CPEC, SEZ (Special Economic Zones) and Entrepreneurial Development Prospects in Pakistan.
Ali, Muhammad Mansoor ; Faisal, Farida
CPEC, SEZ (Special Economic Zones) and Entrepreneurial Development Prospects in Pakistan.
The emergence of Special Economic Zones (SEZ) with the regime of
trade liberalisation around the globe gained importance especially in
the developing world to attract foreign direct investment (FDI). There
is ample evidence in recent researches that establish a strong link
between knowledge spillovers and spatial economic structure.
Conventionally there are similar patterns found in international and
regional economics that describes the incidence of higher factor
mobility within different regions of a country than between countries.
The general results of the spatial production function are that the
output of a given regions is increases with increase in knowledge and
the capital inputs. The study reaches the conclusion that the technology
utilisation in Pakistan is not static and it is evolving with the
passage of time. In order to make the SEZs successful, the government
needs to follow a gradualist approach toward reform, and promote and
strengthen the local governments and decision decentralisation. The
government must set clearly understandable goals and along with
performance benchmarks, scrutinising, and competition not only for
private but also for public sector institutions. At the same time it is
needed to improve the institutional efficiency and data gathering,
processing and dissemination to support research initiatives and policy
making.
Keywords: Special Economic Zones, Spatial Production Function,
Entrepreneurial Clusters
INTRODUCTION
Over the course of their history, China and Pakistan have developed
strong political, defense, economic and strategic relations. The year
2015 proved to be a milestone as both countries decided to move ahead
with their plan to establish China-Pakistan Economic Corridor (CPEC) and
integrate with other sub regions of Asia to actively participate in
regional economic growth. As CPEC is composed of roads, routes,
offshoots, and energy generation projects that would eventually have
immense impact on both the countries in particular and all neighbouring
countries in general and expected to be operational by 2030. It is
reflection of Chinese 'One Belt-One Road (OBOR)' concept that
is poised to connect sixty countries to enhance economic integration
between Asia, Europe, and Africa.
CPEC is of immense importance for Pakistan as it shall run through
its essential geo-strategic locations that have still a huge development
potential to contribute to the national growth. The activities of
construction of corridor are likely to speed up the local development
during and after the completion of the project. Initially it is expected
to bring employment in construction industry but as it runs through the
underdeveloped regions of Pakistan, it holds immense potential to
develop the existing potential and exploit the untapped resources. In
order to attain sustainability in development process the policy focus
must integrate growth and distributional effects of economic gains by
taking into consideration the social barriers of discrimination and
prejudices based on ethnicity, gender, region and language. In order to
attain sustainability of growth effects of CPEC, developments in
agriculture sector can play a key role in attaining food security,
employment protection, adoption of new technologies and bringing
marginalised communities in the mainstream economic activity.
The emergence of Special Economic Zones (SEZ) with the regime of
trade liberalisation around the globe gained importance especially in
the developing world to attract foreign direct investment (FDI). The
'infant industry argument' cannot be forever protective, and
indigenous value creation to compete with the business realities of the
time is a necessity and challenge for public policy initiatives. The SEZ
Ordinance, 2015, is an effort to create the climate for boosting
investment--foreign and local--to capitalise on the opportunities that
CPEC is bound to bring. Pakistan has about 40 percent population below
poverty line and needs a modern approach to economic growth where
benefits of CPEC may be enjoyed by all tiers of the society.
Agriculture, as is a common perception, is the backbone of the
Pakistan's economy and contributes about 23 percent into the
country's annual GDP. Similarly a big majority of the population,
about 70 percent of the total, is directly or indirectly dependent on
agriculture for its livelihood. CPEC has also included agriculture as a
priority area that includes two contracts for establishment of cotton
and marine research institutes. The development of cotton and marines
research institutions under CPEC will open new intellectual avenues in
agriculture sector. Besides the provision of food and nutrition
agriculture provides raw materials and byproducts for use in many
secondary industries. Agriculture also holds immense potential for
development of small and medium scale enterprises that can support
indigenous value addition and employment.
Traditional economic theory suggests that reduction in entry cost
and increasing net returns bring about entrepreneurial action that is
then translated in to formation of clusters. There are also theoretical
evidences that some regions are endowed with greater supply of
entrepreneurs mainly due to higher skills development and soaring
competition to produce differentiable goods and services.
REVIEW OF LITERATURE
Growth process in any country over the course of its history gives
rise to spatial economic structures. This is mainly due to the presence
of externalities in the form of knowledge spillovers and competition in
the markets. This is precisely the main thesis of endogenous growth
theory [Romer (1986, 1990)]. But at the same time other externalities
also come into effect like pooling of labour with similar types of
skills and needs, sharing of intermediate goods for further value
addition, and linkages of firms with suppliers of varying inputs needed
for production activity [Marshall (1920); Krugman (1991)].
Earlier Audretsch and Feldman (1996) and later Caniels and Romijn
(2005) empirically found the link of knowledge spillovers shaping
spatial structures with in a geographical space. But earlier Jaffe, et
al. (1993) empirically found that knowledge spillovers are bounded
geographically but the structure of the economic activity restrain the
spillover effect, whereas impact of technology spillover is mainly due
to factor mobility across regions. The knowledge spillovers are not a
random happening as old ideas generally lead to development of new
technologies and way to conduct business [Weitzman (1998)].
Choice of location and type of organisation among other factors
determine the entrepreneurial action for new startups [Harbison (1956)].
Prescott and Wisscher (1980) pointed out that the growth of firm is
mainly attributed to capital accumulation and firm-specific knowledge.
But the internal structure of organisation determines efficiency and
performance [Chandler (1977); Atkeson and Kehoe (2005)]. Firms
preferring to limit geographical range of production activity succeed to
reduce transaction costs [Coase (1937)]. In addition to existence of
externalities in capital, knowledge and technologies, the individual
factor cannot be overlooked. The idea generation process and
experimenting with new goods and services is outcome of an intellectual
effort. Entrepreneurs play their role in internalising individual
externalities for the general efficiency of the firm. This also has its
impact on decision of the firm to agglomerate with other firms or not
within the same geographical space due to accruing comparative advantage
over other [Papageorgiou (1978); Papageorgiou and Smith (1983)].
Generally the line of research in spatial economics is concerned
with impact of spatial agglomeration along with urban development with
economic growth [Duranton and Storper (2005); Rossi-Hansberg (2005)].
Over the course of history the researchers have considered space as a
single point in theory [Isard (1949); North (1955); Quigley (1998);
Millo (2012)]. But the later developments have expanded the scope of
space as a collection of system of cities [Rossi-Hansberg (2006);
Baldwin and Forslid (2000); Fujita and Thisse (2003)]. Similarly, the
geographical structure of the region has also been under discussion like
Ohlin (1933), and Krugman (1991). They introduced distance of factor
inputs from the centre of economic activity to understand the
geographical structure over a space. Krugman (1998) propagated the use
of modelling strategy that uses a 2-D space in continuous functional
form with consideration of heterogeneity and hierarchical structures.
The centre of economic activity in a geographical location has been
understood in the form of concentric rings [Tinbergen (1961)] or a
hexagon lattice system [Losch (1940)] a circle [Papageorgiou and Smith
(1983); Lucas and RossiHansberg (2002). But starting from Hotelling
(1929), the adoption of simplification in the model building, spatial
structure is considered as a continuum over a straight line even by
Solow and Vickey (1971) and Rossi-Hansberg (2005).
Generally Tobler's first law of geography: "Everything is
related to everything, but close things are more related than things
that are far apart" sets the canvas for spatial analysis. Models
thus constructed usually dealing with cross sectional data take into
consideration the correlation between spatial economic units [Anselin
(1988); Millo (2014)]. But some empirical studies used panel data with
ability to capture the spatial variability while controlling for
multicollinearity among the variables extending the sample size that in
turn yields more efficient estimators [Elhorst (2003)]. Furthermore, the
techniques have been improved to control for both heterogeneity and
spatial correlation in the panel data for spatial analysis [Baltagi, et
al. (2003)].
When it comes to choice of production of goods and services,
Krugman (1980) stressed that lower level of comparative advantage at
home causes a strong thrust of import of a good. Eventually the
increasing returns will cause production to be confined to one
geographical location for production for each type of good especially
when trade and transportation costs are accounted for making the country
an exporter of that good. Therefore, 'home market effects'
distinguish comparative advantage and increasing returns to determine
the spatial production decisions. International and regional economic
literature delves similarly upon factors mobility across different
productive regions within or across countries. Given the supply side
economic factors, Linder hypothesis asserts that supply response in more
than proportional to deviations in the patterns of demand making
production decisions based on merely correlations problematic. At the
same time the relative importance of a good for a specific region in
relation to other regions determines the level of resources commitment
to a particular industry [Walz (1996)]. Therefore, large countries have
higher supply of differentiated and diverse products without incurring
trade costs. Larger countries also provide opportunity to the producer
to locate their production facilities in order to enjoy higher degree of
comparative advantage. This tends to an increase in the returns to the
factors of production especially in the form of wages along with overall
productivity. Therefore, the differences in underlying microeconomic
phenomenon can explain the impact of spatial economic and international
trade theories in the light of comparative and competitive advantages
for geographical locations for production.
Special economic zone (SEZ) is a geographically bounded area having
a central management for providing benefits of physical location within
the zone. These zones have their separate customs area to gain from
duty-free and related liberal laws [World Bank (2009)]. SEZs accrue
direct and indirect economic benefits like employment generation and
foreign exchange earnings; and knowledge based urban growth,
respectively. SEZs are created to cater for needs of export-processing,
centralised industrial parks, free trade activity, and free ports for
merchandising jointly or specifically. China has created SEZ to deliver
more or less all these and related services instead of focusing on
single function of a zone [Wong (1987)]. There are seven specific SEZs
in China: Shenzhen, Zhuhai, Shantou, Xiamen, Hainan, Shanghai Pudong New
Area, and Tianjin Binhai New Area. In addition, China has developed
economic zones that are delivering specialised concentrated services
like: High-tech Industrial Development Zones (HIDZs), Free Trade Zones
(FTZs), Economic and Technological Development Zones (ETDZs),
Export-Processing Zones (EPZs), etc.
Industrial clusters are different from a SEZ as a cluster is
originated because of presence of inter-connected firms from related
industries at a specific geographic location, like financial
intermediaries, heavy industry supporting small related processing
units, governmental agencies, and educational institutions imparting
different skills. The reason for the link of these entities is the
spillover effect of externalities and complementally dependences [World
Bank (2009)]. The support of the government crates an enabling
environment where planned and coordinated efforts of private sector
enhances the ability of resources utilisation leading to enhanced
competitiveness at regional, national and international levels [World
Bank (2010)].
The difference between SEZ and industrial cluster is in their
evolution. There is an organic growth of industrial clusters whereas
SEZs are generally crated through government action with a
'top-down' approach. Developed countries have witnessed the
evolution of industrial clusters from SEZs i.e. industrial parks and
export processing zone. On the other hand this phenomenon is not
generally seen in developing countries indicating the need for
efficiency of the public sector for fostering and supporting growth of
private enterprise development. Zeng (2008) found in a study of 11
industrial clusters in different African countries that most of them
were impulsively created except for export processing zone culminating
the growth of textile cluster in Mauritania. Therefore, creation of SEZ
is a challenging task for governments as there are numerous cases of
failure in developed and developing countries where political or
personal motives were behind such initiatives [Plummer and Sheppard
(2006)]. Government efficiency and policy effectiveness supporting
dynamic economic decisions is necessary for success of a SEZ. If not
generally, at least within the zone there must be present a well
functioning market system supported by public sector. The clear
understanding of markets strengths and comparative advantage at home
along with insight of future development path focused at local and
international business development by the policy makers and business
fraternity is essential for success of a SEZ. Decades of hard work and
efforts from public and private sectors created the environment where
industrial clusters have started to emerge from SEZs in China.
Zhongguancun (Beijing) and Shenzhen have grown cluster related to
information and communication technologies, Pudong (Shanghai) to
electronics and biotech clusters, Wuhan to opto-electronics, Dalian to
software development, are a few examples [Fu and Yuning (2007)].
Therefore, the risk of failure of a SEZ is linked with clear
understanding of domestic potential harnessed to withstand international
competitive environment. Creating of a SEZ with right mix of policies
has reaped benefits to numerous economies across globe. Pakistan also
started to develop the industrial zones in different regions but those
could not generate the expected results. The reasons for their dismal
performance have been structural as well as lack of interest from the
private sector to participate in such zones. Now the history has given
us another chance where need is to learn from previous mistakes and
enact a culture of progress, efficiency and competitive environment with
initiative lying with private sector having support of public sector
growth oriented policies.
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
The study used a cluster (i.e. the aggregated locus of economic
activity) to comprehend whether economic activity accumulates, expands,
or intensifies there. This will help to observe the spatial-temporal
dynamics of a cluster (or SEZ) that federal government intends to
establish in 12 cities of Balochistan and Khyber-Pakhtunkhwa under the
CPEC (i.e. Turban, Khuzdar, Quetta, Bostan, Qila Saif Ullah, Mansehra,
Nowshera, Hattar, D I Khan, Kohat and Bannu). Spatial intensity (I) of
entrepreneurship increases with increased availability of factor input
(W) when the geographical range (D) in the cluster is constant. Spatial
intensity (I) decreases if the geographical range (D) declines with
constant supply of factor input (W). (1) The spatial production function
relates productivity of the cluster on the factor inputs along with
their relative location [Coase (1937)]; enhance knowledge even in the
form of spillovers from the competitive environment; develop or adopt
newer technologies to offset the pressure of increasing wages, rents and
other associated costs of production. The long run cluster growth is
function of growth rates of factor inputs, degree of knowledge and rate
of spatial expansion of inputs. Therefore, accumulation and furthering
the technological base, human and physical capitals are responsible for
growth process over a geographical space. The emergence of
entrepreneurial clusters lead to agglomeration economies that is then
translated into higher degree of sustainability of firms over extended
periods in time, and then the overall economic growth. The assessment of
agglomeration was not the focus of this study though.
Due to non-availability of all the data of labour, firms,
technology, agriculture and natural resources of the specified SEZs, the
study analysed the spatial intensity and performance at the regional
level (i.e. provinces of Pakistan).
Economic geography and spatial economic analysis has gained
attention of researchers especially since last few decades due to global
integration and increased competition like contributions by Anselin
(1988), Elhorst, et al. (2007), Rossi (2005), Lin (2010) and Kapoor, et
al. (2007) are a few.
Empirical analysis of spatial models based on cross sectional data
and identification of correlation in spatial units progressed to
analyses based on panel data with better control of spatial correlations
and heterogeneity [Anselin (1988); Baltagi, et al. (2003)]. But still
the problems persist with availability of reliable spatial data. This
lead to different modeling techniques to improve the fit of data e.g.
transcendental logarithmic production function (trans-log) of the
Cobb-Douglas function imposing no prior restrictions on elasticity of
substitutions of factor inputs and returns to scale [Christensen, et al.
(1971); Klacek, et al. (2007)]. The study specified trans-log
Cobb-Douglas production function in two ways. First, the function
constructed assuming constant and neutral technological progress, and
second, this assumption in relaxed to assess non-constant and
non-neutral technological progress. (2) Wald test enables to select the
appropriate functional form given the fit to the data. This will enable
to ascertain whether in Pakistan the state of use of technology for
production is improving or static.
DATA
The study intended to choose the agriculture inputs that can be
transformed into processed exportable products through value addition.
Indices measuring the value of technology used in processing available
agriculture inputs and capital requirements of new ventures posed
problems in construction due to non availability of relevant data sets.
Similarly, the labour movements and settlement data sets are also not
available with accuracy. Another problem was defining industries and
goods considering industry classifications with technological criteria
and use of factor inputs rather than substitutability in demand. The
standard industry definitions carries information of production
technologies [Maskus (1991)], but in Pakistan, such segregated data sets
are not available. The study, therefore, used the theoretical
underpinnings that varieties of goods within an industry use common
production technologies.
ESTIMATION METHODOLOGY
Equations (1) and (2) are based on cross-section analysis and it
was assumed that the same technology is available for all firms in the
region for the same industry at the same period of time. However, for
Equations (3) and (4) panel data is used for estimation after relaxing
the strong assumption on the state of technology. As the standard
specification of Cobb-Douglas production function is nested in the
trans-log forms, study applied the Wald test to ascertain applicability
of trans-log production function over Cobb-Douglas production function.
Following the literature, generally maximum likelihood method (ML)
[Anselin (1988)] and generalised method of moments (GMM) [Kelejian and
Prucha (1999)] are used for spatial models. But ML is also preferred by
some especially in presence of spatial lag, spatial errors and
non-spherical residuals. The estimation of all the equations were done
with ML [Anselin (1988)].
EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS AND RESULTS
The general results of the spatial production function are that the
regional output is increasing function of knowledge and the capital.
Although most of the individual coefficients are not significant but on
the basis of overall significance of the model, the study concludes that
the output is responsive towards the development of production inputs
especially the human factor. The spatial intensity of the human
development is not evenly distributed in all the regions due to non
availability of technical and skill building institutions in the
peripheral regions. The capital development in the form of
infrastructure, communication networks (roads and electronic
communication) and other urban facilities have lead to development of
small and medium enterprise. That is why the results support the impact
of spatial capital intensity on aggregate output.
As a result of a significant Wald test the study found significant
fir of trans-log function with constant and neutral technological change
over conventional Cobb-Douglas production function. Furthermore, with
the help of Wald-test the study found trans-log function with
non-constant and non-neutral technological progress to be significant
over assumption of constant and neutral technological progress.
Therefore, the study establishes that the technology utilisation in
Pakistan is not static and it is evolving with the passage of time. The
individual coefficients do not show much of the significance for
specific interpretations indicating the problems present within the data
set.
DISCUSSION, INSIGHTS, AND SUGGESTIONS
Special Economic Zones in China lead to a controlled social
experiment to test the efficacy of market-oriented economic reforms.
SEZs lead to creation of new policies and institutions along that
successfully enhanced exports, foreign exchange earnings and employment
by attracting foreign investment and technologies. It lead to the
development of high-tech industrial development zones through Torch
Programme with an objective of to develop culture of research and
development (R&D) at corporate and universities level to support
development of new and high-tech products with commercial value. The
free trade zones established in 1990 enabled China to test impact of
free on national economy and productive capacities before joining World
Trade Organisation (WTO). 44 Out of 61 EPZs are located in the coastal
region to stimulate export-trading and processing [ProLogis (2008)].
Common key elements of China's SEZs success are political,
social as well as business rooted. Top leadership showed strong
commitment to reforms and institutional building that enables these
zones to contribute to economic growth. The top leadership tried to
endure a stable and conducive macro environment and successfully averted
political opposition. Deng's initiative for openness by
decentralising business decision making made institutions autonomous
which in turn encouraged private firms (local and foreign) to invest in
the zones. Some of the measures of his policies included provision of
land at cheaper rents, tax holidays, removing institutional barriers to
speedup customs clearance, removing barriers on imports of raw materials
and intermediate goods used in exportable value added products,
exemptions of exports taxes, improving labor laws to attract inflow of
skilled workers. The restricted quota to sell the product domestically
induced the producer to seek better foreign markets leading to higher
exports and continuous investments by the firms to attain outward
looking comparative advantage [Enright Scott, and Chung (2005)]. With
institutional reforms, the central government formed and encouraged the
local governments to create conducive environment for conducting
business. The efficient regulatory and administrative environment backed
by sound infrastructure of communication, energy, water, sewerage, and
ports, attracted foreign direct investments and remittances. It lead
China to strengthen the local business arena with potential to compete
in international markets. The accumulation of capital, technology, and
business skills has spillover effect that helped building local
industry. All these activities have created an environment that supports
inherent urge to acquire higher level skills eventually translating into
R&D activity [Sonobe and Otsuka (2006)]. This development leads to
evolution of innovation culture especially by qualified workers and
managers. SEZs provided the location advantage by developing them in
coastal regions or near major cities that facilitated foreign trading
due to availability of major infrastructure, such as ports, airports,
and railways [Enright, Scott, and Chung (2005)]. It lead to clusters
formation with involvement of educated labour force especially for
seafood and fruits processing, stone carving, etc. with low-cost
production. The segmentation of manufacturing into smaller productive
units to form a larger industrial cluster is supported and patronised by
the local governments and decision centres. In the light of the above
discussion, the study puts forth the following suggestions:
The top leadership must demonstrate strong commitment to allow
institutional autonomy and flexibility to support small, medium and
large startups. The policy initiatives must support balanced growth in
all the regions to support capital accumulation (human and physical) and
controlling for labour mobility and social distress. Network of
technical training imparting institutions must be built to create
skilled labor force at domestic level. The process of reforms must not
be stagnant but at the same time must be a gradual and cautious.
Public-private partnership approach is necessary to undertake the
initiatives that need large investments but have business development
potential e.g. mining, ports services etc. Research institutions must be
involved in continuous benchmarking and monitoring the business
competitiveness. Improve data gathering, processing and dissemination to
support research and policymaking.
APPENDIX
Table 1
Spatial Production Function
Regions\ A [beta] [GAMMA]
Coefficients
Balochistan 0.0468 * 0.036 * 0.2174 **
KPK 0.0461 * 0.0461 ** 0.197 *
Sindh 0.0678 ** 0.105 * 0.3204 **
Punjab 0.221 * 0.157 ** 0.4358 ***
All variables are logged. * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Table 2
Trans-log Production Function
Loemcients [[alpha].sub.o] [[alpha].sub.i] [[alpha].sub.ij]
Equation (3) 0.0113 ** 0.1037 * 0.1797 **
Equation (4) -0.0498 ** 0.0386 * 0.1127 *
Loemcients [[alpha].sub.t] [[alpha].sub.ti] [[alpha].sub.tt]
Equation (3) 0.0731 *** -- --
Equation (4) 0.1091 *** 0.2036 ** 0.4358 **
(3) ln [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i]
ln [x.sub.i] + 1/2 [SIGMA][SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ij] ln [x.sub.i]
ln [x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t]
(4) ln [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i]
ln [x.sub.i] + 1/2 [SIGMA][SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ij] ln [x.sub.i]
ln [x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ti]
ln [x.sub.i] + 1/2 [[alpha].sub.tt] [t.sup.2]
All variables are logged. * p<0.1, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01
Muhammad Mansoor Ali <mmali@numl.edu.pk> is Lecturer,
Economics Department, NUML, Islamabad. Farida Faisal is Associate
Professor, Department of Management Sciences, PMAS-Arid Agriculture
University, Rawalpindi.
REFERENCES
Anselin, L. (1988) Lagrange Multiplier Test Diagnostics for Spatial
Dependence and Spatial Heterogeneity. Geographical Analysis 20:1, 117.
Atkeson, A. and P. J. Kehoe (2005) Modelling and Measuring
Organisation Capital. Journal of Political Economy 113, 1026-1053.
Audretsch, D. B. and M. P. Feldman (1996) R&D Spillovers and
the Geography of Innovation and Production. American Economic Review 86,
630-640.
Baldwin, R. E. and R. Forslid (2000) The Core-Periphery Model and
Endogenous Growth; Stabilising and Destabilising Integration. Economica
67, 307-324.
Caniels, M. C. J. and H. A. Romijn (2005) What Drives
Innovativeness in Industrial Clusters? Transcending the Debate.
Cambridge Journal of Economics 29, 497-515.
Chandler, A. D. JR. (1977) The Visible Hand: The Managerial
Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, Mass.: Belknap Press.
Coase, R. H. (1937) The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4, 386-405.
Duran'ton, G. and M. Storper (2005) Agglomeration and Growth:
A Dialogue between Economists and Geographers. Journal of Economic
Geography 6, 1-7.
Elhorst, P. (2003) Specification and Estimation of Spatial Panel
Data Models. International Regional Science Review 26:3, 244-268.
Feldman, M. (1999) The New Economics of Innovation, Spillovers and
Agglomeration: A Review of Empirical Studies. Economics of Innovation
and New Technology 8, 5-25.
Fu, Xiaolan, and Gao Yuning (2007) Export Processing Zones in
China: A Survey. Geneva: International Labour Organization.
Fujita, M. and J.-F. Thisse (2003) Does Geographical Agglomeration
Foster Economic Growth? and who Gains and Loses from it? Japanese
Economic Review 54, 121-145.
G. Millo and G. Piras (2012) Spatial Panel Data Models. Journal of
Statistical Software 47: 1, 1381.
Harbison, F. (1956) Entrepreneurial Organisation as a Factor in
Economic Development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 367-379.
Hotelling, H. (1929) Stability in competition. Economic Journal 39,
41-57.
Isard, W. (1949) The General Theory of Location and Space-Economy.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 63, 476-506.
Jaffe, A., M. Trajtenberg, and R. Henderson (1993) Geographic
Location of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 577-598.
Krugman, P. (1991) Increasing Returns and Economic Geography.
Journal of Political Economy 99, 483-499.
Lin, Justin Yifu (2010) New Structural Economics: A Framework for
Rethinking Development. World Bank, Washington, DC. (Policy Research
Working Paper 5197).
Losch, A. (1940) The Economic of Location. Jena: Fischer. English
translation by William H. Woglom with the assistance of Wolfgane F.
Stolper. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1967.
Lucas, R. E. Jr. and E. Rossi-Hansberg (2002) On the Internal
Structure of Cities. Econometrica 70, 1445-476.
Marris, R. and D. C. Mueller (1980) The Corporation, Competition,
and the Invisible Hand. Journal of Economic Literature 18, 32-63.
Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.
Martin, P. and G. I. P. Ottaviano (2001) Growth and Agglomeration.
International Economic Review 42, 947-968.
Ohlin, B. (1933) Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press.
Papageorgiou, G. J. (1978) Spatial externalities I: Theory. Annals
of the Association of American Geographers 68, 465-476.
Papageorgiou, Y. Y. and T. R. Smith (1983) Agglomeration as Local
Instability of Spatially Uniform Steady-States. Econometrica 51,
1109-1120.
Plummer, P. and E. Sheppard (2006) Geography Matters: Agency,
Structures and Dynamics at the Interaction of Economics and Geography.
Journal of Economic Geography 6, 619-637.
Prescott, E and M. Wisscher (1980) Orgnisation Capital. Journal of
Political Economy 88, 446-461.
Romer, P. M. (1986) Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth. Journal
of Political Economy 94, 1002-1037.
Romer, P. M. (1990) Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of
Political Economy 98, S71-S102.
Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2005) A Spatial Theory of Trade. American
Economic Review 95, 1465-1491.
Solow, R. M. and W. S. Vickey (1971) Land Use in a Long Narrow
City. Journal of Economic Theory 3, 430-447.
Tinbergen, J. (1961) The Spatial Dispersion of Production: A
Hypothesis. Schweizerische Zeitschrift fur Volkwirtschaft und Statistik
97, 412-419.
Walz, U. (1996) Transport Costs, Intermediate Goods, and Localised
Growth. Regional Science and Urban Economics 26, 671-695.
Weitzman, M. L. (1998) Recombinant Growth. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 113, 331-360.
Williamson, O. E. (1981) The Modern Corporation: Origins,
Evolution, Attributes. Journal of Economic Literature 19, 1537-1568.
World Bank (2009) Clusters for Competitiveness: A Practical Guide
and Policy Implications for Developing Cluster Initiatives.
International Trade Department, PREM Network, Report. World Bank,
Washington, DC.
World Bank (2010) Innovation Policy: A Guide for Developing
Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.
(1) Spatial intensity index, 1 = [SIGMA][w.sub.j]/[pi][D.sup.2],
where, I = spatial intensity, W = a factor input distributed with amount
[w.sub.j] at location j within geographical region R, D = geographical
range, where [D.sub.j] is the distance of location j from centre of
cluster (and D = [SIGMA][w.sub.j][D.sub.j]/w), C = centre of the
cluster. Given this information, the study estimated the spatial
production function: (1) [Y.sub.i] = f([A.sub.i]/[D.sup.2.sub.Ai],
[H.sub.i], [K.sub.i]/[D.sup.2.sub.Ki]), where output is function of
quantities of technology for production, physical capital, human
capital, [D.sub.Ai], [D.sub.Ki], [D.sub.Hi] are mean distance of the
three factors of production. Cobb-Douglas production function in terms
of spatial intensity of factor of production can be written as: (2)
[Y.sub.i] = [A.sup.[alpha].sub.i] [H.sup.[beta].sub.i]
[D.sub.Ai.sup.-2[beta]] [D.sub.Ki.sup.-2[gamma]].
(2) Consider equation with cross-product terms between time, input
measures and a quadratic time trend, and constant and neutral
technological change:
(3) In [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i] In
[x.sub.i] + [1/2] [SIGMA] [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ij] In [x.sub.i] In
[x.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.t] t and with non-constant and non-neutral
technological change:
(4) In [y.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.i] In
[x.sub.i] + [1/2] [SIGMA][SIGMA] [a.sub.ij] In [x.sub.i] In [x.sub.j] +
[[alpha].sub.t]t + [SIGMA] [[alpha].sub.ti] In [x.sub.i] + [1/2]
[[alpha].sub.tt][t.sup.2]
COPYRIGHT 2017 Reproduced with permission of the Publications Division, Pakistan Institute of Development Economies, Islamabad, Pakistan.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2017 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.