THE APOTHEOSIS OF THE RENTIER: HOW NAPOLEONIC WAR FINANCE KICK-STARTED THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION.
Hutchinson, Martin ; Dowd, Kevin
THE APOTHEOSIS OF THE RENTIER: HOW NAPOLEONIC WAR FINANCE KICK-STARTED THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION.
[T]his state of affairs ... would mean the euthanasia of the
rentier, and, consequently, the euthanasia of the cumulative oppressive
power of the capitalist to exploit the scarcity-value of capital.... I
see, therefore, the rentier aspect of capitalism as a transitional phase
which will disappear when it has done its work.
John Maynard Keynes ([1936] 1977: 375-76)
The development of Britain's economy in the years following
the end of the Napoleonic Wars was heavily influenced by the peculiar
nature of British government wartime finance. Instead of issuing bonds
with higher coupons as interest rates rose, which governments normally
did in wartime, British governments from the 1750s onward relied mostly
on 3 percent "Consols", i.e., perpetual bonds with a 3 percent
coupon issued at deep discounts. In a world in which equity markets were
almost nonexistent and in which there was a gigantic government bond
market swollen by war financing, fluctuations in the prices of Consols
caused swings in investor wealth that had major economic effects, which
have been much underappreciated. After a positive wealth effect in the
postwar 1780s and a negative one in the late 1790s, the large,
long-lasting bond price increase after 1813 played a major role in
capitalizing the Industrial Revolution's final take-off and the
acceleration of economic growth to near-modern levels. As Jeffrey
Williamson (1984: 688) noted when discussing the slow start to the
Industrial Revolution, "Somewhere around the 1820s Britain passed
dirough a secular turning point." In this article, we argue that
the key to that turning point was the massive wealth effect of the
postwar increase in Consols' prices.
The Napoleonic Wars' Financing Mechanism
Normally, when a government wants to borrow to finance a war, it
knows that its borrowing will cause interest rates to rise, especially
if there is inflation. For example, if peacetime interest rates are
about 3 percent, the government might issue a 5 percent bond of 20-year
maturity rather than say the usual 3 percent peacetime bond. When the
bond matures 20 years later and peace reigns again, the government can
refinance the bond at 3 percent. Investors holding the 5 percent bond
receive a higher interest rate, but no capital gain if they hold the
bond to maturity and only a modest gain if they sell mid-term at a
premium while bond prices are higher than normal.
That approach broadly describes how the U.S. wars in Korea and
Vietnam were financed, as well as both U.S. and British contributions to
the two world wars. Earlier, the U.K. government had used a similar
approach to finance the War of the Spanish Succession (1702-13), mostly
at interest rates of 8-10 percent and with heavy use of tontines and
lotteries.
The U.K. government adopted a different approach with its next
major wars. In 1751, Sampson Gideon, a brilliant Jewish-British
financier, persuaded Prime Minister Henry Pelham to convert most of the
outstanding British government debt into 3 percent Consolidated
Annuities (the famous Consols). Until their ill-advised redemption in
2015, these were perpetual--that is, they had an infinite maturity--and
paid 3 percent interest each year. (1) When the government wanted to
finance a war, instead of issuing 5 percent bonds at par, it issued 3
percent Consols at perhaps 60 percent of the "par" principal
amount, which would then yield 5 percent (i.e., 3 percent/60 percent) on
a running yield basis.
Gideon's thinking was as follows: since all wars were
temporary, people who bought 3 percent bonds at 60 percent would make
generous 5 percent yields during the war and would then make a large
capital gain afterwards, when yields dropped to 3 percent and the bonds
went back to par. The Consols were therefore an attractive investment.
The government could then find buyers even in war years, provided (as
was the case) that there was confidence that Britain would later repay
its debts in full.
Not only did investors enjoy strong yields, but they also made big
capital gains when peace came: 21 percentage points in six years after
the bottom in 1762 as the Seven Years Wars (1756-63) drew to an end, and
33 percentage points in 10 years after the wartime bottom in 1782, as
the American War of Independence (1775-82) drew to an end. (2)
There was then strong demand for new issues of Consols throughout
the major wars over the course of the following 50-plus years--the Seven
Years War, the American Wars, and the French Revolutionary and
Napoleonic Wars (1793-1815, with short remissions).
The Consols enabled Britain to finance heavy military expenditures
when its rival France, which had no such mechanism, was unable to do so
without financially crippling itself. Gideon's clever structure,
which gave windfall profits at the end of each war to inventory-holding
bond dealers like himself, was central to Britain's acquiring its
empire and to not losing it again after the American colonies broke
away.
The disadvantage of Gideon's structure from the fiscal point
of view was that, for each 100 [pounds sterling] of war expenditure on 3
percent Consols issued at 60 percent of par, 167 [pounds sterling] was
typically added to the debt. But since the debt was perpetual and never
needed to be redeemed, this feature of Consols finance was not regarded
as a major fiscal disadvantage. Lord North, chancellor of the exchequer
from 1767 to 1782 and prime minister through the American War of
Independence, liked the structure because "it was the interest that
the people were burdened with the paying of and not the capital."
(3)
The interest cost was indeed the same, or even slightly lower than
through issuing new 5-6 percent debt at par, because the Consols'
attractiveness to speculators allowed them to be sold at a slightly
lower running yield. However, over the course of the century after peace
returned in 1815, Britain's outstanding debt would decline only to
650 million [pounds sterling] in 1914, although the growth in the
British economy meant that debt represented only 30 percent of GDP
compared to a peak of around 260 percent of GDP in 1819.
The rise in the prices of British Consols from 1813 onward appears
to have been due, in part, to a reduction in their perceived risk as the
Allies approached France and peace returned, and, in part, to a drastic
reduction in the annual supply of new Consols through budget deficit
financing. (4)
Table 1 shows gross public income and expenditure for the years
1812-27, with the surplus or deficit; it also shows the funded and
unfunded debt outstanding at the start of each year, and the increase in
debt during the year. (5)
The deficit figures and debt increase figures in Table 1 do not
tally because of the timing of government payments and debt financings.
For example, the 1814 military campaign was largely financed by a 22
million [pounds sterling] debt issue (increasing the amount of 3 percent
debt outstanding by 38.9 million [pounds sterling]) on the morning of
the supplementary Budget of November 15, 1813. Nevertheless, the overall
trend is clear: huge deficits and increases in the supply of Consols
during the war years of 1812-15 were followed by near-balanced budgets
in 1816-19 and surpluses thereafter, while the supply of Consols stopped
increasing from 1816 onward, except for a modest blip in 1819-20 caused
by funding 10 million [pounds sterling] of the Bank of England's
holdings of Exchequer Bills in connection with the return to gold. (6)
Table 2 sets out the 823 million [pounds sterling] of British and
Irish government funded and unfunded debt that was held by the public on
February 1, 1817, a date chosen so the special "emergency"
financings for the Waterloo campaign were out of the way.
By far the greatest part of the outstanding debt, 562 million
[pounds sterling] or 68 percent of the total, consisted of perpetual
securities bearing a 3 percent interest rate, payable twice yearly. The
largest single tranche, 384 million [pounds sterling], consisted of
"Consolidated Annuities," the 3 percent Consols, which paid
interest in January and July. There was also an exactly equivalent
obligation, the Reduced Annuities, with principal amount of 148 million
[pounds sterling], which differed from Consols only in paying interest
in April and October. Dealers would arbitrage between these two
securities, with the Reduced Annuities generally trading at a small
discount (subject to fluctuations before and after their interest
payment dates) because of their somewhat lesser liquidity. There were
also two relatively small older issues with 3 percent coupons,
reflecting refinancings of debt incurred early in the 18th century, for
the Bank of England and the South Sea Company, of 16 million [pounds
sterling] and 14 million [pounds sterling], respectively.
In addition to the perpetual 3 percent debt, there was 211 million
[pounds sterling] of 4 percent and 5 percent debt, which would be
refinanced after the war as interest rates declined. The 4 percent debt,
totaling 75 million [pounds sterling], took the form of 4 percent
Consols, while the 5 percent debt, totaling 136 million [pounds
sterling], originally contracted in many cases by the Navy and Army
directly, had been consolidated into 5 percent Consols. By the 1820s,
the 5 percent debt was trading above par. There were then two
refinancing operations carried out at the end of 1823 and in early 1824,
one converting 135 million [pounds sterling] of 5 percent Consols into 4
percent Consols and the second converting 80 million [pounds sterling]
of 4 percent Consols into a new issue of 3.5 percent Consols. (7)
Finally, in 1817 there was 50 million [pounds sterling] of
short-term debt, mostly in the form of Exchequer Bills, which were
short-term instruments, generally converted into long-term debt as new
issues were undertaken. The 50 million [pounds sterling] outstanding in
February 1817 was high by historical standards, a residue of the
emergency financings undertaken at the Napoleonic Wars' climax in
1813-15, and was over the next few years reduced by being converted into
long-term debt. Reducing the amount of Exchequer Bills outstanding,
thereby mopping up excess market liquidity, was an important
precondition for the subsequent return to the gold standard.
In addition to the 822 million [pounds sterling] of debt held by
the public, the government had since 1786 built up a sinking fund,
intended to accrue at compound interest and allow the debt to be
redeemed within 45 years. This fund had been established by William Pitt
the Younger because redeeming debt at par, under Gideon's
structure, was expensive and the sinking fund allowed other debt to be
redeemed through market purchases. Payments had been made into the
sinking fund throughout the war years, even though the government was
running deficits, on the principle that the gradual accrual of the
sinking fund, with each new issue of debt having an amortization
provision to be paid into the sinking fund, would reassure the
nation's creditors. By February 1817 the sinking fund totaled 62
million [pounds sterling]. It would be modified in 1819 and eliminated
in stages in the early 1820s, with the government debt it purchased
being canceled in the process.
As an example of how war finance was structured, we can examine the
last major financing undertaken during the Napoleonic Wars, which was
also the largest single tranche undertaken, and which was announced by
Chancellor of the Exchequer Nicholas Vansittart to the House of Commons
on June 14, 1815, four days before the Battle of Waterloo, and had been
completed that morning. The loan raised 27 million [pounds sterling] in
net proceeds, for each 100 [pounds sterling] of which buyers would be
given 130 [pounds sterling] in 3 percent reduced stock, 10 [pounds
sterling] in 4 percent Consols, and 44 [pounds sterling] in 3 percent
Consols. The 27 million [pounds sterling] of net proceeds was obtained
by issuing a total of 49.68 million [pounds sterling] principal amount
of new debt, at a running interest cost of 5.62 percent and an average
issue price of 54.35 percent of par. In addition to the interest
payable, a sinking fund provision of 2.81 percent was made on the 27
million [pounds sterling] raised, for a total annual debt service charge
of 8.43 percent. (8)
Vansittart told the House of Commons that this record-sized issue,
the pricing of which was determined by negotiated tender and not by
competitive bid, was only just fully subscribed; a great proportion of
the issue was initially left with the underwriters. Four days later the
Battle of Waterloo took place, news of which was received on the late
evening of June 21.
Contrary to widespread belief, there was no great immediate
"bounce" in the market by which (in separate legends) Nathan
Rothschild and the broker/economist David Ricardo were both supposed to
have made 1 million [pounds sterling] each through trading on early
(and, effectively, inside) information of the battle. However, given the
price rise in Consols over the next decade, their holdings of this issue
alone played a major role in generating the Rothschild and Ricardo
fortunes.
As anticipated by Gideon 60 years earlier, City of London
financiers did well from the postwar surges in bond prices. It is no
coincidence that Rothschilds, led by Nathan Meyer Rothschild, and
Barings, led by the second-generation Alexander Baring, became very
powerful after 1815. Their capital base dramatically increased, from
1810 or so as their large long positions in Consols rose in value.
Ricardo also became very rich by the same dynamic.
Postwar Surge in Consol Prices Causes Rentier Apotheosis
The deep discount debt issuance structure had major implications
for the post-Napoleonic War economy because the volume of debt was so
large, both in absolute terms and in relation to other assets in the
economy:
* Britain's debt-to-GDP ratio, at the peak in 1819, was about
260 percent, the highest of any country anywhere that has been
successfully paid down--slightly higher than Britain in 1945. Of course,
Britain had not borrowed 260 percent of 1819 GDP to fight its wars, but
only about 170 percent in cash terms.
* Nearly all the Napoleonic War debt was issued around 60 percent
of par or below, so when peace came holders would have a capital gain of
40 percent as Consols trended back toward par. Consol prices did not
return to par quickly, however. They reached 77.5 percent in 1818 and
almost 91 percent in 1824 at the peak of the boom (see Table 3). They
were not to hit par until the 1840s.
More precisely, there was a total of 562 million [pounds sterling]
of 3 percent debt outstanding on February 1, 1817, in the month
preceding which Consols' average yield had been 4.72 percent, for a
price of 63.6 percent (ignoring accrued interest), with holders having
already enjoyed a 7 percentage point price appreciation since the recent
low of August 1815. By April 1824, Consols' yield had dropped to
3.16 percent, so the price had risen to 94.9 percent. In the period
between August 1815 and April 1824, holders of 3 percent Consols enjoyed
a capital profit of 38.3 percentage points, or a total of 215 million
[pounds sterling] on the 562 million [pounds sterling] of 1817's 3
percent debt. An additional profit of perhaps 10 million [pounds
sterling] would have been received on the 75 million [pounds sterling]
of 4 percent Consols, as their price rose toward and above par. Total
profits to Consols holders over this period would then have been around
75 percent of GDP, equivalent to a profit of $14 trillion in current
U.S. dollars. In addition, investors' 1824 pounds were worth around
20-30 percent more than their 1815 pounds had been based on any of the
Gayer-Rostow-Schwartz price series, the Rousseaux price series, or the
Lindert and Williamson "best guess" cost of living index
(Mitchell 2011: 721-22, 737). Taking the annual figures for 1815 and
1824, these give a deflationary rise in value of 28 percent, 25 percent,
and 18 percent, respectively, primarily due to the resumption of gold
payments in 1819-21.
One might say that this wealth was mostly brand new. Investors in
August 1815 had put in only 57 percent for their 3 percent Consols and
within a few years received a profit of 37 percentage points in capital
gains plus interest at around 5 percent per annum on their initial
investment. This profit was tax-free after the income tax had been
abolished in 1816, and in any case capital gains had been untaxed. The
capital gain was also permanent: once Consols had risen back to
peacetime levels in the early 1820s, they fluctuated only moderately and
indeed rose further until their price peaked late in the century.
Consequently, there was some 60 percent (from 1817) to 75 percent
(from 1815) of GDP of new liquid capital in the early 1820s economy. In
the early 1820s, this new money financed not only a number of subprime
South American governments but also innumerable new factories and
inventions that became the backbone of the Industrial Revolution.
Previous Periods of Rentier Enrichment and I mpoverishment
It is interesting to observe that the same effect had occurred in
the opposite direction in the 1790s. The price of Consols dropped from
an average of 90 in 1792 to below 51 in 1797 and 1798. Since the nominal
value of government debt in 1792 was about 120 percent of 1792 GDP, this
fall caused a capital loss of about 47 percent of GDP in the first five
years of the war.
Both Liverpool, the future prime minister (in 1796), and his father
Charles Jenkinson (in 1798) wrote pamphlets proclaiming that
Britain's wartime economy was prospering, based on a substantial
rise in exports and output over those years. However, the impoverishment
of many savers during those years and the capital losses suffered by
banks and other financial institutions starved the economy of capital.
This latter point explains why Pitt in the 1790s had much more
difficulty raising the necessary war finance than Perceval, Liverpool,
and Vansittart did after 1807, and was a contributory factor to
Britain's going off gold in 1797.
One can trace this Consols' wealth effect back further;
Pitt's benign economic conditions and growth in the 1780s were
largely caused by a rise in Consols' prices from 55 [pounds
sterling] to 90 [pounds sterling] between 1784 and 1792.
It is clear that, owing to Gideon's financing technique, the
size of the government bond market, and its importance in the national
economy, the "wealth effect" of fluctuations in bond prices
far exceeded any Keynesian stimulus from wartime spending.
Consols in the Context of Overall Wealth Holding
Government bonds were only one of the forms in which wealth was
held in the years after 1815. However, unlike other wealth they were
highly liquid, and indeed were the only security quoted on the stock
exchange from its founding in 1801 until 1822. Over the course of the
18th century, government securities ("the funds") and Consols
in particular had become the principal non-landed form of wealth holding
for merchants and the middle class, who tended to be more liquid than
all but the richest aristocracy.
Nevertheless, agricultural land and to an increasing extent urban
real estate remained an important component of British elite fortunes.
Such forms of wealth storage as gold and silver plate had declined in
importance since the 17th century as banks had proliferated, while bank
deposits and insurance policies had appeared and at lower levels of
wealth the savings bank movement was beginning its long 19th century
climb.
The most important form in which wealth was held was still land,
though its importance was beginning to decline during this period as
mercantile relative wealth increased and landowners diversified their
wealth into Consols. Prices of land had enjoyed a massive boom during
the Napoleonic Wars, as corn prices had soared from an average of 43
shillings per quarter in 1794 to 127 shillings per quarter in the dearth
year of 1812 (Mitchell 2011: 756). Then from 1813 to 1822 corn prices
fell, bottoming out at 45 shillings per quarter in 1822 in spite of the
1815 Corn Laws, which had banned imports when the price was below 80
shillings. fean-Baptiste Say, visiting England in late 1814, commented
on the extraordinary profits made by agriculturalists during the war,
and on their large investments both in bringing marginal land into
cultivation and in mechanizing and up-scaling their operations (Say
1815).
Some of the landowner wealth acquired during the war was redeployed
into industrialization, both during the war and in the years after,
partly because the profitability of agricultural land declined after the
war and did not recover for several decades. (9)
Consider the case of John Crichton-Stuart, 2nd Marquess of Bute
(1793-1848). In 1814, he inherited a very large and liquid landed estate
from his grandfather, including major land holdings in South Wales
acquired through the 1st Marquess's advantageous marriage as well
as substantial holdings in the funds.
In 1817 he began surveying the Glamorgan coal fields, consolidating
his local land holdings as he did so and building the Welsh coal mining
industry during the 1820s. Between 1822 and 1848, he also developed the
Cardiff Docks, opening the new Docks in 1837 at a cost of 350,000
[pounds sterling]. His activity in both areas brought him huge debts of
494,000 [pounds sterling] at his death, although his assets greatly
exceeded that value, and their profitability developed further, so that
in the 1870s his grandson and heir was claimed (probably incorrectly,
given the rise of American fortunes by that stage) to be the richest man
in the world.
Between 1813 and 1822 the agricultural prosperity went into
reverse. While costs fell somewhat, with the deflation attendant on
returning to the gold standard in 1819-21, income from land fell
considerably further, and landowners who, unlike Bute, did not have
substantial outside holdings were sorely pressed. Their situation is
well illustrated in an 1822 conversation between the diarist Harriet
Arbuthnot, the young (28) wife of Charles Arbuthnot, a Treasury
Secretary (junior minister) whose wealth was primarily in Consols, and
her older (62) cousin the 10th Earl of Westmorland, Lord Privy Seal (a
cabinet minister) and a large landowner:
I insisted that the cry of agricultural distress was grossly
exaggerated, that the pressure felt by that class now was nothing
compared to that suffered by the manufacturing districts in
1819, when 10,000 able and willing workmen were starving in
one town (Glasgow) for want of work, and every other manufacturing
town suffering in a like degree; that the farmers had
got into luxurious habits which they did not choose to give up
and therefore joined in the cry of "No Taxes;" that those
persons who had borrowed money at 5 per cent interest during
the war to buy land would suffer as any body did who borrowed
money to buy any thing; but that the great landed
proprietors would weather the storm and be just as well off as
ever; that there would certainly be a transfer of property, but
that the country generally would be as rich as ever and that
there could not be a greater proof of it than the enormous
increase of the Revenue in every branch. He said I talked nonsense
and was very childish (which, by the way, is no argument)
and that the transfer of property I talked of so quietly would be
a greater revolution than even a bankruptcy of the funds. (10)
Shares were a relatively insignificant store of wealth in post-1815
Britain, with total public share capital paid in of 49 million [pounds
sterling] in 1827, of which 34 million [pounds sterling] related to
companies formed before 1824. The 624 companies floated in the bubble of
1824-25 had a nominal capital of 372 million [pounds sterling], but only
15.2 million [pounds sterling] of this capital was ever paid in; by
1827, when the dust settled, that had declined in value to 9.3 million
[pounds sterling]. Share prices in 181.5-27 were not especially buoyant,
in spite of the bubble of 1824-25; on a quarterly average basis the
share index rose by only 61 percent, from 3.1 in the second quarter of
1815 (1962 = 100) to 5.0 at the peak in the third quarter of 1824. The
bubble thereafter deflated, with the index in the fourth quarter of 1825
being only 4.44, and 4.1 in the fourth quarter of 1827. Changes in share
wealth were clearly not economically significant during these years.
(11)
There was one final form of nonland wealth that underwent a major
boom in the early 1820s before collapsing in 1825-26: foreign bonds. In
1817-18 several European governments floated bonds totaling 10 million
[pounds sterling], while in the boom of 1821-25 some 43 million [pounds
sterling] (12) was invested in foreign bonds, of which 37 million
[pounds sterling] related to Latin American issues. These investments
were a substantial absorber of British capital, especially during the
1822-25 period as declining yields on Consols caused investors to seek
higher returns elsewhere. However, the profits and losses involved do
not appear to have been significant, except in the immediate aftermath
of the 1825-26 crash.
Who Were the Rentiers?
Information on the owners of Consols can first be gained by
examining the estates of the very wealthiest. Three thed between 1809
and 1839 who are believed to have been Britain's first
millionaires: (1) Nathan Rothschild (1836), worth 5 million [pounds
sterling], whose fortune was largely in Consols and other liquid
securities, and who is known to have grown very much richer in the
decade after 1815; (2) the 1st Duke of Sutherland, formerly Marquess of
Stafford (1833), worth 2 million [pounds sterling], whose fortune was
largely in land, but with substantial agricultural and industrial
development including the Bridgewater Canal; and (3) Sir Robert Peel
(1830) father of the future prime minister, worth 1.5 million [pounds
sterling], whose fortune was derived from the family cotton mill
business that had employed 15,000 people at its peak, but by his death
consisted largely of Consols, houses, and land. (13)
Lower down the scale it is notable that the five-year average of
the annual number of nonland fortunes above 100,000 [pounds sterling]
among the newly deceased took a sharp upward turn, from 16.5 in 1809-14
and 18.2 in 1815-19 to 25.6 in 1820-24, and 29.0 in 1825-29. It then did
not rise significantly further until after 1855 (Robinson 1985: 47).
Although Robinson could think of no explanation for this increase, the
jump's coincidence with the recovery in Consols' prices
suggests that Consols formed a high proportion of the wealth covered by
these statistics, which derive from probate valuations that do not
include real property and therefore relate primarily to mercantile
rather than aristocratic fortunes. At the same time, including land
changes the wealth picture considerably: more than 80 percent of people
worth more than 100,000 [pounds sterling] in 1825 were primarily
landowners.
Of the nonlanded rich dying in the 1820s, a high proportion were in
the City of London, either as merchants, bankers, or in insurance or
stockbroking--15 of the 24 with nonland wealth from 500,000 [pounds
sterling] to 1 million [pounds sterling] thed between 1820 and 1839. It
can safely be assumed that the great majority of these fortunes would
have been held in Consols. Of the other nine, the three in textiles, the
one in publishing, and the two in public administration and defense will
also have held a high percentage of their nonland wealth in Consols,
since none of those occupations is capital intensive. Only three of the
24, with principal occupations in iron/steel, chemicals, and brewing may
have held relatively small stocks of Consols, with the majority of their
nonland wealth in their primary businesses.
The same analysis carried out on the "lesser wealthy" who
thed with nonlanded wealth between 100,000 [pounds sterling] and 500,000
[pounds sterling] in the years 1809-29 shows a similar pattern: 117 of
the 154 such people either were merchants, worked in finance, were
professionals, or worked in public administration. Since these people
had little need for plant and equipment, the majority of their nonland
wealth would have been held in Consols. (14)
We can then conclude that the capital gains from the Consols'
price increase in 1815-24 had a major effect on the net worth of nearly
all those with substantial nonlanded wealth, many of whom like Bute may
also have had large landholdings.
In this context, the wealth accumulation patterns of early 19th
century industrialists, from Sir Robert Peel downward, should also be
borne in mind. There was no public equity market available to raise
money for industrial companies, and bank loans were not available for
long maturities except for a moderate proportion of the value of
buildings and land. Hence, businesses were built up by collaboration
between entrepreneurs through private partnerships, formed, and
dissolved as needed. (15)
The members of those partnerships, once the initial investment in
plant had been made, kept substantial balances of liquid assets to meet
the need for new investment and to protect the business against
downturns, which could be severe and unexpected. Consols, utterly safe,
highly liquid, and yielding a decent return (and a superb return in
1815-24) were a favorite holding for such people, who in the early 1820s
found themselves through their Consols' holdings very much richer
than before. It is then fair to presume that Consols' windfalls
paid for much of the industrial expansion in the 1820s and its
accompanying capital intensification.
Economic Effects of Rentier Apotheosis
Britain's economy in 1814 was already qualitatively different
from any other in the world, or from its own state 30 years earlier. The
French economist Jean-Baptiste Say visited Britain in late 1814, after
the peace but before Napoleon's return from Elba, and set out his
impressions in a pamphlet De l'Angleterre at des Anglais:
But it is principally the introduction of machines in the arts,
which has made the production of riches more economical. There are
almost no big farms in England, where for example, threshing machines
are not used, by means of which, in a large operation, more work is done
in a day than was done in a month by ordinary methods.
At last human labor, which has rendered the high cost of consumer
goods so expensive, is in no circumstances replaced so advantageously,
as by steam engines, improperly called "fire-pumps" by some.
There is no work which cannot be reached to be executed by them. They go
to the mills, weaving cotton and wool; they brew beer, they cut
crystals. I have seen them embroider muslin and beat butter. At
Newcastle, at Leeds, I have seen moving steam engines dragging after
them carts of coal; and nothing is more surprising, at first sight, for
a traveler, than to meet in the country long convoys which advance by
themselves and without the help of any living being.
Everywhere steam engines are prodigiously multiplied. There were no
more than two or three in London thirty years ago, there are thousands
at present. There are hundreds of them in the large manufacturing towns;
one sees them even in the countryside, and industrial works could not be
sustained profitably without their powerful help. But they must have
abundant coal, that combustible fossil which Nature seems to have
reserved to supplement the exhaustion of forests, the inevitable result
of civilization. Thus one could, with the help of a simple mineralogical
map, trace an industrial map of Britain. There is industry everywhere
there is coal in the ground [Say 1815: 29-31]. (16)
Say also noted that high British taxation and the gigantic
government debt were of immense importance in raising the cost of
everything in Britain and depressing the profits of business and
commerce. He believed British goods would be uncompetitive in Europe
once the European economies had recovered from the war. Writing while
Consols' prices were still depressed, Say failed to foresee the
effect of their subsequent rise. Liverpool however foresaw that effect
in the following year, during the postwar economic downturn. Writing to
George Canning on February 13, 1816, and discussing the clamor to
abolish the income and malt taxes (which in the event succeeded) he
wrote, "I am satisfied likewise that those who raise this clamour
have a narrow view of their own interest, as the restoration of public
credit, the run of the funds, and the consequent fall of the interest on
money will afford more relief to the existing distress of the country
than any other measure of relief that could be adopted." (17)
Table 4 sets out U.K. (including Ireland) population, GDP, and GDP
per capita figures for 1801-41, at 10-year intervals, with five-year
additions for 1816 and 1826. The GDP figures are of course a backward
extrapolation of a statistic (and a questionable one at that!) that was
only invented a century later, but for what they are worth they show a
distinct acceleration in growth of per capita GDP, from 2.16 percent per
annum to 3.11 percent per annum between the decades 1811-21 and 1821-31.
Note also that, with population expanding at a very rapid rate of around
1.3 percent annually, the 1820s growth rates are spectacular even by
modern standards, indeed considerably higher than was to be achieved in
any subsequent decade.
Gayer, Rostow, and Schwartz use brick production as a measure of
economic activity in capital goods; this increased from an annual
average of 791.2 million in 1815-18 to 992.4 million in 1819-22 to
1,501.7 million in 1823-26; the 1825 figure of 1,948.8 million was the
highest in any year before 1846 (Gayer, Rostow, and Schwartz 1953: 121,
147, 186).
Other indicators show a similar picture of economic acceleration
after 1820. Coal shipments from Newcastle and Sunderland rose from an
annual average of 1,083 thousand chaldrons in 1814-19 to 1,249 thousand
chaldrons in 1820-26 (Mitchell 2011: 243). (18) Pig iron production rose
from an annual average of 305 thousand tons in 1814-19 to an annual
average of 453 thousand tons in 1820-26 (Mitchell 2011: 280). Raw cotton
consumption rose from an annual average of 96 million pounds in 1814-19
to an annual average of 147 million pounds in 1820-26 (ibid., 332).
Manufactured goods exports at constant prices, mostly textiles, rose
from 15.3 million [pounds sterling] in 1814-19 to 17.9 million [pounds
sterling] in 1820-26 (ibid., 520).
The Hoffman index of industrial production rose from an average of
9.39 in 1815-18 to 10.67 in 1819-22 and then to 12.28 in 1823-26 (ibid.,
431). Perhaps most significantly, the annual average number of English
patents granted fell slightly from 114 in 1815-18 to 105 in 1819-22, but
then soared to 177 in 1823-26-surely a sign of entrepreneurial activity
in those years, though it fell back to 153 in 1827-30 (ibid., 438).
Thus, the overall real return to Consols' investors over the
period 1813-24 was in excess of 300 percent. If they held on and
reinvested income during that period, Consols holders quadrupled their
money in real terms.
The mechanism by which British economic growth benefitted from the
1815-24 rise in Consols' prices is well set out in Gayer, Rostow,
and Schwartz (1953: vol. 1, 185):
The character of the (1822-26) cycle as a whole, however, can
be distinguished from earlier cycles by the scale and the
scope of new private investment. There was an increase in
railways construction, new docks were built, and what
appears to be the greatest building boom until the forties took
place. Gas-light, insurance, building, trading, investment,
provision companies, in addition to many others, were
formed on a large scale. These, the fluctuations of foreign
government and mining issues and the fabulous Stock
Exchange boom and crash (1824-25) impart to these years
their unique character.
The economics is clear. For the British economy to industrialize,
its capital intensity had to increase. This increase accelerated in the
decade after Waterloo, and Consols' profits provided wealth
enabling this increase to take place more quickly, more smoothly and
with less pressure on workers' living standards than would
otherwise have occurred. (19)
Gayer, Rostow, and Schwartz (1953: vol. 1, 185) blame the excess
speculation in 1824-25 on two additional factors, both of which seem
pertinent. First, in April 1822, the government had extended the
privilege of country banks issuing 1 [pounds sterling] and 2 [pounds
sterling] notes, which had the effect of an unexpected increase in the
money supply. Second, the double refinancing of 5 percent and 4 percent
Consols in 1823-24 produced "a restless feeling and a disposition
to hazardous investment," (20) and a surge in foreign bond
purchases.
The extent of the speculative fervor was spelled out by a
contemporary stockbroker, Henry English, and his analysis has remained
authoritative to this day. (21) Briefly, English listed 624 companies
that were floated in the years 1824 and 1825. They had a capitalization
of 372,173,100 [pounds sterling]. By 1827, only 127 of these existed
with a capitalization of 102,781,600 [pounds sterling], of which only
15,185,950 [pounds sterling] had been paid in; but the market value had
sunk even lower to only 9,303,950 [pounds sterling]. Of the 127 still
existing in 1827, 44 were mining companies (mostly in Latin America), 20
gas companies, 14 insurance, and 49 miscellaneous, including salt, silk,
lard, bridge, emigration, glass distilling, brick, bank, and
agricultural companies.
In addition, 15 railway companies were formed by Acts of Parliament
in 1823-26, for a total projected construction cost of 3.64 million
[pounds sterling], of which the Stockton and Darlington, authorized in
1823 at a cost of 450,000 [pounds sterling] and opened in 1825, and the
Liverpool and Manchester, authorized in 1826 at the immense construction
cost of 1,832,375 [pounds sterling], more than all the rest put
together, and opened in 1830 in the presence of the Duke of Wellington,
are the most famous. The experimental and dangerous nature of this
technology is indicated by the fact that the Stockton and Darlington
used steam trains only for goods traffic, with passengers being drawn by
horse carriages until 1833, while the Liverpool and Manchester
accidently knocked over and killed the former Cabinet Minister William
Huskisson at its opening on September 15, 1830.
Mrs. Arbuthnot was a keen observer of the stock market bubble of
1825, which she discussed in detail with Wellington, who thought it
would all end in a crash (as did Liverpool, who said so in the House of
Lords). However, she could not resist a good speculation herself:
There is a railway going to be made between Liverpool and
Manchester which promises to answer immensely. We have 10 shares in it
for which we gave 3 [pounds sterling] a piece and which are now worth
above 58 [pounds sterling] each and they are expected to be worth above
100 [pounds sterling]. I am very fond of these speculations and should
gamble greatly in them if I could, but Mr. Arbuthnot does not like them,
and will not allow me to have any of the American ones as their value
depends on political events and he thinks in his official situation it
would be improper [Bamford and Wellington 1950: vol. 1, 382].
Improper or not, Mrs. Arbuthnot got in on the ground floor. Her
diary entry was dated March 16, 1825, and the Liverpool and Manchester
Railway Company had been formed in 1823. However, its first attempt to
get Parliamentary authorization in 1825 failed (largely through
opposition by the Marquess of Stafford, owner of the competing
Bridgewater Canal), and it gained authorization only at a second attempt
in May 1826.
Since Arbuthnot had been what today would be called the
government's Chief Whip in the House of Commons (though he had
given up that job in 1823 while remaining a junior minister as
Commissioner for Woods and Forests) his 10 shares (of an eventual total
of 4,233, spread among 308 shareholders, with Stafford eventually owning
1,000) may have been a special allocation. It was however not quite the
handout it appears. Following corporate finance practices of the time,
the shares will have been partly paid, with say 10 [pounds sterling]
paid on a 100 [pounds sterling] share, and Arbuthnot will have been
called for the other 90 [pounds sterling] when Parliament had approved
the company and construction began. While 900 [pounds sterling] was
affordable for the comfortably off Arbuthnots, larger sums would not
have been, so Arbuthnot was right to stop his wife punting on South
American mining companies. Nevertheless, their Liverpool and Manchester
Railway investment was a successful one, if they kept it; the company
paid an average dividend of 9.5 percent in its 15 years as an
independent company.
Since the Bubble Act, requiring an Act of Parliament to form a new
company, was not repealed until 1826, much of the new investment in
1822-25 was informal and small-scale, in start-ups and other kinds of
experimentation. The surge in patents granted in 1823-26 itself confirms
that the surge in Consols' wealth allowed exploration of projects
that were not immediately profitable. One such project, far more famous
in 2017 than it was at the time, was that carried out by Charles
Babbage.
Babbage was a typical beneficiary of the surge in Consols'
prices. His father was a partner in the banking house of Praed &
Co., whose wealth, like that of most bankers, will have been
substantially augmented by the rise in Consols. Babbage was partly
supported by his father and inherited a fortune of 100,000 [pounds
sterling] when his father thed in 1827. However, the initial funding for
his difference engine project came not from his father but from
Liverpool's government, which made a grant to Babbage of 1,700
[pounds sterling] in 1823 to start work on the project. Alas, endless
redesigns meant the prototype was never finished, and the government,
under the unimaginative Sir Robert Peel (son of the textile millionaire)
canceled further funding for the project in 1842 after it had absorbed
17,000 [pounds sterling] of public money.
In spite of Babbage's failure, the statistics show that the
pace of innovation, industrialization, and Britain's overall
economic growth quickened substantially in the early and middle 1820s,
and that the new wealth produced by the return of Consols' prices
to peacetime levels substantially contributed to this quickening.
Britain's industrial lead established during this period was not to
be relinquished until the last quarter of the century.
Conclusion
The rise in Consols' prices in 181.5-24, under the able
economic management of Lord Liverpool created not the "euthanasia
of the rentier" of Maynard Keynes' leftist fantasies but his
apotheosis, in which, combining the rise in Consols and given the
decline in prices that accompanied the return to gold, rentier nonland
wealth nearly quadrupled in real terms during Liverpool's
premiership. That increase in wealth coincided with and likely produced
a surge in capital investment and innovation, which, apart from the
follies of the Latin American bond market, produced the first great
surge of the Industrial Revolution, with U.K. economic growth
accelerating to unprecedented levels.
References
Ashton, T. S. (1948) The Industrial Revolution 1760-1830. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Bamford, F., and Wellington, 7th Duke, eds. (1950) Journal of Mrs.
Arbuthnot. London: Macmillan.
Gayer, A.; Rostow, W. W.; and Schwartz, A. J. (1953) The Growth and
Fluctuation of the British Economy, 1790-1850. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Hansard, T. C. (1815) The Parliamentary Debates from the Year 1803
to the Present Time, Vol. 31.
--(1817) The Parliamentary Debates from the Year 1803 to the
Present Time, Vol. 36.
Homer, S., and Sylla, R. (2005) A History of Interest Rates, 4th
ed. Hoboken, N.J.: Wiley.
Keynes, J. M. ([1936] 1977) The General Theory of Employment,
Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.
Mitchell, B. R., ed. (2011) British Historical Statistics.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Neal, L. (1998) "The Financial Crisis of 1825 and the
Restructuring of the British Financial System." Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review 80 (May-June): 53-76.
Robinson, R. D. (1985) Men of Property: The Very Wealthy in Britain
since the Industrial Revolution. London: Croom Helm.
Say, J. B. (1815) De l'Angleterre et des Anglais. Paris: Chez
Arthur Bertrand.
Tooke, T. (1838) A History of Prices. London: Longman.
Ventura, J., and Voth, H. J. (2015) "Debt into Growth: How
Sovereign Debt Accelerated the First Industrial Revolution." NBER
Working Paper No. 21280.
Williamson, J. G. (1984) "Why Was British Growth So Slow
during the Industrial Revolution?" Journal of Economic History 44
(3): 687-712.
Yonge, C. D. (1868) The Life and Administration of Robert Banks
Jenkinson, Second Earl of Liverpool. London: Macmillan.
Martin Hutchinson is the author of the Bear's Lair column
(www.tbwns.com /category/the-bears-lair). Kevin Dowd is Professor of
Finance and Economics at Durham University. The authors thank Mark
Billings, Charles Goodhart, Alasdair Macleod, Basil Zafiriou, and an
anonymous referee for helpful feedback. The usual caveat applies.
(1) The securities issued in the 1751 refinancing paid 3.5 percent
interest for the first six years, then 3 percent from 1757. There was a
further refinancing in 1888, carried out by Chancellor of the Exchequer
George Joachim Goschen, into new securities paying 2.75 percent from
1888 to 1903, then 2.5 percent thereafter. Thus, the classic "3
percent Consols" existed without refinancing from 1757 to 1888.
(2) Homer and Sylla (2005: 57 for 1752-99; 192 for 1800-27). We
take the Homer-Sylla estimate of annual average prices as the basis for
these calculations.
(3) Quoted in The Economist, "Percents and Sensibility,"
December 20, 2005.
(4) A more elaborate explanation might go as follows. The prices of
Consols surged primarily because of a decline in supply as the
Napoleonic Wars ended and the government moved toward fiscal surplus.
Moreover, because Consols were almost the only store of liquid wealth,
their price rise would have made investors wealthier--thereby creating
an even greater demand for Consols. It is noteworthy that the two main
investments available to the rich were Consols and land, but land became
much less profitable after 1815 as grain prices declined. Stocks and
bonds were relatively unimportant (though a small foreign bond market
arose in the 1820s), while direct investment in companies was risky,
illiquid, and poorly diffused among the investing public.
In loanable funds terms, the primary driving factor in the market
for Consols--the decline in supply--would correspond to a reduced demand
by the government for loanable funds.
(5) The debt figure jumps in 1818 because of the inclusion of Irish
government debt from that year onward.
(6) There is, thus, the following implied counterfactual. Reduced
supply of Consols, itself associated with a move toward fiscal surplus,
combined with increased demand for them and the anticipated then actual
resumption of specie payments at the old parity to create a secular
decline in interest rates. Falling yields also suggest that, contrary to
Ashton (1948) or Williamson (1984), fiscal crowding out was no longer an
issue by this period.
(7) This, and much other useful information about British
government financing in 1815-25, is set out in Neal (1998).
(8) Vansittart's budget is contained in Hansard (1815: cols
795-822, June 14).
(9) This is largely consistent with the theoretical analysis of
Ventura and Voth (2015): landholders experienced wealth gains from their
Consols that led them to switch out of low-return agricultural
investments, thereby lowering factor demand in the old sectors and
raising profitability in the new sectors.
(10) Bamford and Wellington (1950: vol. 1, 139), diary entry for
February 2, 1822.
(11) Flotations in 1824-25: Stockbroker Henry English, quoted in
Neal (1998: 64). Share price index: Bank of England Statistics
"Share Prices in the United Kingdom" held in the St. Louis
Fed.'s FRED database, accessed March 3, 2017.
(12) Figures quoted on foreign bond issues are from Neal (1998: 63)
and the detail is from Gayer, Rostow, and Schwartz (1953: vol. 1,
188-89).
(13) Data on these holdings of the very rich are contained in
Robinson (1985).
(14) Data on the occupations of the dying wealthy in these
paragraphs come from Robinson (1985: 82-87).
(15) Manufacturers themselves did not borrow for long-term plant
investment, but accumulated retained earnings and savings, much of them
in Consols, which were more secure than the local English banks. The
brokers and embryonic "merchant banks" did not invest directly
in industry, but country banks lent to it, and would have been
encouraged to lend more by the Consols-driven increase in their capital.
The capital gains accrued to small holders as well as large and gave
manufacturers more capital with which to expand their own factories or
invest in other people's. The holdings of Consols in manufacturing
districts were also more significant for industrialization than those
among the gentry, who had limited ability to access industrial
investment opportunities and tended like Mrs. Arbuthnot to buy South
American bond issues and shares, mostly in canals and early railways.
(16) Martin Hutchinson's translation.
(17) Quoted in Yonge (1868: vol 2: 253-55). The italics are ours,
and we take "the run of the funds" to be a direct reference to
the price rise to be expected as public credit recovered.
(18) The chaldron was a volume measure used for coal. By a law of
1694, the Newcastle chaldron of coal was defined to weigh 5,940 pounds.
(19) There is a good counterexample in the 1831-46 period that
supports our main thesis, a decade without significant Consols'
profits but with the massive capital needs for the railways. During this
period, the economy underwent the "Engels pause" without
rising living standards, as manufacturing was starved for capital.
Engels believed living standards would never rise and had never risen.
He was wrong but writing in 1844, after a decade of stagnant real wages
and the 1820s ebullience had been forgotten. Our point is that, without
the Consols' profit, new capital needs for the industrializing and
capital-intensifying economy were hard to come by, and could only be
gotten slowly by the workers being squeezed.
(20) Gayer, Rostow, and Schwartz (1953) quoting Tooke (1838).
(21) "A Complete View of the Joint Stock Companies Formed
during the Years 1824 and 1825," Henry English, 1827, quoted in
Neal (1998: 64).
TABLE 1
BUDGET POSITION AND DEBT CHANGES, 1812-27
Start of
Gross Public Year Debt
Surplus/ Funded Debt
Year Income Expend. Deficit Funded Unfunded Increase
1812 70.3 94.8 -24.5 583.4 42.6 24.1
1813 74.7 111.1 -36.4 607.5 44.8 70.0
1814 77.9 112.9 -35.0 677.5 48.1 7.1
1815 79.1 99.5 -20.4 684.6 60.3 49.0
1816 69.2 71.3 -2.1 733.6 44.7 -17.3
1817 57.6 58.7 -1.1 716.3 49.8 --
1818 59.5 57.6 1.9 780.6 62.6 15.0
1819 58.1 57.5 0.6 795.6 48.7 2.9
1820 59.9 58.4 1.5 798.5 41.6 6.4
1821 61.6 58.4 3.2 804.9 33.3 -6.4
1822 59.9 56.5 3.4 798.5 32.7 -1.1
1823 58.5 54.3 4.2 797.4 38.7 -4.5
1824 59.7 55.5 4.2 792.9 35.8 -10.6
1825 57.7 54.1 3.6 782.3 37.9 -3.0
1826 55.2 56.1 -0.9 779.3 31.7 5.7
1827 54.7 55.9 -1.2 785.0 25.0 --
NOTES: All units are in m[pounds sterling].
Figures from 1818 onward include Irish debt.
Fiscal year-end January 5 during this period,
so figures are for January 6 of the year
concerned to January 5 of the following year.
SOURCE: Mitchell (2011), Table Public Finance 3
(Income: 581), Public Finance 4 (Expenditure: 587),
and Public Finance 7 (Debt: 601).
TABLE 2
FUNDED AND UNFUNDED BRITISH GOVERNMENT DEBT,
FEBRUARY 1, 1817
Security Held by Public
'000 [pounds sterling]
Bank of England Annuities 1726 15,686
South Sea Old and New Annuities 1791 14,346
Consolidated Annuities 383,708
Reduced Annuities 148,164
Total 3 Percent Debt 561,905
Consolidated Annuities at 4 [pounds
sterling] Percent 74,919
Consolidated Annuities at 5 [pounds
sterling] Percent 134,882
Annuities, 1797 and 1802 1,059
Total 4 Percent and 5 Percent Debt 210,860
Total Funded Debt 772,765
Unfunded Debt, Exchequer Bills 44,650
Unfunded Treasury and Other Bills 5,397
Total Unfunded Short-Term Debt 50,047
Total Debt 822,812
Security Held in Sinking Fund
'000 [pounds sterling]
Bank of England Annuities 1726 1
South Sea Old and New Annuities 1791 6,692
Consolidated Annuities 18,370
Reduced Annuities 36,852
Total 3 Percent Debt 61,914
Consolidated Annuities at 4 [pounds
sterling] Percent 16
Consolidated Annuities at 5 [pounds
sterling Percent 18
Annuities, 1797 and 1802 5
Total 4 Percent and 5 Percent Debt 39
Total Funded Debt 61,953
Unfunded Debt, Exchequer Bills --
Unfunded Treasury and Other Bills --
Total Unfunded Short-Term Debt --
Total Debt 61,953
SOURCE: Hansard (1817).
TABLE 3
AVERAGE PRICE OF CONSOLIDATED 3 PERCENT
ANNUITIES, 1752-1829
Average
Year Consols' Price
([pounds sterling])
1752 105.00
1753 104.88
1754 103.06
1755 95.50
1756 89.00
1757 88.50
1758 93.44
1759 83.56
1760 79.44
1761 76.94
1762 69.94
1763 89.00
1764 83.13
1765 88.00
1766 88.50
1767 89.00
1768 90.63
1769 86.44
1770 82.38
1771 84.50
1772 90.94
1773 86.43
1774 87.43
1775 88.50
1776 85.50
1777 77.94
1778 66.50
1779 61.50
1780 61.50
1781 57.50
1782 57.00
1783 63.00
1784 55.43
1785 63.00
1786 74.00
1787 73.50
1788 74.00
1789 76.50
1790 76.87
1791 83.75
1792 90.00
1793 75.75
1794 68.19
1795 66.38
1796 62.50
1797 50.81
1798 50.50
1799 59.19
1800 63.69
1801 61.00
1802 70.94
1803 60.13
1804 56.62
1805 59.50
1806 61.63
1807 61.00
1808 65.94
1809 66.81
1810 67.13
1811 64.25
1812 59.00
1813 61.00
1814 61.00
1815 67.00
1816 59.75
1817 73.19
1818 77.50
1819 71.94
1820 67.88
1821 73.75
1822 79.13
1823 78.94
1824 90.94
1825 84.75
1826 79.13
1827 83.13
1828 84.75
1829 89.81
Source: Homer and Sylla
(2005: 157 for 1752-99; 192 for 1800-27).
TABLE 4
BRITISH REAL PER CAPITA GDP GROWTH RATE, 1801-41
Nominal Price
GDP Level
(m [pounds sterling]) (1826 = 100)
1801 257 155.7
1811 334 145.4
1816 328 118.6
1821 322 99.7
1826 403 100.0
1831 480 95.3
1841 520 97.7
Real GDP
(millions
of 1826 Population
s [pounds sterling]) (thousands)
1801 165.1 16,300
1811 229.7 18,500
1816 276.6 19,700
1821 323.0 21,000
1826 403.0 22,500
1831 503.7 24,100
1841 532.2 26,900
Annual real
Real per per capita
capita GDP (1826 GDP
s [pounds sterling]) Growth (%)
1801 10.1 --
1811 12.4 2.06
1816 14.0 2.49
1821 15.4 1.84
1826 17.9 3.09
1831 20.9 3.13
1841 19.8 -0.55
Sources: For GDP,
www.ukpublicspending.co.uk/year_spending_1841UKmn_16mc1#ukgs302;
for population and prices, Mitchell (2011: 11, 721).
COPYRIGHT 2018 Cato Institute
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.