firm. We start
by using Lemmon, Ma, and Tashjian's (2009) classification scheme
for Chapter 11 filings by distress type: financial versus economically
distressed. Lemmon et al. (2009) show that one of the main determinants
of the outcome of the Chapter 11 process is the type of distress faced
by the filing firm. Financially distressed firms are those that have
borrowed too much but are not faltering in terms of underlying operating
performance whereas economically distressed firms have very poor
operating performance and therefore, have difficulty repaying even low
levels of debt. Lemmon et al. (2009) show that a financially distressed
filing firm has a higher probability of emerging as a standalone entity
from the Chapter 11 process compared to an economically distressed firm.
Overall, when an economically distressed firm files for bankruptcy,
competitors are likely to have more scope for gains. In contrast, a
financially distressed firm is likely to emerge with less debt and
remain a viable competitor. Therefore, when a financially distressed
firm files for Chapter 11, the potential for gain to rivals will be
lower.
Next, we consider the effects of industry concentration. Lang and
Stulz (1992) showed that competitive effects arise in more concentrated
industries which allows rivals larger marginal gains in market share at
the expense of their bankrupt peer. Using distress type and industry
concentration, we find that rivals to economically distressed filing
firms in concentrated industries experience 2.62% (significant at the 1%
level) abnormal equity returns around the 10 days of filing. This
increases to over 5% (significant at the 1% level) when we account for
the state of distress of the entire industry.
Next we turn to addressing the question of when the effect on the
stock of rivals is likely to be most pronounced. From a
competitor's perspective, financial distress in a rival leads to
negative stock effects, but the potential to gain from enlarged market
share will not arise until the distressed rival actually files for
bankruptcy. However, few, if any, Chapter 11 filings are surprises as
most firms try to avoid bankruptcy by restructuring their assets and
liabilities. It follows that the act of filing Chapter 11 is unlikely
lead to any new information about the distress of the filing firm. Since
the market already knows about the distress, the rivals would not lose
due to contagion effects but may gain because Chapter 11 may lead to a
collapse of the rival leading to enlarged market share. The event of
filing itself night be positive for the filing firm's rivals. To
disentangle the differential effects of distress versus filing, we study
equity effects on two dates for each bankruptcy filing: the filing date
itself and a distress date. To identify the distress date, we follow the
method described in Kolay, Lemmon, and Tashjian (2016) which aims to
identify the distress date as that date in the pre-filing year when news
of a firm's financial distress first arrives in the market. We
conduct event studies on both sets of dates and we find that rivals of
economically distressed filing firms operating in concentrated
industries experience CAR equaling -1.96% (significant at the 1% level)
in the 10 days around the distress date compared to the +2.62%
(significant at the 1% level) we found for the same subset of firms
during the 10 days surrounding the filing date. As expected, industry
concentration plays a large role in determining the existence of
competitive effects. We find that firms in competitive industries
experience a uniformly negative contagion effect both around filing and
around the distress date. The severity is greater in the 10-day distress
period (-1.54% significant at the 1% level) than the filing period
(-1.00% significant at the 1% level). Regressions confirm that all our
findings hold in multivariate settings.
If competitive effects on peer groups are material enough, these
should be reflected in changes in their operating performance during the
period around filing. To test this, we examine changes in rival
portfolios' excess operating performance around the year of filing.
We find that between the pre-filing year and the year of filing,
irrespective of industry concentration, rivals experience declines in
SGandA which are positively correlated to the degree of economic
distress in the concentrated subsample. This implies that firms in
concentrated industries gain from a lower SGandA when the likelihood of
emergence of a rival declines.
Overall we contribute to the existing bankruptcy literature by
showing that competitive effects of bankruptcy arise from the event of
rival filing, and not necessarily due to the distress of the rival
filing firms. Such competitive gains, which depend on the likelihood of
the rival emerging successfully and on industry concentration, are
stronger compared to what has been documented in the literature. We also
show that even firms in concentrated industries experience contagion
effects when the news of the rival's distress first arrives in the
market. On the other hand, firms operating in competitive industries
stand to lose both during the distress- and the filing- period. Further,
we find that rivals operating in concentrated industries lower costs
during the period of filing and these changes are higher if the rival is
economically distressed. The paper is organized as follows. Section II
describes the sample in detail including the choice of announcement
date. In Section III, we present the results of the univariate and
multivariate analysis of the different announcement effects on rivals.
Section IV describes the results of the analysis of realized operating
performance for rivals following the announcement. Section V concludes.
II. SAMPLE DESCRIPTION AND ANNOUNCEMENT DATES
We start with the LoPucki Bankruptcy Research Database for our
initial sample of 869 Chapter 11 filings between 1980 and 2009. Each of
these firms possesses assets of at least $100 million (in 1980 dollars)
at the time of filing and has at least one publicly traded security. (1)
We ensure that each filing firm has enough historical data to calculate
the main variable of interest which is the degree of economic distress
and has an identifiable distress date.
To classify firm by their distress type and level, we follow
Lemmon, Ma, and Tashjian (2009) and perform in-sample sorts of the
sample of bankrupt firms into deciles (zero being smallest and nine
being largest) on the basis of both their industry-adjusted
EBITDA-to-assets as well as leverage. Both individual rankings are then
added resulting in a proxy for the degree of economic versus financial
distress, ranging from 0 to 18. The industry adjustment for EBITA/Assets
is done by subtracting the industry median EBITDA-to-total assets from
the sample firm's EBITDA-to-total assets. Industry medians are
calculated based on 4-digit SIC codes provided that there are five or
more firms in the industry, excluding the sample firm. Leverage is
calculated as the ratio of total liabilities to total assets averaged
over two years prior to the year of filing. Following Lemmon et al.
(2009), we label firms in categories 0 to 5 as economically distressed,
firms in categories 14 to 18 as financially distressed, and the
remaining firms as having mixed type of distress. In addition to
distress type, the filing firm's RandD expenditure-to-asset ratio,
RandD intensity, is used as a measure of product specialization.
Industry concentrations is measured using the Herfindahl index of all
the firms having the same 4-digit SIC code as the filing firm.
To identify distress date for each bankrupt firm, we follow Kolay
et al (2016) and search for news articles in Lexis Nexis over one year
prior to the filing date for each firm. We rank order the articles based
on the kind (and severity) of news e.g. resultant trading partner's
distress and failed restructuring efforts are considered more serious
than an initial attempt at restructuring (see Kolay et al. (2016) for a
detailed discussion) and choose the date on which first such negative
information arrived to the market. We also use an industry distress
indicator variable which is similar to that used in Acharya, Bharath,
and Srinivasan (2007), Lemmon et al. (2009) and Kolay (2016). We compute
the industry median (based on 4-digit SIC code) stock return for the 12
months immediately prior to the Chapter 11 filing. If there are less
than five firms in that 4-digit SIC code, we use the 3-digit (or, if
required, 2-digit) SIC code to calculate the industry median. Industries
with median return lower than -30% are identified as distressed with an
indicator variable equal to one if distressed and zero otherwise.
In terms of regulatory regimes, the sample period is constructed
such that it mostly lies in between the two most recent major regulatory
changes to the laws governing corporate bankruptcy practices: the
Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978 and, more recently, the Bankruptcy Reform
Act of 2005 (BAPCPA) (Hotchkiss, Kose, Mooradian, and Thorburn, 2008).
While the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978 established most of the current
corporate bankruptcy procedures, the BAPCPA, which became effective in
October 2005, led to several major changes to the existing system,
specifically with regards to deadlines for bankruptcy plan filings,
disclosure statements and for plan confirmation. (2) Empirical research
in this area shows that as Chapter 11 case law evolves, characteristics
such as absolute priority rule violations, debtor-in-possession
financing, management turnover, and time spent in Chapter 11 change over
time as well (Bharath, Panchapagesan, and Werner, 2008). For instance,
anecdotal evidence suggests that post-BAPCPA, bankrupt retailers may
have been adversely affected, as the time period allowed to the debtors
to assume or reject leases has been effectively reduced under the new
regulation. (3) Since the aim of this study is to assess competitive
effects, regulatory changes, especially those that might affect any
single subgroup more than others, may lead to confounding effects and
therefore, in general, we aim to avoid these.
However, at the same time, one of the aims of this study is also to
assess what role, if any, industry distress (industries with returns
less than -30%) plays in the generation of competitive or contagion
effects. Therefore, we balance both these requirements by extending our
sample period to the post-BAPCPA period to include the most recent
recession of 2008-2009 but truncate the sample at 2009, so that the
effects of changes induced by BAPCPA are relatively lower. (4) Further,
since this study relies on manually collected data about the arrival of
news into the market during the pre-filing year, fewer bankruptcies in
any given year make it less cost-effective to collect data. While the
number of filing firms in 2009 spiked to 91, it dropped sharply to 36 in
2010. For the next five years, the number of filing firms per year
remained below 30. (5)
Overall, our sample period covers a twenty-nine year period which
includes the major recessions of 2000-2001 (the dot come bust) as well
as that of 2008-2009, while simultaneously attempting to minimize any
potential confounding effects on our results due to major legal changes.
After ensuring that enough data is available for the identification
of distress dates and calculation of industry distress indicator as well
as the degree of economic distress of the filing firm, we are left with
219 bankruptcy events. Table 1 shows the yearly distribution of the
bankruptcies along with the rival distributions. A rival firm is
identified as a firm which operates in the same 4-digit SIC code as the
filing firm in the filing year. The average bankrupt firm has about 2
billion in assets and each year, the filings are spread out over 4
different industries. The average number of rivals (firms in the same
4-digit SIC as the filing firm) is 31 for each filing firm. We create
equal weighted portfolios of industry rivals of the filing firm. Using
market share weighted portfolios of industry rivals leads to
qualitatively similar results.
Panel A of Table 2 presents the key statistics of the main
variables while panel B presents the correlation matrix between the main
variables. By construction, the degree of economic distress is
correlated with leverage and profits of both the filing firm as well as
the rivals (due to industry adjustment). All data used for calculations
are averaged values from years -3 and -2 relative to the filing year for
both filing firms as well as rival firms. Variables relating to rivals
are means and medians of the values found using equal weighted
portfolios. The average filing firm suffers from mixed distress (median
value of degree of economic distress is 9.00) while 31% of the filing
firms operate in distressed industries.
III. DETERMINANTS OF ABNORMAL RETURNS TO RIVALS
A. Distress and Filing Announcement Abnormal Returns to Rivals
Table 3 presents abnormal returns over various event windows using
the market-adjusted returns method (Brown and Warner, 1985), which is
the daily abnormal return calculated as the firm-specific return minus
the CRSP value-weighted market return. The average rival return is the
simple average of equal weighted portfolios of all firms in Compustat
operating in the same 4-digit SIC code returns. The portfolios are
grouped into subsamples by industry concentration (above and below
sample average Herfindahl Index 0.22). Firms operating in highly
concentrated industries are further subdivided by degree of economic
distress and industry distress. A high degree of economic distress
indicates a firm with below sample average mean of degree of economic
distress (9.28). A firm (and its rivals) are considered to be operating
within a distressed industry if the industry median (based on 4-digit
SIC code) stock return for the 12 months immediately prior to the
Chapter 11 filing is less than -30%. (6)
Panel A of Table 3 presents the results for the filing date. All
portfolios of rivals to filing firms operating in concentrated
industries experience significant positive abnormal returns over the
3-day whereas rivals to filing firms operating in competitive industries
experience significant negative abnormal returns over all three event
windows. Looking at the competitive effects experienced by the
concentrated industries, we find that abnormal returns increase in
magnitude and significance if the filing firm is economically distressed
and operates in a concentrated industry (2.38% over the 5-day window,
significant at the 1% level). This provides evidence to support the
notion that competitors stand to gain more when the probability that the
filing firm will not emerge is high. That the bankruptcy filing of a
competitor may benefit rivals is further shown by the abnormal CAR even
when the industry distressed over the 5-day window, we find that the CAR
for rival portfolios is an economically significant 6.36% (significant
at the 1% level) when the industry is concentrated and distressed while
the filing firm is economically distressed. Thus, in a distressed
industry with few competitors (high concentration), rivals may stand to
gain more than losses due to extra information released to the market at
the time of filing, especially if the entire industry is distressed.
Panel B presents the results for the distress date and provides
further evidence that the positive returns experienced by the rivals on
the filing date are due to competitive effects. Contagion effects
occurring due to information about the rival firm's distress would
have already happened since the information is already available in the
market at the time of filing. This is evidenced from the uniform
negative abnormal returns around all the event windows surrounding the
distress date. Rivals operating in competitive industries lose more than
those in concentrated industries (-1.41% significant at the 1% level
versus -0.35% insignificant over the 5-day window). However, when the
subsample of economically distressed filing firms operating in
concentrated industries is considered, the effects are more severe, over
the 5-day window, rivals to economically distressed filing firms
operating in concentrated industries experience -0.92% abnormal equity
returns (significant at the 1% level). When broken into a further
subsample based on industry distress, the point estimates increase in
magnitude but the 5-day abnormal returns are not statistically
significant though the 3-day and the 11-day are significant at the 1%
level. The distress date is, by construction, one in which new and
unambiguous information is available to the market about the filing
firm's distress. Therefore, on this date, we observe clear
contagion effects. Competitive effects are not seen on the distress date
since such effects arise from the potential elimination of the competing
firm and while current distress might lead to future elimination, it is
not sure that it will.
B. Multivariate Analysis of Distress and Filing Announcement
Abnormal Returns to Rivals
Table 4 presents the results from the multivariate regression using
the equal weighted rival portfolio returns around the 5-day period
surrounding the filing date as the dependent variable. Column 1 presents
the results from using the full sample of firms. In the preceding
analysis of abnormal returns, firms operating in competitive industries
experienced significant negative abnormal returns due to the information
effect while those in concentrated industries experienced significant
positive abnormal returns due to competitive gains from the potential
elimination of a rival. Therefore, within the full sample of firms, some
firms are expected to gain while others stand to lose. This is in
accordance with the overall lack of explanatory power and the lack of
significance in the results in Column 1.
In Column 2, we consider the subsample of firms operating in
concentrated industries only. We find that the degree of economic
distress is strongly negatively associated with the rival portfolio
returns. As the filing firm's moves from being purely economically
distressed to purely financially distressed, the rival portfolios
experience more negative abnormal returns. The degree of distress
variable alone explains about 5.9% of the variation in the rival
portfolio returns around the filing date. In Column 3, where all the
other explanatory variables are also included, the coefficient remains
virtually unchanged, both in size and in significance. The only other
variable significant is the RandD intensity of the filing firm. Rivals
stand to lose more if the filing rival had a large amount of RandD
expenditure. This is expected since higher RandD expenses would imply
that product specificity is important for the industry. Therefore, the
filing might convey new information about the industry. (7)
In Column 4, the subsample of only those rival portfolios where the
industry is distressed is included. The number of observations in this
specification drops to 28. However, the degree of economic distress
remains significant and the point estimate increases in magnitude. Rival
firms stand to gain more from the potential elimination of a competitor
when the entire industry is struggling. Filing firm size is also
significantly negatively related to the abnormal equity returns realized
by the rivals. This is in accordance with Aghion, Hart, and Moore, 1992
whereby the relatively larger level of financing requirements as well as
higher asset fire sale costs, makes larger firms more difficult to
acquire, sell or liquidate. The leverage of the filing firm's
rivals is also negatively associated with the CAR. This is in agreement
with Lang and Stulz (1992) finding that rivals of the filing firm with
higher leverage suffer greater contagion effects. The effect of the
filing firm's distress on its rivals is likely to be amplified in
the presence of higher debt levels in the rival's own capital
structure.
Column 5 presents the results for the subsample of filing firms
which operate in competitive industries. Apart from the indicator for
prepackaged bankruptcies, none of the other explanatory variables are
significant. Filings which use prepackaged bankruptcies are associated
with a positive effect on the rival CAR. Rivals operating in competitive
industries do not stand to gain much if the filing firm is eliminated.
Therefore, a rival filing for a prepackaged bankruptcy might convey
positive information to the market since empirical evidence (e.g.,
Tashjian et al (1996) show that prepackaged bankruptcies are associated
with a higher likelihood of emerging as standalone firms from the
Chapter 11 process). Overall, the abnormal returns of concentrated
industries are driven by factors which are different from those driving
the CARs of completive industries. While such differences in the drivers
of CAR are evident when the samples are divided by the concentration, it
is surprising that the concentration variable itself is not significant
in any of the specifications.
Table 5 presents the results of the same multivariate regression as
in Table 4 but using the CAR of the equal weighted rival portfolios in
the 5-day period surrounding the distress date rather than the filing
date. Column 1 includes only the filing firm's degree of economic
distress as an explanatory variable for the full sample while Column 2
includes both filing firm's degree of economic distress as well as
an indicator for industry distress. While the coefficient of the filing
firm degree of economic distress is positive and marginally significant
implying that the more (less) financially (economically) distressed the
filing firm is, the more the CAR of the rival portfolio. Therefore,
competitive effects are not in evidence during the distress period.
Instead, strong information effects are evident as shown by the
significant negative coefficient on the industry distress variable.
During the distress period of the rival firm, information about the
industry is released to the market. The negative and significant
coefficient is present in Column 3 in which all explanatory variables
are included. However, while the degree of economic distress variable
remains marginally significant, none of the other variables are
significant. Columns 4 and 5 present results for the subsamples in
concentrated and competitive industries respectively. In the subsample
of concentrated industries, neither industry distress nor the filing
firm's degree of economic distress is significant though both
coefficients retain the same sign as that in the specification using the
full sample. In contrast, firms operating in competitive industries
experience significantly lower CAR if their industry is also distressed.
The filing firm's degree of economic distress remains only
marginally significant in this subsample.
Taking the results from both the distress and the filing date into
account, it is clear that firms which operate in concentrated industries
derive significant gains in terms of stock returns, but only at the time
of the Chapter 11 filing. When the first news of their rival's
distress is released to the market, rivals experience significant
negative abnormal returns. Therefore, rivals experience both positive
and negative effects but the timing differs. Negative Information
effects dominate during the distress period but the filing itself which
might lead to the potential elimination of a rival is construed as a
positive development. If the filing firm is economically rather than
financially distressed, and consequently has lower probability of
emergence, rivals in concentrated industries stand to gain relatively
more.
IV. ANALYSIS OF CHANGES IN OPERATING PERFORMANCE OF RIVALS AROUND
FILING PERIOD
In this section, we examine changes in rivals' realized
operating performance following the filing announcement to investigate
whether rival bankruptcy results in changed sales, costs, or margins and
whether such changes are related to the probability of successful
emergence of the filing rival firm. We start by following Zhang
(2010)'s approach to calculate the average measure of each
operating performance measure using the entire universe of Compustat
firms for that particular year. We then adjust each rival
portfolio's operating measure by subtracting this Compustat-average
operating measure. The bankrupt firms and their rivals are excluded when
calculating the Compustat average. We follow this process and calculate
adjusted operating metrics for both the pre-filing year (year before the
filing) and the first post-filing year. Ultimately, we are able to find
220 Compustat-adjusted rival portfolios in the years prior to and after
rival bankruptcy.
Table 6 presents changes in several adjusted financial measures for
rival portfolios beginning at time -1, the fiscal year end prior to
their distressed rival's Chapter 11 filing to the subsequent
(filing) year. In the concentrated subsample results in Panel A, the
change in adjusted sales-to-assets is insignificant but there is a
significant (in the median) increase in the size of assets between the
two years. The operating profit and SGandA show significant (at 5%
level) improvements in median terms as well. (8) Panel B presents the
results for the subsamples for firms operating in competitive
industries. For the subsample operating in competitive industries, the
adjusted operating profit margin improves significantly and is
economically more significant than that for the concentrated subsample.
In both subsamples, the increase in operating profits (scaled by assets)
arises despite the statistically significant increase in asset size. The
source of the increase in operating profit seems to arise for improved
selling efficiencies as seen from the decline in SGandA for both
concentrated and competitive industries. There is a drop in SGandA in
concentrated industries which is significant at the 5% level but
surprisingly, firms operating in competitive industries also experience
significant declines in SGandA.
In order to identify whether the changes in the operating profits
and SGandA of the rivals are related to the filing firm's distress,
we run a multivariate regression with the change in Compustat-adjusted
SGandA around the filing year as the dependent variable. The independent
variables remain the same as in previous regressions. Table 7 presents
the results of the regression. Column 1 presents the results for the
full sample while Columns 2 and 3 present results for subsamples of
concentrated and competitive industries respectively. As can be seen
from Column 1, for the full sample, as the filing firm's degree of
distress goes up numerically i.e. the filing firm moves from pure
economic distress to pure financial distress, and therefore is more
likely to emerge as a standalone firm, the SGandA of the rival portfolio
increases. Therefore, change in SGandA is positively correlated with the
degree of economic distress. This is expected since a rival stands to
gain more in terms of selling efficiencies if the filing firm
disappears. Results in Column 2 and Column 3 indicate that changes in
SGandA are related to the filing firm's degree of economic distress
only in those firms which operate in concentrated industries. Both the
coefficient size and significance increases in the concentrated
subsample and declines to insignificance in the competitive subsample.
Therefore, only firms in concentrated industries stand to gain if their
rival potentially disappears due to the effects of distress. The
indicator for industry distress is significant only in the competitive
subsample and indicates that rivals operating in competitive industries
appear to have lower SGandA if the industry is distressed. This might be
possible if lower SGandA is associated with declining sales and by
extension, declining selling costs. Untabulated results using the change
in Compustat-adjusted operating profits over the same period as the
dependent variable shows qualitatively similar results (i.e. firms in
concentrated industries experience increases in operating profits if the
rival filing for Chapter 11 is more economically distressed rather than
financially distressed).
In summary, after examining changes in operating performance around
the filing year, we find that all rival portfolios in the sample
experience significant improvements in operating profits, declines in
SGandA and increases in asset size. However, there is no evidence to
point towards increases in actual sales. When considered in a
multivariate setting, changes in SGandA in only the concentrated
subsample of rivals is shown to be related to the filing firm's
degree of economic distress. As the filing is less likely to emerge from
the filing as a standalone firm if it is economically distressed, its
competitors improve their selling efficiency more.
V. CONCLUSION
This study shows that the competitive effects of bankruptcy arise
from the event of rival filing and not necessarily due to the pre-filing
distress of rivals. Around the event windows surrounding the distress
date (date of first news about filing firm's distress), rival firms
operating in concentrated industries experience negative abnormal equity
returns i.e. contagion effects. However, the event of filing is
associated with an increased likelihood that the distressed firm will be
eliminated from the industry. Consistent with this hypothesis, we
observe competitive gains in abnormal equity returns around the filing
dates for rivals in concentrated industries. Such competitive gains
depend on the likelihood of the rival emerging successfully and results
show that if the filing firm is economically distressed and therefore,
has a lower likelihood of emerging as a standalone firm, rivals gain
more. On the other hand, rival firms operating in competitive industries
lose both during the distress- and the filing- period. In competitive
industries, rivals operating in distressed industries experience greater
contagion during the distress period and a filing firm which is more
financially rather than economically distressed (and would therefore
have a higher chance of survival) seems to have positive effects on its
rivals.
Turning to operating performance changes over the filing period,
univariate tests show that rival firms gain in assets, operating margins
and lower costs during this period. However, these changes are linked to
the chances of survival (in the form of economic versus financial
distress) of the filing firm for only those rivals operating in
concentrated industries.
ENDNOTES
(1.) http://lopucki.law.ucla.edu/
(2.) BAPCPA amended a number of provisions applicable to chapter 11
cases such as amendments to 11 U.S.C. [section][section] 1112, 1121, and
1129 set deadlines for the filing of plans and disclosure statements and
for plan confirmation.
(4.) Under BAPCPA, the entire process of assumption or rejection of
leases must be completed within 210 days whereas pre-BAPCPA, debtors
were allowed 60 days but with potential for extensions.
(5.) Dropping the post BAPCPA bankruptcies leads to weaker results
due to a much smaller sample size though the trends and directions
observed remain qualitatively similar.
(6.) http://lopucki.law.ucla.edu/tables_and_graphs/Filings_by_year.pdf
(7.) Value weighting the portfolios leads to similar results.
(8.) Results are robust to inclusion of year and industry fixed
effects.
(9.) To ameliorate the concern that the insignificance of the
change in sales/asset ratio is driven by the large changes in assets, we
calculate the percentage change in sales (not tabulated) and find it to
be insignificant.
REFERENCES
Acharya, V., S. Bharath, and A. Srinivasan, 2007, "Does
Industry-Wide Distress Affect Defaulted Firms? Evidence from Creditor
Recoveries." Journal of Financial Economics 85, 787-821.
Aghion, P., O. Hart, and J. Moore, 1992, "The Economics of
Bankruptcy Reform." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 8
(3), 523-546.
Bharath, S., V. Panchapagesan, and I. Werner, 2014, "The
Changing Nature of Chapter 11." Unpublished working paper. IIM
Bangalore.
Ferris, S., N. Jayaraman, and A. Makhija, 1997, "The Response
of Competitors to Announcements of Bankruptcy: An Empirical Examination
of Contagion and Competitive Effects," Journal of Corporate Finance
3, 367-395.
Hertzel, M., Z. Li, M. Officer, and K. Rogers, 2008,
"Inter-firm Linkages and the Wealth Effects of Financial Distress
along the Supply Chain." Journal of Financial Economics 87,
374-387.
Hotchkiss, E., J. Kose, R. Mooradian, and K. Thorburn, 2008,
"Bankruptcy and the Resolution of Financial Distress," in B.
Espen Eckbo (ed.), Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate
Finance, Vol. 2, Elsevier/North-Holland, Ch. 14, 234-287.
Jorion, P., and G. Zhang, 2007, "Good and Bad Credit
Contagion: Evidence from Credit Default Swaps." Journal of
Financial Economics 84, 860-883.
Jorion, P., and G. Zhang, 2009, "Credit Contagion from
Counterparty Risk." Journal of Finance 64, 2053-2087.
Kolay, M., 2017, "Competitive Effects in Corporate Bankruptcy:
Evidence from Industry Factors." Journal of Strategic and
International Studies, 12(2), 72-79.
Kolay, M, M. Lemmon, and E. Tashjian, 2016, "Spreading the
Misery? Sources of Bankruptcy Spillover in the Supply Chain."
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 51 (6), 1955-1990.
Lang, L., and R. Stulz, 1992, "Contagion and Competitive
Intra-Industry Effects of Bankruptcy Announcements." Journal of
Financial Economics 32, 45-60.
Lemmon, M., Y. Ma, and E. Tashjian, 2009, "Survival of the
Fittest? Financial and Economic Distress and Restructuring Outcomes in
Chapter 11." Unpublished working paper. University of Utah.
Patell, J., 1976, "Corporate Forecasts of Earnings per Share
and Stock Price Behavior: Empirical Test." Journal of Accounting
Research, 246-276.
Tashjian, E., R. Lease, and J. McConnell, 1996, "Prepacks: An
Empirical Analysis of Prepackaged Bankruptcies." Journal of
Financial Economics 40, 135-162.
Zhang G., 2010, "Emerging from Chapter 11 Bankruptcy: Is It
Good News or Bad News for Industry Competitors?" Financial
Management, Winter, 1719-1742.
Madhuparna Kolay
University of Portland
kolay@up.edu
Table 1
Distribution of firms filing chapter 11 and rival portfolios
This table describes the distribution of the final sample of firms
filing for Chapter 11 bankruptcies by year. The sample period is from
1980 to 2009 and includes 225 events. Column 2 reports the number of
firms filing each year while Column 3 provides information about
industry coverage in terms of four-digit SIC code. Column 4 presents
the average book value of total assets in millions of the filing firm.
Columns 5-7 present information about the mean, minimum and maximum
number of rivals included in equal weighted industry portfolios for
each filing event. (*) denotes in millions.
Year of Frequency Average Number of Mean
Chapter of total industries number of
11 filing assets (*) rival firms
1980 1 625 1 1
1981 1 1,432 1 5
1982 5 413 4 68
1983 2 580 2 33
1984 3 1,021 3 108
1985 2 770 2 8
1986 3 2,654 2 87
1987 4 9,689 3 12
1988 2 828 2 17
1989 6 2,214 3 22
1990 11 986 6 30
1991 10 1,611 6 16
1992 5 1,453 5 40
1993 8 699 7 14
1994 2 1,082 2 10
1995 5 596 3 20
1996 6 848 4 13
1997 4 535 3 7
1998 6 433 6 65
1999 12 738 8 36
2000 18 1,431 7 54
2001 22 3,037 7 67
2002 26 5,899 10 41
2003 15 1,131 7 23
2004 8 1,179 5 12
2005 10 8,476 4 17
2006 2 5,744 1 25
2007 2 370 2 22
2008 6 1,633 5 10
2009 12 20,148 9 42
Full sample 219 2,609 4 31
Year of Min Max
Chapter number of number of
11 filing rival firms rival firms
1980 1 1
1981 5 5
1982 1 291
1983 30 35
1984 21 272
1985 7 8
1986 19 222
1987 1 33
1988 13 21
1989 14 28
1990 3 193
1991 1 41
1992 2 175
1993 4 30
1994 7 13
1995 2 33
1996 2 31
1997 5 8
1998 14 185
1999 3 175
2000 3 440
2001 2 209
2002 2 176
2003 1 87
2004 1 33
2005 1 31
2006 25 25
2007 15 28
2008 2 24
2009 1 155
Full sample 7 100
Table 2
Descriptive statistics of main variables
This table provides descriptive statistics for cross-sectional
variables (N = 219). Rival firm leverage is calculated as the average
of the rival's total liabilities-to-total assets at year -1 and -2
relative to filing. Filing firm RandD intensity is RandD expenses/total
assets for each bankrupt firm calculated as average of RandD
expenses-to-total assets at year -1 and -2 relative to filing. Industry
concentration is the Herfindahl index calculated for each filing firm
using all the firms in the same 4 digit SIC code. The degree of
economic (v. financial distress) is proxied for each firm by summing
the deciles obtained by performing in-sample sorts of the sample of
bankrupt firms into deciles (zero being smallest and nine being
largest) on the basis of both industry-adjusted EBITDA-to-assets and
leverage. Industry adjustment is done by subtracting the industry
median EBITDA-to-total assets from the sample firm's EBITDA-to-total
assets. Leverage is calculated as the ratio of total liabilities to
total assets averaged over two years prior to the year of filing. The
proxy ranges from 0 to 18, 0-5 being economically distressed, 14-18
being financially distressed, and the remaining being mixed type of
distress. Industry distress is an indicator variable that equals one if
stock return of the median firm in the filing firm's industry is less
than -30% in the 12 months immediately prior to Chapter 11 filing.
Filing firm size is the log of the book value of total assets of the
filing firm averaged at year -1 and -2 relative to filing. Prepackaged
filing is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm's Chapter 11 is
a prepackaged bankruptcy, and zero otherwise. Panel A reports the
summary statistics for the main variables, and Panel B presents the
Pearson correlation coefficients. In Panel B, p-values are presented in
parentheses.
Panel A: Summary statistics of main variables
Variable N Mean Median
Filing firm degree of economic distress 219 9.28 9.00
Rival firm leverage 219 0.78 0.69
Filing firm size 219 7.86 7.01
Industry concentration 219 0.23 0.17
Filing firm RandD intensity 219 0.01 0.00
Industry distress 219 0.31 0.00
Prepackaged filing 219 0.26 0.00
Panel B: Correlation table
Filing firm Rival firm Filing Industry
degree of leverage firm size concentration
economic
distress
Rival firm 0.1234
leverage (0.066)
Filing firm size 0.1195 0.0265
(0.074) (0.694)
Industry 0.1331 -0.0462 -0.0823
concentration (0.047) (0.492) (0.220)
Filing firm -0.0698 -0.0376 -0.0183 0.1007
RandD intensity (0.297) (0.577) (0.784) (0.133)
Industry distress -0.0417 0.0047 0.0864 -0.0346
(0.534) (0.945) (0.197) (0.607)
Prepackaged 0.1662 0.1480 0.0043 0.1118
filing (0.013) (0.027) (0.950) (0.095)
Variable
Filing firm degree of economic distress
Rival firm leverage
Filing firm size
Industry concentration
Filing firm RandD intensity
Industry distress
Prepackaged filing
Panel B: Correlation table
Filing Industry
firm distress
RandD
intensity
Rival firm
leverage
Filing firm size
Industry
concentration
Filing firm
RandD intensity
Industry distress 0.1333
(0.046)
Prepackaged -0.0546 -0.0394
filing (0.415) (0.557)
Table 3
Industry abnormal equity returns around a firm's filing and distress
events
The table contains average filing-period and distress-period rival
cumulative abnormal portfolio returns. A rival portfolio is an
equal-weighted portfolio of all other Compustat firms in the same
four-digit SIC code for which equity returns are available. The market
return is proxied by the CRSP value-weighted equity index. The distress
day is the first date with major news of financial distress in the 12
months prior to filing. Industry concentration is the Herfindahl index
calculated for each filing firm or supplier firm using all the firms in
the same 4 digit SIC code. High (low) concentration indicates that the
industry has above (below) sample average industry concentration. The
degree of economic (v. financial distress) is proxied using a measure
that is constructed similarly to Lemmon et al. (2009) by 1) averaging
the firm's industry-adjusted EBITDA-to-assets and ranking this into
deciles among all Chapter 11 sample firms, 2) leverage and ranking this
into deciles among all Chapter 11 sample firms, and 3) summing these
two decile rankings. The degree of economic distress takes on values
from 0 to 18, with high values having a higher degree of financial
distress and low values having a higher degree of economic distress. A
high degree of economic distress indicates a firm with below sample
average mean of degree of economic distress. Industry distress is an
indicator variable that equals one if stock return of the median firm
in the filing firm's industry is less than -30% in the 12 months
immediately prior to Chapter 11 filing. Panel A presents results for
the filing-day period while Panel B presents results for the
distress-day period. Standard errors are computed as described in
Patell (1976). (***), (**), or (*) indicates that the average is
significantly different from zero (using a two-sided t-test) at the 1%,
5%, or 10% level, respectively. Panel A: Rival average cumulative
abnormal returns for filing announcement date
Panel A: Rival average cumulative abnormal returns for filing
announcement date
Rival Cumulative Abnormal Returns on Filing date
Full High Low High concentration
sample concentration concentration /High degree of
economic distress
[-1,1] 0.43% 0.84% (*) -0.63% (***) 1.99% (***)
[-2,2] 0.59% 1.10% (**) -0.61% (***) 2.38% (***)
[-5,5] 0.71% 1.36% (**) -1.00% (***) 2.62% (***)
# of 219 140 79 74
portfolios
High concentration /High
degree of economic
distress/Industry distressed
[-1,1] 4.99% (***)
[-2,2] 6.36% (***)
[-5,5] 5.23% (**)
# of 20
portfolios
Panel B: Rival average cumulative abnormal returns for distress
announcement date
Full High Low
sample concentration concentration
[-1,1] -0.84% (***) -0.63% (***) -1.14% (***)
[-2,2] -0.83% (***) -0.35% -1.41% (***)
[-5,5] -1.35% (***) -1.04% (*) -1.54% (***)
# of 219 140 79
portfolios
High concentration High concentration /High
/High degree of degree of economic
economic distress distress/Industry distressed
[-1,1] -1.02% (***) -2.07% (***)
[-2,2] -0.92% (***) -1.15%
[-5,5] -1.96% (***) -4.28% (***)
# of 74 20
portfolios
Table 4
Cross-sectional analysis of industry rival's CAR around filing date
This table presents the coefficient estimates of cross-sectional
regressions for the rival portfolio's abnormal returns around the
filing date. The dependent variable is the CAR for the industry
portfolio from a MAR model for the [-2, +2] daily interval, where Day 0
is the firm filing date. Rival firm leverage is calculated as the
average of the rival's total liabilities-to-total assets at year -1 and
-2 relative to filing. Filing firm RandD intensity is RandD
expenses/total assets for each bankrupt firm calculated as average of
RandD expenses-to-total assets at year -1 and -2 relative to filing.
Industry concentration is the Herfindahl index calculated for each
filing firm using all the firms in the same 4 digit SIC code. The
degree of economic (v. financial distress) is proxied using the measure
described in Table 2. Industry distress is an indicator variable that
equals one if stock return of the median firm in the filing firm's
industry is less than -30% in the 12 months immediately prior to
Chapter 11 filing. Filing firm size is the log of the book value of
total assets of the filing firm averaged at year -1 and -2 relative to
filing. Prepackaged filing is a dummy variable that equals one if the
firm's Chapter 11 is a prepackaged bankruptcy, and zero otherwise.
Model 1 includes the full sample for which data is available while
Models 2-5 present results for subsample of filing firm rivals for whom
the industry concentration is above the sample median. Model 6 presents
results from using the subsample with below median industry
concentration. The t-statistics are presented in parentheses are
heteroscedasticity-robust.
Full Above median Above
sample industry median
(1) concentration industry
(2) concentration
(3)
Intercept 0.044 0.045 0.094
(2.15) (**) (3.09) (***) (3.00) (***)
Filing firm -0.001 -0.004 -0.004
degree of econ. (-1.49) (-3.08) (***) (-2.94) (***)
distress
Industry distress 0.012 0.018
(1.43) (1.31)
Filing firm size -0.006 -0.006
(-2.02) (*) (-1.4)
Rival firm -0.004 -0.010
leverage (-0.84) (-1.56)
Filing firm -0.088 -0.240
RandD intensity (-0.81) (-2.47) (**)
Industry 0.017 -0.012
concentration (0.88) (-0.42)
Prepackaged 0.010 0.002
filing (1.39) (0.18)
Year dummies No No No
Industry No No No
dummies
# of 219 140 140
observations
p-value of 0.120 0.006 0.048
F statistic
Adjusted 0.021 0.059 0.068
R-squared
Above Above median At or below
median industry median
industry concentration/ industry
concentration Industry concentration
(4) distressed (5) (6)
Intercept 0.224 0.342 0.013
(4.63) (***) (3.25) (***) (0.39)
Filing firm -0.004 -0.006 0.001
degree of econ. (-2.63) (***) (-2.57) (**) (1.19)
distress
Industry distress 0.023 0.008
(0.21) (0.82)
Filing firm size -0.015 -0.027 -0.005
(-3.87) (***) (-2.41) (**) (-1.34)
Rival firm -0.006 -0.143 0.006
leverage (-0.97) (-2.18) (**) (0.98)
Filing firm -0.159 -0.849 -0.067
RandD intensity (-1.23) (-1.49) (-0.35)
Industry -0.053 0.060 -0.025
concentration (-1.62) (0.63) (-0.22)
Prepackaged -0.010 0.013 0.017
filing (-0.69) (0.59) (1.95) (**)
Year dummies Yes No No
Industry Yes No No
dummies
# of 140 28 79
observations
p-value of 0.114 0.043 0.265
F statistic
Adjusted 0.120 0.273 0.018
R-squared
Table 5
Cross-sectional analysis of industry rival's CAR around distress date
This table presents the coefficient estimates of cross-sectional
regressions for the rival portfolio's abnormal returns around the
distress date. The dependent variable is the CAR for the industry
portfolio from a MAR model for the [-2, +2] daily interval, where Day 0
is the distress date. The distress day is the first date with major
news of financial distress in the 12 months prior to filing. Additional
details are in Section 3. Rival firm leverage is calculated as the
average of the rival's total liabilities-to-total assets at year -1 and
-2 relative to filing. Filing firm RandD intensity is RandD
expenses/total assets for each bankrupt firm calculated as average of
RandD expenses-to-total assets at year -1 and -2 relative to filing.
Industry concentration is the Herfindahl index calculated for each
filing firm using all the firms in the same 4 digit SIC code. The
degree of economic (v. financial distress) is proxied using the measure
described in Table 2. Industry distress is an indicator variable that
equals one if stock return of the median firm in the filing firm's
industry is less than -30% in the 12 months immediately prior to
Chapter 11 filing. Filing firm size is the log of the book value of
total assets of the filing firm averaged at year -1 and -2 relative to
filing. Prepackaged filing is a dummy variable that equals one if the
firm's Chapter 11 is a prepackaged bankruptcy, and zero otherwise.
Models 1-3 use the full sample while models 4 and 5 use subsamples with
industry concentration above (below) the sample median. The
t-statistics are presented in parentheses are heteroscedasticity-robust.
Dependent CAR over (-2, +2) for rival portfolios of filing
Variable firms over distress period
Full Full Full
sample sample sample
(1) (2) (3)
Intercept -0.018 -0.011 0.002
(-2.67) (***) (-1.59) (0.12)
Filing firm degree 0.001 0.001 0.001
of economic (1.80) (*) (1.67) (*) (1.81) (*)
distress
Industry distress -0.022 -0.022
(-2.95) (***) (-2.98) (***)
Filing firm size -0.003
(-1.26)
Rival firm 0.007
leverage (0.77)
Filing firm 0.084
RandD intensity (1.06)
Industry -0.009
concentration (-0.46)
Prepackaged -0.003
filing (-0.42)
# of observations 219 219 219
p-value of 0.128 0.003 0.011
F statistic
Adjusted 0.006 0.044 0.038
R-squared
Dependent CAR over (-2, +2) for rival portfolios of filing
Variable firms over distress period
Above Below
median median
industry industry
concentration concentration
(4) (5)
Intercept 0.023 -0.006
(0.81) (-0.20)
Filing firm degree 0.001 0.002
of economic (1.06) (1.91) (*)
distress
Industry distress -0.013 -0.029
(-1.25) (-2.67) (***)
Filing firm size -0.003 -0.002
(-0.77) (-0.65)
Rival firm 0.006 0.010
leverage (1.32) (0.57)
Filing firm 0.154 -0.126
RandD intensity (3.52) (***) (-1.00)
Industry -0.047 -0.105
concentration (-1.60) (-0.99)
Prepackaged -0.016 0.010
filing (-1.91) (*) (0.96)
# of observations 140 79
p-value of 0.191 0.023
F statistic
Adjusted 0.028 0.085
R-squared
Table 6
Change in operating performance of rivals around filing year
This table presents the Compustat-adjusted measures of operating
performance for rival portfolios to filing firms. Each value is a
difference found by subtracting the variable value of the average of
all firms in Compustat for that fiscal year. Year 0 is the fiscal year
end following the bankruptcy filing while Year 1 is the pre-filing
year. Operating profit margin is defined as EBITDA/Total Assets. Gross
margin is defined as (Sales-COGS)/Sales. SGA is the Selling, General
and Administration costs. Panel A presents results for the subsamples
where the industry concentration is above the median sample value
whereas Panel B presents the results for the subsample of firms with
below median industry concentration. The p-values (reported in
parentheses) are calculated from t-tests for the means and from
Wilcoxon rank sum tests for the medians. (*), (**), and (***) indicate
significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Panel A: Above median industry concentration
Variable N Mean p value of Median
t-stat
Gross profit/sales 105 -0.794 0.27 -0.068
Operating profit/Assets 105 -0.042 0.86 0.066
SGA/Sales 105 -0.110 0.63 -0.310
Sales/Assets 105 0.319 0.13 0.026
Percent change in assets 105 -0.339 0.53 0.124
Variable p value of signed rank
z-stat
Gross profit/sales 0.98
Operating profit/Assets 0.05 (**)
SGA/Sales 0.03 (**)
Sales/Assets 0.17
Percent change in assets <.0001 (***)
Panel B: Below median industry concentration
Change from pre-filing year to year of rival's Chapter 11 filing of
below median industry concentration
Variable N Mean p value of Median
t-stat
Gross profit/sales 105 -0.371 0.56 -0.032
Operating profit/Assets 105 0.822 0.21 0.089
SGA/Sales 105 0.011 0.97 -0.078
Sales/Assets 105 0.009 0.80 0.011
Percent change in assets 105 -0.073 0.69 0.124
Variable p value of signed rank
z-stat
Gross profit/sales 0.73
Operating profit/Assets 0.00 (***)
SGA/Sales 0.18
Sales/Assets 0.65
Percent change in assets <.0001 (***)
Table 7
Multivariate regression of changes in SGandA of rivals around filing
year
This table presents the results of regressing the changes in rival
portfolio's Compustat-adjusted SGandA from the pre-filing year (-1) to
the filing year (0). Rival firm leverage is calculated as the average
of the rival's total liabilities-to-total assets at year -1 and -2
relative to filing. Filing firm RandD intensity is RandD expenses/total
assets for each bankrupt firm calculated as average of RandD
expenses-to-total assets at year -1 and -2 relative to filing. Industry
concentration is the Herfindahl index calculated for each filing firm
using all the firms in the same 4 digit SIC code. The degree of
economic (v. financial distress) is proxied using the measure described
in Table 2. Industry distress is an indicator variable that equals one
if stock return of the median firm in the filing firm's industry is
less than -30% in the 12 months immediately prior to Chapter 11 filing.
Filing firm size is the log of the book value of total assets of the
filing firm averaged at year -1 and -2 relative to filing. Prepackaged
filing is a dummy variable that equals one if the firm's Chapter 11 is
a prepackaged bankruptcy, and zero otherwise. Models 1-3 use the full
sample while models 4 and 5 use subsamples with industry concentration
above (below) the sample median. The t-statistics are presented in
parentheses are heteroscedasticity-robust.
Full sample Above median industry
(1) concentration (2)
Intercept -0.373 -0.567
(-0.52) (-0.75)
Filing firm degree of 0.105 0.139
economic distress (2.33) (**) (2.77) (***)
Industry distress -0.366 0.905
(-0.81) (1.52)
Filing firm size 0.009 0.021
(0.09) (0.19)
Rival firm leverage 0.132 0.265
(0.51) (1.13)
Filing firm RandD -12.87 -16.87
intensity (-1.67) (*) (-1.08)
Industry
concentration -1.348 -2.825
(-0.96) (-1.35)
Prepackaged filing -1.174 -1.095
(-2.56) (***) (-1.92) (*)
# of observations 210 105
p-value of F statistic 0.007 0.001
Adjusted R-squared 0.056 0.152
Below median industry
concentration (3)
Intercept -0.169
(-0.12)
Filing firm degree of 0.053
economic distress (0.79)
Industry distress -1.470
(-2.33) (**)
Filing firm size 0.062
(0.38)
Rival firm leverage 0.310
(0.57)
Filing firm RandD -5.795
intensity (-1.29)
Industry
concentration -1.908
(-0.30)
Prepackaged filing -1.248
(-1.88) (*)
# of observations 105
p-value of F statistic 0.224
Adjusted R-squared 0.023
COPYRIGHT 2018 Premier Publishing, Inc.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.