MEASURING THE WORLD NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST.
Wynne, Mark A. ; Zhang, Ren
MEASURING THE WORLD NATURAL RATE OF INTEREST.
I. INTRODUCTION
The natural rate of interest--also sometimes referred as a neutral
or real equilibrium rate of interest--is commonly defined as the real
short-term rate of interest consistent with stable inflation and output
equal to potential. It is one of the key concepts for interpreting
macroeconomic relationships and the effects of monetary policy. For
example, it provides a metric for the stance of the monetary policy,
which is expansionary (contractionary) when the real interest rate is
below (above) the natural rate. Thus, monetary policy makers have a deep
interest in estimating the level of the natural interest rate. (1)
Most of the previous work on this topic estimates the natural rate
for only a single country or a specific area of the world such as the
European Union. However, in light of the increasing degree of global
economic integration, measuring the global natural rate is of some
interest. This article tries to make a contribution in this direction.
We assume that the world is fully integrated and ask the following
questions: How has the world natural rate evolved over the past half
century? Does it exhibit a similar pattern to the natural rate in the
United States? What are the main contributors to historical fluctuations
in the world natural rate? Does it tell us anything about the
international interaction between the United States and the rest of the
world?
In order to answer the questions above, we broadly apply a commonly
used methodology first proposed by Laubach and Williams (2003) to the
world, proxied by an aggregate of 20 advanced economies over the period
1961-2015. (2) Laubach and Williams use a state-space model to estimate
the unobservable natural rate from observed output, inflation, and
interest rate data by specifying a couple of simple macroeconomic
relationships including a crucial natural rate equation relating the
natural rate of interest to the trend rate of potential output growth,
an investment/saving (IS) curve relating the output gap to the deviation
of real interest rate from its natural level, and a Phillips curve that
links the inflation rate to the deviation of output from potential.
Our specification and estimation deviate from the original Laubach
and Williams model in a couple of ways. First, we omit import prices
from our Phillips curve specification since we are interested in global
aggregates and the world does not trade with anyone. For the same
reason, the FRB/U.S. imported oil price in Laubach-Williams'
Phillips curve is replaced with the world oil price proxied by the price
of West Texas Intermediate crude oil. Second, we apply standard maximum
likelihood methods to estimate the trend growth shock instead of the
medium unbiased estimator proposed by Stock and Watson (1998). We do so
because shocks to world trend growth are bigger than the respective
individual country shocks, so that standard maximum likelihood methods
do not suffer from the "pile-up problem" (Stock 1994) as by
Laubach and Williams (2003). Third, while implementing the Kaiman
filter/smoother algorithm, we set the conditional expectation and
covariance matrix of the initial states with a diffuse prior instead of
the generalized least squares (GLS hereafter) method proposed by Harvey
(1989) because the latter tends to exacerbate the "pile-up
problem."
There are several main findings to highlight. First, the world
neutral interest rate has been declining for the past half century in a
similar pattern as the trend growth rate of potential output. The trend
potential output growth can explain over a quarter of the forecast error
variance of the natural rate at all finite horizons. Nevertheless,
consistent with Hamilton et al. (2016), we find that the relationship
between the world natural rate and trend potential output growth is
modest. The point estimate of the parameter that connects the natural
interest rate with the trend growth rate is 0.458, which is less than
half of Laubach and Williams' estimate of its U.S. counterpart and
is not statistically significant. In addition, our estimates of the
output gap pick up the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) recession turning points quite accurately. The
estimation of the IS curve indicates that the world natural rate gap
imposes a significant contractionary pressure on the world output gap.
Last, the Phillips curve indicates that the world output gap has a
significantly positive effect on the global inflation, which shows that
the short-run output-inflation trade-off exists at the global level.
II. MODEL SPECIFICATION
Our benchmark model broadly follows Laubach and Williams (2003).
The key motivating equation in Laubach and Williams (2003) is the
following version of the relationship between the real rate of interest
(r) and the growth rate of consumption ([g.sub.c]) that falls out of
almost any intertemporal household optimization problem:
(1) r = [sigma][g.sub.c] + [theta],
where [sigma] is the inverse of intertemporal elasticity of
substitution and 0 is the pure rate of time preference. Laubach and
Williams use this theoretical relationship to motivate a relationship
between the unobserved natural rate of interest ([r.sup.*.sub.t]) and
the annualized trend growth rate of potential output ([g.sub.t]):
(2) [r.sup.*.sub.t] = [cg.sub.t] + [z.sub.t],
where [z.sub.t] captures other determinants of the natural rate of
interest such as time preference, fiscal policy, and so on.
The dynamics of the output gap are described by a backward-looking
IS equation, where the output gap ([[??].sub.t]) (defined as the
percentage deviation of real output [[y.sub.t]] from potential output
[[y.sup.*.sub.t]]) is determined by its own lags, the lagged deviation
of the real short-term interest rate ([r.sub.t]) from the equilibrium
real interest rate ([r.sup.*.sub.t]) and a serially uncorrected shock
([[epsilon].sub.1t]):
(3) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
where the ex-ante real interest rate ([r.sub.t]) is constructed by
subtracting the expected inflation rate ([E.sub.t] [[pi].sub.t+1]) from
the nominal interest rate ([R.sub.t]).
The core consumption price inflation rate ([[pi].sub.t]) is assumed
to be determined by its own lags, the lagged output gap ([[??].sub.t-1])
and the crude oil price inflation rate ([[pi].sup.O.sub.t]) (as a proxy
for global supply shocks) and a serially uncorrelated shock
([[epsilon].sub.2t]):
(4) [[pi].sub.t] = [B.sub.[pi]] (L)[[pi].sub.t-1] +
[b.sub.3][[??].sub.t-1] + [b.sub.4] ([[pi].sup.o.sub.t-1] -
[[pi].sub.t-1]) + [[epsilon].sub.2t].
For parsimony, we restrict the coefficients on the lagged inflation
terms--not rejected in our sample--to sum to one. This implies that the
trade-off between output and inflation exists only in the short run. We
also assume that the coefficients on the second through fourth lags are
equal to each other, as are the coefficients on the fifth to eighth
lags, that is, [B.sub.[pi]] (L) [[pi].sub.t-1] = [b.sub.1]
[[pi].sub.t-1] + [b.sub.2] [[summation].sup.4.sub.i=2] [[pi].sub.t-i]/3
+ (1 - [b.sub.1] - [b.sub.2]) [[summation].sup.8.sub.i=5]
[[pi].sub.t-i]/4. This specification is similar to the Phillips curve
equation in Laubach and Williams (2003), except that we omit the core
import price inflation term, which they include in their specification,
and replace the imported oil price with a measure of the global oil
price.
Equations (3) and (4) are the measurement equations of our state
space model. Turning to the transition equations, we assume that the
variable [z.sub.t] representing the non-trend-growth determinants of the
natural rate in Equation (2) follows a random walk:
(5) [z.sub.t] - [z.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.3t].
The potential output ([y.sup.*.sub.t]) and annualized trend growth
rate of potential output ([g.sub.t]) are given by:
(6) [y.sup.*.sub.t] = [y.sup.*.sub.t-1] + 0.25[g.sub.t-1] +
[[epsilon].sub.4t],
(7) [g.sub.t] = [g.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.5t].
We scale the annualized trend growth rate g, by 0.25 (as by Trehan
and Wu 2007) because our output data are quarterly. We assume that the
shocks [[epsilon].sub.1t] through [[epsilon].sub.5t] are serially
uncorrected and uncorrected with one another. The assumption that
potential output evolves according to a random walk with drift can be
traced to the seminal papers by Kuttner (1992, 1994) who first proposed
the use of an unobserved components approach to the modeling of
potential output. Kuttner in turn motivated this assumption with a
reference to Watson (1986), and, implicitly, to the enormously
influential paper of Nelson and Plosser (1982) which argued that many
macroeconomic time series were better characterized as difference
stationary rather than trend stationary series. In a basic real business
cycle model with perfect competition and flexible prices, the levels of
potential and actual output will coincide. Potential output in a New
Keynesian model of the sort that implicitly underlies the Laubach and
Williams specification is essentially the flexible price level of output
of a real business cycle model. The main difference between our
specification and that of Kuttner is that we allow the long-run trend
rate of growth g to vary over time also (and specifically, to evolve as
a random walk without drift). The rationale for this assumption is that
the long-run trend rate of growth of actual output has shown a tendency
to change over time, and presumably this also reflects changes in the
rate of trend. Potential output growth rates were a lot higher in
Germany and Japan in the decades following the destruction of World War
II than they have been since. Productivity growth (a key determinant of
long-run growth) was a lot higher in most advanced economies in the
quarter century up to 1973 than in the two decades after 1973. And
growth in most advanced economies has been a lot slower in the years
since the global financial crisis of 2007-2008 than in the years that
preceded it.
As detailed in Appendix A, the model can be expressed in the form
of a state-space model:
(8) [Y.sub.t] = H[S.sub.t] +A[X.sub.t] + [u.sub.t]
and
(9) [S.sub.t] = F[S.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t],
where [mathematical expression not reproducible]
In applying the Kaiman filter to the model, standard maximum
likelihood estimation of [[sigma].sub.3], the standard deviation of the
shock to [z.sub.t], is biased towards zero because of the so-called
"pile-up problem," which usually arises when the shock to the
random walk process is of small size. (3) Accordingly, our estimation
proceeds in two steps. In the first step, we use the median unbiased
estimator proposed by Stock and Watson (1998) to estimate the noise to
signal ratio [[lambda].sub.z] =
[a.sub.3]([[sigma].sub.3]/[[sigma].sub.1]). In the second step, we
impose the estimated value of [[lambda].sub.z] obtained in the previous
step and estimate the remaining model parameters with standard maximum
likelihood methods. (4)
The above estimation procedure deviates from the three-step method
designed by Laubach and Williams (2003). Laubach and Williams (2003)
find that the U.S. trend growth shock is small, so that the standard
maximum likelihood estimates of the standard deviation of the trend
growth shock ([[sigma].sub.5]) suffers from the "pile-up
problem." Accordingly, they include an extra step to estimate the
ratio [[lambda].sub.g] = [[sigma].sub.5]/ [[sigma].sub.4] with Stock and
Watson's median unbiased estimation method and impose that ratio in
latter steps. However, as we will show later, the world trend growth
shock exhibits more volatility than the U.S. trend growth shock
estimated by Laubach and Williams (2003), and is immune to the
"pile-up problem." Thus, we skip the extra step and estimate
the standard error of the trend growth shock together with other
parameters simultaneously using the standard maximum likelihood method
instead.
III. DATA
The model is estimated using quarterly data for the world from
1959Q1 to 2015Q4. Due to data availability, we proxy the world by an
aggregate of 20 advanced economies: Canada, France, Germany, Italy,
Japan, United Kingdom, United States, Australia, Austria, Belgium,
Finland, Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, South Korea,
Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. These 20 countries account for a
substantial fraction of global economic activity. Moreover, the set of
countries are all market economies and exhibit a high degree of economic
and financial integration with each other, which justifies the
assumption underlying our model. The practice of proxying the world with
an aggregate of a group of mainly industrialized economies has a long
precedent in the open economy macroeconomics literature. A good recent
example of this is the paper by King and Low (2014) where they present
estimates of what they call the "world" real interest rate
based on data from government bonds that are issued with inflation
protection by the G7 countries. (In fact, their preferred estimates use
data from only six of the countries on the grounds that the real rate
for Italy may have been unduly influenced by issues related to the
potential for default or exit from European Economic and Monetary
Union.) Ciccarelli and Mojon (2010) present estimates of what they term
"global" inflation based on data for 22 mainly advanced OECD
countries. D'Agostino and Surico (2009) ask whether
"global" liquidity can help forecast U.S. inflation, and then
define "global" liquidity in terms of growth rates of measures
of broad money for the G7 economies. There are many other examples.
Nevertheless, we recognize that major emerging market economies,
especially the BRICS (Brazil, Russia, India, China and [sometimes] South
Africa), have played an increasingly important role in the global
economy in recent decades. But including those countries into the
analysis is challenging for a variety of reasons. The first has to do
with history. Our sample period runs from 1959 through 2015. For more
than half of that period, countries like China and Russia simply did not
participate in the global economy in any meaningful way. Things began to
change gradually in China in the late 1970s and in Russia in the early
1990s. Second, to the extent that these countries did become integrated
into the global economy in the 1990s, it was primarily through trade
rather than financial linkages. Financial globalization (as proxied by
growth in Lane and Milesi-Ferretti's 2007 estimates of foreign
assets and foreign liabilities as a share of gross domestic product
[GDP]) has proceeded at a much faster pace among the industrial
countries than it has among the developing countries. Many developing
and emerging market economies still have extensive capital controls in
place. For example, the recent paper by Rebucci et al. (2015) classifies
the degree of openness/closedness of the capital account of different
countries as being either "open," having controls that amount
to a "gate" or having controls that amount to a
"wall." Brazil and Russia fall in the gate category, while
China and India are classified as having controls that amount to walls.
According to the classification presented in their paper, no major
developing or emerging market economy falls in the "open"
category. Third, for many developing or emerging market economies,
consistent time series data only become available in the early 1990s.
And even then, many of these countries tended to experience extreme
events. For example, Brazil experienced a hyperinflation in the early
1990s and another episode of very high inflation in the early 2000s.
Mexico also experienced episodes of very high inflation in the early
1980s, in the late 1980s, and then again in the mid-1990s (in the
aftermath of the Tequila Crisis.) Annual inflation in Turkey did not
fall below 25% between the 1980s and the early part of this century, and
peaked at rates in excess of 125% in the mid-1990s, and so on. However,
in our robustness discussion below we explore the sensitivity of our
estimates of the world real rate to the inclusion of such data for the
BRICS as is available.
The aggregated GDP data for our baseline estimation are constructed
by adding up the GDP series (measured in constant purchasing power
parity [PPP] dollars) of each individual country. The nominal world
interest rate and inflation rate are derived by taking weighted averages
of the corresponding indicators for individual countries with the
time-varying PPP-adjusted GDP shares displayed in Figure 1 as the
weights. (5) The GDP shares are calculated by the ratios of the real GDP
of the individual countries to the aggregated GDP of the 20 countries
included in our sample. We compute the expectation of world inflation
rate four quarters ahead from a univariate autoregression (AR) (Berger
and Kempa 2014) model of inflation estimated over the 80 quarters prior
to the date at which expectations are being formed. (6) Then, we
construct the ex-ante real interest rate by subtracting the world
expected inflation from the nominal world interest rate. We use the West
Texas Intermediate oil price as a measure of the global oil price. The
sources and construction of the data are detailed in Appendix B.
IV. RESULTS
The second column of Table 1 reports the estimates of parameters.
While our data start in 1959Q1, our estimates start in 1961Q1 because of
the lags in the model. To facilitate comparison with previous studies of
U.S. natural rate, we also update the estimation of the model in Laubach
and Williams (2003) to 2015Q4, with the parameter estimates listed in
the third column of Table 1. (7)
Similar to other individual country studies, we find the world
output gap to be a fairly persistent process. The summation of the
autoregressive parameters in the IS equation, [a.sub.1] and [a.sub.2],
is as high as 0.922. The coefficient relating the output gap to the real
rate gap ([a.sub.3]) is negative and statistically significant, which
indicates that a positive world real interest rate gap is indeed
contractionary.
In terms of the evidence on inflation, we find that the slope of
the Phillips curve ([b.sub.3]) is significantly positive as is predicted
by standard economic theory. Our estimated value of [b.sub.3] (0.159) is
four times the size of its U.S. counterpart (0.040). (8) One possible
reason for this is that Phillips curve equations estimated using
individual country data insufficiently capture the role that foreign
slack plays as a driver of domestic inflation dynamics, especially in a
more open economy. Borio and Filardo (2007) argued that the
well-documented decline in the sensitivity of inflation to measures of
domestic slack in recent decades was due in no small part to the rise of
globalization, and showed that proxies for global economic slack
enhanced the explanatory power of traditional Phillips curve
regressions. (9) As the world becomes more integrated through trade and
factor flows, domestic slack should matter less for domestic inflation
dynamics and global slack should matter more. Another way of thinking
about this is in the context of an individual country: inflation in
Texas, for example, depends less on the level of resource utilization or
unemployment in Texas and more on the level of resource utilization or
unemployment in the United States as a whole, seeing as firms in Texas
can access workers and resources across the United States. The reduction
of barriers to international trade and factor movements (primarily
capital) as a result of globalization means that the same should be true
at the international level as well. Martinez-Garcia and Wynne (2010)
formalized this idea in the context of a standard New Keynesian model,
referring to it as the "global slack hypothesis." A direct
corollary of this hypothesis is that the relationship between slack or
the output gap and inflation should be stronger at the global level than
at the domestic level (since the world as a whole is a closed economy),
which is what our parameter estimates suggest.
Lastly, for the natural rate equation, the link between the world
natural rate and the world trend growth is weak. The point estimate of
the parameter c is 0.458, which is only one third of its U.S.
counterpart. By contrast to the U.S. estimate, the parameter c is
insignificantly different from zero, which indicates that the
relationship between the natural rate and the trend growth rate is
modest. This finding is consistent with the findings of Hamilton et al.
(2016), who draw a similar conclusion by studying the simple
cross-country correlation between the average GDP growth rate and the
average real interest rate.
For the estimates of the standard errors, the shock to trend growth
rate ([[epsilon].sub.5]) is more volatile than its U.S. equivalent. The
standard deviation of the trend growth shock ([[sigma].sub.5]) equals
0.171, which is more than four times its U.S. counterpart. The large
size of trend growth shock makes it possible to avoid the "pile-up
problem" in estimating [[sigma].sub.5] which usually arises in
single country studies. On the other hand, the standard deviation of the
other determinants of the natural rate ([[sigma].sub.3]) is 0.127 which
is around one half of the U.S. estimate. The estimates of the standard
errors shed some light on the driving forces underlying the natural
rate. By combining Equations (2), (5), and (7), the natural rate of
interest ([r.sup.*.sub.t]) follows a random walk:
(10) [r.sup.*.sub.t] = [r.sup.*.sub.t-1] + [".sub.rt],
where the shock to the natural rate equation [[epsilon].sub.rt] =
c[[epsilon].sub.5t] + [[epsilon].sub.3t]. Given the estimates above, the
standard deviation of the world natural rate shock [[sigma].sub.r] =
[square root of [c.sup.2] [[sigma].sup.2.sub.5] + [[sigma].sup.2.sub.3]]
is 0.149 while the standard deviation of the corresponding U.S. shock is
0.254. Thus, our estimation suggests that the shock to the world natural
rate is of smaller size than the shock that drives the U.S. natural
rate. Furthermore, the forecast error variance of the natural rate
contributed by the trend growth at all finite horizons, measured by
[c.sup.2] [[sigma].sup.2.sub.5]/ [[sigma].sup.2.sub.r], is 27.6%, which
is much greater than the respective U.S. ratio of 4.8%. Thus, a
substantial amount of the variation in the world natural rate is
contributed by the world trend potential output growth.
Figure 2 plots our two-sided estimates of the world output gap,
where the shaded areas indicate recession periods as defined by the
OECD. (10) It turns out that the estimated output gap picks up the
business cycle turning points quite accurately. The output gap decreases
significantly in each of the OECD recessions. In particular, the world
output gap decreases most sharply during the global oil crisis of
1973M5-1975M5 and 1979M9-1982M12 as well as the recent 2007M12-2009M5
global financial crisis.
Figure 3 displays our two-sided estimates of the growth rate of
potential output in blue dashed lines along with trend growth in black
solid lines. The world potential output growth rate fluctuates around
the trend growth rate as expected. It becomes less volatile between the
mid-1980s and 2007, which corresponds to the so-called Great Moderation
period in the United States. The potential output growth rate reaches
its trough at a historically low value of -1.2 in 2009Q1 during the
global financial crisis, which was the worst recession since World War
II. The world trend growth rate captures the low-frequency movement in
the potential output growth, which has been declining since the
mid-1960s until the recent global financial crisis. The annualized trend
growth rate drops from 4.8% in 1966Q1 to 0.8% in 2009Q1 and then
recovers slowly to 1.2% in 2015Q4 at the end of our sample. Based on the
discussion above, our estimates of the output gap, potential output, and
trend growth are consistent with global economic history, which provides
some support to our estimates of the natural rate.
Figure 4 depicts the two-sided estimates of the natural rate of
interest in black solid lines together with the historical realization
of the exante real interest rate in blue dashed lines. Similar to the
single country estimates of Laubach and Williams (2003), the world
natural rate of interest has been trending down during the past half
century. The declining pattern is also consistent with the world real
yields on 10-year government bonds estimated by King and Low (2014),
which is plotted in red in Figure 4. Based on our estimates, the real
interest rate lies below the natural rate for most of the period prior
to 1980, which has expansionary effects on output. This loose monetary
policy helped raise the global inflation rate in the 1970s as documented
in Ciccarelli and Mojon (2010). In the late 1970s, the central banks in
major advanced economies raised policy rates to fight inflation. The
real interest rate exceeded the natural rate starting in 1980Q2 and the
real interest rate gap reached almost 4.6% points in 1982Q3. This
positive real interest rate gap, signifying the contractionary stance of
world monetary policy, persisted until 2001Q4. The natural rate started
to decline more significantly in the late 1990s and kept falling even as
the real interest rate rose from 2004Q2 to 2007Q3. The divergent
movement in the real interest rate and the natural rate created a big
2.1% point real interest rate gap in 2007Q3, which was followed by the
global financial crisis and the Great Recession. The natural rate drops
to a historically low level of 0.2% in 2009Q3 and then recovers slowly
until the end of our sample in 2015Q4. During and after the Great
Recession, major central banks lowered their policy rates and launched
quantitative easing (QE) programs to support economic activity. In light
of the low natural rate, global monetary policy was not overly
aggressive but necessary to help the world economy recover from the
Great Recession.
The natural rate equation above shows that the world natural rate
is determined by two factors: the world trend growth rate [g.sub.t] and
the other determinant [z.sub.t]. Figure 5 displays the natural rate
along with the contribution of each of the underlying determinants. Most
of the fluctuation in the world natural rate is determined by the trend
growth rate while the other determinant ([z.sub.t]) plays a rather
limited role. This is quite different from the previous estimates of the
U.S. natural rate, where the other determinant ([z.sub.t]) acts as a
significant contributor to the natural rate, especially in recent years
as is shown in Figure 6. A possible explanation to account for such a
difference is that much of the [z.sub.t] for the U.S. natural rate is
contributed by the trend growth of the rest of the world. Nevertheless,
to further verify this possibility requires a two-country model where
the natural rate in the United States is determined by both home country
trend growth and the foreign country trend growth as explored in Wynne
and Zhang (forthcoming), which is beyond the discussion of this article.
V. ROBUSTNESS ANALYSIS
In this section we consider the robustness of our results to a
number of deviations from our baseline specification. First, since our
estimated value of the c parameter differs from what Laubach and
Williams estimated for the United States, we explore the implications
for our estimates of the world natural rate of simply setting the c
parameter equal to the value estimated by Laubach and Williams. We also
explore the implications of setting the value equal to 1, which would
correspond to an assumption of log utility, and follow what Holston,
Laubach, and Williams (2017) do in their international comparison of
natural rate estimates. Second, we explore the implications of
estimating the model in per capita terms given the significant variation
in population growth rates that occurred over our sample period. And
third, we explore the implications of including such limited data as
there are for the BRICS countries.
A. Sensitivity to Different Values of c
Table 2 reports the estimated parameters of the model when we
impose c - 1 or c = 1.321 which is the value we estimate using the
Laubach and Williams methodology on just U.S. data. Note that the
imposition of these different values for c makes very little difference
to the estimated value of the other parameters of the model: some are
the same to the second or third decimal place. However an exception is
[[sigma].sub.3] (the standard deviation of the shock to the other
[nontrend growth] determinants of the natural rate), which increases
from 0.127 to 0.269. Our estimates of the trend growth rate [g.sub.t]
are robust to different values of c. Figure 7 shows the consequences of
imposing the different values for the c parameter for our estimates of
the world natural rate. Perhaps not surprisingly given the results in
Figure 5, the higher imposed values for c generate much higher estimates
of the world natural rate in the earlier part of our sample (when trend
growth rates were much higher) than in the later part of our sample
(when trend growth rates were lower). Comparing the actual real rate of
interest with the natural rate estimated assuming c = 1.321 implies an
extraordinarily accommodative stance of global monetary policy from the
early 1960s through the early 1980s. From about the early 1990s on, the
three sets of estimates track each other closely, at least up to the
onset of the global financial crisis, when they diverge and the
estimates with the higher assumed values for the c parameter become
negative, as do measured real rates. The key feature of the data that
leads the estimated model to prefer a lower value of c appears to be
that while the trends in output growth in the United States and the
world were quite similar over the sample period, real interest rates
exhibited quite different patterns. Specifically, our measures of real
interest rates are a lot higher for the United States during the 1960s
and the 1970s than they are for the world, whereas they are more similar
in the latter half of the sample.
B. Demographics
In our baseline model, we have shown that the natural interest rate
and trend rate of growth of output have been declining over our sample
period. One assumption implicitly underlying the baseline model is that
the population growth is stable across the sample period. However, as
shown in Figure 8, world population growth declined significantly from
an annual rate of 1.2% in 1961 to 0.4% in 2015. In order to examine
whether this considerable shift in demographic factors contributed to
the decline in the trend growth and thus the natural rate, we implement
a robustness check where we redefine [y.sub.t] in the baseline model as
the output per capita. (11)
The third column of Table 3 displays the parameters estimated with
the output per capita data. Most of the parameters are very close to the
baseline case. The exception is the parameter c that connects the
natural rate with the trend growth is now 0.6, which is 31% bigger than
the baseline estimate but still insignificantly different from zero. As
a consequence, trend potential output growth contributes more to the
volatility in the natural rate of interest than in the baseline model.
The unconditional forecast error variance of the natural rate
attributable to trend growth, measured by
[c.sup.2][[sigma].sup.2.sub.5]/ [[sigma].sup.2], rises from 27.6% to
42.8%.
The output gap estimated using the per capita data matches very
closely to the output gap estimated by the baseline model. Moreover, the
trend growth rate of the potential output per capita is lower than the
baseline potential output trend growth rate as expected where the gap
diminishes in recent years as the population grows more slowly. Finally,
Figure 9 shows that the per capita estimates of the natural rate tracks
the baseline estimates very closely for most of history. The two
estimates diverge most substantially in 2009Q1 when the natural rate in
per capita model reaches its trough at 0% compared to 0.2% in the
baseline model. Nevertheless, the baseline estimates of the world
natural rate are by and large robust to the historical demographic
shifts.
C. Inclusion of BRICS
A potentially more significant omission from our analysis is the
failure to include data for the increasingly important BRICS countries
in the global aggregates. As noted above, many of these countries that
account for an increasingly important share of global economic activity
played little or no role in the global economy during the 1960s, 1970s,
and 1980s when the Cold War was at its height. As the Cold War ended and
more countries adopted outward looking policies, these formerly excluded
countries came to play an increasingly important role in the global
economy. However, the transitions were not always smooth: many of these
countries experienced economic crises that limit the usefulness of their
economic data for inclusion in global aggregates. However, by the late
1990s most of these countries had successfully integrated into the
global trading system and were playing a greater role in global economic
developments.
To see how robust our findings are to the broadening of our
definition of the world to include some of the larger emerging market
economies, we re-did our estimation with a sample of 25 countries that
includes in addition to the 20 advanced economies included in our
baseline estimate the five BRICS countries (Brazil, Russia, India,
China, and South Africa). This group of countries accounted for about
17% of global output in 1992, according to International Monetary Fund
(IMF) estimates; by 2015, that share had increased to just under 31%.
(12) Column 4 of Table 3 reports the estimated model parameters when we
include the BRICS in our global aggregate. Note that the sample period
is much shorter than for our baseline model, and only runs from 1999Q1
to 2015Q4. (13) Many of the parameter estimates are qualitatively
similar to our baseline estimates; the most noteworthy change is to the
estimated value of c, which increases from 0.458 using just the data for
the advanced economies to 1.466 using the extended set of countries. The
alternative estimate also happens to be closer to the number estimated
for the United States (shown in Table 1).
Figure 10 shows our measure of the world real interest rate for the
broader grouping of countries along with our estimate of the world
natural rate. Note that the measured world real rate does not go
negative in the post financial crisis period, unlike the rate shown in
Figure 4. Rather it hovers around zero, which is not too surprising as
it is an average of the mainly negative real rates in the advanced
economies and the higher positive real rates in the BRICS. The estimated
world natural rate becomes mildly negative in 2008 but quickly returns
to positive territory and by the end of 2015 was close to 2%. Contrast
that with the estimates shown in Figure 4 for the aggregate based on
just the advanced economies, which was less than 0.5% by the end of
2015.
An obvious question is how much of the difference in the estimates
of the world natural rate shown in Figure 10 is due to the inclusion of
the BRICS countries in the global aggregate, and how much is due to the
estimation of the model using a much shorter sample of data. Figure 11
attempts to shed some light on this question by showing four different
estimates of the world natural rate over the 1999-2015 period: our
baseline estimates from Figure 4 which are based on an aggregate of just
advanced economies (labeled "AE" in Figure 11), our estimates
based on the aggregate that includes the BRICS countries (labeled
"AE + BRICS"), an estimate for the advanced economies
aggregate using the parameter estimates for the full 1961-2015 sample
(labeled "AE-II"), and an estimate for the advanced economies
aggregate based on coefficient estimates for the 1999-2015 period
(labeled "AE-III"). This shows that using the shorter sample
of data makes a significant difference to the estimates of the natural
rate, which should not be too surprising. The period from 1999 to 2015
was different in many ways from the period that preceded it,
incorporating as it does the global financial crisis and the extended
period of ultra-low interest rates that followed it. Thus while we
attribute some of the difference between our baseline estimates and the
estimates based on the aggregates including the BRICS to the inclusion
of the latter group of countries, we also attribute some of the
difference to the shorter sample period.
VI. CONCLUSION
A growing literature utilizes unobserved components models to
estimate the equilibrium rate of interest by means of multivariate
trend-cycle decompositions. However, most such models focus on either an
individual country or a specific area like the European Union. In this
article, we contribute to the literature by jointly estimating the world
natural interest rate, potential output, and the trend growth rate of
potential output using an unobserved components model broadly following
Laubach and Williams (2003). We find that both the world natural
interest rate and the trend potential output growth rate have been
declining significantly in the past 50 years. The global trend growth
rate of potential output contributes substantially to the variation in
the global natural real interest rate. Nevertheless, our estimation
shows that the relationship between the world natural rate and the world
trend growth rate is modest. The estimates of the natural interest rate
are robust even while controlling for demographic shifts.
By comparing the determinants of the natural rate in the United
States and the world, we find that the other determinants of the natural
rate in Laubach and Williams (2003) might be mostly contributed by the
trend growth in the rest of the world. However, formally testing this
inference requires a two-country model (or more likely a multi-country
model), which is beyond the discussion of this article and is left for
future research.
The biggest challenge for future research is properly incorporating
the rapidly growing emerging market economies into the analysis. In our
robustness discussion, we reported the results we obtain when we include
the BRICS countries in our global aggregate and re-estimate our model
over the period 1999-2015. The shorter sample period is dictated by data
availability for these countries and the need to avoid episodes of
extremely high inflation. While the results we obtain are plausible, it
is hard to disentangle the effects on our estimates of broadening the
aggregate to include the BRICS countries from the consequences of
working with a much shorter sample of data. Our guess is that the most
fruitful way forward may be to use an unbalanced panel framework with
time varying coefficients.
APPENDIX A. THE STATE-SPACE REPRESENTATION OF THE MODEL
Space form:
(Al) [Y.sub.t] = H[S.sub.t] + A[X.sub.t] + [u.sub.t]
(A2) [S.sub.t] = F[S.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t].
Here, [Y.sub.t] and [X.sub.t] are respectively vectors of
contemporaneous endogenous, and of exogenous and predetermined
variables. [S.sub.t] is the vector of unobserved states. The vectors of
stochastic disturbance [u.sub.t] and [v.sub.t] are assumed to be
Gaussian and mutually uncorrected with mean zero and covariance matrices
R and Q, respectively.
The vector of observables [Y.sub.t] is given by:
(A3) [Y.sub.t] = ([y.sub.t], [[pi].sub.t])',
where [y.sub.t] denotes 100 x log real GDP and [[pi].sub.t] denotes
inflation. The predetermined and exogenous variables are:
(A4) [X.sub.t] = ([y.sub.t], [y.sub.t-1], [y.sub.t-2], [r.sub.t-1],
[r.sub.t-2], [[pi].sub.t-1],
[[pi].sub.t-2,4][[pi].sub.t-5,8][[pi].sup.0.sub.t-l -
[[pi].sub.t-1])' .
where [r.sub.t] is the real interest rate, [[pi].sub.t-j,k] is
shorthand for the moving average of inflation between dates t - k and t
-j and [[pi].sup.0.sub.t] is oil price inflation. The state vector is:
(A5) [S.sub.t] = [y.sup.*.sub.t] - [y.sup.*.sub.t-1],
[y.sup.*.sub.t-2] [g.sub.t-1], [g.sub.t-2], [z.sub.t-1],
[z.sub.t-2])',
where [y.sup.*.sub.t] is 100 xlog potential GDP, [g.sub.t] denotes
the trend growth, and [z.sub.t] represents other determinants of the
natural rate. The coefficient matrices are:
(A6) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
(A7) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
(A8) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
(A9) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
(A10) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
The signal-to-noise ratio [[lambda].sub.z] is estimated with the
median unbiased method introduced in Stock and Watson (1998). Given
[[lambda].sub.z], the vector of parameters to be estimated by maximum
likelihood is [THETA] = ([a.sub.1], [a.sub.2], [a.sub.3], [b.sub.1],
[b.sub.2],[b.sub.3],[b.sub.4], c, [[sigma].sub.1], [[sigma].sub.2],
[[sigma].sub.4] x [[sigma].sub.5]).
APPENDIX B. DATA SOURCES
This appendix describes the data used in this project. The data are
constructed by aggregating quarterly data from 1959Q1 to 2015Q4 for 20
advanced countries: Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United
Kingdom, United States, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Finland, Greece,
Ireland, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, South Korea, Spain, Sweden, and
Switzerland.
The variable y refers to the log of aggregated PPP-adjusted real
GDP (seasonally adjusted at annual rate) measured in millions of 2011
U.S. dollars. The aggregated data are obtained by taking the sum of the
real GDP from each of the individual countries. Except for South Korea,
the PPP-adjusted real GDP data are available from the OECD Quarterly
National Accounts dataset (OECDNAQ) in Haver Analytics. For South Korea,
the PPP-adjusted real GDP data from OECDNAQ only goes back to 1970.
Nevertheless, the real GDP data in local currency from 1960 to 1970 are
available from the Emerging Market dataset (EMERGEPR). We combine the
two series by adjusting the observations of earlier periods with the
formula: [y.sup.EMERGEPR.sub.t]
([y.sup.OECDNAQ.sub.1970Q1]/[y.sup.EMERGEPR.sub.1970Q1]) for f from
1960Q1 to 1969Q4.
The aggregated nominal interest rate is the weighted average of the
quarterly average annualized short-term interest rate in each individual
country using GDP share as the weight. (14) We use the central bank
policy rate for most of the countries. (15) For the rest of the
countries, we use money-market rates instead due to the lack of
availability of the central bank policy rate. For the Eurozone
countries, we splice their old interest rates with the Main Refinancing
Rate in 1999Q1 when the European Central Bank was formed. The only
exception is Greece which joined the Eurozone in 2001 so that we stack
the earlier Bank of Greece Bank Rate with the European Main Refinancing
Rate in 2001Q1.
The aggregated core inflation rate is created by taking a weighted
average of the annualized quarterly growth rate of each country's
seasonally adjusted core consumer price index (CPI) using the GDP share
as weights. For many countries, the core CPI is unavailable back to the
1960s. Statistical agencies only began to develop measures of core
inflation in response to the commodity price shocks of the 1970s. As a
result, we proxy the core CPI inflation rates with the CPI inflation
rate when the former rates are missing.
To construct the ex-ante real interest rate, we compute the
expectation of average aggregate inflation over the four quarters ahead
from a univariate AR (Berger and Kempa 2014) of inflation estimated over
the 80 quarters prior to the date at which expectations are being
formed. In practice, because of the limited sample, for the first 20
years we use the data from 1959 to 1981 to estimate the coefficients of
the AR model. After 1981, the AR model is estimated using a rolling
window with the size fixed at 80 quarters. Finally, the oil price is the
West Texas Intermediate spot oil price (HAVER mnemonic PZTEXP@USECON).
All the data, except for the early CPI of Ireland, (16) are from
Haver Analytics. To facilitate replication of our results, we list the
Haver mnemonics in the following:
Data for Baseline Advanced Economy Estimates
Real GDP. Canada: B156GDPC@OECDNAQ; France: B132GDPC@OECDNAQ;
Germany: B134DPC@ OECDNAQ; Italy: B136GDPC@OECDNAQ; Japan: B15
8GDPC@OECDNAQ; United Kingdom: B112GDPC@OE CDNAQ; United States: BI
11GDPC@0ECDNAQ; Australia: B193GDPC @ OECDNAQ; Austria: B122GDPC @
OECDNAQ; Belgium: B124GDPC@OECDNAQ; Finland: B172GDPC@OECDNAQ; Greece:
B174GDPC@ OECDNAQ; Ireland: B178GDPC@OECDNAQ; Netherlands: B13 8GDPC @
OECDNAQ; Norway: B142GDPC @OECDNAQ; Portugal: B182GDPC@OECDNAQ; South
Korea: S542NGPC @EMERGEPR(prior 1970Q1), B542GDPC@OECDNAQ(post 1970Q1);
Spain: B184GDP C@OECDNAQ; Sweden: B144GDPC@ OECDNAQ; Switzerland:
B146GDPC@OECDNAQ.
Interest Rate. Canada: Central Bank Rate, C156FROS @OECDMEI;
France: Overnight Interbank Rate, C132FRUO@ OECDMEI; Germany: Overnight
Interbank Rate C134IM@IFS; Italy: Discount Rate, C136IC@IFS; Japan:
Tokyo Overnight Call Rate, C158IM@IFS; United Kingdom: Official Bank
Rate, N112RTAR@G10; United States: Federal Funds Rate, BI 11GDPC@DAILY;
Australia: Official Cash Rate, N193RTAR@G10; Austria: Discount Rate,
C122IC@IFS; Belgium: 3-month Interbank Rate, C124IM@IFS; Finland:
Discount Rate, C172IFC@IFS; Greece: Central Bank Rate, C174IC@IFS;
Ireland: short-term facility rate, C178IC@IFS; Netherlands: Discount
Rate (prior 1993Q4) C138IC@IFS, Inter Bank Offer Rate (94Q1-98Q4)
C138FRIO@IFS; Norway: Discount Rate, C142IC@IFS; Portugal: Discount
Rate, C182IC@IFS; South Korea: Discount Rate, C542IFC@IFS; Spain:
Central Bank Rate, C184IC@IFS; Sweden: Overnight Money Rate, C144FRUO@
OECDMEI; Switzerland: Discount Rate, B146IC@IFS; Eurozone (post 1999Q1):
ECB main refinancing Rate, N023RTAR@G10.
Price Index. Canada: CPI (prior 1961Q1), C156CZN@ OECDMEI, Core
CPI, C156CZCN@OECDMEI; France: CPI(prior to 1970Q1), C132CZN @OECDMEI,
Core CPI, C1 32CZCN@OECDMEI; Germany: CPI (prior to 1962Q1), C1
34CZN@OECDMEI, Core CPI, C134CZCN@OECDMEI; Italy: CPI (prior to 1960Q1),
C136CZN@OECDMEI. Core CPI, C136CZCN@OECDMEI; Japan: Core CPI, C134
CZCN@OECDMEI; United Kingdom: CPI (prior to 1970Q1), C112CZN@OECDMEI,
Core CPI, C112CZ CN@OECDMEI; United States: Core CPI, SHIP CXG@G10;
Australia: CPI (prior to 1976Q3), C193 CZN@OECDMEI, Core CPI,
C193CZCN@OECDMEI; Austria: CPI (prior to 1966Q1), C122CZN@OECDMEI, Core
CPI, C122CZCN@OECDMEI Belgium: CPI (prior to 1976Q2), C124CZN@OECDMEI.
Core CPI, C124CZCN@OECDMEI; Finland: Core CPI, C172CZC N@OECDMEI;
Greece: CPI (prior to 1970Q1), C174CZN @ OECDMEI, Core CPI. C174CZCN@OEC
DMEI; Ireland: CPI (prior to 1975Q4), Central Statistics Office of
Ireland, Core CPI, C178CZCN@OECDMEI; Netherlands: CPI(prior 1960Q2),
C138PC@IFS, Core CPI, C138CZCN@OECDMEI; Norway: CPI(prior 1979Q1),
C142CZN @OECDMEI, Core CPI, C142CZCN @OECDMEI; Portugal: CPI (prior
88Q1), C182CZN @ OECDMEI, Core CPI, C182CZCN @ OECDMEI; South Korea
(prior to 1990Q1): C542CZN@OECD MEI, Core CPI. C542CZCN@OECDMEI; Spain:
CPI (prior to 1976Q1), C184CZN@OECDMEI, Core CPI, C184CZCN@OECDMEI;
Sweden: CPI (prior to 1970Q1), C144CZN@OECDMEI, Core CPI, C144CZCN@OECD
MEI; Switzerland: Core CPI, C146CZCN@OECDMEI. (17)
Population. Canada: C156TB@UNPOP; France: C132TB@UNPOP: Germany:
C134TB@UNPOP; Italy: C136TB@UNPOP; Japan: C158TB@UNPOP; United Kingdom:
C112TB@UNPOP; United States: C111TB@UN POP; Australia: C193TB@UNPOP;
Austria: C122TB@UN POP; Belgium: C124TB@UNPOP; Finland: C172TB@UN POP;
Greece: C174TB@UNPOP; Ireland: C178TB@UN POP; Netherlands: C138TB@UNPOP;
Norway: C142TB@ UNPOP; Portugal: C182TB@UNPOP; South Korea:
C542TB@UNPOP; Spain: C184TB@UNPOP; Sweden: C144TB@UNPOP; Switzerland:
C146TB@UNPOP.
Datafor BRICS
Real GDP. The OECD Quarterly National Accounts database in HAVER
includes estimates of PPP-adjusted real GDP in levels for Brazil, India,
and South Africa: Brazil: C223GDPC@OECDNAQ (from 1996Q1); India:
G534GDPC@OECDNAQ (from 1996Q2); South Africa: E199GDPC@OECDNAQ (from
1960Q1). PPP-adjusted real GDP data in USD for Russia and China are not
available directly in the OECDNAQ database. We construct these series
using each country's share of global GDP based on PPP as reported
in the IMFWEO database, specifically, series A922GPPS@ IMFWEO (Russia)
and A924GPPS@ IMFWEO (China) and then use each country's GDP share
in 2011 to back out its real GDP in 2011 and infer the whole GDP series
based on their real GDP denominated in local currency.
Interest Rate. Brazil: Federal Funds Rate, C223FRAD@0 ECDMEI;
Russia: Discount Rate, C922FROS@OECDMEI; India: Discount Rate,
C534IFC@IFS; China: Discount Rate, C924IFC@IFS; South Africa: Discount
Rate, C199IC@IFS.
Price Index. Brazil: Core CPI, C223PCX@EMERGELA; Russia: CPI excl
food, C922CGFN@OECDMEI (prior 2003Q1), Core CPI, H922PCX@EMERGECW;
India: CPI (prior to 2006Q1), C534CZN@OECDMEI, Core CPI. N534PCXG
@EMERGEPR; China: CPI (prior to 2005Q1), H924PC@EMERGE, CoreCPI,
H924PCXZ@EMERGEPR; South Africa: CPI (prior to 2002Q1), H199PC@EMERGE,
Core CPI, N199PCXG@ EMERGE.
ABBREVIATIONS
AE: Advanced Economies
AR: Autoregression
BRICS: Brazil, Russia, India, China and (sometimes) South Africa
CPI: Consumer Price Index
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
GLS: Generalized Least Squares
IMF: International Monetary Fund
IS: Investment/Saving
LW: Laubach-Williams
OECD: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
PPP: Purchasing Power Parity
QE: Quantitative Easing
REFERENCES
Balakrishnan, R., and S. Ouliaris. "U.S. Inflation Dynamics:
What Drives Them over Different Frequencies?" IMF Working Paper,
No. 06/159, 2006.
Barsky, R., A. Justiniano, and L. Melosi. "The Natural Rate of
Interest and Its Usefulness for Monetary Policy." American Economic
Review: Papers & Proceedings, 104(5), 2014, 37-43.
Berger, T., and B. Kempa. "Time-Varying Equilibrium Rates in
Small Open Economies: Evidence for Canada." Journal of
Macroeconomics, 39, 2014, 203-14.
Borio, C., and A. Filardo. "Globalisation and Inflation: New
Cross-Country Evidence on the Global Determinants of Domestic
Inflation." BIS Working Papers No. 227, 2007.
Ciccarelli, M., and B. Mojon. "Global Inflation." Review
of Economics and Statistics, 92(3), 2010, 524-35.
Clark, T., and S. Kozicki. "Estimating Equilibrium Real
Interest Rates in Real Time." North American Journal of Economics
and Finance, 16, 2005, 395-413.
Curdia, V., A. Ferro, G. Ng, and A. Tambalotti. "Has U.S.
Monetary Policy Tracked the Efficient Interest Rate?" Journal of
Monetary Economics, 70, 2015, 72-83.
D'Agostino, A., and P. Surico. "Does Global Liquidity
Help to Forecast U.S. Inflation?" Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 41(2-3), 2009, 479-89.
Gamber, E., and J. Hung. "Has the Rise in Globalization
Reduced U.S. Inflation in the 1990s?" Economic Inquiry, 39, 2001,
58-73.
Hamilton, J., E. Harris, J. Hatzius, and K. West. "The
Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present and Future." IMF
Economic Review, 64(4), 2016, 660-707.
Harvey, A. Structural Time Series Models and the Kaiman Filter.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
Holston, K., T. Laubach, and J. Williams. "Measuring the
Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants."
Journal of International Economics, 108, 2017, S59-S75.
King, M., and D. Low. "Measuring the 'World' Real
Interest Rate." NBER Working Paper No. 19887, 2014.
Kuttner, K. "Monetary Policy with Uncertain Estimates of
Potential Output." Economic Perspectives, 16, 1992, 2-15.
--. "Estimating Potential Output as a Latent Variable."
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 12, 1994, 361-8.
Lane, P., and G. Milesi-Ferretti. "The External Wealth of
Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and
Liabilities, 1970-2004." Journal of International Economics, 73,
2007, 223-50.
Laubach, T. "Documentation of Gauss Code for 'Measuring
the Natural Rate of Interest'." Manuscript, 2002.
Laubach, T., and J. Williams. "Measuring the Natural Rate of
Interest." Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 2003,
1063-70.
Martinez-Garcia, E., and M. Wynne. "The Global Slack
Hypothesis." Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Staff Papers No. 10,
2010.
Martinez-Garcia, E., V. Grossman, and A. Mack. "A Contribution
to the Chronology of Turning Points in Global Economic Activity."
Journal of Macroeconomics, 46(2015), 2015, 170-85.
Nelson, C., and C. Plosser. "Trends and Random Walks in
Macroeconomic Time Series." Journal of Monetary Economics, 10,
1982, 139-62.
Pescatori, A., and J. Turunen. "Lower for Longer: Neutral
Rates in the United States." IMF Working Paper No. 15/135, 2015.
Razin, A., and C. Yuen. "The 'New Keynesian'
Phillips Curve: Closed Economy versus Open Economy." Economics
Letters, 75, 2002, 1-9.
Rebucci, A., A. Fernandez, M. Schindler, M. Uribe, and M. Klein.
"Capital Control Measures: A New Data Set." IMF Working Paper
No 15/80, 2015.
Stock, J. "Unit Roots, Structural Breaks and Trends," in
Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. 4, edited by R. Engle and D. McFadden.
Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier, 1994, 2739-841.
Stock, J., and M. Watson. "Median Unbiased Estimation of
Coefficient Variance in a Time-Varying Parameter Model." Journal of
the American Statistical Association, 93, 1998, 349-58.
Tootell, G. "Globalization and U.S. Inflation." New
England Economic Review, July/August, 1998, 21-33.
Trehan, B., and T. Wu. "Time-Varying Equilibrium Real Rates
and Monetary Policy Analysis." Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 31, 2007, 1584-609.
Watson. M. "Univariate Detrending Methods with Stochastic
Trends." Journal of Monetary Economics, 18, 1986, 49-75.
Wynne, M., and R. Zhang. "Estimating the Natural Rate of
Interest in an Open Economy." Empirical Economics, Forthcoming.
(1.) See, for example, Laubach and Williams (2003), Clark and
Kozicki (2005), Berger and Kempa (2014), Barsky, Justiniano, and Melosi
(2014), Curdia et al. (2015), Hamilton et al. (2016), Pescatori and
Turunen (2015), and Holston, Laubach, and Williams (2017).
(2.) The 20 advanced countries include Canada, France, Germany,
Italy, Japan, United Kingdom, United States, Australia, Austria,
Belgium, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, South
Korea, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. We limit our definition of the
"world" to an aggregate of these 20 countries due mainly to
data availability issues, although in our robustness analysis we
consider the implications of including the BRICS countries (Brazil,
Russia, India, China, South Africa) in the aggregate for the shorter
time period for which data are available for these countries.
(3.) For more detailed discussion on the "pile-up
problem," see Stock (1994), Stock and Watson (1998) among others.
(4.) To proceed the Kaiman filter/smoother procedure, we need to
set the conditional expectation and covariance matrix of initial states.
In both steps, different from Laubach and Williams (2003), the
conditional expectation and covariance matrix of initial states are set
by diffuse prior instead of the GLS method introduced by Harvey (1989).
There are two reasons for the deviation. First, as is mentioned by
Laubach (2002), the GLS method tends to exacerbate the "pile-up
problem." Second, as in Laubach and Williams (2003), the GLS method
fails in the last step because of singularity problems. Thus, it is more
consistent to use diffuse prior in both steps rather than using GLS
method in the first step while using a diffuse prior in the second step.
(5.) This approach to measuring the world nominal interest rate as
a GDP-weighted average of individual national interest rates is very
much in the spirit of King and Low (2014).
(6.) Due to data availability, before 1981 we use a fixed window of
the data from 1959 to 1981 to estimate the coefficients of the AR model.
After 1981 the AR coefficients are estimated using a rolling window with
the sample size fixed at 80 quarters
(7.) The U.S. natural rate estimated by the Laubach-Williams model
is also updated in real time on the website of the San Francisco Fed.
Our replication matches with their results closely. The slight
difference might arise as a result of the different observation vintage.
Our data are observed in June 2016 as our world natural rate estimates
while the data used by Laubach and Williams for the same sample period
are observed in March 2016.
(8.) The estimates reported by Laubach and Williams (2003) using a
shorter sample of U.S. data range from 0.032 to 0.089.
(9.) Earlier studies of the impact of openness on the Phillips
curve estimates include Tootell (1998), Gamber and Hung (2001), Razin
and Yuen (2002), and Balakrishnan and Ouliaris (2006).
(10.) We use the OECD business cycle chronology for two reasons.
First, our sample of countries is all OECD members and the aggregate of
the 20 countries we select makes up dominant share of the total GDP of
OECD countries. Second, it is the only public source we are aware of
that dates the turning points of global economic activity back to the
1960s. Martinez-Garcia, Grossman, and Mack (2015) provide a global
business cycle chronology for a broader group of countries but their
chronology only begins in 1980.
(11.) Here we assume that this demographic shift is exogenous.
(12.) According to estimates reported in the April 2017 edition of
the IMF's World Economic Outlook.
(13.) While data are available for the BRICS countries from about
the mid-1990s on, we elected to start our sample in 1999 so as to avoid
the high inflation episode in Russia and Brazil in the first half of the
1990s. In Russia inflation was running at rates in excess of 200%. In
Brazil, inflation peaked at 4,922% in June 1994, and the Central Bank of
Brazil's main policy rate reached 132,532%. A second reason for
starting in 1999 rather than earlier is that this date is closer to the
date of China's accession to the World Trade Organization.
(14.) The GDP share is time-varying as is depicted in Figure 1. It
is the ratio between the PPP-adjusted real GDP and the aggregated real
GDP of the 20 countries.
(15.) Specifically, Canada, Italy, United Kingdom, United States,
Australia, Austria, Finland, Greece, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal,
South Korea, Spain, and Switzerland.
(16.) The CPI of Ireland before 1975Q4 is acquired from the Central
Statistics Office of Ireland.
(17.) Except for the United States, we import the
nonseasonal-adjusted price series from the Haver since they have longer
samples. Then we make the seasonal adjustment to the data using Haver
built in function. The early Ireland CPI data are seasonally adjusted by
Tramo-Seats.
MARK A. WYNNE and REN ZHANG *
* The views in this article are those of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or
the Federal Reserve System.
Wynne: Vice President, Research Department. Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas, Dallas, TX 75201. Phone 214-922-5159, Fax 214-922-5194, E-mail
mark.a.wynne@dal.frb.org
Zhang: Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Bowling Green
State University, Bowling Green, OH 43403. Phone 469-394-3198, Fax
419-372-1557, E-mail renz@bgsu.edu
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12500
Online Early publication September 22, 2017
Caption: FIGURE 1 GDP Share: 1960Q1-2015Q4
Caption: FIGURE 2 The World Output Gap: 1961Q1-2015Q4
Caption: FIGURE 3 The World Potential Output Growth and Its Trend
(Annualized)
Caption: FIGURE 4 The World Real Interest Rate and Natural Rate of
Interest
Caption: FIGURE 5 The World Natural Rate and Its Decomposition
Caption: FIGURE 6 The U.S. Natural Rate and Its Decomposition
Caption: FIGURE 7 The World Natural Rate Estimates with Different
Value of Parameter c
Caption: FIGURE 8 Aggregated World Population Growth Rate
Caption: FIGURE 9 The World Real Interest Rate and Natural Rate of
Interest (Per Capita)
Caption: FIGURE 10 The World Real Interest Rate and Natural Rate of
Interest (Including BRICS)
Caption: FIGURE 11 Comparing Different Estimates of the Natural
Interest Rate
TABLE 1
Model Parameter Estimates
Parameters Baseline LW
[a.sub.1] 1.554 (14.56) 1.553 (14.61)
[a.sub.2] -0.632 (5.88) -0.598 (5.71)
[a.sub.3] -0.035 (1.93) -0.058 (3.18)
[b.sub.1] 0.782 (10.94) 0.569 (8.52)
[b.sub.2] 0.114 (1.35) 0.379 (4.34)
[b.sub.3] 0.159 (2.45) 0.040 (1.36)
[b.sub.4] 0.002 (1.81) 0.0025 (2.18)
[b.sub.5] -- 0.036 (3.38)
c 0.458 (1.14) 1.321 (2.22)
[[sigma].sub.1] 0.343 0.360
[[sigma].sub.2] 0.706 0.767
[[sigma].sub.3] = 0.127 0.248
[[lambda].sub.z]
[[sigma].sub.1]/
[a.sub.3]
[[sigma].sub.4] 0.229 0.599
[[sigma].sub.5] 0.171 0.042
[[sigma].sub.r] = 0.149 0.254
[square root of
([c.sup.2]
[[sigma].sup.2
.sub.5] +
[[sigma].sup.2
.sub.3])]
[[lambda].sub.z] 0.013 0.040
[[lambda].sub.g] 0.187 0.017
Notes: t-Statistics are reported in parentheses.
LW, Laubach-Williams.
TABLE 2
Model Parameter Estimates: Robustness Check I
Parameters Baseline c = 1 c = 1.321
[a.sub.1] 1.554 (14.56) 1.543 (14.18) 1.542 (14.10)
[a.sub.2] -0.632 (5.88) -0.621 (5.64) -0.619 (5.58)
[a.sub.3] -0.035 (1.93) -0.023 (1.67) -0.017 (1.48)
[b.sub.1] 0.782 (10.94) 0.781 (10.90) 0.781 (10.91)
[b.sub.2] 0.114 (1.35) 0.116 (1.37) 0.117 (1.38)
[b.sub.3] 0.159 (2.45) 0.161 (2.43) 0.162 (2.43)
[b.sub.4] 0.002 (1.81) 0.002 (1.89) 0.002 (1.89)
[b.sub.5] -- -- --
c 0.458 (1.14) 1 1.321
[[sigma].sub.1] 0.343 0.350 0.352
[[sigma].sub.2] 0.706 0.706 0.706
[[sigma].sub.3] = 0.127 0.198 0.269
[[lambda].sub.z]
[[sigma].sub.1]/
[a.sub.3]
[[sigma].sub.4] 0.229 0.222 0.220
[[sigma].sub.5] 0.171 0.173 0.174
[[sigma].sub.r] = 0.149 0.263 0.354
[square root of
[c.sup.2]
[[sigma].sup.2
.sub.5] +
[[sigma].sup.2
.sub.3]]
[[lambda].sub.z] 0.013 0.013 0.013
[[lambda].sub.g] 0.187 0.195 0.198
Note: t-Statistics are reported in parentheses.
TABLE 3
Model Parameter Estimates: Robustness Check II
Parameters Baseline Per Capita With BRICS
[a.sub.1] 1.554 (14.56) 1.569 (15.41) 1.406 (12.66)
[a.sub.2] -0.632 (5.88) -0.653 (6.24) -0.649 (5.47)
[a.sub.3] -0.035 (1.93) -0.034 (1.94) 0.170 (1.87)
[b.sub.1] 0.782 (10.94) 0.763 (9.91) 0.236 (2.99)
[b.sub.2] 0.114 (1.35) 0.123 (1.44) 0.311 (3.43)
[b.sub.3] 0.159 (2.45) 0.186 (2.25) 0.103 (1.51)
[b.sub.4] 0.002 (1.81) 0.002 (1.84) 0.001 (0.80)
[b.sub.5] -- -- --
c 0.458 (1.14) 0.600 (1.21) 1.466 (3.58)
[[sigma].sub.1] 0.343 0.330 0.339
[[sigma].sub.2] 0.706 0.700 0.515
[[sigma].sub.3] = 0.127 0.116 0.517
[[lambda].sub.z]
[[sigma].sub.1]/
[a.sub.3]
[[sigma].sub.4] 0.229 0.243 0.052
[[sigma].sub.5] 0.171 0.168 0.009
[[sigma].sub.r] = 0.149 0.154 0.517
[square root of
([c.sup.2]
[[sigma].sup.2
.sub.5] +
[[sigma].sup.2
.sub.3])]
[[lambda].sub.z] 0.013 0.012 0.259
[[lambda].sub.g] 0.187 0.174 0.045
Notes: t-Statistics are reported in parentheses.
LW, Laubach-Williams.
COPYRIGHT 2018 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.