首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月01日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:CPEC, SEZ (Special Economic Zones) and Entrepreneurial Development Prospects in Pakistan.
  • 作者:Ali, Muhammad Mansoor ; Faisal, Farida
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2017
  • 期号:December
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:The emergence of Special Economic Zones (SEZ) with the regime of trade liberalisation around the globe gained importance especially in the developing world to attract foreign direct investment (FDI). There is ample evidence in recent researches that establish a strong link between knowledge spillovers and spatial economic structure. Conventionally there are similar patterns found in international and regional economics that describes the incidence of higher factor mobility within different regions of a country than between countries. The general results of the spatial production function are that the output of a given regions is increases with increase in knowledge and the capital inputs. The study reaches the conclusion that the technology utilisation in Pakistan is not static and it is evolving with the passage of time. In order to make the SEZs successful, the government needs to follow a gradualist approach toward reform, and promote and strengthen the local governments and decision decentralisation. The government must set clearly understandable goals and along with performance benchmarks, scrutinising, and competition not only for private but also for public sector institutions. At the same time it is needed to improve the institutional efficiency and data gathering, processing and dissemination to support research initiatives and policy making.
  • 关键词:Special Economic Zones, Spatial Production Function, Entrepreneurial Clusters

CPEC, SEZ (Special Economic Zones) and Entrepreneurial Development Prospects in Pakistan.


Ali, Muhammad Mansoor ; Faisal, Farida


CPEC, SEZ (Special Economic Zones) and Entrepreneurial Development Prospects in Pakistan.

The emergence of Special Economic Zones (SEZ) with the regime of trade liberalisation around the globe gained importance especially in the developing world to attract foreign direct investment (FDI). There is ample evidence in recent researches that establish a strong link between knowledge spillovers and spatial economic structure. Conventionally there are similar patterns found in international and regional economics that describes the incidence of higher factor mobility within different regions of a country than between countries. The general results of the spatial production function are that the output of a given regions is increases with increase in knowledge and the capital inputs. The study reaches the conclusion that the technology utilisation in Pakistan is not static and it is evolving with the passage of time. In order to make the SEZs successful, the government needs to follow a gradualist approach toward reform, and promote and strengthen the local governments and decision decentralisation. The government must set clearly understandable goals and along with performance benchmarks, scrutinising, and competition not only for private but also for public sector institutions. At the same time it is needed to improve the institutional efficiency and data gathering, processing and dissemination to support research initiatives and policy making.

Keywords: Special Economic Zones, Spatial Production Function, Entrepreneurial Clusters

INTRODUCTION

Over the course of their history, China and Pakistan have developed strong political, defense, economic and strategic relations. The year 2015 proved to be a milestone as both countries decided to move ahead with their plan to establish China-Pakistan Economic Corridor (CPEC) and integrate with other sub regions of Asia to actively participate in regional economic growth. As CPEC is composed of roads, routes, offshoots, and energy generation projects that would eventually have immense impact on both the countries in particular and all neighbouring countries in general and expected to be operational by 2030. It is reflection of Chinese 'One Belt-One Road (OBOR)' concept that is poised to connect sixty countries to enhance economic integration between Asia, Europe, and Africa.

CPEC is of immense importance for Pakistan as it shall run through its essential geo-strategic locations that have still a huge development potential to contribute to the national growth. The activities of construction of corridor are likely to speed up the local development during and after the completion of the project. Initially it is expected to bring employment in construction industry but as it runs through the underdeveloped regions of Pakistan, it holds immense potential to develop the existing potential and exploit the untapped resources. In order to attain sustainability in development process the policy focus must integrate growth and distributional effects of economic gains by taking into consideration the social barriers of discrimination and prejudices based on ethnicity, gender, region and language. In order to attain sustainability of growth effects of CPEC, developments in agriculture sector can play a key role in attaining food security, employment protection, adoption of new technologies and bringing marginalised communities in the mainstream economic activity.

The emergence of Special Economic Zones (SEZ) with the regime of trade liberalisation around the globe gained importance especially in the developing world to attract foreign direct investment (FDI). The 'infant industry argument' cannot be forever protective, and indigenous value creation to compete with the business realities of the time is a necessity and challenge for public policy initiatives. The SEZ Ordinance, 2015, is an effort to create the climate for boosting investment--foreign and local--to capitalise on the opportunities that CPEC is bound to bring. Pakistan has about 40 percent population below poverty line and needs a modern approach to economic growth where benefits of CPEC may be enjoyed by all tiers of the society.

Agriculture, as is a common perception, is the backbone of the Pakistan's economy and contributes about 23 percent into the country's annual GDP. Similarly a big majority of the population, about 70 percent of the total, is directly or indirectly dependent on agriculture for its livelihood. CPEC has also included agriculture as a priority area that includes two contracts for establishment of cotton and marine research institutes. The development of cotton and marines research institutions under CPEC will open new intellectual avenues in agriculture sector. Besides the provision of food and nutrition agriculture provides raw materials and byproducts for use in many secondary industries. Agriculture also holds immense potential for development of small and medium scale enterprises that can support indigenous value addition and employment.

Traditional economic theory suggests that reduction in entry cost and increasing net returns bring about entrepreneurial action that is then translated in to formation of clusters. There are also theoretical evidences that some regions are endowed with greater supply of entrepreneurs mainly due to higher skills development and soaring competition to produce differentiable goods and services.

REVIEW OF LITERATURE

Growth process in any country over the course of its history gives rise to spatial economic structures. This is mainly due to the presence of externalities in the form of knowledge spillovers and competition in the markets. This is precisely the main thesis of endogenous growth theory [Romer (1986, 1990)]. But at the same time other externalities also come into effect like pooling of labour with similar types of skills and needs, sharing of intermediate goods for further value addition, and linkages of firms with suppliers of varying inputs needed for production activity [Marshall (1920); Krugman (1991)].

Earlier Audretsch and Feldman (1996) and later Caniels and Romijn (2005) empirically found the link of knowledge spillovers shaping spatial structures with in a geographical space. But earlier Jaffe, et al. (1993) empirically found that knowledge spillovers are bounded geographically but the structure of the economic activity restrain the spillover effect, whereas impact of technology spillover is mainly due to factor mobility across regions. The knowledge spillovers are not a random happening as old ideas generally lead to development of new technologies and way to conduct business [Weitzman (1998)].

Choice of location and type of organisation among other factors determine the entrepreneurial action for new startups [Harbison (1956)]. Prescott and Wisscher (1980) pointed out that the growth of firm is mainly attributed to capital accumulation and firm-specific knowledge. But the internal structure of organisation determines efficiency and performance [Chandler (1977); Atkeson and Kehoe (2005)]. Firms preferring to limit geographical range of production activity succeed to reduce transaction costs [Coase (1937)]. In addition to existence of externalities in capital, knowledge and technologies, the individual factor cannot be overlooked. The idea generation process and experimenting with new goods and services is outcome of an intellectual effort. Entrepreneurs play their role in internalising individual externalities for the general efficiency of the firm. This also has its impact on decision of the firm to agglomerate with other firms or not within the same geographical space due to accruing comparative advantage over other [Papageorgiou (1978); Papageorgiou and Smith (1983)].

Generally the line of research in spatial economics is concerned with impact of spatial agglomeration along with urban development with economic growth [Duranton and Storper (2005); Rossi-Hansberg (2005)]. Over the course of history the researchers have considered space as a single point in theory [Isard (1949); North (1955); Quigley (1998); Millo (2012)]. But the later developments have expanded the scope of space as a collection of system of cities [Rossi-Hansberg (2006); Baldwin and Forslid (2000); Fujita and Thisse (2003)]. Similarly, the geographical structure of the region has also been under discussion like Ohlin (1933), and Krugman (1991). They introduced distance of factor inputs from the centre of economic activity to understand the geographical structure over a space. Krugman (1998) propagated the use of modelling strategy that uses a 2-D space in continuous functional form with consideration of heterogeneity and hierarchical structures. The centre of economic activity in a geographical location has been understood in the form of concentric rings [Tinbergen (1961)] or a hexagon lattice system [Losch (1940)] a circle [Papageorgiou and Smith (1983); Lucas and RossiHansberg (2002). But starting from Hotelling (1929), the adoption of simplification in the model building, spatial structure is considered as a continuum over a straight line even by Solow and Vickey (1971) and Rossi-Hansberg (2005).

Generally Tobler's first law of geography: "Everything is related to everything, but close things are more related than things that are far apart" sets the canvas for spatial analysis. Models thus constructed usually dealing with cross sectional data take into consideration the correlation between spatial economic units [Anselin (1988); Millo (2014)]. But some empirical studies used panel data with ability to capture the spatial variability while controlling for multicollinearity among the variables extending the sample size that in turn yields more efficient estimators [Elhorst (2003)]. Furthermore, the techniques have been improved to control for both heterogeneity and spatial correlation in the panel data for spatial analysis [Baltagi, et al. (2003)].

When it comes to choice of production of goods and services, Krugman (1980) stressed that lower level of comparative advantage at home causes a strong thrust of import of a good. Eventually the increasing returns will cause production to be confined to one geographical location for production for each type of good especially when trade and transportation costs are accounted for making the country an exporter of that good. Therefore, 'home market effects' distinguish comparative advantage and increasing returns to determine the spatial production decisions. International and regional economic literature delves similarly upon factors mobility across different productive regions within or across countries. Given the supply side economic factors, Linder hypothesis asserts that supply response in more than proportional to deviations in the patterns of demand making production decisions based on merely correlations problematic. At the same time the relative importance of a good for a specific region in relation to other regions determines the level of resources commitment to a particular industry [Walz (1996)]. Therefore, large countries have higher supply of differentiated and diverse products without incurring trade costs. Larger countries also provide opportunity to the producer to locate their production facilities in order to enjoy higher degree of comparative advantage. This tends to an increase in the returns to the factors of production especially in the form of wages along with overall productivity. Therefore, the differences in underlying microeconomic phenomenon can explain the impact of spatial economic and international trade theories in the light of comparative and competitive advantages for geographical locations for production.

Special economic zone (SEZ) is a geographically bounded area having a central management for providing benefits of physical location within the zone. These zones have their separate customs area to gain from duty-free and related liberal laws [World Bank (2009)]. SEZs accrue direct and indirect economic benefits like employment generation and foreign exchange earnings; and knowledge based urban growth, respectively. SEZs are created to cater for needs of export-processing, centralised industrial parks, free trade activity, and free ports for merchandising jointly or specifically. China has created SEZ to deliver more or less all these and related services instead of focusing on single function of a zone [Wong (1987)]. There are seven specific SEZs in China: Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Shantou, Xiamen, Hainan, Shanghai Pudong New Area, and Tianjin Binhai New Area. In addition, China has developed economic zones that are delivering specialised concentrated services like: High-tech Industrial Development Zones (HIDZs), Free Trade Zones (FTZs), Economic and Technological Development Zones (ETDZs), Export-Processing Zones (EPZs), etc.

Industrial clusters are different from a SEZ as a cluster is originated because of presence of inter-connected firms from related industries at a specific geographic location, like financial intermediaries, heavy industry supporting small related processing units, governmental agencies, and educational institutions imparting different skills. The reason for the link of these entities is the spillover effect of externalities and complementally dependences [World Bank (2009)]. The support of the government crates an enabling environment where planned and coordinated efforts of private sector enhances the ability of resources utilisation leading to enhanced competitiveness at regional, national and international levels [World Bank (2010)].

The difference between SEZ and industrial cluster is in their evolution. There is an organic growth of industrial clusters whereas SEZs are generally crated through government action with a 'top-down' approach. Developed countries have witnessed the evolution of industrial clusters from SEZs i.e. industrial parks and export processing zone. On the other hand this phenomenon is not generally seen in developing countries indicating the need for efficiency of the public sector for fostering and supporting growth of private enterprise development. Zeng (2008) found in a study of 11 industrial clusters in different African countries that most of them were impulsively created except for export processing zone culminating the growth of textile cluster in Mauritania. Therefore, creation of SEZ is a challenging task for governments as there are numerous cases of failure in developed and developing countries where political or personal motives were behind such initiatives [Plummer and Sheppard (2006)]. Government efficiency and policy effectiveness supporting dynamic economic decisions is necessary for success of a SEZ. If not generally, at least within the zone there must be present a well functioning market system supported by public sector. The clear understanding of markets strengths and comparative advantage at home along with insight of future development path focused at local and international business development by the policy makers and business fraternity is essential for success of a SEZ. Decades of hard work and efforts from public and private sectors created the environment where industrial clusters have started to emerge from SEZs in China. Zhongguancun (Beijing) and Shenzhen have grown cluster related to information and communication technologies, Pudong (Shanghai) to electronics and biotech clusters, Wuhan to opto-electronics, Dalian to software development, are a few examples [Fu and Yuning (2007)].

Therefore, the risk of failure of a SEZ is linked with clear understanding of domestic potential harnessed to withstand international competitive environment. Creating of a SEZ with right mix of policies has reaped benefits to numerous economies across globe. Pakistan also started to develop the industrial zones in different regions but those could not generate the expected results. The reasons for their dismal performance have been structural as well as lack of interest from the private sector to participate in such zones. Now the history has given us another chance where need is to learn from previous mistakes and enact a culture of progress, efficiency and competitive environment with initiative lying with private sector having support of public sector growth oriented policies.

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

The study used a cluster (i.e. the aggregated locus of economic activity) to comprehend whether economic activity accumulates, expands, or intensifies there. This will help to observe the spatial-temporal dynamics of a cluster (or SEZ) that federal government intends to establish in 12 cities of Balochistan and Khyber-Pakhtunkhwa under the CPEC (i.e. Turban, Khuzdar, Quetta, Bostan, Qila Saif Ullah, Mansehra, Nowshera, Hattar, D I Khan, Kohat and Bannu). Spatial intensity (I) of entrepreneurship increases with increased availability of factor input (W) when the geographical range (D) in the cluster is constant. Spatial intensity (I) decreases if the geographical range (D) declines with constant supply of factor input (W). (1) The spatial production function relates productivity of the cluster on the factor inputs along with their relative location [Coase (1937)]; enhance knowledge even in the form of spillovers from the competitive environment; develop or adopt newer technologies to offset the pressure of increasing wages, rents and other associated costs of production. The long run cluster growth is function of growth rates of factor inputs, degree of knowledge and rate of spatial expansion of inputs. Therefore, accumulation and furthering the technological base, human and physical capitals are responsible for growth process over a geographical space. The emergence of entrepreneurial clusters lead to agglomeration economies that is then translated into higher degree of sustainability of firms over extended periods in time, and then the overall economic growth. The assessment of agglomeration was not the focus of this study though.

Due to non-availability of all the data of labour, firms, technology, agriculture and natural resources of the specified SEZs, the study analysed the spatial intensity and performance at the regional level (i.e. provinces of Pakistan).

Economic geography and spatial economic analysis has gained attention of researchers especially since last few decades due to global integration and increased competition like contributions by Anselin (1988), Elhorst, et al. (2007), Rossi (2005), Lin (2010) and Kapoor, et al. (2007) are a few.

Empirical analysis of spatial models based on cross sectional data and identification of correlation in spatial units progressed to analyses based on panel data with better control of spatial correlations and heterogeneity [Anselin (1988); Baltagi, et al. (2003)]. But still the problems persist with availability of reliable spatial data. This lead to different modeling techniques to improve the fit of data e.g. transcendental logarithmic production function (trans-log) of the Cobb-Douglas function imposing no prior restrictions on elasticity of substitutions of factor inputs and returns to scale [Christensen, et al. (1971); Klacek, et al. (2007)]. The study specified trans-log Cobb-Douglas production function in two ways. First, the function constructed assuming constant and neutral technological progress, and second, this assumption in relaxed to assess non-constant and non-neutral technological progress. (2) Wald test enables to select the appropriate functional form given the fit to the data. This will enable to ascertain whether in Pakistan the state of use of technology for production is improving or static.

DATA

The study intended to choose the agriculture inputs that can be transformed into processed exportable products through value addition. Indices measuring the value of technology used in processing available agriculture inputs and capital requirements of new ventures posed problems in construction due to non availability of relevant data sets. Similarly, the labour movements and settlement data sets are also not available with accuracy. Another problem was defining industries and goods considering industry classifications with technological criteria and use of factor inputs rather than substitutability in demand. The standard industry definitions carries information of production technologies [Maskus (1991)], but in Pakistan, such segregated data sets are not available. The study, therefore, used the theoretical underpinnings that varieties of goods within an industry use common production technologies.

ESTIMATION METHODOLOGY

Equations (1) and (2) are based on cross-section analysis and it was assumed that the same technology is available for all firms in the region for the same industry at the same period of time. However, for Equations (3) and (4) panel data is used for estimation after relaxing the strong assumption on the state of technology. As the standard specification of Cobb-Douglas production function is nested in the trans-log forms, study applied the Wald test to ascertain applicability of trans-log production function over Cobb-Douglas production function. Following the literature, generally maximum likelihood method (ML) [Anselin (1988)] and generalised method of moments (GMM) [Kelejian and Prucha (1999)] are used for spatial models. But ML is also preferred by some especially in presence of spatial lag, spatial errors and non-spherical residuals. The estimation of all the equations were done with ML [Anselin (1988)].

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS AND RESULTS

The general results of the spatial production function are that the regional output is increasing function of knowledge and the capital. Although most of the individual coefficients are not significant but on the basis of overall significance of the model, the study concludes that the output is responsive towards the development of production inputs especially the human factor. The spatial intensity of the human development is not evenly distributed in all the regions due to non availability of technical and skill building institutions in the peripheral regions. The capital development in the form of infrastructure, communication networks (roads and electronic communication) and other urban facilities have lead to development of small and medium enterprise. That is why the results support the impact of spatial capital intensity on aggregate output.

As a result of a significant Wald test the study found significant fir of trans-log function with constant and neutral technological change over conventional Cobb-Douglas production function. Furthermore, with the help of Wald-test the study found trans-log function with non-constant and non-neutral technological progress to be significant over assumption of constant and neutral technological progress. Therefore, the study establishes that the technology utilisation in Pakistan is not static and it is evolving with the passage of time. The individual coefficients do not show much of the significance for specific interpretations indicating the problems present within the data set.

DISCUSSION, INSIGHTS, AND SUGGESTIONS

Special Economic Zones in China lead to a controlled social experiment to test the efficacy of market-oriented economic reforms. SEZs lead to creation of new policies and institutions along that successfully enhanced exports, foreign exchange earnings and employment by attracting foreign investment and technologies. It lead to the development of high-tech industrial development zones through Torch Programme with an objective of to develop culture of research and development (R&D) at corporate and universities level to support development of new and high-tech products with commercial value. The free trade zones established in 1990 enabled China to test impact of free on national economy and productive capacities before joining World Trade Organisation (WTO). 44 Out of 61 EPZs are located in the coastal region to stimulate export-trading and processing [ProLogis (2008)].

Common key elements of China's SEZs success are political, social as well as business rooted. Top leadership showed strong commitment to reforms and institutional building that enables these zones to contribute to economic growth. The top leadership tried to endure a stable and conducive macro environment and successfully averted political opposition. Deng's initiative for openness by decentralising business decision making made institutions autonomous which in turn encouraged private firms (local and foreign) to invest in the zones. Some of the measures of his policies included provision of land at cheaper rents, tax holidays, removing institutional barriers to speedup customs clearance, removing barriers on imports of raw materials and intermediate goods used in exportable value added products, exemptions of exports taxes, improving labor laws to attract inflow of skilled workers. The restricted quota to sell the product domestically induced the producer to seek better foreign markets leading to higher exports and continuous investments by the firms to attain outward looking comparative advantage [Enright Scott, and Chung (2005)]. With institutional reforms, the central government formed and encouraged the local governments to create conducive environment for conducting business. The efficient regulatory and administrative environment backed by sound infrastructure of communication, energy, water, sewerage, and ports, attracted foreign direct investments and remittances. It lead China to strengthen the local business arena with potential to compete in international markets. The accumulation of capital, technology, and business skills has spillover effect that helped building local industry. All these activities have created an environment that supports inherent urge to acquire higher level skills eventually translating into R&D activity [Sonobe and Otsuka (2006)]. This development leads to evolution of innovation culture especially by qualified workers and managers. SEZs provided the location advantage by developing them in coastal regions or near major cities that facilitated foreign trading due to availability of major infrastructure, such as ports, airports, and railways [Enright, Scott, and Chung (2005)]. It lead to clusters formation with involvement of educated labour force especially for seafood and fruits processing, stone carving, etc. with low-cost production. The segmentation of manufacturing into smaller productive units to form a larger industrial cluster is supported and patronised by the local governments and decision centres. In the light of the above discussion, the study puts forth the following suggestions:

The top leadership must demonstrate strong commitment to allow institutional autonomy and flexibility to support small, medium and large startups. The policy initiatives must support balanced growth in all the regions to support capital accumulation (human and physical) and controlling for labour mobility and social distress. Network of technical training imparting institutions must be built to create skilled labor force at domestic level. The process of reforms must not be stagnant but at the same time must be a gradual and cautious. Public-private partnership approach is necessary to undertake the initiatives that need large investments but have business development potential e.g. mining, ports services etc. Research institutions must be involved in continuous benchmarking and monitoring the business competitiveness. Improve data gathering, processing and dissemination to support research and policymaking.

APPENDIX
Table 1
Spatial Production Function

Regions\           A        [beta]      [GAMMA]
Coefficients

Balochistan    0.0468 *     0.036 *    0.2174 **
KPK            0.0461 *    0.0461 **    0.197 *
Sindh          0.0678 **    0.105 *    0.3204 **
Punjab          0.221 *    0.157 **    0.4358 ***

All variables are logged. * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

Table 2
Trans-log Production Function

Loemcients     [[alpha].sub.o]   [[alpha].sub.i]   [[alpha].sub.ij]

Equation (3)      0.0113 **         0.1037 *          0.1797 **
Equation (4)     -0.0498 **         0.0386 *           0.1127 *

Loemcients     [[alpha].sub.t]   [[alpha].sub.ti]   [[alpha].sub.tt]

Equation (3)     0.0731 ***             --                 --
Equation (4)     0.1091 ***         0.2036 **          0.4358 **

(3) ln [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i]
ln [x.sub.i] + 1/2 [SIGMA][SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ij] ln [x.sub.i]
ln [x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t]

(4) ln [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i]
ln [x.sub.i] + 1/2 [SIGMA][SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ij] ln [x.sub.i]
ln [x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ti]
ln [x.sub.i] + 1/2 [[alpha].sub.tt] [t.sup.2]

All variables are logged. * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01


Muhammad Mansoor Ali <mmali@numl.edu.pk> is Lecturer, Economics Department, NUML, Islamabad. Farida Faisal is Associate Professor, Department of Management Sciences, PMAS-Arid Agriculture University, Rawalpindi.

REFERENCES

Anselin, L. (1988) Lagrange Multiplier Test Diagnostics for Spatial Dependence and Spatial Heterogeneity. Geographical Analysis 20:1, 117.

Atkeson, A. and P. J. Kehoe (2005) Modelling and Measuring Organisation Capital. Journal of Political Economy 113, 1026-1053.

Audretsch, D. B. and M. P. Feldman (1996) R&D Spillovers and the Geography of Innovation and Production. American Economic Review 86, 630-640.

Baldwin, R. E. and R. Forslid (2000) The Core-Periphery Model and Endogenous Growth; Stabilising and Destabilising Integration. Economica 67, 307-324.

Caniels, M. C. J. and H. A. Romijn (2005) What Drives Innovativeness in Industrial Clusters? Transcending the Debate. Cambridge Journal of Economics 29, 497-515.

Chandler, A. D. JR. (1977) The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.

Coase, R. H. (1937) The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4, 386-405.

Duran'ton, G. and M. Storper (2005) Agglomeration and Growth: A Dialogue between Economists and Geographers. Journal of Economic Geography 6, 1-7.

Elhorst, P. (2003) Specification and Estimation of Spatial Panel Data Models. International Regional Science Review 26:3, 244-268.

Feldman, M. (1999) The New Economics of Innovation, Spillovers and Agglomeration: A Review of Empirical Studies. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 8, 5-25.

Fu, Xiaolan, and Gao Yuning (2007) Export Processing Zones in China: A Survey. Geneva: International Labour Organization.

Fujita, M. and J.-F. Thisse (2003) Does Geographical Agglomeration Foster Economic Growth? and who Gains and Loses from it? Japanese Economic Review 54, 121-145.

G. Millo and G. Piras (2012) Spatial Panel Data Models. Journal of Statistical Software 47: 1, 1381.

Harbison, F. (1956) Entrepreneurial Organisation as a Factor in Economic Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 367-379.

Hotelling, H. (1929) Stability in competition. Economic Journal 39, 41-57.

Isard, W. (1949) The General Theory of Location and Space-Economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 63, 476-506.

Jaffe, A., M. Trajtenberg, and R. Henderson (1993) Geographic Location of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 577-598.

Krugman, P. (1991) Increasing Returns and Economic Geography. Journal of Political Economy 99, 483-499.

Lin, Justin Yifu (2010) New Structural Economics: A Framework for Rethinking Development. World Bank, Washington, DC. (Policy Research Working Paper 5197).

Losch, A. (1940) The Economic of Location. Jena: Fischer. English translation by William H. Woglom with the assistance of Wolfgane F. Stolper. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1967.

Lucas, R. E. Jr. and E. Rossi-Hansberg (2002) On the Internal Structure of Cities. Econometrica 70, 1445-476.

Marris, R. and D. C. Mueller (1980) The Corporation, Competition, and the Invisible Hand. Journal of Economic Literature 18, 32-63.

Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.

Martin, P. and G. I. P. Ottaviano (2001) Growth and Agglomeration. International Economic Review 42, 947-968.

Ohlin, B. (1933) Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Papageorgiou, G. J. (1978) Spatial externalities I: Theory. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 68, 465-476.

Papageorgiou, Y. Y. and T. R. Smith (1983) Agglomeration as Local Instability of Spatially Uniform Steady-States. Econometrica 51, 1109-1120.

Plummer, P. and E. Sheppard (2006) Geography Matters: Agency, Structures and Dynamics at the Interaction of Economics and Geography. Journal of Economic Geography 6, 619-637.

Prescott, E and M. Wisscher (1980) Orgnisation Capital. Journal of Political Economy 88, 446-461.

Romer, P. M. (1986) Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth. Journal of Political Economy 94, 1002-1037.

Romer, P. M. (1990) Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy 98, S71-S102.

Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2005) A Spatial Theory of Trade. American Economic Review 95, 1465-1491.

Solow, R. M. and W. S. Vickey (1971) Land Use in a Long Narrow City. Journal of Economic Theory 3, 430-447.

Tinbergen, J. (1961) The Spatial Dispersion of Production: A Hypothesis. Schweizerische Zeitschrift fur Volkwirtschaft und Statistik 97, 412-419.

Walz, U. (1996) Transport Costs, Intermediate Goods, and Localised Growth. Regional Science and Urban Economics 26, 671-695.

Weitzman, M. L. (1998) Recombinant Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 331-360.

Williamson, O. E. (1981) The Modern Corporation: Origins, Evolution, Attributes. Journal of Economic Literature 19, 1537-1568.

World Bank (2009) Clusters for Competitiveness: A Practical Guide and Policy Implications for Developing Cluster Initiatives. International Trade Department, PREM Network, Report. World Bank, Washington, DC.

World Bank (2010) Innovation Policy: A Guide for Developing Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.

(1) Spatial intensity index, 1 = [SIGMA][w.sub.j]/[pi][D.sup.2], where, I = spatial intensity, W = a factor input distributed with amount [w.sub.j] at location j within geographical region R, D = geographical range, where [D.sub.j] is the distance of location j from centre of cluster (and D = [SIGMA][w.sub.j][D.sub.j]/w), C = centre of the cluster. Given this information, the study estimated the spatial production function: (1) [Y.sub.i] = f([A.sub.i]/[D.sup.2.sub.Ai], [H.sub.i], [K.sub.i]/[D.sup.2.sub.Ki]), where output is function of quantities of technology for production, physical capital, human capital, [D.sub.Ai], [D.sub.Ki], [D.sub.Hi] are mean distance of the three factors of production. Cobb-Douglas production function in terms of spatial intensity of factor of production can be written as: (2) [Y.sub.i] = [A.sup.[alpha].sub.i] [H.sup.[beta].sub.i] [D.sub.Ai.sup.-2[beta]] [D.sub.Ki.sup.-2[gamma]].

(2) Consider equation with cross-product terms between time, input measures and a quadratic time trend, and constant and neutral technological change:

(3) In [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i] In [x.sub.i] + [1/2] [SIGMA] [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ij] In [x.sub.i] In [x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t] t and with non-constant and non-neutral technological change:

(4) In [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i] In [x.sub.i] + [1/2] [SIGMA][SIGMA] [a.sub.ij] In [x.sub.i] In [x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t]t + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ti] In [x.sub.i] + [1/2] [[alpha].sub.tt][t.sup.2]
COPYRIGHT 2017 Reproduced with permission of the Publications Division, Pakistan Institute of Development Economies, Islamabad, Pakistan.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2017 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有