Do Political Leaders Affect Sectoral Composition of FDI Inflows to Favour Their Constituencies in Pakistan?
Faridi, Muhammad Zahir ; Nazir, Rabia ; Murtaza, Ghulam 等
Do Political Leaders Affect Sectoral Composition of FDI Inflows to Favour Their Constituencies in Pakistan?
The present study investigates the dynamic causal relationship
between net inflows of skill intensive industry/sectoral FDI and
different political regimes (a movement from autocratic to democratic
government), to test our primary hypothesis that whether the political
leaders favour their constituencies/median-voters by fiddling the
sectoral composition of FDI inflows in Pakistan, to please them
economically. Learning from the prior literature, we have categorised
the median voter, the most populous, in low skill industry, while less
populous in medium skill industry, and least populous in the high
skilled industry. To address the question, that politically which
industry fetch more FDI, we have employed novel Frequency Domain
Spectral Granger causality (GC) test, using time series data, to our
dynamic models, to gauge the cyclical fluctuations in causal
relationship between political regimes and skill intensive FDI. The
causal relationship between skill intensive FDI and political regimes is
analysed with and without some confounding economic variables (e.g.,
trade openness, human capital and exchange rate) for the robustness of
the results. Our findings show that, rather than political, there are
some economic reasons cause to attract more FDI in low skill
(sub)sectors. We have also found bi-directional causal relationship, in
short as well as in the long run, for medium and high skill
FDI-indicating the intentions of political interests in designing FDI
sectoral distribution. However conducive economic environment is a
fundamental confounding factor fetching FDI in different (sub)sectors of
Pakistan economy, and in return, FDI has also instigated the development
of political institutions by empowering middle class populace to
participate more in the democratic process, the results reveal.
JEL Classification: PI6, CI4, H10
Keywords: Politics, Inward FDI, Frequency-Domain Granger Causality,
Pakistan
1. INTRODUCTION
In the recent experience of developing world, remarkable
differences in economic development have been observed, most probably
ensued from the economic and regional integration of the country with
rest of the economies. The empirical findings of Rodrik (2008) suggest
that the capital inflows and outflows are one of the means to form such
type of integration, and can be enhanced through good economic and
political institutions. In order to analyse the political aspects of FDI
policy, it is prime to study the political institutional framework of
host country that determine the level and sectors/industry wise FDI
(characterised in term of High, Medium and Low Skill Intensive FDI) as
argued by Garrett (1998), Mosley (2003), Oliva and Bati (2002), Khan and
Kim (2011).
The study of Zhu (2013) narrated that among political stability,
institutional quality, political freedom, investors' preferences,
these are the host country 'political institutions/political
regimes' that create distinct tastes for different types of FDI
inflows. Among others, pragmatic studies of Borner, et al. (1995), Barro
(1997) have also well documented about the types of FDI flows which are
more productive, and about the institutional factors attract productive
capital flows.
Empirical literature regarding skill biasness of inward FDI
depending upon political regime is not in surfeit. Studies including
[e.g., Markusenm, et al. (1996); Mundell (1957); Yeaple (2003)] claim
that capital moves into countries where factor abundance and low prices
exist. On the other side, Baum and Lake (2003) argued that democratic
countries invest more for median voter and attract low skilled inward
FDI, while autocratic governments suppress labour unions and wages,
equipping nations with greater proportion of high skill intensive FDI.
More explicitly, the studies of [Pandya (2007); Pinto (2004); Pinto
and Pinto (2008); Bueno de Mesquita, et al. (1999, 2003); Milner and
Kubota (2005)] showed that the relative demand of skilled and unskilled
labour and income distribution is affected by distinct policies for high
skill intensive and low skill intensive FDI. In order to retain office,
the democratic leaders need support of majority, i.e., median voters
which are mainly unskilled labour hence low skill intensive FDI inflows
are favoured. In contrast authoritarian leaders rely on only a small
winning coalition typically consisting of skilled workers attract high
skill intensive FDI [Zhu (2013)].These aforesaid narratives, thus, arise
the question that is--whether it is the democracy and/or autocracy, in
which the political leaders adjust FDI inflows in different sectors of
the economy to accommodate their constituencies for political support in
case of Pakistan.
Concerning with the aggregated level of FDI, existing literature
is, still, not conclusive on the political economy of FDI policy. Some
of the studies found that democracy makes a country more attractive to
foreign investors by putting institutional constraints on politicians
opportunist behaviour and reducing consequent political risk [e.g.,
Jensen (2003)], while the others take the position on the opposite side
by claiming that politician's capacity to offer favourable
treatment to foreign investors is restricted due to plurality of
interests [see, Li and Resnick (2003)]. Keeping in view such a
controversial findings on the concerned issue, the objective of this
study is to test the hypothesis that whether the political
institutions/regimes are essential ingredients to shape level as well as
skill intensive industry/(sub) sectoral FDI in the case of Pakistan.
After the precise introduction in the first section, rest of the
paper follows: Section 2 is consists of trends and patterns of sectoral
FDI under different political regimes. Review of the prior work is made
in the Section 3. Section 4 is based on model, data and methodology.
Interpretations of results and discussions are made in the Section 5,
while Section 6 concludes.
2. SKILL INTENSIVE FD I INFLOWS UNDER DIFFERENT POLITICAL REGIME:
TRENDS AND PATTERNS
By disaggregating FDI inflows on the basis of skill intensities of
workers engaged in specific industry in Pakistan, we have observed
distinct patterns of FDI distribution across different (sub)
sectors/economic groups. Some sectors, like sugar, leather and leather
products, rubber and rubber products, basic metals and metal products,
electrical machinery, paper and pulp and machinery, have received a very
minor share of FDI over the years. Metal products stand at bottom in
receiving FDI in selected years. In years 1999 to 2006, during the
autocratic era, all these sectors were receiving less FDI as compared to
the years in which country has improved in terms of polity score and
moved towards democracy as shown in Figure 2.1. We observed a sharp
surge in FDI inflows to this high skill intensive sectors. However FDI
inflows touched bottom in 2001 and then started rising slowly.
After the year 2006, when country was on way to regain democracy,
FDI to this sector started declining again, touched bottom in 2011 and
became even negative in 2012. Hence this trend of machinery other than
electrical, show that authoritarian leaders favour high skill intensive
FDI to benefit the few elite capitalists form whom they get support to
gain and retain their office as shown in Figure 2.3. In the sectors of
textile, cement, electronics, petro chemicals and petroleum refining,
transport equipment, social and personal services and tourism, we
observed very moderate FDI flows.
Food and beverages which is a low skill intensive sector, FDI
inflows to this sector remained low on average in all time period of
autocracy, touched bottom in 2002 with $ -5.1 million inflows. On the
other hand, with highest inflows in 2007 and 2015 with $515 million and
$553 million respectively. Electronic sector which is a medium skill
intensive sector received total of $ 251 million of net FDI in 20 years
since 1997, with highest inflow of $ 27 million in 2008 and lowest in
2015 on average inflows to this sector were high in democratic regime.
Inflows to medium skill intensive sectors of petro chemicals and
petroleum refining and transport equipment both experienced increasing
trend since 2008. Total of $571 million of net FDI has been received by
transport equipment sector since 1997, and $ 497 million of which has
been received from 2007 to 2016 as shown in Figure 2.2. Similarly petro
chemicals and petroleum refining has received 579.72 million US dollars
since 1997. $595.1 million of which was received during years of
democratic government and rest during authoritarian regime.
Chemicals, pharmaceuticals and fertilisers, trade and construction
received almost equal total FDI in 20 years with $1277.78, 1018.77 and $
1110.88 million inflows. $722.41 million of FDI in chemicals,
pharmaceuticals and fertilisers sector is received since 2006. Similarly
maximum of inflows were received in trade and construction during
democratic regimes. FDI to power sector was not encouraged during
autocratic regime and inflows to this sector were high in democratic
era.
Transport, storage and communication, mining and quarrying-oil and
gas and financial business are the highest receiver of FDI in twenty
years. Transport, storage and communication has received highest FDI
inflows in all 24 economic groups of around $7678.06 million with
highest influx of 1633.98 million in 2008 along with Mining and
Quarrying-Oil and Gas and financial business reaching at the top in same
year, as shown in Figure 2.3. All the sectors, from low to high skill
intensive, have received higher inflows in years of high democratic
regime.
3. LITERATURE REVIEW
A large body of prior literature focus on exploring institutions
effects of FDI, considering it a major determinant of FDI inflows
[Alfaro, et al. (2008); Cuervo-Cazurra (2008); Javorcik and Wei (2009);
Kinda (2010); Wei (2000)]. Yet, how does FDI influences institutions
have not been under greater academic scrutiny.
Michel (2000) has explored the impact of domestic institutions on
capital flows which is mostly positive and directs country's
capital. He also found positive impact of institutional quality, trade
openness, market potential and infrastructure development, while
negative impact of natural resources and human capital on FDI.
Zhu (2013) tested for 38 developing economies and found that
democracy and high skill intensive FDI were negatively associated
supporting his claim of political regime creating difference in sectoral
structure of inward FDI.
In case of China, the institutions (like lower level of tax, less
arbitrariness in tax burdens and better legal protection) of host
regions of china were found to be positively associated with FDI [Yang
and Zhang (2003)], indicating simultaneity between FDI and institutions.
Madani and Nobakhtin (1990) found a positive impact of democracy in
contrast to autocracy on FDI inflows. The impact is transmitted through
political risk perceived by foreign firms. Previous literature can be
divided into three section regarding impact of political regime type on
FDI inflows. Firstly, institutions and political procedures under
democracy are intended to encourage business foe multinationals and
reduce political risk for foreign investors, e.g., audience and
reputation cost, checks and balances, large number of veto players and
transparency (1) which increase credibility of democratic governments
for their commitments in sight of foreign investors. Foreign investors
in return give financial support to the leaders in their election
campaign who commit to liberal and market friendly policies to benefit
multinationals. The audience cost for such leaders can make begging
campaign contributions, a startling challenge, because of the fear to
lose financial support of multinationals [Hansen and Mitchell (2000);
Hillman and Ursprung (1988)].
Turning to the relationship between multinationals and
dictatorship, Alsina and Dollar (2000) showed that authoritarian leaders
give no ear to political pressure and rivals, and can present liberal
fiscal and financial incentives to multinationals. Market friendly
policies can easily be adopted and implemented to attract FDI by these
leaders without any fear of domestic actors acting against these
policies. This ability of authoritarian leaders lends flexibility and
timely responsiveness of policies to macroeconomic environment by such
regimes and makes FDI more attractive for foreign investors.
In contrast, large number of veto players becomes hurdle in passing
new resolutions and decisions regarding foreign investors due to
diversity of preferences, hence democracy fails to attract higher FDI
inflows [Mathur and Singh (2013)]. On the other hand autocratic leaders
can ensure contract enforcement to stimulate growth [Olson (1993); Geh
Ibach and Keefer (2011)]. Similarly, empirical studies of Oneal (1994),
Li and Resnick (2003), Gehlbach and Keefer (2011), and Resnick (2001)
supporting the argument of positive relation between autocracy and
multinationals activities. There are also studies which provide
ambiguous picture on this relation. The argument claims that higher
level of motivation on part of the politicians under both type of
regimes increase political risk. Thus leaders both in autocracy and
democracy expropriate multinationals in host countries [Li (2009)].
Decomposing FDI into manufacturing, primary and services sector,
Schulz (2009) found that there is a significant relation between
manufacturing sector FDI inflows and democracy, rejecting the
relationship between FDI inflows to primary and services sector with
democracy.
Pandya (2007) explored relation between FDI inflows and regime type
by distinguishing between vertical and horizontal FDI. Regime
characteristics matter in opposing or supporting horizontal FDI because
politicians have to face a tradeoff between different interest groups
and consumer welfare. However vertical FDI is favoured by left wing
parties because it extends employment opportunities for domestic labour.
In addition, Dorobantu (2010) argued that to benefit workers of their
constituencies, democratic leaders tend to support FDI inflows (under
assumption that FDI hurt domestic capital but benefits domestic labour).
On the other hand authoritarian leaders, who gain and retain their
offices with support of only a few capitalists, try to restrict FDI
inflows.
Although above-mentioned studies has advanced FDI literature in the
field of politics of FDI to a new level but still analysis of FDI at
disaggregated level remains to be explored in detail.
Literature shows that different countries attract different type of
FDI, and as a result FDI policy varies across industries. Mostly studies
examine the supply side factors of FDI and role of external and internal
institutions, but demand side determinants like domestic interest
groups, political competition, partisanship, government turnout etc.
have been ignored. That is the reason, this study intends to fill this
gap by focusing on political economy of FDI policy with some new
composition of FDI inflows and methodological framework.
4. DATA AND METHODOLOGY
In this Section, we present model, data and methodology. Dynamic
model is formulated to gauge the impact of different political regimes
(PR) on Skill intensive FDI (FDI) in case of Pakistan, employing time
series data. The study follows a novel Granger causality infrequency
domain, taking into account the time series properties of data, i.e.,
the cyclical and time varying characteristics.
From the macroeconomic perspectives, New Classical trade theory,
and H-0 theory suggest that factor endowment differentials across
countries, and the return to capital are the primary intuition for
capital to flow from one to another country considering perfect capital
mobility. While Lucas (1990), negating the perfect capital mobility,
argues that these are the economies of scale, systemic distortion,
regulations and political factors, along with economic factors that
determine FDI in the host country. Keeping in view these arguments, we
have constructed the following VAR model for the estimating GC in
frequency domain in the next section.
[mathematical expression not reproducible] (4.1)
Where, the [x.sub.t] is a vector consists of control variables,
e.g., Human capital (SEE), Exchange Rate (ER), and Trade Openness (TOP).
The variable fdi indicates the foreign direct investment, and its
superscript T indicates the type of FDI i.e., Low/Medium/High Skill
intensive FDI, and pr represents the political regimes. The terms
[epsilon]t and [upsilon]t are the white noise errors, and Mis the lag
order of the series.
(i) Econometric Methodology
Extensive literature is available on the econometric
methods/techniques that have been developed to investigate the causal
relationship among the concerned time series variables. Yet there exist,
still, a missing area that is to analyse the time varying
characteristics of time series data. In order to analyse the causal
relationship and taking into account the cyclical fluctuation in the
data, a novel spectral Granger Causality (GC) in frequency domain is
used in this study. For the unit root test we have used augmented
Dickey-Fuller test (ADF) and Phillips-Perron test. Following Lemmens, et
al. (2008), we employed bivariate GCS pectral analysis in order to
address the cyclical characteristics of the data.
Spectral Granger Causality (GC) in Frequency Domain
Starting from the original work proposal by Pierce (1979), GC test
measures the coefficient of coherence (CoQ estimated in a non-parametric
fashion. The application this novel methodology to our analysis would
provide the nonlinear causality patterns, and cyclical fluctuation in
causal relationship, i. e., the long run, medium, and short run
causality patterns corresponding to low, medium and high frequency
domains respectively [Tiwari, et al. (2105)].
For the spectral GC analysis, the series must be stationary if
these are not cointegrated (i.e., their linear combination must turn to
be of order zero). For the series, if the co-integration exist, the
series at level with logarithm can be used for the analysis [Lemmens, et
al. (2008)].
Stating with our concerns variables, we used political regimes
(PR), skilled intestine foreign direct investment (FDI) consisting on
Low, Medium and high skill intensive FDI of T time periods, to test out
primaty hypothesis. If there exist cointegration between FDI and PR,
then goal is to test our primary hypothesis, that whether PR Granger
cause skill intensive FDI at a given level of frequency co. For this
sake, following Pierce (1979) framework, frequency domain is applied in
the univariate innovation series, Ut and Vt, obtained from filtering FDI
and PF from ARMA processes, i.e.,
[[PHI].sup.pr] (L)[fdi.sub.t] = [C.sup.pr] + [[THETA].sup.pr]
(L)[[zeta].sub.t]
[[PHI].sup.fdi] (L)[fdi.sub.t] = [C.sup.fdi] + [[THETA].sup.fdi]
(L)[[zeta].sub.t] ... (4.2)
Where [[PHI].sup.pr] (L), [[PHI].sup.fdi] (L) are the
autoregressive polynomials, [[PHI].sup.fdi] (L), [[PHI].sup.pr] (L) are
the moving average polynomials, and [C.sup.pr], [C.sup.fdi] are the
deterministic components.
Following Lemmens, et al. (2008), the obtained series [zeta]'
and [[xi].sup.t] are white-noise errors with zero mean and correlated,
at different lags and leads, with each other. In defining [[zeta].sup.t]
and [[xi].sup.t] in term of frequency domain; [[zeta].sub.t] ([omega])
and ([xi]t), also termed as the spectra, or density functions of
[[zeta].sub.t] and at frequency [omega][member of] [R.sub.+], we have;
Spectra[zeta]([omega]) = 1 / 2[pi], [[infinity].summation over
(k-[infinity])][GAMMA][[zeta].sub.t](k) [e.sup.-[omega]k]
Spectra[zeta]([omega]) = 1 / 2[pi], [[infinity].summation over
(k-[infinity])][GAMMA][[zeta].sub.t](k) [e.sup.-[omega]k] ... (4.3)
[GAMMA][[zeta].sub.t], (k) is the Cov ([[zeta].sub.t],
[[zeta].sub.t-k]at kth lag of innovation series [zeta] and
[GAMMA][xi],(k) is the Cov
([[zeta].sub.t], [[zeta].sub.t-k]) at kth lags of series [xi].
Thus, the above function shows that the spectral/density representation
is actually the decomposition of time series into the sum of unrelated
components, where each unrelated component occurs [C] times (i.e.,
indicating particular frequency of happening a specific events). So
interpreting the spectrum GC precisely, its each spectrum indicates the
decomposition of the series variances in term of frequency.
In the similar fashion, now the covariance between two innovation
series, cov ([[zeta].sub.t], [[xi].sub.t]), also termed as
cross-spectrum at lags M(= [square root of]T).sup.2], establishes the
relationship between two series as a function of frequency co, given as
under;
Spectra[zeta][zeta]([omega]) = 1/2[pi] [[M.summation over
(k=M)][w.sub.k][GAMMA][zeta][zeta](k)[e.sup.-i[omega]k]] ... (4.4)
Now, the coefficient of coherence (CoC, obtained from dividing
absolute value of cross spectrum, [asolute value of
[Spectra.sub.[zeta][zeta]] ([omega])], over the squared root of the
product of spectra of individual innovation series i.e.,
[Spectra.sub.[zeta][zeta]]([omega])] and [Spectra.sub.[xi]](([omega]).
So, Granger causality coefficient of coherence, which value varies from
0 to 1, interpreted same as R-square of ordinary regression, is then
given by,
CoC[zeta][zeta](w) = [absolute value of
([Spectra.sub.[zeta][zeta]]([omega]))]/[square root of
([Spectra.sub.[zeta]]([omega]) x [[Spectra.sub.[xi]]([omega]))] ...
(4.5)
The hypothesis that the political regime (PR) does not GC skill
intensive FDI, if [CoC.sub.[zeta][xi]] ([omega]) = 0 for every [omega]
in ]0, [pi] [, that follows the chi-square distribution.
Following the Breitung and Candelon (2006), we further extend this
test in a VAR framework;
[mathematical expression not reproducible] (4.6)
For such VAR specification, now, the Null hypothesis for testing
Spectral GC can be stated as;
[mathematical expression not reproducible]
Here, [bar.[omega]] is the vector of coefficients of x, and
F-Statistics against this restriction follows chi- distribution as F(2,
T-2M) for [omega] [member of]]0, [pi][. And in the co-integrated VAR
system, the values of low frequency (high frequency) represent the long
run causality (short run causality) as suggested by Breitung and
Candelon (2006). Further, to check the Spectral GC in cointegrated VAR
systems, we have replaced x by [DELTA][x.sub.t]. It is also noted that
the frequency [omega] can be observed into periodicity or a cycle of
time T years by the formula; T = 2[pi]/[omega] (in years, for annual
data).
(ii) Data
The study uses annually time series data ranges from 1980 to 2016,
depending upon the availability of the data. The data on the dependent
variable; economic group/sectoral Foreign Direct Investment net Inflows
(FDI) measured in Millions of US Dollar, are collected from Liabilities
and Assets and Foreign Investment in Pakistan (various issues), State
Bank of Pakistan, Khan and Kim (1999), and World Investment Directory,
Vol. I and Vol. Ill, United Nations Conference on Trade and Investment,
UNCTI. While the data on independent variables; Gross Domestic Product
(GDP) measured in US Dollar, Trade Openness (TOP) measured as percentage
of GDP, Nominal Exchange rate (ER), and Human Capital (SEE) measured
with number of individuals with Secondary School Education, are taken
from World Development Indications (WDI) and Economic Survey of Pakistan
(various issues). The data on Political Regimes (PR), proxied by Polity
II, is collected from the Integrated Network for Societal Conflict
Research (INSCR) Database, Centre for Systematic Peace. The index ranges
from -10 (autocratic government) to +10 (full democratic government).
Learning from the prior literature [for detail, see Nunn and
Trefler (2006); Antweiler and Trefler (2002); Nunn (2007) and Milner and
Mukherjee (2009)], we have followed Zhu (2012) to categorised
industries/(sub)sectors into low, medium and high skill industries,
while the median voter, the most populous, is engaged professionally in
low skill industry, while less populous in medium skill industry, and
least populous in the high skilled industry. Following this
classification, reported in Table 4.1, we have re-aggregated economic
group/sectoral FDI inflows to obtain skill intensive FDI in
Low/Medium/High skill categories, measured in Millions of US Dollars.
5. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
This segment provides the results of GC in the frequency domain
among the different political regimes and skill intensive FDI in order
to investigate our prior hypothesis. For the robustness of causal
relationship between Political Regimes (PR) and FDI, we further extent
our analysis from bivariate to multivariate modelling by including
economic variables, i.e., Human capital (SEE), Exchange rate (ER), and
Trade openness (TOP). The results (2) of ADF and PP unit root test
indicate that the series have mixed order of integration. While the
co-integration tests show that the series hold a long run relationship,
so we have applied the spectral GC on the co-integrated series.
Low Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Estimating the time varying GC relationship among political regimes
and low skill FDI, we have found that, firstly--in the bivariate
analysis i.e., considering only PR and low skill FDI, there exist no GC
relationship running from political regime to low skill FDI. While there
are strong evidences of reverse causation from low skill intensive FDI
to political regimes. These findings show, albeit this is one side of
the picture, that democratic leader do not intends to influence the FDI
policy for their constituencies to win the support of their voters in
Pakistan. While foreign investment distributed in low skill sector of
the economy reshape the political institutions, as show in Figure 1. In
analysing the other side of the picture, we have extended our causality
analysis by including some economic variables i.e., human capital (SEE),
exchange rate (ER), trade openness (TOP), to investigate whether these
economic variables are the confounding variables, rather than political
factors, that fetch FDI in low skill sectors of the Pakistan economy.
The findings indicate, as shown in Figure 2, that there involve no
political interest in formulating the FDI policy, rather these are the
favourable economic conditions responsible for allocation of FDI in low
skill intensive sectors. Such sectors, like Beverages Tobacco, Sugar,
Textiles, fetch FDI because of cheap labour and input cost in these
sectors.
Medium Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Now, we extend our analysis by investigating the causal
relationship between medium skill intensive FDI and political regime. We
have found a strong bidirectional causal relationship between medium
skill intensive FDI and political regime, in case of bivariate analysis.
The results are robust in case of controlling the causal relationship by
including some economic variables like trade openness (TOP), exchange
rate (ER), and human capital (SEE), indicating that the political
leaders take care of occupants of medium skill (sub)sectors, i.e.,
Electronics, Chemicals, Pharmaceuticals and Fertilisers, Petro Chemicals
and Petroleum Refining, Machinery, Paper and Pulp, Transport Equipment,
Transport, Storage and Communication sectors etc. On the other hand, the
evidence of reverse causal relationship shows that social and economic
wellbeing of middle class populace strengthen its ability of being more
participatory in the democratic process--by striving for the achievement
of political rights/freedom, and competing for the public office, so
that to make the democratic process more forte, in reverse, for feasible
FDI policy.
High Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
The findings of causal relationship are mixed in case of high skill
FDI, as shown in Figure 5. In the short run (in the high frequency
areas), and long run (in the low frequency areas) the evidences of
causality from political regimes to high skill FDI indicates that, in
short and long run, political leaders have favoured the high skill
industry in formulating FDI policy regarding FDI distribution across
different sectors of Pakistan economy.
While, after controlling the causal relationship with economic
conditions of the economy, we have made our analysis sturdier and found
that better economic conditions, along with political reasons, are also
responsible for the increase in the volume of FDI in high skill
industry. The existence of reverse causation i.e., from high skill FDI
to political regimes, may also indicate the presence of patron-client
relationship between specific (economic) interest group and political
coalitions.
Aggregated FDI and Political Regimes
Now, finally, we have investigates the GC relationship between
aggregated FDI and political regimes. Figure 7 shows that there exist
time varying bi-directional causal relationship between aggregated FDI
and political regime; running from political regime to FDI, and from FDI
to political regimes. The results are verified by including economic
variable to make clear whether the relationship is direct or there are
any economic reasons that establish this relationship. The prudent
outcomes showed that, along with economic reasons, there are strong
political reasons cause to fetch FDI. The reason may be that the strong
democratic political institutions avoid a number of political risks
including the risks of expropriation and nationalisation that involve
the loss of ownership of transnational firms. Similarly, democratic
governments establish cooperation between states being more credible in
term of dealings with multinationals and by forming Regional Trade
Agreements (RTAs), which permit a high collaboration among
multinationals and the state.
The results are reveal that FDI flows also develop institutions of
a country via improving property rights. Our results are in line with
the findings of Jensen (2013), Zhu (2013), Dorobantu (2010),
Olney(2013), Macdonald (2011), Dang (2013), among others.
6. CONCLUSIONS
The present study have investigated our prime hypothesis--that
whether the political leaders (autocrats/democrats) adjust the FDI
inflows in favour of the (sub)sectors where their majority of voters are
engaged professionally, in order to please the constituencies/voters, to
get their political favour. Using time series data from 1980-2016, we
test this hypothesis, by employing a novel GC in frequency domain
methodology, keeping in view the time varying and cyclical fluctuating
properties of time series data. We have disaggregated the net inflows of
FDI in term of Low/medium/high skill intensive industries of Pakistan
economy, considering the low skill industry the most populous of
low-cost work force, medium skill industry the less populous of
low-skill workers, while high skill industry the least populous of
low-skill workers.
The findings of the study indicate that there are strong economic
reasons causing to affect the FDI inflows in the low skill intensive
industry/sectors. While, in high skilled industrial sector, besides some
significant economic factors, historically the political leaders have
favoured their constituencies in short as well as in long run, to uplift
the economic condition of middle working class in order to sustain their
political reliability, and to drive the political power from supporters
who are benefited from the investment of the transnational firms. While
in the authoritarian regimes, where autocrats have found it hard to
balance the economic power, and undermine the privileged position of
median voters resulted in upsetting FDI distribution in favour of
wealthy domestic elites. The findings of the study leaves a vibrant
massage that economic planners should focus on regional cooperation and
collaboration via feasible FDI policy keeping in view the economic
structure and position of the Pakistan economy in order to achieve
sustainable and inclusive economic development, and to enrich the
political power of people for strengthening the democratic process.
Muhammad Zahir Faridi, and Ghulam Murtaza <GM.QAUI@gmail.com>
are affiliated with School of Economics, Bahauddin Zakariya University,
Multan. Rabia Nazir is Assistant Professor, Islamia University of
Bahawalpur and PhD scholar at Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics, Islamabad. Fareeha Armaghan is Sr. Project Manager, HEC, and
PhD scholar at Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Alesina, A. and D. Dollar (2000) Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and
Why? Journal of Economic Growth 5:1, 33-63.
Alfaro, L., S. Kalemli-Ozcan, and V. Volosovych (2008) Why
Doesn't Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries? An Empirical
Investigation. The Review of Economics and Statistics 90:2, 347-368.
Antweiler, W. and D. Trefler (2002) Increasing Returns and All
That: A View from Trade. The American Economic Review 92:1, 93-119.
Baum, M. A. and D. A. Lake (2003) The Political Economy of Growth:
Democracy and Human Capital. American Journal of Political Science 47:2,
333-347.
Buthe, T. and H. V. Milner (2008) The Politics of Foreign Direct
Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through
International Trade Agreements? American Journal of Political Science
52:4, 741-762.
Buthe, T. and H. V. Milner (2009) Bilateral Investment Treaties and
Foreign Direct Investment: A Political Analysis. The Effect of Treaties
on Foreign Direct Investment: Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double
Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows, 171-225.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. and M. Gene (2008) Transforming Disadvantages
into Advantages: Developing-Country MNEs in the Least Developed
Countries. Journal of International Business Studies 39:6, 957-979.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. P. A. and P. D. C. L. A. Dau (2009) Structural
Reform and Firm Exports. Management International Review 49:4, 479-507.
Dorobantu, S. P. R. (2010) Political Competition and the Regulation
of Foreign Direct Investment. Doctoral dissertation, Duke University.
Garrett, G. (1998) Partisan Politics in the Global Economy.
Cambridge University Press.
Gehlbach, S. and P. Keefer (2011) Investment without Democracy:
Ruling-party Institutionalization and Credible Commitment in
Autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics 39:2, 123-139.
Hansen, W. L. and N. J. Mitchell (2000) Disaggregating and
Explaining Corporate Political Activity: Domestic and Foreign
Corporations in National Politics. American Political Science Review
94:04, 891-903.
Harms, P. and H. W. Ursprung (2002) Do civil and Political
Repression Really Boost Foreign Direct Investments? Economic Inquiry
40:4, 651-663.
Hillman, A. L. and H. W. Ursprung (1988) Domestic Politics, Foreign
Interests, and International Trade Policy. The American Economic Review
729-745.
Javorcik, B. S. and S. J. Wei (2009) Corruption and Cross-border
Investment in Emerging Markets: Firm-level Evidence. Journal of
International Money and Finance 28:4, 605-624.
Jensen, N. (2008) Political Risk, Democratic Institutions, and
Foreign Direct Investment. The Journal of Politics 70:04, 1040-052.
Jensen, N. M. (2003) Democratic Governance and Multinational
Corporations: Political Regimes and Inflows of Foreign Direct
Investment. International Organization 57:03, 587-616.
Jensen, N. M., and S. Schmith (2005) Market Responses to Politics;
The Rise of Lula and the Decline of the Brazilian Stock Market.
Comparative Political Studies 38:10, 1245-1270.
Keefer, P. and D. Stasavage (2003) The Limits of Delegation: Veto
Players, Central Bank Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary
Policy. American Political Science Review 97:03, 407-423.
Khan, A. H. and Y. H. Kim (1999) Foreign Direct Investment in
Pakistan: Policy Issues and Operational Implications.
Khan, M. A. and S. A. Khan (2011) Foreign Direct Investment and
Economic Growth in Pakistan: A Sectoral Analysis. (Working Papers and
Research Reports 2011).
Kinda, T. (2010) Investment Climate and FDI in Developing
Countries: Firm-level Evidence. World Development 38:4, 498-513.
Li, Q. and A. Resnick (2003) Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic
Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows to Developing
Countries. International Organization 57:01, 175-211.
Long, C., J. Yang, and J. Zhang (2015) Institutional Impact of
Foreign Direct Investment in China. World Development 66, 31-48.
Madani, S. and M. Nobakht (2014) Political Regimes and FDI Inflows:
Empirical Evidence from Upper Middle Income Countries. Journal of
Finance and Economics 2:3, 75-82.
Markusen, J. R., J. R. Melvin, K. E. Maskus, and W. Kaempfer (1995)
International Trade: Theory and Evidence (No. 21989). University Library
of Munich, Germany.
Mathur, A. and K. Singh (2013) Foreign Direct Investment,
Corruption and Democracy. Applied Economics 45:8, 991-1002.
Milner, H. V. and B. Mukherjee (2009) Democracy and the Skill-Bias
in Trade Policy in Developing Countries. Available at SSRN 2182080.
Milner, H. V. and K. Kubota (2005) Why the Move to Free Trade?
Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries. International
Organization 59:01, 107-143.
Mina, W. M. (2012) The Institutional Reforms Debate and FDI Flows
to the MENA Region: The "Best" Ensemble. World Development
40:9, 1798-1809.
Morrow, J. D., B. B. De Mesquita, R. M. Siverson, and A. Smith
(2008) Retesting Selectorate Theory: Separating the Effects of W from
other Elements of Democracy. American Political Science Review 102:03,
393-400.
Mosley, L. (2003) Global Capital and National Governments.
Cambridge University Press.
Mundell, R. A. (1957) International Trade and Factor Mobility. The
American Economic Review 47:3, 321-335.
North, D. C. and B. R. Weingast (1989) Constitutions and
Commitment: The Evolution of' Institutions Governing Public Choice
in Seventeenth-Century, England. The Journal of Economic History 49:04,
803-832.
Nunn, N. (2007) Relationship-Specificity, Incomplete Contracts, and
the Pattern of Trade. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 569-600.
Olney, W. W. (2013) A Race to the Bottom? Employment Protection and
Foreign Direct Investment. Journal of International Economics 91:2,
191-203.
Olson, M. (1993) Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. American
Political Science Review 87:03, 567-576.
Oneal, J. R. (1994) The Affinity of Foreign Investors for
Authoritarian Regimes. Political Research Quarterly 47:3, 565-588.
Pandya, S. S. (2007) Trading Spaces: Political Economy of Foreign
Direct Investment Regulation, 1963-2000. Doctoral dissertation, Harvard
University, Cambridge, Mass.
Pinto, P. M. (2004) Domestic Coalitions and the Political Economy
of Foreign Direct Investment. Unpublished Ph. D. Dissertation,
University of California, San Diego.
Pinto, P. M. and S. M. Pinto (2008) The Politics of Investment
Partisanship: And the Sectoral Allocation of Foreign Direct Investment.
Economics and Politics 20:2, 216-254.
Resnick, A. L. (2001) Investors, Turbulence, and Transition:
Democratic Transition and Foreign Direct Investment in Nineteen
Developing Countries. International Interactions 27:4, 381-398.
Rodrik, D. (2008) Second-best Institutions. American Economic
Review 98:2, 100-104. Schulz, H. (2009) Political Institutions and
Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries: Does the Sector
Matter? Available at SSRN 1403983.
Straub, S. (2008) Opportunism, Corruption and the Multinational
Firm's Mode of Entry. Journal of International Economics 74:2,
245-263.
Tsebelis, G. (1999) Veto Players and law production in
Parliamentary Democracies: An Empirical Analysis. American Political
Science Review 93:03, 591-608.
Weingast, B. R. (1995) The Economic Role of Political Institutions:
Market-preserving Federalism and Economic Development. Journal of Law,
Economics, and Organization 1-31.
Yeaple, S. R. (2003) The Role of Skill Endowments in the Structure
of US Outward Foreign Direct Investment. Review of Economics and
Statistics 85:3, 726-734.
Zhu, B. (2012) Essays on the Political Economy of Foreign Direct
Investment. PhD. Thesis, The Graduate School of Arts and Sciences,
Columbia University.
(1) See [Jensen (2008), p. 9, 81; Harms and Ursprung (2002); Jensen
and Schmith (2005); Olson (1993); Weingast (1995); North and Weingast
(1989); Tsebelis (1999); Keefer and Stasavage (2003) and Straub (2008)].
(2) The results of ADF and PP unit root tests, and tests for
co-integration are not reported here in the study, as it is beyond the
scope of this study, yet are available on demand.
Caption: Fig. 2.1. Low Skill Intensive FDI Inflows in Pakistan
(Million $)
Caption: Fig. 2.2. Medium Skill Intensive FDI Inflows in Pakistan
(Million $)
Caption: Fig. 2.3. High Skill Intensive FDI Inflows in Pakistan
(Million $)
Caption: Fig. 1. Low Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 2. Low Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 3. Medium Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 4. Medium Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 5. High Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 6. High Skill Intensive FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 7. Aggregated FDI and Political Regimes
Caption: Fig. 8. Aggregated FDI and Political Regimes
Table 4.1
Skill Intensity of Industries/(Sub)Sectors
Industries/Sub-sectors Skill Intensity
Low Skill Intensive FDI Sectors/Economic Group
* Food, Beverages Tobacco Low Skill Intensive
* Sugar Low Skill Intensive
* Textiles Low Skill Intensive
* Leather and Leather Products Low Skill Intensive
* Rubber and Rubber Products Low Skill Intensive
* Cernent Low Skill Intensive
* Basic Metals Low Skill Intensive
* Metal Products Low Skill Intensive
* Construction Low Skill Intensive
* Trade Low Skill Intensive
* Tourism Low Skill Intensive
* Others Low Skill Intensive
Industries/Sub-sectors Skill Intensity
Medium Skill Intensive FDI Sectors/Economic Group
* Electronics Medium Skill Intensive
* Chemicals, Pharmaceuticals Medium Skill Intensive
and Fertilisers
* Petro Chemicals and Medium Skill Intensive
Petroleum Refining
* Electrical Machinery Medium Skill Intensive
* Paper and Pulp Medium Skill Intensive
* Transport Equipment Medium Skill Intensive
* Transport, Storage and
Communication
High Skill Intensive FDI Sectors/Economic Group
* Financial Business High Skill Intensive
* Machinery other than Electrical High Skill Intensive
* Mining and Quarrying-Oil and Gas High Skill Intensive
* Power High Skill Intensive
* Social and Personal Services High Skill Intensive
COPYRIGHT 2017 Reproduced with permission of the Publications Division, Pakistan Institute of Development Economies, Islamabad, Pakistan.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2017 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.