EXPLORING COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE IN A REGIONAL COMMUNITY CONTEXT.
Rowe, James E. ; McLaren, Don
EXPLORING COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE IN A REGIONAL COMMUNITY CONTEXT.
1. INTRODUCTION
Most people do not associate competitive advantage with strategic
business planning. We believe that communities need to rethink how to
leverage competitive advantage by approaching the problem from a
business planning perspective. According to Deimler and Stern (2006),
strategy is one of the most used and abused words in the business world.
Bruce Henderson captured the concept when he observed that:
"All competitors who persist over time must maintain a unique
advantage by differentiation over all others. Managing that
differentiation is the essence of long-term business strategy"
(Deimler and Stern, 2006).
Michael Porter also makes the link between strategy and competitive
advantage who when describing strategy states that:
"Strategy attempts to achieve sustainable competitive
advantage by preserving what is distinctive about the company. It means
performing different activities from rivals or performing similar
activities in different ways" (Porter, 2011).
Using strategy for gaining a competitive advantage is not new,
history informs us that strategy and competitive advantage has its
origins with Sun Tzu, Alexander the Great and other great military
leaders, and was then grounded in winning battles and wars both on land
and at sea. If we consider where strategy originated, the fundamentals
are about influencing the end state or simply winning.
The notion of creating shared value is that the competitiveness of
a company and the health of the communities around it are mutually
dependent, it could be argued that economic development practitioners
have understood this concept of strategic development for some time
especially those at the front line of regional or community economic
development. These same practitioners also appreciate the value of
collaborations as a tool for stimulating or creating economic action in
a community. Porter and Kramer (2011) expanded this concept when they
stated that:
"Shared value creation will involve new and heightened forms
of collaboration. While some shared, value opportunities are possible
for a company to seize on its own, others will benefit, from insights,
skills, and resources that cut across profit/nonprofit and
private/public boundaries."
Essentially adopting a shared value strategy moves the enterprise
business operations boundaries from a commercially defined place to an
economic development landscape that is inclusive of the community,
region or nation.
The Sun Tzu approach of two forces-the Zheng element, which fixes
the enemy in place, and the Qi element, which flanks or encircles the
enemy, either actually or psychologically-is still a relevant
fundamental principle today. The Zheng (ordinary) force is direct and
more obvious, while the Qi (extraordinary) is indirect, unexpected,
distracting, or unorthodox. Using both elements ensures that decisive
blows will fall where the enemy does not anticipate them, and is least
prepared. Alexander the Great adopted a similar approach when faced with
a far greater enemy he took the Qi element and flanked the opposing army
and divided it. If we consider these basic strategies to gain an
advantage in today's business context we find these principles are
still valid and used by organisations around the globe.
By 1805, Napoleon had conquered much of Europe and was planning to
invade England (Rumelt, 2011). Before he could invade, he had to gain
control of the seas over the British in order to cross the channel with
some certainty. Off the coast of Spain, the combined Spanish and French
fleet of 33 ships met the smaller British fleet of 27 ships. The
accepted battle tactics of the day were to stay the line and bombard the
opposing fleet with broadside shells. However, Nelson who had some
strategic insight split the fleet into two columns and drove them at the
opposing fleet hitting the line perpendicularly, betting on the
resulting confusion and the more experienced British captains. Nelson
won the battle of Trafalgar with the Franco-Spanish fleet losing 22
ships and no losses for Nelson. Nelson was fatally wounded but became
one of Britain's great naval heroes.
Consequently, many of us fully understand the agricultural and
industrial age with the advantage of hindsight and history (see Figure 1
below). However, the information and consciousness ages present some
challenges, mostly because we are never quite sure which age we are in,
we need the wisdom of hindsight to determine that and both of these are
quite intangible. With the industrial age, we built and manufactured
goods that were bought and sold, we touched it, photographed it and
transported it around the world. These two new ages are soft in nature
because they were not built or manufactured. The entire theatre of
competitive battle has moved not only to another paddock but to another
farm and this affects or influences every part of our lives today, from
the goods and services we buy to the places we visit. This in turn
affects communities as they need to attract visitors, investment and
residents.
2. COMPETITIVENESS
The concept of competitiveness has grown significantly in the past
decade (Kitson et al, 2004; Malecki, 2002, 2004) and is particularly
important for local economic development because many view it as the
path to economic prosperity (Camagni, 2002, p. 2395). While prominent
economists such as Paul Krugman (1996a; 1996b) have been highly critical
of the current fashion of promoting competitiveness, arguing that it is
nothing more than 'mercantilism in sheep's clothing' and,
thus, a threat to free trade, others disagree. Michael Porter (1998), in
his seminal study of competitive advantage, deplores the lack of
attention to competitiveness in standard international trade theory and
suggests that economic analysis is diminished by the lack of research in
this area. He criticises Krugman for his narrow view of competitiveness
as an attribute of companies, not of cities, regions, countries or
continents.
The vagueness of the concept of global competitiveness is open to
multiple interpretations and has led to confusion in the policy debate
(Francis, 1989; Polenske, 2004); if only because so many policy
initiatives are undertaken in its name. It is important to appraise the
different senses in which the term competitiveness is used. At one
level, it is equated, usually loosely, with the performance of an
economy as an absolute measure. At another, because it relates to
competition and it implies a comparative element, it is equated with the
implication that to be competitive, a city has to undercut its rivals or
offer better value for money (Begg, 1999). Rowe (2012, p. 75) has argued
that measuring the performance of the economy may be a useful indicator
of its competitiveness, but it is fundamentally flawed as an indicator
or criterion for assessing the effectiveness of an economic development
strategy.
In attempting to explain the determinants of competitiveness, Kresl
(1995) argues for a dichotomy between what he calls economic
determinants (factors of production, infrastructure and similar) and
strategic determinants which include policy factors and institutional
design. According to Malecki (2002; 2004), the competitiveness of places
(localities, regions and nations) refers to the ability of the local
economy and society to provide an increasing standard of living for its
inhabitants. The preoccupation with competitiveness and the predilection
for its measurement is premised on certain pervasive beliefs; most
notable that globalisation has created a world of intense competition
between regions (Raco, 2002). As a result of this competition, many
cities and regions copy 'best practice' strategies from other
areas in an effort to become more competitive.
This competition has also led to a proliferation of rankings. For
example, Auckland has recently been ranked the fifth best city in the
world for liveability by the Mercer Index (Walsh, 2003). Unfortunately,
such comparisons rely on subjective criteria that often fail to
'compare apples with apples'. Many United States communities
such as Lexington, Kentucky and Columbus, Ohio develop elaborate
strategies to place well on the Money and Fortune magazine's
popular urban liveability rankings (McCann, 2004, p. 1910). Rankings and
their development and use in the policy process can be analysed in the
context of the neoliberal shift towards a view of cities as
fundamentally competitive entities and consumption spaces (Malecki,
2004, p. 1107; McCann, 2004). As a result, in order to score well,
communities generate their own policy space instead of developing
innovative initiatives to solve local problems.
Consequently, the quest for better rankings has seen the emergence
of decontextualised copy-cat policies that fail to achieve their long
term economic development goals. In this context, contemporary urban
growth coalitions find themselves challenged with balancing their need
to learn from best practices while avoiding uncritically copying other
cities' policies (Harvey, 1989; McCann, 2004, p. 1922). As a
result, "cities look[ing] for best practice [often] end up
imitating each other" (Evan, 2003, p. 417). Many cities, such as
Wellington, developed its vision of the future based on the work of
Richard Florida (see Perry, 2011). Florida examined the factors that
encouraged creativity and found that social and ethnic diversity were
key ingredients (Florida, 2002, p. 745).
There is some evidence that new immigrants do add taxes and skills
to the local labour pools. However, there are the social drag effects of
newcomers as well. The notion that the best and brightest human
resources are the most likely to move to a new nation, in the current
world economic and political situation, may not be necessarily correct.
It has been shown that the mere presence of creative people is not
enough to sustain a creative urban area for the long term (Scott, 2006,
p. 11).
Despite the criticisms, Florida has argued that regional
development strategies should be about attracting and retaining creative
people. Yin (2002/2003) suggests that Florida's concepts only apply
to metropolitan areas of over 1 million people. If the population
thresholds are correct, then it would appear that smaller metropolitan
regions and rural areas are destined to remain backwaters of the new
economy (SGS Economic and Planning, 2004, p. 7). Therefore, according to
Rainnie (2005, p. 8), the "only future for these areas is to
accommodate the lifestyle or leisure pursuits of the burnt out beautiful
people". In the New Zealand context, based on Yin's
assumptions, only Auckland has the population base to cross the digital
divide and enjoy the benefits of the creative class. Florida's
creative people are human capital that should be imagined as a flow of
creative migrants. His research examines the factors that shape or
influence the flow by attempting to determine the divergent levels of
human capital across regions (Florida, 2006). This flow can be related
to the movements within nomadic space and the concept of
reterritorialisation (Colebrook, 2005, p. 182).
3. GLOBALISATION
The definitions of globalisation in the literature remain largely
elusive, vague and 'chaotic'. Globalisation is the
involvement, at a day-to-day level, of firms, people, and communities
with the rest of the world through global networks or a web of
connections (O'Conner et al., 2001). As a result, one cannot define
globalisation as concrete processes of socioeconomic and political
restructuring on a global scale without underscoring the ideological
foundations on which these processes operate (Y eung, 2002, p. 288). It
can, however, be defined as the rapid proliferation of crossborder
production, trade, and investment activities, spearheaded by global
corporations and international financial institutions that facilitate
the emergence of an increasingly integrated and interdependent global
economy seeking to maximise financial returns (Yeung, 2002, p. 289).
Globalisation is associated with increasingly complex circuits of
capital and an increasing flexibility in the response to changes in its
state of equilibrium. It enhances capital's capacity to defer and
displace its internal contradictions by increasing the scope of its
operation on a global scale. As a result, the world economy is being
reshaped by a complex dialectic of globalisation and regionalisation.
This has made it more difficult for national states to control economic
activities within their borders, let alone global capitalist dynamics.
This has led to an increase in the unstructured complexity of the
economy on a world scale and has triggered attempts to change existing
global smooth space into one that is controlled and regulated, i.e.
striated space.
Olma (2001, p. 116) has even asserted that "contemporary
mainstream discourse of social science has come to be called
globalisation ... and that capitalism has 're-invented' itself
in the form of globalisation". In giving support to this claim,
Jameson (1991, p. xiv) argues that one of postmodernism's tasks is
to coordinate new forms of practice with new forms of economic
production and organisation. David Harvey (1989) has also suggested that
postmodernism is the cultural form associated with the more flexible
modes of capital accumulation and a new phase of space-time compression
which has emerged in response to the crisis of the Fordist regime of
capitalist accumulation. This is noteworthy because according to Zizek
and Daly (2004, p. 149) "capitalism is becoming a problem again ...
[T]he honeymoon of globalisation, which lasted through the 90s, is
coming to an end ... which points out that people are again perceiving
capitalism as a problem". In the context of this article, Zizek and
Daly are articulating that the forces of globalisation are shaping local
economies and are being perceived as a problem because local people have
so little control over the process.
To further explain globalisation, Jessop and Sum (2000) coined the
term glurbanisation and borrowed the term glocalisation from Swyngedouw
(1997, p. 170). The former refers to entrepreneurial strategies that are
designed to create a local, regional or national state strategy that
builds global advantage by restructuring urban spaces to enhance
international competitiveness. Cities that seek to enhance their
place-based dynamic competitive advantages to capture certain types of
mobile capital and to fix local capital in place (Jessop, 2000; Jessop
and Sum, 2000) are better positioned to succeed. Economic globalisation
is therefore associated with such rescaling effects as global
localisation, or glocalisation and changing urban/regional governance.
The latter term, glocalisation, is concerned with establishing a
geographically concentrated interfirm division of labour (Jessop and
Sum, 2000, p. 2294). It refers to a firm's strategy to build global
advantage by exploiting local differences. It supplements market
exchange and government hierarchy with institutionalised negotiations to
mobilise consensus and build mutual understanding.
To paraphrase Marston et al. (2005, p. 425) globalisation is
composed of "dynamic collections of potential force relations and
movements". A globalised community can be visualised as being
anchored in an "ontology in which the world is made up of billions
of ... encounters ... consisting of multitudinous paths which
intersect" (Thrift, 1999, p. 302), and a "situated
epistemology which recognises [the] very strong limits on what can be
known and how we can know it" (p. 302) owing to the multiplicity of
its inter-connections.
As Harvey (1969, p. 208) notes, "much of the philosophy of
geography . stems from a container view of space which is particularly
associated with concepts of Newton and Kant". Harvey (1989) later
advocated for a meta-theoretical engagement with globalisation which was
subsequently criticised for generating the "illusion that [the meta
-theory] stands outside, not in, the world" (Morris, 1992, p. 275).
Such a view has led some scholars to embrace poststructuralism and Actor
Network Theory (ANT) to establish how hybridity and identities of
actants are relationally constituted via different varieties of networks
(Yeung, 2005, p. 41). These networks as part of the globalised world
offer a useful means of understanding the increasingly complex milieu of
interconnections and transterritorial transactions (Chesters and Welsh,
2005, p. 204).
Globalisation's deterritiorialisations tend to weaken the
national state in advanced capitalist societies and, according to
Deleuze, capitalism in its current phase has co-opted the state and
reduced it to an arm and instrument of market forces. Capitalism today
has the character of an "international ecumenical
organisation" that eludes the control of states. Capitalism, is
thus, "an independent, worldwide axiomatic that is like a singe
city, a megapolis ... of which the States are parts or
neighbourhoods" (Deleuze and Guattari, 1987, pp. 434-435).
"Never before," writes Deleuze and Guattari (1983, p. 252),
"has a State lost so much of its power in order to enter with so
much force into the service of the signs of economic power".
According to Harvey (1985) the concept of institutional thickness
introduced by Amin and Thrift "hold[s] the key to understanding the
working of the global economy". It involves a plethora of
organisations that interact intensively, generating shared
understandings and developing mutual awareness of being involved in a
common project to promote and sustain local or regional economic
development. Local development policies and practices are thus central
to the regulatory milieu of regional economies and the creation of
stabilised 'structured coherence'. Participation in the
globalised economy may be fluid along emerging lines of flight that are
informed, motivated and aspirational. In practical terms, the process
involves imaginaries, inventions and experimentation.
4. GLOBAL CITIES
The terms world cities or global cities have come to denote upwards
of thirty urban centres which are connected in a network that spans the
globe as the skeleton of the globalised economy (Beaverstock et al.,
2000). The prolifera of definitions for these cities are
indistinguishable because of the "undecidability of [its] meaning,
the constitutive power of discourse and the political effectivity of
theory and research" (Gibson-Graham, 2000, p. 95). In our opinion,
global cities should be seen as "a partially connected multiplicity
which can only ever be known partially and from multiples places"
(Thrift, 1997, p. 143) because global cities are "assemblages of
more or less distanciated economic relations" (Amin and Thrift,
2002, p. 52) that extend well beyond their borders.
Such world cities are places where this newly globalised economic
world has a tangible, concrete reality (Carroll, 2007). Global flows of
capital and labour move through world cities, and are controlled from
them through an integrated world capitalist system (Guattari, 2000).
This gives civil society and politics in such places a specific role:
they are not just products but also producers of these sets of seemingly
universal power. Because of this, global cities pose the challenge of a
governance of complexity (Keil, 1998, p, 617).
Global competitiveness in the urban context of rhizomatic networks
has been decoded in the notion of the global city. Early writings in the
world city literature dealt with the attributable dimensions of cities,
in particular how much power they possess vis-a-vis each other.
Friedmann (1978, p. 329) for example, treats power as a 'stock of
resources' to be used instrumentally as 'power over'
others. In contrast, Sassen (2000, p. 51) observes an emerging
'transnational urban system' with inter-city relations that
transcend simple competition. Smith and Doel (2007) offer a more
poststructuralist interpretation by suggesting that "global cities
need to be re-conceptualized as (not, in) networks: always connecting,
associating, affecting and being affected".
This is consequential because global cities exist as multiples of
complex interconnections and are not isolated single centres of
activity. This implies that an aspiring global city such as Auckland has
to be connected to other major cities, such as Sydney and Melbourne, via
air and sea transportation, telecommunications, etc. and more
importantly be a financial and business centre, competing with and
complimentary to, the other centres as a precondition to joining the
ranks of global cities (Rowe, 2006).
In Australia, the federal government pushed for national
competitiveness with the National Competition Policy. The New South
Wales government articulated the competitive city discourse and strongly
advocated for Sydney to graduate to global city status through a series
of position papers and strategies. This discourse can be articulated
from a neo-Gramscist perspective as:
"The institutional landscape in a discursive field where
stories of past, present and future create and dissolve economic
activity and opportunity. In this sense, we argue for a consciousness
about the metaphors devised to represent institutions within economic
territories and consciousness that requires understanding of the close
links between text, discourse and social change " (O'Neill and
McGuirk, 2005, p. 289).
This developed into a conscious agenda for seeking global city
status. There was a growing recognition of Sydney's position as a
strategic site in the transformation of the Australian national economy,
and a significant transition from government to governance and toward
entrepreneurial politics. Thus, it became a self-fulfilling prophesy
(McGuirk, 2004, pp. 1026-31).
The laws, principles and approaches of economic development have
moved and changed over time down through the ages as detailed in Figure
2. As society moves through the eras their perception and interpretation
of economic development and the appropriate response changes with the
environment around them and economic forces influencing them at the
time.
5. THE NOTION OF STRATEGY AS IT RELATES TO LOCAL ECONOMIC
DEVELOPMENT
Strategy according to Pfeffer and Sutton (2006) is the most used
and misunderstood concept in the world of business and commerce. In
Figure 2 below are three views of competitive strategy from the
recognised gurus of the subject. The common theme with all of these are
the ability to visualise, plan and execute a plan of action that
produces an advantage, whether that advantage is in a theatre of war,
the global competitive market place or a localised market.
To put strategy into a context with this discussion we will
consider the height and breadth of the strategic function. Johnson et
al. (2011) view the strategic function through two planes as shown in
Figure 3 below. This approach demonstrates that strategy or gaining a
competitive advantage touches all sections of an enterprise.
Continuing this line of reason then we can assume that creating a
community competitive advantage touches and or relies on the whole
community to be committed to the developed an agreed strategy that
delivers the competitive advantage that is being sought.
Before launching into community competitive advantage we need to
define what a community is, to be able to consider competitive advantage
or the strategies that create this state. The Cambridge Dictionary
definition of a town or community is:
"a place where people live and work, containing many houses,
shops, places of work, places of entertainment, etc., and usually larger
than a village but smaller than a city"
A regional community is a cluster of worlds and around each world
there are smaller nations, for example around a natural resource world
may be a tourism industry (see Figure 4 below). There could also be an
agriculture or mining industry. In our model, the manufacturing sector
may surround the infrastructure world.
For a community to create or to determine what its competitive
advantage is, it must first unite the worlds and connect the nations
that suround it. Figure 4 above is not comprehensive and there may well
be regional communities that have more worlds, however, it is intended
that the diagram be representitive of the concept and an average
community. The geography, regional science and economics literatures
have long discussed comparative/competitive advantage, typically without
regard to political boundaries. Distance to inputs and markets, the
local cost and productivitiy of factors of production, access to natural
resources and amenities, all were used to explain the growth and
development of city-regions (Luger, 2009, p. 113).
According to Johnson et al. (2011) strategy exists in three levels
of an enterprise as shown below in Figure 5:
This suggests that creating a strategy that delivers or defines
competitive advantage touches all aspects of the organisation or
enterprise.
The notion of strategy as the corner stone for future planning and
creating a competitive advantage is very popular. Pfeffer and Sutton
(2006) discovered 4.5 million entries for business strategy in google.
They noted a survey by the National Association of Directors in the US
showing that CEO's considered strategy ranking as number two in
importance to their companies. If strategy and the creation thereof is
so popular and important to enterprise then is strategy in itself a
destiny of competitive advantage? Richard Kovacevich of Wells Fargo Bank
argues that organisational culture and execution are more important and
has said "I could leave our strategy on a plane and it
wouldn't make any difference" (Pfeffer and Sutton, 2006). Anne
Mulcahy of Xerox and Kevin Rollins of Dell Computers agree with
Kovaceich saying that working towards common objectives, operational
efficiencies, culture and execution are the common ingredients to their
companies competitive advantage. Assuming that strategy is the destiny
of competitive advantage may not be the classic solution that is often
presented or relied upon to deliver.
Strategy and the production of strategic plans have also come a
long way in two decades. Most of us remember the first corporate
strategic plan we produced. The analysis and presentation in the
strategy was nothing short of a masterpiece and the CEO looked at it,
agreed with it, congratulated the author and promptly stamped
confidential on it and put it in his office safe never to see the light
of day again. Today we see business leaders carrying their strategic
plan around in a Powerpoint for all to see.
Strategy and the creation and implementation thereof in many
enterprises can take on the role of the piano player in the bar of an
old time western saloon. He understands the customers downstairs, what
they are doing and talking about but has no idea what is happening
upstairs at all. A truly competitive strategic plan delivering
competitive advantage must fully appreciate the culture, the modus
operandi and the operation both downstairs in the bar and upstairs for
the plan to be subscribed to by the stakeholders and executed at all.
6. STRATEGIC PLANNING FOR A COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE
The concept of formulating a competitive advantage through
strategic planning is not an exact science and a complex process with
many stakeholders and influencers to consider. The following diagram
(see Figure 6) sets out the landscape for such planning and development
endeavours and presents the scope of the project.
When approaching the development planning scope there is not only
the landscape to consider but there are a number of development levels
to include or address. These levels of development interest are depicted
in Figure 7. These levels are not definitive. They are only a guide to
options for planning and we anticipate each region or community
undertaking this activity will create their own levels of interest and
landscape to explore and develop.
The process of strategic planning in a community or regional
economic development context is not a precise science or a best guess
creative masterpiece, this type of planning requires in-depth analysis
of the surrounding environment and the economic players in the region.
The final production document must contain enough vision and innovative
content to inspire all of the stakeholders that dwell in the various
nations and worlds that surround the region or community.
An underpinning complexity for most regional economic development
plans is that the majority of strategic modelling or planning is built
around industry or on commercial foundations and therefore do not
contain the imprecise factors that are present in a community.
The planning model depicted in Figure 8 is designed to account for
the various factors that are important to communities but not so for a
commercial enterprise. The model starts on the right side using all the
appropriate strategic planning tools and models for analysis that create
a picture of the region. Then by contextualising the outputs we can
account for the community and its unique situation, and by incorporating
that into the strategic plan can generate meaningful outputs and
actions.
The input zone is populated by data, both historic and forecasts,
placed alongside trends and future development initiatives that will
affect the sector. This analysis will create a landscape or view of the
community that highlights development trends and options from a sector
view that will provide the foundation for contextualising the developing
strategy.
During the contextualising zone of strategic development, the
location factors are introduced for example:
* The geography--where is the community located in relation to
transport, access, natural and created attractions;
* The available infrastructure--how much is available and the
capital cost and challenges of expanding in terms of roads, power,
communications, water etc.;
* The retail and people infrastructure--this includes shopping,
accommodation, attractions ease of access etc.;
* The underpinning industry around the community--what industry and
other economic generators are at force in the community. Is it the
community growing, static or decreasing in terms of economic growth; and
* Support--what support is available for immigrants into the
community or business development support from Government or other
sources to encourage development
From this analysis, a community attractiveness factor can be
determined.
7. CONCLUSION
A region is competitive, by definition, in economic development
terms when it has the conditions to enable it to raise its standard of
living at a greater rate than the 'average' region that it
competes with or when it has developed the ability to sustain winning
outcomes. These conditions are perceived to include a mixture of
Porterian competitive advantage for firms and the attractiveness of the
regional environment for business, as well as the volume and rate at
which the region's human capital is employed (Bristow, 2005, p.
289). In conclusion, it could be said that neo-liberal restructuring has
de- and reterritorialised the political structure of most western
nations as the economy has been actively folded into the globalised
world without regard to effect or affect based on the assumption that
the market knows best.
REFERENCES
Amin, A. and Thrift, N. (2002). Cities Reimagining the Urban.
Cambridge: Polity Press.
Beaverstock, J. V., Smith, J., Taylor, R. G., Walker, D. R. and
Lorimer, H. (2000). Globalization and World Cities: Some Measurement
Methodologies. Applied Geography, 20, pp. 43-63.
Begg, I. (1999). Cities and Competitiveness. Urban Studies,
36(5-6), pp. 795-809.
Bristow, G. (2005). Everyone's a 'Winner':
Problematising the Discourse of Regional Competitiveness. Journal of
Economic Geography, 5, pp. 285-304.
Camagni, R. (2002). On the Concept of Territorial Competitiveness:
Sound or Misleading? Urban Studies, 39, pp. 2395-2411.
Cambridge University Press (2008). Cambridge online dictionary,
Cambridge Dictionary. Online version accessed September 14 2017,
http://dictionary.cambridge.org/dictionary/english/.
Carroll, W. K. (2007). Global Cities in the Global Corporate
Network. Environment and Planning A, 39(10), pp. 2297-2323.
Chesters, G. and Welsh, I. (2005). Complexity and Social
Movement(s): Process and Emergence in Planetary Action. Theory, Culture
and Society, 22(5), pp. 187-211.
Colebrook, C. (2005). Nomadicism. In A. Parr (Ed) The Deleuze
Dictionary (pp. 180-183). New York: Columbia University Press.
Deimler, C. W. and Stern M. S. (2006). The Boston Consulting Group
on Strategy. John Wiley and Sons Inc., Hoboken, New Jersey, USA.
Deleuze, G. and Guattari, F. (1987). Thousand Plateaus: Capitalism
and Schizophrenia (B. Massumi, Trans.). University of Minnesota Press,
Minneapolis, USA.
Deleuze, G. and Guattari, F. (1983). Anti-Oedipus: Capitalism and
Schizophrenia (R. Hurley, M. Seem and H. Lane, Trans.). Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press.
Evans, G. (2003). Hard-Branding the Cultural City: from Prado to
Prada. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 27(2), pp.
417-440.
Florida, R. (2002). The Economic Geography of Talent. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers, 92(4), pp. 743-755.
Florida, R. (2006). What Really Drives Economic Development? Online
version accessed 28 February 2007,
http://creativeclass.typepad.com/thecreativityexchange/2006/11/wh at
really dri.html
Francis, A. (1989). The Concept of Competitiveness. In A. Francis
and P. Tharakan (Eds) The Competitiveness of European Industry (pp.
5-20). Routledge, London.
Friedmann, J. (1978). The Spatial Organisation of Power in the
Development of Urban Systems. In L. S. Bourne and J. W. Simmons (Eds)
Systems of Cities (pp. 328-340). Oxford University Press, New York.
Gibson-Graham, K. J. (2000). Poststructural Interventions. In T.
Barnes and E. Sheppard (Eds) A Companion to Economic Geography (pp.
95-111). Blackwell, Oxford.
Guattari, F. (2000). The Three Ecologies (I. Pindar, Trans.).
Athlone Press, New Brunswick, New Jersey, USA.
Harvey, D. (1969). Explanation in Geography. Edward Arnold, London,
UK.
Harvey, D. (1985). The Urbanization of Capital. Johns Hopkins
University Press, Baltimore, USA.
Harvey, D. (1989). From Managerialism to Entrepreneurialism: the
Transformation of Urban Governance in Late Capitalism. Geografiska
Annaler, 71 B, pp. 3-17.
Jameson, F. (1991). Postmodernism or, the Cultural Logic of Late
Capitalism. Duke University Press, Durham, North Carolina, USA.
Jessop, B. (2000). The Crisis of the National Spatio-temporal Fix
and the Tendential Ecological Dominance of Globalizing Capitalism.
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 24 (2). 323-360.
Jessop, B. and Sum, N.-L. (2000). An Entrepreneurial City in
Action: Hong Kong's Emerging Strategies in and for (Inter) Urban
Competition. Urban Studies, 37(12), pp. 2287-2313.
Johnson, G., Whittington, R. and Scholes, K. (2011). Exploring
Strategy Text and Cases. Pearson Education Ltd., England
Keil, R. (1998). Globalization Makes States: Perspectives of Local
Governance in the Age of the World City. Review of International
Political Economy, 5(4), pp. 616-646.
Kitson, M., Martin, R., and Tyler, P. (2004). Regional
Competitiveness: an Elusive Yet Key Concept? Regional Studies, 38(9),
pp. 991-999.
Kresl, P. (1995). The Determinants of Urban Competitiveness. In P.
Kresl and G. Gappert (Eds) North American Cities and the Global Economy:
Challenges and Opportunities (pp. 45-68). Sage Publications, London.
Krugman, P. (1996a). Making Sense of the Competitiveness Debate.
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 12, pp. 17-25.
Krugman, P. (1996b). Pop Internationalism. Cambridge, MIT Press,
Massachusetts, USA.
Luger, M. (2009). Configuring to be Globally Competitive. In Rowe,
J.E. (Ed) Theories of Local Economic Development: Linking Theory to
Practice, pp. 113-126, Ashgate Publishing Company, Farmham, UK.
Malecki, E. J. (2002). Hard and Soft Networks for Urban
Competitiveness. Urban Studies, 39(5-6), pp. 929-945.
Malecki, E. J. (2004). Best Places: Interurban Competition, Quality
of Life and Popular Media Discourse. Urban Studies, 41, pp. 190-192.
Marston, S., Jones, J. P. and Woodward, K. (2005). Human Geography
without Scale. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers,
30(4), pp. 416-432.
McCann, E. J. (2004). 'Best Places': Interurban
Competition, Quality of Life and Popular Media Discourse. Urban Studies,
41(10), pp. 1909-1929.
McLaren, D. and Rowe, J.E. (2013). Our Journey as Economic
Development Practitioners: Observations from the Coalface. Economic
Development: The Quarterly Journal of Economic Development Australia, 6
(2), pp. 17-21.
McGuirk, P. M. (2004). State, Strategy, and Scale in the
Competitive City: a Neo-Gramscian Analysis of the Governance of
'Global Sydney'. Environment and Planning A, 36, pp.
1019-1043.
Morris, M. (1992). The Man in the Mirror: David Harvey's
'Condition' of postmodernity. Theory, Culture and Society, 9,
pp. 253-279.
O'Conner, K., Stimson, R., and Daly, M. (2001).
Australia's Changing Economic Geography: A Society Dividing. Oxford
University Press, Melbourne.
Olma, S. (2001). Globalization, the Pudding and the Question of
Power. Theory, Culture and Society, 18(4), pp. 111-122.
O'Neill, P. and McGuirk, P. M. (2005). Reterritorialisation of
economies and institutions: The Rise of the Sydney Basin Economy. Space
and Polity, 9(3), pp. 283-305.
Perry, M. (2011). Finding Space for the Creative Class: A Review of
the Issues. Regional Policy and Practice, 29(1), pp. 325-341.
Pfeffer, J. and Sutton, R. (2006). Hard Facts. Harvard Business
School Publishing, Boston, USA.
Polenske, K. (2004). Competition, Collaboration and Cooperation: an
Uneasy Triangle in Networks of Firms and Regions. Regional Studies,
38(9), pp. 1029-1043.
Porter, M. (1998). Clusters and the New Economies of Competition.
Harvard Business Review, 76(6), pp. 77-90.
Porter, M. (2011). HBR 10 Must Reads on Strategy. Harvard Business
School Publishing Corporation, USA.
Porter, M. and Kramer, M. (2011). Creating Shared Value. Online
version accessed 17 August 2017,
http://business.edf.org/blog/2011/05/04/3-takeaways-creatingshared-value-by-porter-kramer/1.
Raco, M. (2002). The Social Relations of Organisational Activity
and the New Local Governance in the UK. Urban Studies, 39(3), pp.
437-456.
Rainnie, A. (2005). Hurricane Florida: the False Allure of the
Creative Class. Sustaining Regions, 4(3), pp. 4-9.
Rowe, J. E. (2006). Is Auckland an Entrepreneurial or Global City?
Town Planning Review, 77(5), pp. 593-614.
Rowe, J. E. (2012). The Case for Employing Deleuzian Philosophical
Concepts for Understanding Local Economic Development. Applied
Geography, 32 (1): pp. 73-79.
Rumelt, R. (2011). Good Strategy Bad Strategy. Profile Books Ltd.,
London, UK.
Sassen, S. (2000). The Global City: Strategic Site/New Frontier. In
E. F. Isin (Ed) Democracy, Citizenship and the Global City (pp. 48-61).
Routledge, New York, USA.
Scott, A. J. (2006). Creative Cities: Conceptual Issues and Policy
Questions. Journal of Urban Affairs, 28(1), pp. 1-17.
SGS Economic and Planning. (2003). Urbecon, March.
Smith, R. G. and Doel, M. A. (2007). A New Theoretical Basis for
Global-city Research: From Structures and Networks to Multiplicities and
Events. Online version accessed 8 June 2007,
http://www.lboro.ac.uk/gawc/rb/rb221.html.
Swyngedouw, E. (1997). Neither Global Nor Local:
'Glocalization' and the Politics of Scale. In K. R. Cox (Ed)
Spaces of Globalization: Reasserting the Power of the Local (pp.
137-166). Guilford, New York, USA.
Thrift, N. (1997). Cities without Modernity, Cities with Magic.
Scottish Geographical Magazine, 113, pp. 138-149.
Thrift, N. (1999). Steps to an Ecology of Place. In D. Massey, J.
Allen and P. Sarre (Eds) Human Geography Today. Polity Press, Cambridge,
UK. pp. 295-323.
Walsh, R. (2003). Auckland Ranked 5th Best City in the World. The
New Zealand Herald, 4 March, A7.
Yeung, H. W.-c. (2002). The Limits to Globalization Theory: a
Geographic Perspective on Global Economic Change. Economic Geography,
78(3), pp. 285-306.
Yeung, H. W.-C. (2005). Rethinking Relational Economic Geography.
Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 30(1), pp. 37-51.
Yin, S. (2002/03). Creativity at Work. American Demographics,
24(11), pp. 22-23.
Zizek, S. and Daly, G. (2004). Conversations with Zizek. Polity
Press, Cambridge, UK.
James E. Rowe
Economic Development Manager, Napier City Council, Napier, 4142,
New Zealand. E mail: jamesr@napier.govt.nz.
Don McLaren
Head of Telford Agriculture Training College, Balclutha, Otago,
9240, New Zealand, E mail: don.mclaren@xtra.co.nz.
Caption: Figure 1. Evolution of Competitive Advantage.
Caption: Figure 2. Competing View of Competitive Strategies.
Source: Designed by the Authors.
Caption: Figure 3. Two Planes of Strategic Function. Source:
Johnson et al. (2011).
Caption: Figure 4. Clusters Surrounding a Regional Community.
Source: Designed by the Authors.
Caption: Figure 5. Three Levels of Strategy. Source: Designed by
the Authors
Caption: Figure 6. Factors Influencing Economic Development
Activities. Source: Designed by the Authors
Caption: Figure 7. Levels of Understanding Required for Community
Strategic Planning. Source: Designed by the authors
Caption: Figure 8. Framework for Developing Regional Community
Strategies. Source: Designed by the Authors.
COPYRIGHT 2017 Regional Science Association, Australian and New Zealand Section
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2017 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.