Stated Preferences of Alaska Resident Saltwater Anglers for Contemporary Regulatory Policies.
Lew, Daniel K. ; Larson, Douglas M.
Stated Preferences of Alaska Resident Saltwater Anglers for Contemporary Regulatory Policies.
Introduction
Saltwater recreational fishing in Alaska occurs almost exclusively
in two regions: Southeast Alaska and Southcentral Alaska (Fig. 1). The
primary saltwater fish targeted by recreational anglers in these regions
are Pacific salmon, Oncorhynchus spp.; especially Chinook salmon, O.
tshawytscha, and coho salmon, O. kisutch; and the Pacific halibut,
Hippoglossus stenolepis. Fishery managers rely on bag and size limit
restrictions as the principal management tools to manage harvest levels
for these species. For state-managed salmon, bag limits and minimum size
limits (minimum length of a fish) vary depending upon the time of year
and specific location.' For federally managed Pacific halibut, bag
limits (two fish per day of any size for both unguided and
guided/charter boat anglers) (2) were the primary management tool used
until 2007.
Since then, management of the Pacific halibut sport fishery in
Alaska has undergone a number of significant changes due to concerns
over declining stock abundance and distribution, size at age, and
allocation disputes between commercial and recreational charter boat
fishing interests. Of principal concern arc the changes directly
affecting anglers (3)--the traditional bag limit regulatory structure
for this fishery has been retained, but with a variety of new features
such as different size limits for different fish in the bag limit, and
"large-or-small fish" size limits that have both a maximum
size limit and a higher minimum size limit. These so-called
"reverse slot" regulations are designed to protect fish in the
intermediate size (and age) range, since they arc especially important
for reproduction.
To help understand the trade-offs between regulatory tools for
managing charter halibut harvest, it is important to understand how
angler values are affected. The most common approach used in recent
years to evaluate the effect of harvest restrictions on recreational
fishing values is the stated preference (SP) method (i.e., Criddle et
al., 2003; Carter and Liese, 2012; Anderson and Lee, 2013; Lew and
Larson, 2012, 2014, 2015). Stated preference methods use responses to
carefully-constructed questions typically asked in a survey to provide
information about people's preferences and values (Mitchell and
Carson, 1989; Bateman et al., 2002; Kanninen, 2006). The principal
reason for the popularity of these methods in fisheries applications is
that fishery managers arc often interested in the effects of angler
harvest regulations under consideration that have yet to be tried, which
precludes collection of data on how people respond to the regulations.
One particular type of SP method, the choice experiment (CE), has
increasingly been used for valuing the effects of angler harvest
regulations because of its ability to provide economic value information
across a range of potential policy changes (Kanninen, 2006). Choice
experiment questions present a choice between two or more alternatives
(e.g., fishing trip options) that are described in terms of several
attributes (e.g., trip cost, regulations, fish targeted), one or more of
which are policy variables (e.g., bag or size limits). Surveys will
generally contain multiple CE questions that differ in the levels of the
attributes that make up each option, so a great deal of information
about a person's preferences is obtained parsimoniously. Random
utility maximization (RUM) models (Louviere et al., 2000) are used with
CE responses to predict the probability that a given respondent will
choose a particular alternative, and from this both the marginal value
of individual attributes and the value of a policy containing several
attributes are obtained.
This article investigates how the economic values received by
Alaska resident saltwater recreational anglers are affected by different
configurations of bag and size limits that are either contemplated for
the future or are now in use. The focus on Alaska resident anglers
distinguishes this work from Lew and Larson (2015), which focused on
nonresident anglers (i.e., anglers who lived outside Alaska). In this
study, we use CE data from a 2012 survey of Alaska resident anglers and
the methodology of Lew and Larson (2015), who analyzed economic values
for halibut and salmon fishing trips associated with Alaska
nonresidents, to provide comparable estimates of the values received by
residents of both Southcentral and Southeast Alaska. In addition to
providing estimates of status quo values, we analyze how these values
change with different regulatory configurations. Because they arc
described well elsewhere in the literature (Lew and Larson, 2015), our
discussions of the data and methods used are somewhat succinct.
Data
Data for this analysis are from a mail survey conducted during the
first half of 2012 of Alaska resident anglers who purchased Alaska sport
fishing licenses during 2011. (4) The survey was very similar in content
to a 2007 survey of Alaska resident anglers (Lew et al., 2010) but was
reworked to acknowledge changes in harvest regulations that have
occurred in recent years (primarily size restrictions on Pacific halibut
for charter boat anglers). It was pretested with Alaska saltwater
fishermen via cognitive interviews (Willis, 2005) held in two Alaska
cities (Juneau and Anchorage). Fisheries analysts involved in Alaska
fishery management also provided valuable input that was incorporated
into the survey design.
Surveys contained four CE questions, each of which offered two
saltwater boat fishing trips and a third nonsaltwater boat fishing
option. Respondents were asked to choose the options they liked best and
second best, which allows for a full rank ordering and provides more
information than simply modeling which option is preferred. Two separate
versions of the survey were developed--the first for resident anglers
who live in Southeast Alaska, referred to as the SE version (Fig. 2),
and the second for all other resident anglers, referred to as the SC
version (Fig. 3). The saltwater boat fishing trips in the CE questions
in the SE version were described as occurring in Southeast Alaska. Due
to the size of the state, travel for residents between Southeast and
Southcentral Alaska is costly, both in terms of time and money. For this
reason, few resident anglers of one region have been observed to fish in
the other region in previous survey work (Lew et al., 2010).
Consequently, the CE questions ask about fishing within the resident
angler's "home region."
For this same reason, the SC version presented saltwater fishing
trip options that would occur in Southcentral Alaska. Attributes in the
CE questions in both the SE and SC versions included the species
caught--either one or two of the three species available, Pacific
halibut, Chinook salmon, and coho salmon; the daily bag (take) limit;
size restriction (if any); and the fishing-related costs.
Since saltwater fishing trips in Southeast Alaska typically are day
trips only (5), the number of fishing days on the trip was only included
as an attribute in the SC version of the survey. Moreover, the SC
version includes an attribute that indicates whether the fishing trip
was on a private or charter boat. Previous survey results suggested that
very few Southeast Alaska residents take charter fishing trips (due in
part to residents in this region generally having more access to private
fishing boats), so the same attribute was not included in the SE
version.
There were 30 versions of the SC survey and 20 versions of the SE
survey. These versions differed only in the levels of attributes
describing the trips; attribute levels are given in Table 1. The
combination of attribute levels seen in each of these survey versions
was determined using a procedure that maximized the statistical
efficiency of the overall experimental design (Huber and Zwerina, 1996).
The survey implementation followed a modified Dillman Tailored
Design Method (Dillman et al., 2014), with an advance letter, survey
mailing (which included the survey booklet, cover letter, map, business
reply envelope, and a small monetary incentive), thank you/reminder
postcard, a second full survey mailing, and a follow-up telephone
contact. The overall survey response rates for the SE and SC versions
were 46.1% and 41.1%, respectively. (6) Choice experiment data from the
two versions were analyzed separately. After removing respondents who
did not answer the CE questions consistently or at all, as well as
protest responses, the sample sizes used in the analysis were 335
anglers for the SE version analysis and 430 anglers for the SC version
analysis.
The demographic group represented most heavily in both samples was
older and very experienced Caucasian male anglers (Table 2). The SE and
SC samples were generally very similar in terms of demographics with the
majority (between 60% and 65% depending on the sample) being male,
Caucasian (about 88%), and having a college degree or higher education
(between 51% and 55% depending on the sample). Across both samples, the
mean age was about 46 or 47 years and mean years of fishing experience
was about 30 or 31 years. (7) There were slight differences in household
income between the SE and SC samples, with the SE sample having a lower
mean income (about $84,000) compared to anglers in the SC sample (about
$96,000).
Modeling Approach
To analyze the CE data, we used the panel rank-ordered random
utility maximization model described in Lew and Larson (2015), which
explicitly accounts for both the rank-order nature of the CE data (Bcggs
et al., 1981; Chapman and Staelin, 1982) and the panel nature of the
data. This approach avoids the restrictive Independence of Irrelevant
Alternatives (IIA) assumption embodied in fixed-parameter RUM models by
introducing preference heterogeneity, so that some or many parameters
are randomly distributed over the population (Train, 2003). To be more
precise, in the RUM model the utility (or satisfaction) of alternative j
(j = A, B, or C) for question i (i = 1,...,4) is assumed to be composed
of a systematic component, consisting of observable characteristics or
attributes, and a random component:
[U.sub.ij] = [V.sub.ij]([beta]) + [[epsilon].sub.ij], (1)
where [V.sub.ij]([beta]) is the systematic part of utility and a
function of attributes for alternative j in question i, [beta] are
parameters of the utility function, and [[epsilon].sub.ij] is an
independent and identically distributed Type I extreme value (TEV) error
term that represents the part of utility unknown to the researcher. Here
it is assumed that the non-cost parameters are randomly distributed over
the population; that is, these parameters arc assumed to follow a normal
distribution. To this end, let [[beta].sub.n] [member of] [beta] be
distributed [[beta].sub.n] ~ N([[bar. [beta]].sub.n],
[[OMEGA].sub.[beta]] where [[bar. [beta]].sub.n] is a vector of mean
parameters and [[OMEGA].sub.[beta]] is a variance-covariancc matrix. In
practice, this means two parameters for each random parameter arc
estimated, a mean and standard deviation, which describe the
distribution. The individual is assumed to choose the alternative that
yields the most utility out of the available choices (A, B, and C) in
each question as the "best" choice, and the one with the next
largest utility as the "second best" choice. Given the
assumption about the distribution of the error term [[epsilon].sub.ij]
(and assuming it is independent across the four CE questions in each
survey), the probabilities of observing an individual's choice of
best (j) and second best (k) for a single choice question take the form:
Pr[j >k>l] = Pr[j | j, k, l]*Px[k |k,l], (2)
where j, k, and l are each one of the elements of the available
choices (A, B, and C) and are not equal to one another, Pr[j |j,
k,l]=[integral] exp([V.sub.j])/[exp([V.sub.j]) + exp([V.sub.k]) +
exp([V.sub.l])] d[beta] and Pr[k |k, l] =
[integral]exp([V.sub.k])/[exp([V.sub.k]) + exp([V.sub.l])] d[beta] are
probabilities evaluated over the distribution of random parameters. This
model is estimated by maximum simulated likelihood, where the
log-likelihood function is the product of the probabilities in equation
2 over each of the four choice questions. Separate models were estimated
for the CE data from the SE sample (SE model) and SC sample (the SC
model).
Model Specification
The systematic component of utility associated with the fishing
trip alternatives (Choices A and B in each question) was assumed to be a
linear-in-parameters function of two types of variables: non-regulatory
and regulatory.
Nonregulatory Variables
For both the SE and SC models, the nonregulatory variables include
an alternative-specific constant (ASC) associated with the nonfishing
trip option (Choice C) and cost (COST). The SC model specification
additionally contains a dummy variable for whether the fishing trip is
taken with a private boat (PRIV) and the trip length (DAY). The first
lines of Table 3 contain descriptions of these nonregulatory variables.
Regulatory Variables
Three categories of utility function attributes arc needed to
describe anglers' preferences for both past and present
regulations, as well as potential regulations that have not been
implemented, for the salmon and Pacific halibut fisheries. The first two
are uniform regulations (a bag limit or size limit applying to the
entire day's harvest, which were used historically) and
differentiated regulatory variables, which vary for individual fish in
the bag limit and have been introduced relatively recently.
To date, regulators have only used uniform regulations for the
Alaska salmon fisheries, and there do not appear to be any significant
reasons for changing this strategy. In the Pacific halibut fishery,
however, managers have been introducing two other categories of
regulations: differentiated regulations and compound regulations that
either use combinations of size and bag limits, or apply differently for
individual fish in the daily harvest, or both.
The salmon fisheries regulations of interest here use just uniform
bag limits, which determine the maximum number of fish that can be
caught in a day fishing without size limits. (8) As a result, the part
of the utility function pertaining to Chinook (king) salmon includes
dummy variables for bag limits of one (KLIM1), two (KLIM2), or three
(K.LIM3) fish, which cover the range of bag limits actually observed
(Table 3). For coho (silver) salmon, dummy variables for bag limits of
three (SLIM1), four (SLIM2), and six (SLIM3) fish arc used,
corresponding to the higher harvest levels permitted in that fishery.
Fishing regulations in the Pacific halibut fishery are more
complex. Bag limits have been the primary harvest control tool used in
this fishery, but beginning in 2007, compound halibut management
regulations were introduced for the charter (guided) fishing sector in
Southeast Alaska (International Pacific Halibut Commission [IPHC]
regulatory area 2C), in part due to this sector's rapid growth and
concomitant increase in harvests. During 2007-08, halibut harvest was
managed with a compound regulation consisting of a 2-fish bag limit,
with one fish of any size and the other subject to a maximum size limit.
In 2009 and 2010, halibut harvest was limited to one fish of any size on
charter vessels. In 2011, a compound regulation with a bag limit of one
halibut no larger than 37 inches (about 23 lb (9)) was introduced. A
further permutation of the compound limit structure was introduced in
2012, with a "reverse slot" regulation that consists of both a
maximum size limit and a minimum size limit, with the latter larger than
the former. (10)
In 2012-13, the reverse slot regulation in effect was one halibut
less than 45 inches (about 43 lb) or greater than 68 inches (about 163
lb). In 2014, this was modified slightly so that the maximum size limit
was 44 inches (about 40 lb), with the bag limit and minimum size limit
parts of the regulation remaining the same. However, in 2015, the
maximum size limit was reduced to 43 inches while the minimum size limit
was increased to 80 inches (about 272 lb), which restricted charter
anglers in Southeast Alaska to smaller fish or very large fish.
Additionally, 2014 marked the first time harvest by charter boat anglers
in Southcentral Alaska (IPHC regulatory area 3A) was made subject to a
compound regulation, with one of the fish in the two fish bag limit
being restricted to 29 inches (about 10 lb) or less. The same
regulations were used in Southcentral Alaska during 2015. Given these
recent trends in charter halibut regulations, the use of compound
regulations, particularly reverse slot regulations, appears likely to
continue. (11)
This brief discussion of recent Alaska Pacific halibut regulation
makes clear that the interaction of bag limits and two size limits
creates many possible regulatory outcomes for Pacific halibut,
particularly for the charter fishing sector. The number of fish in a bag
limit that arc subject to size limit(s), the number that arc not, and
the levels of the size limits arc all potentially important
considerations for anglers. In addition, it is important to try to
provide information on regulations that may be used in the future. Thus,
the utility functions in this study embody considerably more halibut
regulation attributes than salmon regulation attributes. (12)
The specific regulatory attributes for Pacific halibut are also
listed in Table 3. The additional uniform regulatory variables defined
arc dummy variables for halibut bag limits of one (HLIM1), two (HLIM2),
or three (HLIM3) fish, and an integer variable (HBL, taking values of 0,
1, 2, or 3) representing the number of fish allowed in the bag limit. A
final uniform regulation is a dummy variable (HMIN) indicating whether a
minimum size limit is in effect; both this and HBL are used in defining
compound regulations, which arc described in Table 4.
Table 3 also presents several differentiated regulatory variables.
They include dummy variables indicating whether the first fish in the
bag limit (HMAX1) or additional fish in the bag limit (HMAX2) have
maximum size limits; and integer variables (HSIZE1 and HSIZE2)
indicating what those limits are. In addition, dummy variables define
whether the first fish (HNOMAX1) or other fish (HNOMAX2) in the bag
limit can be any size or arc restricted by a size limit.
Table 4 describes compound regulations that include the reverse
slot option and other options that treat individual fish in the bag
limit differently. The first set of regulations applies to trips where
there is not a reverse slot restriction, but there is a bag limit and a
maximum size limit on one or more fish. (These regulations pertain to
cases where only a maximum size limit, not a maximum and a minimum, is
in effect.) Three dummy variables (HBL1FSH, HBL2FSH, and HBL3FSH) define
whether the first, second, or third fish in the bag limit (when
applicable) are subject to a maximum size limit. The parameters
estimated when these variables arc in the model correspondingly measure
the marginal utility of the ith fish (i = 1, 2, 3) when it is subject to
a maximum size limit.
In addition, since the marginal utility of a size-limited fish may
vary depending on the maximum size limit itself, there are three
additional dummy variables for the different fish in the bag limit that
indicate whether a maximum size limit is applied to that fish. HBLIMAX1
equals one when there is a maximum size limit on the first (only) fish
in a 1 -fish bag limit, and zero otherwise; similarly, HBL3MAX1 and
HBL3MAX2 equal one when there is a maximum size limit on the first and
second fish in a multi-fish bag limit, respectively.
Table 4 also contains definitions and descriptions of a set of
conditional dummy variables that exactly parallel those just described,
but apply to fishing trips where there is a reverse slot option. Thus,
HML1FSH, HML2FSH, and HML3FSH are dummy variables for the first, second,
and third fish, respectively, with maximum size limits when at least one
of them is a part of a reverse slot regulation. HML1MAX1, HML3MAX1, and
HML3MAX2 are dummy variables that indicate which fish in the bag limit,
if any, has a maximum size limit level imposed on it when there is a
one-bag limit (HML1MAX1) or a multi-fish bag limit (HML3MAX1 and
HML3MAX2).
Estimation Results
Panel-ordered mixed logit models were estimated using maximum
simulated likelihood estimation (Train, 2003; Lew and Larson, 2012) for
each sample (SE and SC samples), and the resulting parameter estimates
are presented in Table 5 (for Southeast Alaska) and Table 6
(Southcentral Alaska). The estimated models allowed for all noncost
parameters to be normally distributed over the population. (13) A
comparison of the mixed logit model results with those from conditional
logit models for each specification showed significant improvement in
statistical fit by introducing preference heterogeneity by way of random
parameters for both the SE and SC models. In fact, as Table 5 presents,
9 of the 10 random parameters in the SE model had statistically
significant standard deviation parameters, indicating respondents across
the sample varied in terms of how their utility was affected by most of
the noncost variables.
The ASC mean parameter was negative and statistically significant,
indicating that on average the nonsaltwater boat fishing trip option
(Choice C) was not preferred over the saltwater boat fishing trip
options, which are assumed for the SE sample to be private boat fishing
trips. However, the large and significant standard deviation parameter
associated with the ASC suggests there was considerable variation in
preferences toward the nonsaltwater boat fishing option across the
sample with some preferring it to the fishing options and others
preferring the fishing options.
The other mean parameters were generally statistically significant
with the expected signs: the cost parameter was negative and highly
significant, while all of the regulatory attributes, which arc uniform
bag limits of different sizes for the three species (Pacific halibut and
Chinook and coho salmon) were positive and statistically significant,
suggesting there is utility to being allowed to fish (i.e., having a
nonzero bag limit). The bag limit mean parameter estimates along with
their standard errors (implied by the asymptotic t-statistics) indicate
that for halibut and coho salmon, the second fish in the bag limit is
valued more highly than the first fish, with no difference in valuation
of a 2-fish limit vs. a 3-fish limit for halibut and between a 4-fish
and 6-fish limit for coho salmon. Thus, for the average SE resident
angler (i.e., evaluating at the mean parameter estimates), there is
increasing marginal utility for the first and second fish bag limit but
zero marginal utility from relaxing the bag limit to the third level
(three fish for halibut and six fish for coho). For Chinook salmon,
there is no statistical difference between any of the bag limit mean
parameter estimates, implying positive marginal utility of the first
fish and zero marginal utility of the second and third fish.
Table 6 presents the results for the SC sample, which contains
resident angler respondents who were presented CE questions with both
private boat and charter boat fishing trip options. The model results
indicate a general preference for the status quo (nonsaltwater boat
fishing) option; the mean estimate is significantly positive, and its
magnitude relative to the standard deviation estimate suggests that it
is positive for the majority of SC anglers. Additionally, they indicate
a strong preference for private boat trips relative to charter boat
trips, all else being equal: the mean parameter estimate (4.04) relative
to the standard deviation estimate (2.55) implies that a large majority
of the population of anglers in this region prefers private boat trips.
Of the other nonregulatory attributes, trip length (represented by the
DAY and DAY squared variables) had a statistically insignificant mean
effect, but the significant standard deviations on these variables
indicate a considerable dispersion of preferences for trip length in the
population. The cost parameter, as expected, was negative and highly
significant.
Of the regulatory attributes, the parameter estimates on the
uniform bag limits are the most straightforward to interpret in
isolation. For private boat trips, bag limits had statistically
significant positive mean effects for halibut and coho salmon, but
statistically insignificant effects for Chinook salmon, except for the
3-fish bag limit, which is significant and positive (at the 10% level).
For halibut, the means of 2- and 3-fish bag limits were both
substantially higher than for a single fish bag limit, with no
appreciable difference between them. For coho salmon, this was reversed:
a 3-fish bag limit had a substantially higher marginal utility than did
4- and 6-fish bag limits, with no appreciable difference between the
latter two.
For charter trips, Chinook salmon bag limits (with 2- and 3-fish
limits) and coho salmon bag limits (with 3- and 4-fish limits) had
statistically significant positive mean effects; the remaining mean
effects were insignificant. The significant standard deviation
parameters for 2-fish halibut limits, 1-fish Chinook salmon limits, and
all of the coho salmon bag limits indicate statistically significant
dispersion of mean effects.
Figure 4.--Total economic values and associated 95% confidence bounds
of Southeast Alaska resident anglers for private-boat saltwater trips
with different bag limits.
1 halibut 211.87
1 halibut 268.61
3 halibut 262.22
1 Chinook 195.93
2 Chinook 238.42
3 Chinook 226.12
3 coho 171.59
4 coho 173.85
5 coho 174.31
1 halibut & 1 Chinook 312.15
2 halibut & 1 Chinook 338.75
3 halibut & 1 Chinook 364.6
3 halibut & 3 Chinook 389.86
1 halibut & 3 coho 290.2
1 halibut & 6 coho 291.45
1 halibut & 3 coho 338.26
3 halibut & 6 coho 338.23
1 Chinok & 3 coho 273.67
1 Chinok & 6 coho 275.25
3 Chinok & 3 coho 302.54
3 Chinok & 6 coho 306.18
Note: Table made from line graph.
Each differentiated regulatory attribute had either a significant
mean effect or a significant standard deviation. The significant and
negative mean and insignificant standard deviation for HALSIZE2, which
indicates maximum size limits on all fish in the bag limit beyond the
first one, shows a uniform dislike for the regulation. The insignificant
mean and significant standard deviation on HALSIZE1 (maximum size limit
on the first fish) indicate that some people like, and some dislike, the
regulation (independent of HALSIZE2). The same is true for HNOMAX1 and
HNOMAX2, which indicate the presence or absence of size limits (whether
maximum or minimum) on the first and additional fish, respectively, in
the bag limit: some in the population like and some dislike size
regulations.
The compound regulations place maximum size limits on one or more
fish in the bag limit, with or without minimum size limits. The first
set of compound regulation variables (HBL1FSH, HBL2FSH, HBL3FSH,
HBL1MAX1, HBL3MAX1, HBL3MAX2), which define maximum size limits only,
are generally not statistically significant; only the standard deviation
parameters on HBL1MAX1 and HBL3MAX2 are statistically significant, which
only indicate utility variation across anglers for maximum size limits.
The second set of compound regulation variables (HML1FSH, HML2FSH,
HML3FSH, HML1MAX1, HML3MAX1, HML3MAX2) define the reverse slot or
combination maximum and minimum size limits, which relative to the first
set of variables add the option to catch and retain a very large fish
when there is a (maximum) size limit in effect.
The reverse slot option when there is a 1-halibut bag limit
(HML1FSH) has a statistically significant positive effect on angler
utility. In the presence of the reverse slot option, angler utility
decreases with increases in the maximum size limit (lower size limit in
the reverse slot restriction) when a 1-fish bag limit is in effect
(HML1MAX1) and for all but the first fish when a multiple fish bag limit
is in effect (HML3MAX2).
The interactions of these variables cover four of the six cases for
regulating individual fish in bag limit limits of up to 3 fish: the only
cases not covered are the first fish in a 2- or 3-fish bag limit. These
latter two cases are situations where only HML2FSH is in effect, for
which there is not a significant effect on utility. For the other cases
discussed above, both HML1FSH and HML1MAX1 are in effect, and there is a
small (net) positive effect on utility. To summarize these implications,
for trips with a reverse slot option to catch a very large fish and a
single fish bag limit, there is a positive effect on utility. When the
reverse slot option is used on one or more fish with a multi-fish bag
limit, the effect on utility is negative, all else being equal.
Economic Values for Fishing
Two types of economic values are calculated using the SE and SC
model estimation results: marginal economic values of an attribute
associated with a one unit change and the total economic value of, or
willingness to pay (WTP) for, a fishing trip with a specific set of
attribute levels. The former are important for understanding the
incremental effect that trip characteristics, such as the type of boat
used and regulations, have on the value of charter fishing trips with
all else held constant. In contrast, total economic values of fishing
trips represent the WTP for a fishing trip given a specific set of
regulations on target species, as they may vary by the type of boat used
and area fished.
Figure 4 displays estimates of total value for Southeast Alaska
trips with different types of uniform bag limits and 95% confidence
bounds for the estimated values (calculated using the Krinsky and Robb,
1986, simulation-based method). These are values associated with 1-day
trips on private boats, and all have bag limits of different levels.
Different values are presented for fishing trips that target different
species--some trip values are for single species trips where one species
is caught and others are for trips on which more than one species is
caught. For single-species bag limit trip values, the mean ranged from
about $172 to $269, and all of the lower 5% levels of the confidence
intervals are above zero, indicating that total value is strictly
positive. Halibut-only and Chinook-only trips with 2-or 3-fish bag
limits have higher mean total values than those with 1-fish bag limits,
while for coho salmon trips there is no appreciable difference in mean
total value regardless of the bag limit (i.e., the confidence intervals
are almost identical).
Figure 5.--Marginal values and associated 95% confidence intervals of
bag limit changes in Southeast Alaska saltwater fisheries.
1 halibut $170.55
1 to 2 halibut 55.46
2 to 3 halibut -6.04
1 Chinook 101.5
1 to 2 Chinook 40.42
2 to 3 Chinook 12.58
3 coho 77.37
3 to 4 coho -1.03
4 to 6 coho 4.01
Note: Table made from line graph.
Values associated with trips on which two species are caught arc
presented for each of the three 2-species combinations ranging from the
lowest to highest level of bag limit for each species. Halibut-Chinook
trips had mean total values ranging from $312 to $390, while
halibut-coho mean trip values ranged from $290 to $338 and Chinook-coho
trip values ranged from $273 to $306.
Marginal values of bag limits and associated confidence bounds for
each species from the SE model are presented in Figure 5. For each
species, the first fish in the bag limit was the most valuable (or, the
first three fish for coho salmon), with mean marginal values of 1-fish
bag limits being $171 for Pacific halibut, $102 for Chinook salmon, and
$77 for coho salmon trips. For both Pacific halibut and Chinook salmon
trips, there was a decreasing positive mean marginal utility of the
second fish in the bag limit ($55 and $40, respectively), while for coho
salmon the mean marginal values of both the increase to 4 fish from 3
fish and to 6 fish from 4 fish in the bag limit were not different from
zero statistically.
Total economic values for South-central Alaska private boat trips
(and the associated confidence bounds) are presented in Figure 6.
Private boat trips in Southcentral Alaska were valued more highly than
those in Southeast Alaska, with mean total values for halibut-only trips
ranging from $1,415 to $2,083 depending on the bag limit, from $831 to
$973 for Chinook salmon-only trips, and from $1,119 to $1577 for coho
salmon-only trips. As in Southeast Alaska, the lower bounds on the
confidence intervals were positive in every case, indicating clearly
that the total values are statistically significant and positive. Unlike
for the Southeast Alaska trip values, though, there was generally not a
clear trend in how total values change with increases in the bag limit;
only for an increase from 1 to 2 fish in the Pacific halibut bag limit
was there evidence of a (statistically significant) positive change in
mean total value (indicated by non-overlapping confidence intervals).
Multiple-species private boat trips in Southcentral Alaska also had
mean total values that were considerably higher than those for Southeast
Alaska. Not surprisingly, total values for the halibut-coho combination
were the highest since these arc the highest valued in single-species
trips. Adding either halibut or coho to a Chinook salmon trip increases
mean total value substantially, while conversely, adding Chinook to
either a halibut or coho trip increases mean total value only modestly,
by less than one-half of the single-species Chinook mean value.
Strikingly, however, total economic values for charter boat trips
in South-central Alaska were effectively zero in every case and arc
therefore not presented. The basic result is that South-central Alaska
resident anglers on average do not have positive total values for
saltwater charter boat fishing trips regardless of the species targeted
or regulations. In other words, the mean values for Southcentral Alaska
charter boat trips are not statistically different from zero (and in the
case of some trips under certain regulations the total trip value was
statistically negative). This means the demand for charter boat fishing
trips is zero for the average Southcentral Alaska resident angler. This
result is not particularly surprising within our model in light of the
fact that both the alternative-specific constant (indicating preference
for the nonfishing option) and the parameter on the private boat dummy
variable were highly significant and positive with large magnitudes.
Additionally, the statistical noise around the parameter estimates
associated with the charter-specific variables, most of which were not
statistically significant, is also likely a major reason for this
result. Additional discussion of this is in the next section.
Figure 7 presents the marginal values of trip attributes (and
associated confidence intervals) for all South-central Alaska saltwater
fisheries private boat trips. Reinforcing the point made earlier about
private boat trips increasing angler utility, the marginal value of a
trip being taken on a private boat, all else equal, is statistically
greater than zero with a mean marginal value of about $1,811. For
private boat Pacific halibut trips, the mean marginal value of both the
increase from 0 to 1 fish and from 1 to 2 fish is positive and
significant, while the marginal value of an increase from 2 to 3 fish is
not significantly different from zero. For both Chinook and coho salmon
trips on private boats, the marginal values of all levels of bag limit
increase arc not significantly different from zero.
Figure 6.--Total economic values of Southcentral Alaska resident
anglers for private-boat saltwater trips with different bag limits.
1 halibut 1,415
2 halibut 2,059
3 halibut 2,083
1 Chinook 898
2 Chinook 831
3 Chinook 973
3 coho 1,577
4 coho 1,119
6 coho 1,253
1 halibut & 1 Chinook 1,653
1 halibut & 3 Chinook 1,738
3 halibut & 1 Chinook 2,251
3 halibut & 3 Chinook 2,355
1 halibut & 3 coho 2,425
1 halibut & 6 coho 1,947
3 halibut & 3 coho 2,975
1 halibut & 6 coho 2,617
1 Chinook & 3 coho 1,953
1 Chinook & 6 coho 1,498
3 Chinook & 3 coho 2,033
3 Chinook & 6 coho 1,529
Note: Table made from line graph.
For charter boat Southcentral Alaska trips, most of the marginal
values of bag limit increases are not different from zero (Fig. 8).
However, for both Pacific halibut and Chinook salmon the marginal value
of an increase in bag limit from 1 to 2 fish is significantly positive,
as is the increase from 0 to 3 fish in the coho salmon bag limit.
However, due to the magnitudes of angler preference for the
non-saltwater fishing option, these significant and positive marginal
values are not sufficient to shift the total value of saltwater charter
fishing trips to be positive.
Discussion
The estimation results and estimated economic values make several
points about the Alaska resident saltwater salmon and Pacific halibut
fisheries. First, the economic value of the private boat fishery in
Southeast Alaska (the predominant way of fishing by residents) is
positive and significant, with single-species 1-day trips generating
mean total economic values in the range of $172-269, depending on
species harvested and the bag limit. Second, the Southcentral Alaska
private boat fishery also generates positive and significant total
values, and these are considerably larger than in Southeast Alaska: for
single-species trips,
the mean total value of a 1-day trip ranged from about $831 to
$2,083. Third, in both these fisheries, 2-species trips generally are
valued more highly than single-species trips, though there is declining
marginal value to adding a second species harvest to the trip. Fourth,
there is not much evidence that increases in bag limits beyond the first
fish for single-species trips increases the total value of a trip. The
increase in the Pacific halibut bag limit in Southcentral Alaska from 1
to 2 fish may be the possible exception.
The only charter fishery engaged in by Alaska residents in
substantial numbers is the one in Southcentral Alaska. Here, the
modeling and economic value estimates indicate strongly that the average
total economic value of trips with characteristics similar to those
available to anglers in recent years (or any others we tried) is not
statistically positive. The estimation results indicate very clearly two
facts that explain why. First is a strong preference toward the
nonfishing option when compared with charter boat trips, which is
indicated by the highly significant, positive, and large coefficient on
the alternative-specific constant in the Southcentral Alaska fishery
(ASC in Table 6). For the private boat fishery, this is fully offset by
the large positive and significant coefficient on the private boat dummy
variable (PRIV) in this model.
Figure 7.--Marginal values and associated 95% confidence intervals of
bag limit changes for private boat saltwater fishing trips by
Southcentral Alaska residents.
1 halibut 780.34
1 to 2 halibut 633.01
2 to 3 halibut 12.53
1 Chinook 272.59
1 to 2 Chinook -266.94
2 to 3 Chinook 165.14
1 coho 272.59
2 to 4 coho -460.75
4 to 6 coho 117.24
Note: Table made from line graph.
Figure 8.--Marginal values and associated 95% confidence intervals of
bag limit changes for charter boat saltwater fishing trips by
Southcentral Alaska residents.
1 halibut -276.96
1 to 2 halibut 563.31
2 to 3 halibut 352.04
1 Chinik 319.94
1 to 2 Chinik 429.1
2 to 3 Chinik -254.4
3 coho 768.49
3 to 4 coho -337.91
4 to 6 coho 263.05
Note: Table made from line graph.
This basic conclusion regarding Southcentral Alaska resident
anglers' preferences is not changed by including the specific
regulations that have been used recently. The reason is that there is
virtually no net impact on utility from including most of the
differentiated and compound regulations that describe current and recent
charter fishing opportunities in the region. The variables for maximum
size limits without the reverse slot option all have statistically
insignificant mean effects. Three of the variables for maximum size
limits with the reverse slot option do have significant mean effects,
but their combined effect is near zero for most of the regulatory
scenarios possible.
This does not mean that charter boat fishing trips in Southcentral
Alaska have no overall total economic value, since the discussion here
is just of Alaska residents' preferences. Lew and Larson (2015)
found that for nonresidents of Alaska, charter trips with more than a
1-fish bag limit, and those which did not have very small maximum size
limits (23 lb in their analysis), had total values of 1-day trips that
exceeded $1,150 in every case considered, with several regulatory
scenarios generating total values exceeding $2,000. Trips with a 1-fish
bag limit and a 23 lb maximum size limit generated total economic values
of about $330.
However, each of the Southcentral Alaska charter boat fishing trips
with differentiated or compound halibut regulations generated in this
study had mean total values to Alaska residents that were not
statistically different from zero, while the same trip types generated
significantly positive total values to nonresidents of Alaska in the Lew
and Larson (2015) study. This suggests that charter boat halibut trips
have large total values for the fishery as a whole, but that most of it
accrues to nonresidents.
Importantly, at the time of the survey, Southcentral Alaska charter
boat trips were not subject to any of the size restrictions asked about
in the CE questions. At that time, charter boat anglers in Area 3A were
allowed to catch and keep two fish of any size. Thus, in this study SC
respondents were asked to choose between fishing trip alternatives that
were much stricter in terms of the regulations imposed on charter
halibut fishing than they were accustomed to. This likely explains the
strong preference for private boat trip alternatives and the nonboat
saltwater fishing trip option, which likely greatly contributed to the
finding of there being effectively zero demand for saltwater charter
fishing trips.
Since this study used data from the same survey effort and a
modeling approach similar to Lew and Larson (2015), it is worth briefly
mentioning the caveats they discuss that apply here. First, the
scenarios we analyze cannot be taken literally as assessments of the
economic value of current regulations, since there are some differences
between what was anticipated when the study was designed and what
regulations were actually implemented. Probably the biggest difference
is in the minimum size thresholds for the reverse slot option, which arc
130 lb in our scenarios but larger in the actual regulations. This may
increase the angler's perception of their chance of being able to
keep a large fish, which in turn may increase their valuation of the
reverse slot option. This seems unlikely to affect any conclusions in
our analysis, since economic values in the halibut charter fishery were
statistically zero.
Second, the experimental design was complex to attempt to best
reflect the many facets of current halibut regulation. This large design
contributed to the wide confidence intervals seen for many regulatory
scenarios for halibut. (We have also estimated simpler specifications
which aggregate many of the detailed regulatory attributes of this
analysis, but the basic conclusions about the effects of regulation and
economic values do not change qualitatively. (14)) This was not an issue
for the salmon scenarios since they involved bag limits only and
therefore required a relatively simple experimental design.
Third, the estimated total economic values are WTP values, not net
economic values. Thus, the charter prices, which in recent years have
ranged from about $300 for a single day trip to about $1,500 or more for
a multi-day trip, and travel costs (e.g., fuel) from the angler's
home to the dock need to be accounted for. These costs must be
subtracted from the WTP estimates presented in this paper to generate
net economic trip values. Fourth, the significance of the standard
deviation terms suggests that heterogeneity of preferences across
anglers is important, with considerable variation of total values of
regulatory scenarios across the sample.
In addition to these caveats that are shared with the nonresident
angler analysis in Lew and Larson (2015), we note several additional
ones that are important limitations specific to our analysis of Alaska
resident anglers. First, compared to the nonresident sample in Lew and
Larson (2015) (of 825 respondents), the SC sample had roughly half as
many respondents (430 resident anglers). However, the same fairly
complex utility specification was applied in both studies. In the
present case there were far fewer statistically significant parameters
associated with the charter-specific halibut harvest regulations. It is
possible this may be a product of the smaller sample being used in a
complex model specification and there not being sufficient sample to
isolate the effects of the regulatory attributes. (15) Thus, given the
complexity of contemporary regulations related to charter fishing in
Alaska, future analyses may need to utilize much larger samples.
Second, we note that our Alaska resident samples are not limited to
saltwater anglers. Among survey respondents in the SC sample, for
example, half had fished in saltwater during the 2011 fishing season,
and 21% had fished by charter boat (the remainder of the saltwater
anglers had only fished by private boat or from shore). Our results,
however, arc based on analyzing CE responses from any Alaska resident
angler who was licensed to fish in Alaska during 2011, regardless of
their experience saltwater fishing.
Although it is likely that preferences for saltwater fishing trips
will differ between those who primarily fish in saltwater compared to
those who primarily fish in freshwater, we do not distinguish or
investigate these differences here since our principal goal was to
generate estimates of saltwater fishing opportunities for all anglers,
both those who have saltwater fished and those that would potentially do
so. However, we acknowledge that future research can and should be done
to investigate the differences in values and preferences between these
angler types.
Conclusions
This article has presented results on the value of saltwater
charter boat fishing trips to Alaska residents using data from a 2012
survey of nonresident anglers in a stated preference choice experiment
analysis. The econometric estimation approaches utilized here followed
those used in Lew and Larson (2015). Moreover, the results of this study
are intended to complement the economic value information from Lew and
Larson (2015), which consisted of economic values for saltwater fishing
of Alaska nonresidents. Together, the two studies provide a relatively
complete picture of saltwater angler preferences in Alaska (circa 2012),
and the economic values they generate.
As with the previous study, an important goal is to be responsive
to the potential needs of fishery managers for information about
economic values when considering modifications to existing regulations.
Because the regulatory landscape has been changing rapidly for Pacific
halibut, a focus was placed primarily on regulations for that fishery.
This is needed since an annual evaluation of recreational harvest
regulations is now a formal part of the regulatory process under the
newly-implemented halibut catch sharing plan (NOAA, 2013). Since recent
regulations for Pacific halibut have been applied specifically to the
charter sector in Alaska and are stricter than those applied to unguided
anglers, understanding the role of regulations on the charter sector is
especially important.
A second goal of the article is to increase the available knowledge
about economic values associated with recreational charter boat fishing
for both salmon and Pacific halibut in recent years, since regulations,
personal preferences for fishing, and broad economic conditions change,
and with them the economic values of fishing can change. Providing
economic value information for each of the principal types of fishery
users can help fishery managers better understand the effects that
changes in regulations have on different groups of people, which often
differ.
Our results indicate that the private boat fisheries for both
Pacific halibut and salmon have significantly positive total economic
values to Alaska residents. These values ranged from about $172 to
$2,083 for 1-day trips, depending on the species harvested and the bag
limit and which region in Alaska the fishing trip occurred. In contrast,
the charter boat fisheries for these species have total trip values that
are generally not statistically positive and thus indicate there is no
significant demand among residents for the types of restrictive charter
boat fishing trips that have been prevalent in recent years. The reasons
for this appear to be the strong preferences of Alaska residents for
private boat fishing or other options over saltwater charter boat
fishing.
As a result, the differentiated and compound regulations that
characterize recent Pacific halibut regulations in the charter boat
sector had no practical effect on economic values in 2012, since the
total values of charter boat trips arc effectively zero with or without
them. Additional findings are that private boat trips where two species
are harvested have higher total value to anglers than single species
trips, but it is a proportionately smaller increase in value. These
values ranged from about $274 to almost $3,000, again depending on the
species harvested, the bag limits, and in which region the trip
occurred. Also, increases in bag limits, all else equal, had little
discernible effect on total values, except possibly the case of
increasing the bag limit from one to two fish in the Pacific halibut
fishery.
Knowledge of the economic values of fisheries to anglers can be
informative and useful in policy discussions. However, they are of
course but one of numerous considerations that fishery managers must
take into account when decisions are made.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank the Alaska Department of Fish and Game,
particularly Gretchen Jennings and Bill Romberg, for access to data that
was helpful in this study. They also thank Ron Felthoven, Sabrina
Lovcll, and Brian Garbcr-Yonts of the National Marine Fisheries Service,
NOAA, and two anonymous reviewers for useful comments. All remaining
errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Funding
support from the NMFS Office of Science and Technology is gratefully
acknowledged. This article and its findings do not necessarily reflect
the views of the National Marine Fisheries Service, NOAA.
Literature Cited
Anderson, L. E., and S. T. Lee. 2013. Untangling the recreational
value of wild and hatchery salmon. Mar. Res. Econ. 28:175-197.
(doi:https://doi.Org/10.5950/0738-1360-28.2.175).
Bateman, I. J., R. T. Carson, B. Day, M. Hanemann, N. Hanley, T.
Hett, M. Jones-Lee, G. Loomes, S. Mourato, K. Ozdemiroglu, D. W. Pearce,
R. Sugden, and J. Swanson. 2002. Economic valuation with stated
preference techniques: a manual. Edward Elgar, Northampton, Mass., 458
p.
Beggs, S., S. Cardell, and J. Hausman. 1981. Assessing the
potential demand for electric cars. J. Econometrics 16:1-19. (doi:
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(81)90056-7).
Carter, D. W., and C. Liese. 2012. The economic value of catching
and keeping or releasing saltwater sport fish in the Southeast USA. N.
Am. J. Fish. Manage. 32:613-625.
(doi:https://doi.org/10.1080/02755947.2012.675943).
Chapman, R. G., and R. Staelin. 1982. Exploiting rank ordered
choice set data within the stochastic utility model. J. Market. Res.
19(3):288-301. (doi: https://doi.org/10.2307/3151563).
Criddle, K. R., M. Herrmann, S. T. Lee, and C. Hamel. 2003.
Participation decisions, angler welfare, and the regional economic
impact of sportfishing. Mar. Res. Econ. 18:291-312. (doi:
https://doi.org/10.1086/mre.18.4.42629404).
Dillman, D. A., J. D. Smyth, and L. M. Christian. 2014 Internet,
mail, and mixed-mode surveys: the tailored design method. John Wiley and
Sons, 4th ed., Hoboken, N.J., 509 p.
Huber, J., and K. Zwerina. 1996. The importance of utility balance
in efficient choice designs. J. Market. Res. 33(3):307-317.
(doi:https://d0i.0rg/10.2307/3152127).
Kanninen, B. J. 2006. Valuing environmental amenities using stated
choice studies: a common sense approach to theory and practice.
Springer, Dordrecht, Netherl., 336 p.
Krinsky, 1., and A. L. Robb. 1986. On approximating the statistical
properties of elasticities. Rev. Econ. Stat. 68:715-719.
Lew, D. K., and D. M. Larson. 2012. Economic values for saltwater
sport fishing in Alaska: a stated preference analysis. N. Am. J. Fish.
Manage. 32(4):745 759.(doi:
https://doi.org/10.1080/02755947.2012.681012).
__ and __. 2014. Is a fish in hand worth two in the sea? Evidence
from a stated preference study. Fish. Res. 157:124-135. (doi:
https://doi.Org/10.1016/j.fishres.2014.04.005).
__ and __. 2015. Stated preferences for size and bag limits of
Alaska charter boat anglers. Mar. Pol. 61:66-76. (doi:
https://doi.Org/10.1016/j.marpol.2015.07.007).
__, J. Lee, and D. M. Larson. 2010. Saltwater sportfishing in
Alaska: a summary and description of the Alaska saltwater sportfishing
economic survey, 2007. U.S. Dep. Commer., NOAA Tech. Memo.
NMFS-AF-SC-214, 229 p.
Louviere, J. C, D. A. Hensher, and J. D. Swait. 2000. Stated choice
methods: analysis and applications. Camb. Univ. Press, U.K., 402 p.
Mitchell, R. C, and R. T. Carson. 1989. Using surveys to value
public goods: the contingent valuation method. Resour. Future, Wash.,
D.C., 463 p.
NOAA. 2013. Pacific halibut fisheries; catch sharing plan for
guided sport and commercial fisheries in Alaska. Final rule. 78 Fed.
Regist. 75843 (15 Mar. 2013), p. 75,843-75,895. (Available online at
https://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/FR-2013-12-12/pdf/2013-29598.pdf).
Train, K. E. 2003. Discrete choice methods with simulation. Camb.
Univ. Press, U.K., 334 p.
Willis, G. B. 2005. Cognitive interviewing: a tool for improving
questionnaire design. Sage Publ., Thousand Oaks, Calif, 333 p.
Daniel K. Lew is an economist in the Resource Ecology and Fisheries
Management Division, Alaska Fisheries Science Center, National Marine
fisheries Service, NOAA, 7600 Sand Point Way NE, Seattle WA, 98115; and
visiting scholar in the Department of Environmental Science and Policy,
University of California, One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA 95616. Douglas
M. Larson is a Professor in the Department of Agricultural and Resource
Economics and member of the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural
Economics at the University of California, One Shields Avenue, Davis, CA
95616. The corresponding author is Dan Lew (e-mail: Dan.Lew@noaa.gov).
(1) A detailed discussion of the recent history of Pacific halibut
fishery regulation can be found in Lew and Larson (2015) (current
regulations can be found at
http://www.adfg.alaska.gov/index.cfm?adfg=fishingSportFishinglnfo.main).
(2) As used here, guided fishing refers to fishing on for-hire
trips.
(3) For a full description of recent changes, see NOAA (2013).
(4) Sport fishing licenses arc required for both nonresidents and
Alaska residents aged 16 or older. Residents 60 years or older do not
need a sport fishing license to fish in Alaska, but do need to have a
"Permanent Identification Card" (PIC). We include PIC holders
in the sampling frame used to select the random samples for this study.
(5) Based on earlier survey results, about 89% of Southeast Alaska
resident angler saltwater fishing trips were single day trips (Lew et
al., 2010). Also, we note that although halibut and Chinook and eoho
salmon are the primary target speeies on most Alaska saltwater fishing
trips, and thus those modeled in the angler's utility
specification, other secondary species like other salmon, rockfish, and
lingcod may also contribute towards a fishing trip's value.
(6) A total of 1,000 Southeast Alaska anglers and 1,500 other
Alaska anglers were randomly selected and contacted to participate (71
and 97 surveys, respectively, from these two sample strata were
undeliverable). The sample sizes used in the analysis exclude
respondents who did not answer any of the SP questions.
(7) In contrast, about 75% of the nonresident angler sample were
male, 95% were Caucasian, mean age was 52.6 years, mean income was a
little over $110,000, and mean fishing experience was 35 years. In
addition, about two-thirds had at least some college education.
(8) There are longstanding size-differentiated regulations for
Chinook salmon in both Southeast and Southcentral Alaska, but these arc
not the subject of this study.
(9) Standard Pacific halibut length-weight tables available from
the IPMC" were used to convert minimum size length restrictions
into pounds (whole fish), which is the metric most commonly used by
Alaska anglers when discussing fish size and the metric used to
represent size in the survey discussed in this study. The weight of a
fish without its head and entrails is assumed to be 75% of the whole
fish weight.
(10) As noted in the introduction, the reverse slot allows the
angler to retain either a small or a very large fish, with the goal of
the restriction being to protect the breeding stock, which arc
intermediate in size.
(11) Note that under the Guided Angler fish provision of the Catch
Sharing Plan, which became effective in 2014, charter boat anglers may
in some circumstances be able to harvest fish outside of these size
limits, for details, see NOAA (2013).
(12) At present, we are not aware of any plans to significantly
alter the suite of harvest regulations in the salmon fisheries.
(13) Several alternative model specifications were tried that
treated the regulatory variables differently, but they were not
qualitatively different from the model presented here. They are
available upon request from the authors.
(14) These results are available on request from the authors.
(15) Technically, to isolate the marginal effects of variables in
the RUM model, the attribute levels need to vary considerably across the
alternatives seen by respondents, and there needs to be at least some
people who choose alternatives that cover the range of attribute levels
for the model to fit well. In this application, the smaller sample size
(N=435) may not have been sufficient for this purpose.
doi: https://doi.Org/10.7755/MFR.79.3-4.2
Table 1.--Choice experiment attributes and levels.
Attribute Levels
Type of fishing trip Private boat or charter
(SC version only) (1)
Length of fishing trip 1, 2, or 3 days
(SC version only) (1)
Chinook salmon daily 1, 2, or 3 fish
bag limit
Coho salmon daily bag 3, 4, or 6 fish
limit
Halibut bag daily limit 1, 2, or 3 fish
Maximum size limit on No limit, 18 lb, 23 lb, 28 lb, or 35 lb
1st fish in limit
Maximum size limit on No limit, 18 lb, 23 lb, 28 lb, or 35 lb
additional fish in limit
beyond 1st fish
Minimum size limit No min size limit, 130 lb (2)
(reverse slot)
Daily total fishing $25 to $500
trip cost
(1) There were two versions of the survey: A version developed for
Southeast Alaska resident anglers (SE version) and a version for all
other Alaska resident anglers (SC version). There were two attributes
in the choice experiment questions in the SC version that did not
appear in the SE version.
(2) Note that this minimize size limit differs from the realized size
limits, which are greater.
Table 2.--Demographic characteristics of the choice experiment samples.
SE version SC version (Other
Variable Description (Southeast Alaska residents)
Alaska
resident
anglers)
Gender % male 65.40% 61.40%
Age mean in years 47.21 46.09
Fishing experience mean years 31.46 29.64
Household size mean number 2.31 2.53
Ethnicity % Caucasian 88.06% 88.14%
Education % with college 51.0% 55.12%
degree or
higher
Household income mean income $84,191 $95,858
No. in sample 335 430
Table 3.--Variable names and definitions.
Name Description
Nonregulatory attributes
ASC Alternative specific constant (dummy variable): 1 =
Choice C (nonfishing alternative selected);
0 otherwise
PRIV Dummy variable for private boat trip (vs. charter trip)
DAY Days fished (length of trip): 1, 3, or 5 days
COST Per day cost of fishing trip
Uniform regulatory variables
HLIM1 Halibut bag limit dummy: 1 = t fish; 0 otherwise
HLIM2 Halibut bag limit dummy: 1 = 2 fish; 0 otherwise
HLIM3 Halibut bag limit dummy: 1 = 3 fish; 0 otherwise
KLIM1 Chinook salmon daily bag limit dummy: 1 = 1 fish; 0
otherwise
KLIM2 Chinook salmon daily bag limit dummy: 1 = 2 fish; 0
otherwise
KLIM3 Chinook salmon daily bag limit dummy: 1 = 3 fish; 0
otherwise
SL1M1 Coho salmon daily bag limit dummy: 1=3 fish; 0 otherwise
SLIM2 Coho salmon daily bag limit dummy: 1 = 4 fish; 0
otherwise
SLIM3 Coho salmon daily bag limit dummy: 1 = 6 fish; 0
otherwise
HBL Pacific halibut daily bag limit {if present): 1, 2, or 3
fish; 0 otherwise
HMIN Halibut minimum size limit in place (dummy variable): 1
= yes; 0 = no
Differentiated regulatory variables
HMAX1 Halibut maximum size limit on first fish (dummy variable)
: 1 = yes; 0 otherwise
HMAX2 Halibut maximum size limit on additional fish beyond 1st
fish (dummy variable): 1 = yes; 0 otherwise
HALSIZE1 Halibut maximum size limit on first fish (integer): 0,
18, 23, 28, or 35
HALSIZE2 Halibut maximum size limit on add'l. fish beyond 1st
(integer): 0, 18, 23, 28, or 35
HNOMAX1 Dummy variable for whether the first fish in halibut bag
limit has no size restriction
HNOMAX2 Dummy variable for whether the second fish in halibut bag
limit has no size restriction
Table 4.--Compound regulatory attributes. (1)
Name Description Definition
Reverse slot regulation not in effect
HBL1FSH No reverse slot: dummy (HMIN=0)*(HBL>1)*HMAX1
variable for first fish in halibut bag
limit with max size limit (halibut or
no halibut): (values = 0, 1)
HBL2FSH No reverse slot: dummy (HMIN=0)*(H BL>1)*H M AX2
variable for second fish in 2 or 3- bag
limit with max size limit (values = 0, 1)
HBL3FSH No reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN=0)*(HBL>2)*HMAX2
for third fish in 3-bag limit with max
size limit (values = 0, 1)
HBL1MAX1 No reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN=0)*(HBL=1)*(HALSIZE1>0)
for max size limit in effect on first
fish in bag limit when bag limit is 1
fish (values = 0, 1)
HBL3MAX1 No reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN=0)*(HBL>1)*(HALSIZE1>0)
for max size limit in effect on first
fish in bag limit when bag limit is 2
or 3 halibut {values = 0, 1)
HBL3MAX2 No reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN=0)*(HBL>1)*(HALSIZE2>0)
for max size limit effect on second+
fish in bag limit when bag limit is 2
or 3 halibut (values = 0, 1)
Reverse slot regulation in effect
HML1FSH Reverse slot: dummy variable for (HMIN=1)*(HBL= 1)*HMAX1
halibut bag limit with max
size limit (halibut or no halibut)
(values = 0, 1)
HML2FSH Reverse slot: dummy variable for (HMIN=1)*(HBL>1)*HMAX2
second fish in 2 or 3- bag
limit with max size limit
(values = 0, 1)
HML3FSH Reverse slot: dummy variable for (HMIN=1)*(HBL>2)*HMAX2
third fish in 3-bag limit wit
h max size limit (values = 0, 1)
HML1MAX1 Reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN=1)*(HBL= 1)*(HALSIZE1
for max size limit in effect on >0)
first fish in bag limit when bag limit
is 1 fish (values = 0, 1)
HML3MAX1 Reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN 1)*(HBL>1)*(HALSIZE1>0)
for max size limit in effect on first
fish in bag limit when bag limit is 2
or 3 halibut (values = 0, 1)
HML3MAX2 Reverse slot: dummy variable (HMIN=1)*(HBL>1)*(HALSIZE2>0)
max size limit in effect on second+ fish in
bag limit when bag limit is 2 or 3 halibut
(values = 0, 1)
(1) Note: In the SC model, all compound regulatory variables are
interacted with the private boat trip dummy variable (PRIV = 0).
Table 5.--Southeast Alaska (SE) model estimation results (W=335). (1)
Mean parameter
Variable Estimate Asymptotic t-value
Nonregulatory attributes
ASC -1.235 -3.989
COST (2) -0.013 -6.380
Uniform regulatory attributes (3)
HLIM1 1.466 7.843
HLIM2 2.182 10.328
HLIM3 2.115 8.469
KLIM1 0.998 5.588
KLIM2 0.976 6.138
KLIM3 1.035 4.533
SLIM1 1.291 7.370
SLIM2 1.821 9.845
SLIM3 1.648 7.615
Standard deviation parameter
Variable Estimate Asymptotic t-value
Nonregulatory attributes
ASC 4.206 12.555
COST (2)
Uniform regulatory attributes (3)
HLIM1 -0.984 -2.911
HLIM2 -1.879 -7.861
HLIM3 2.171 7.619
KLIM1 -0.792 -2.498
KLIM2 0.653 2.267
KLIM3 -0.204 -0.467
SLIM1 0.805 2.536
SLIM2 0.779 3.254
SLIM3 -1.220 -4.319
(1) Note: Parameters in bold are statistically significant at the 5%
level.
(2) Trip cost is estimated as a fixed parameter; all others parameters
are random.
(3) AII trips are unguided (private) boat trips.
Table 6.--Southcentral Alaska (SC) model estimation results (N=430). (1)
Mean parameter Standard deviation parameter
Variable Estimate Asymptotic Estimate Asymptotic t-value
t-value
Nonregulatory
attributes
ASC 2.267 2.794 4.225 13.309
PRIV 4.041 5.919 2.547 9.0870
DAY -0.126 -0.165 0.799 7.213
DAY squared -0.155 -0.821 0.152 4.203
COST (2) -0.002 -3.618
Uniform regulatory
attributes
PB_HLIM1 (3) 1.730 4.107 -2.878 -5.998
PB_HLIM2 3.124 9.776 -0.687 -2.032
PB_HLIM3 3.044 4.649 -3.556 -4.777
PB_KLIM1 0.598 1.446 -2.386 -4.951
PB_KLIM2 0.400 1.122 -0.415 -1.021
PB_KLIM3 0.755 1.894 1.391 2.665
PB_SLIM1 2.122 5.254 -1.153 -1.681
PB SLIM2 1.041 2.847 1.537 4.103
PB SLIM3 1.290 3.266 0.951 1.710
CH_HLIM1 -0.544 -0.754 0.4879 0.929
CH_HLIM2 0.722 1.0168 0.885 2.179
CH_HLIM3 1.493 1.466 0.045 0.061
CH_KLIM1 0.664 1.379 -2.411 -4.618
CH_KLIM2 1.586 3.827 -0.367 -0.844
CH_KLIM3 1.027 2.028 -0.988 -7.779
CH_SLIM1 1.708 3.144 -1.508 -3.404
CH_SLIM2 0.976 2.256 -0.935 -2.250
CH_SLIM3 0.598 1.446 -2.386 -4.951
Differentiated
regulatory
attributes
HALSIZE1 0.029 0.820 -0.086 -6.801
HALSIZE2 -0.049 -2.228 0.020 1.727
HNOMAX1 -0.470 -0.510 -2.136 -4.813
HNOMAX2 -0.619 -0.618 -0.811 -2.017
Compound
regulatory
attributes
HBL1FSH 1.381 1.442 0.355 0.806
HBL1MAX1 -0.736 -0.575 -2.883 -3.533
HBL2FSH 0.663 0.774 -0.703 -1.425
HBL3FSH -0.343 -0.350 -0.504 -0.563
HBL3MAX1 -0.073 -0.080 -0.585 -1.143
HBL3MAX2 -0.378 -0.361 -1.020 -2.381
HML1FSH 3.888 4.121 1.813 4.910
HML1MAX1 -3.0135 -2.821 1.060 1.365
HML2FSH -0.388 -0.590 0.588 1.436
HML3FSH 0.766 0.770 0.870 1.003
HML3MAX1 0.796 0.751 0.768 1.813
HML3MAX2 -3.540 -3.207 1.178 2.679
Mean -5.150
log-likelihood
AIC (corrected) 4616.565
BIC 4895.352
(1) Note: Parameters in bold are statistically significant at the 5%
level. Parameters in italics are statistically significant at the 10%
level.
(2) Trip cost (number of days times per-day cost) is estimated as a
fixed parameter; all others parameters are random.
(3) The prefixes PEL and CH_refer to private and charter boat trips,
respectively.
(1) Note: Parameters in bold are statistically significant at the 5%
level. Parameters in italics are statistically significant at the 10%
level. All differentiated and compound regulatory parameters are for
charter boat fishing trips only. Standard deviation parameters can be
positive or negative, but only the absolute value has meaning in the
estimation program and in interpretation of results.
COPYRIGHT 2017 U.S. Department of Commerce
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2017 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.