THE RELIGIOUS OBSERVANCE OF RAMADAN AND PROSOCIAL BEHAVIOR.
Haruvy, Ernan E. ; Ioannou, Christos A. ; Golshirazi, Farnoush 等
THE RELIGIOUS OBSERVANCE OF RAMADAN AND PROSOCIAL BEHAVIOR.
I. INTRODUCTION
Does alimentary (henceforth, aliments refer to food and fluids)
intake amplify prosocial behavior? Recent physiological research
indicates that self-control, which is necessary for prosocial acts,
requires glucose intake (see Gailliot 2015; Gailliot and Baumeister
2007; Gailliot et al. 2007). Glucose-depleted individuals may profess
greater support for social welfare, but when incentivized they do not
seem to behave in a prosocial manner. Specifically, when these
individuals are asked to redistribute an endowment between themselves
and a recipient, higher blood glucose levels are shown to lead to
greater giving (Aaroe and Petersen 2013). Perhaps, the most striking
field evidence of the association between alimentary intake and
prosocial behavior is from a study on decisions by Israeli judges
(Danziger, Levav, and Avnaim-Pesso 2011). In the study, Israeli judges
are shown more likely to grant a parole or a parolee's request
after a meal break when controlling for the characteristics of the cases
examined.
Given the evidence that alimentary intake is associated with higher
prosocial giving, it might seem strange that major religious festivities
integrate fasting with giving. However, the ritual of fasting may serve
other goals aside from prosocial giving. For instance, it may serve to
strengthen the bond between the individual and God or between the
individual and the religion itself. These aspects of religiosity trigger
different effects on socioeconomic outcomes (see Barro and McCleary
2003; Carpantier and Litina 2014; McCleary and Barro 2006), which
complicate both conceptually and empirically the task of assessing and
identifying their impact on economic decisions. (1)
In this study, we propose a controlled between-subjects'
experiment to investigate the impact on prosocial behavior of the
religious observance of Ramadan, where fasting is part of the ritual.
Ramadan is the ninth month of the Islamic lunar calendar and is
considered sacred as it is the month in which Prophet Muhammad first
received revelations. The month lasts 29-30 days based on the visual
sightings of the crescent moon. Muslims are called upon to use this
month to re-evaluate their lives in light of the Islamic guidance.
Specifically, the observance of Ramadan dictates a well-defined rule of
behavior whereby followers all over the world engage in fasting (Sawm).
Sawm is one of the five Pillars of Islam. The five Pillars are
understood to be obligatory for all Muslim believers and form the
foundation of Muslim life. The other four central tenets consist of: (1)
declaring there is no god except God and Muhammad is God's
Messenger (Shahadah), (2) ritual prayer five times a day (Salat), (3)
giving to the poor and needy (Zakat), and (4) pilgrimage to Mecca
(Hajj). Sawm encompasses abstention from any consumption of aliments
from dawn to sunset during the entire month. Naturally, this entails
physiological consequences. Medical literature has consistently found
body weight loss, significant metabolic changes and symptoms, such as
irritability, headaches, sleep deprivation, and lassitude (see, e.g.,
Ziaee et al. 2006). Furthermore, studies have documented significant
prevalence of individuals reporting tiredness and unwillingness to work
as well as reduced levels of activity and concentration ability (see,
for instance, Karaagaoglu and Yucecan 2000). To date, however, very few
economic studies have been conducted in Islamic countries in the context
of religious observances, such as the month of Ramadan. (2)
Our unique sample consists of male workers in a manufacturing
factory in a Muslim country. We employ a standard Dictator Decision task
(Forsythe et al. 1994) to assess prosocial behavior as is often done in
the literature (see, e.g., Aaroe and Petersen 2013). Specifically, the
decision maker (the "dictator") is provided with a monetary
endowment. He is then asked to allocate the endowment between himself
and a passive (outside) recipient with the understanding that the
allocation will be implemented immediately.3 We examine behavior of
observants and nonobservants before and after the daily break of the
Ramadan fast, which allows us to associate fasting and prosocial
behavior. We also examine the behavior of the factory workers outside
Ramadan, where we do not have the daily break of the fast as the natural
time separation. Instead, we treat alimentary abstention as akin to a
long fasting period.
In line with existing literature, we confirm that, outside Ramadan,
decision makers who abstained from any alimentary intake transfer less
money to recipients relative to decision makers who did not abstain.
Furthermore, we test the hypothesis that, in the midst of the Ramadan
fast, abstention from any consumption of food and fluids along with the
spirit of the religious observance will make religious principles more
salient, and Ramadan-observant workers will be far more generous to
recipients than those who have had their evening meal. Indeed, observant
workers, in the midst of their fast, give significantly more to
recipients. Interestingly, observant workers during Ramadan, who have
had their evening meal, and workers outside Ramadan, who did not abstain
from any food and fluids intake make statistically similar transfers.
These findings suggest that it is the interaction between alimentary
abstention and religious observance that amplifies prosocial behavior
during Ramadan, where fasting is part of the ritual.
The layout of this paper adheres to the following plan. In Section
II, we describe the experimental design, and in Section III, we
formulate our general hypotheses. In Section IV, we report the important
findings, and in Section V, we discuss them. Finally, in Section VI, we
offer concluding remarks.
II. EXPERIMENTAL METHODOLOGY
The experiments were run in a manufacturing facility. In Figure 1,
we display the age and monthly wage distribution of the factory's
labor force at the time of the experiments. At that time, the factory
had 881 workers where almost 90% were men. Workers work in the factory
in 12hour shifts. There are two types of shifts: the day shift that
starts at 6:30 a.m. and the night shift that starts at 6:30 p.m.
Typically, two meals are served in the factory: a lunch in the day
shift, which takes place around 1:30 p.m., and a dinner in the night
shift, which takes place around 8:30 p.m. In addition, a snack in lieu
of a breakfast is served to the day-shift workers around 10:00 a.m.
Finally, from 10:00 a.m. until 6:00 p.m. a canteen operates that sells
various nourishments. During the month of Ramadan, no snack or lunch is
served and the dinner takes place a few minutes after the sunset.
Furthermore, people not observing the Ramadan fast must use the
cafeteria space to eat and drink in order not to provoke the individuals
that observe the fast. The canteen is closed throughout the month of
Ramadan.
Our objective in this study is to examine the impact on prosocial
behavior of the religious observance of Ramadan, where fasting is part
of the ritual. In the experimental design, we focused on three
dimensions. The first dimension is whether the decision maker abstained
from any intake of aliments. The second dimension is whether the
calendar date of the experiment coincided with the month of Ramadan. The
third dimension is whether the participant was a Ramadan observant. We
thus examined behavior of observants and nonobservants before and after
the daily break of the Ramadan fast as well as outside of Ramadan, where
we treated alimentary abstention as akin to a long fasting period.
All sessions took place in the cafeteria at the factory premises.
On the days of the experiments, both the cafeteria and the canteen were
kept closed to enable the experimenters to arrange the space
appropriately. Our between-subjects' experimental design consisted
of three sessions. In each session, we invited 80 participants. Two
sessions (one night session and one day session) took place during the
month of Ramadan, which started on June 28, 2014 and ended on July 27,
2014. Specifically, the night session was conducted on July 14, 2014 at
10:30 p.m. with nightshift workers, and the day session was conducted on
July 16, 2014 at 1:00 p.m. with day-shift workers. One more day session
with day-shift workers was conducted outside of Ramadan on March 5, 2015
at 1:30 p.m. (4) All experimental sessions were paper-and-pencil.
Employees were allowed to participate in only one session. Any concerns
for spillover effects across sessions were mitigated by the calendar
distance between the two day sessions, and by the management's
reassurance that day-shift workers and night-shift workers very rarely
overlap or interact at the factory premises. The characteristics of the
experimental sessions are shown in Table 1. A total of eight
participants were excluded from the analysis as they did not fit the
definitional requirements of abstention and nonabstention imposed by the
experimenters (see our terminology below). The age and monthly wage
distribution of the participants by group (the group classification is
given in Section IV. A) is provided in Appendix S1, Supporting
Information.
Initially, participants were offered 50,000 Rials (around $1.60)
for their participation in the experiment. This amount was paid to them
at the very end of the experiment. Participants were instructed that the
session consisted of two parts to be described at the appropriate time.
In the first part, they were presented with a single shot, Dictator task
and were all in the role of dictator. (5) Specifically, dictators were
given an envelope, which contained 10 notes of 10,000 Rials each, for a
total of 100,000 Rials. They were then asked to decide how many Rials
out of the 100,000 Rials they would like to keep, while noting that the
remaining amount would be transferred to a person outside of the
factory. (6) All dictators were informed that the outside recipient
would not be given any identifying information about them and that all
information was completely anonymous. The recipients of the money were
women who are under the supervision of the Seddigin-Charity Foundation.
The foundation is dedicated to feeding hungry women. Neither the
recipients' gender nor the name of the foundation was disclosed to
the decision makers. Dictators had to place the amount to be transferred
inside the envelope. The amount that was not transferred was theirs to
keep. The envelopes were collected at the end of the session and the
amount in the envelopes was recorded. In the second part, participants
were asked to complete a questionnaire. Two questions asked participants
to report on their religion (all participants self-reported to be
Muslims), and on whether they observed the Ramadan fast. (7) Further
questions were posed to determine whether participants had consumed any
food or fluids at all in the last 7 hours, and for those who did
consume, what they had consumed and how many hours had elapsed since
their very last consumption. These questions were placed to enable the
experimenters to classify abstaining and nonabstaining participants
appropriately. For instance, a participant who consumed food in the last
7 hours, but had no nourishments whatsoever in the last 3 hours could
potentially have depleted his glucose levels. In contrast, a participant
who consumed food within the hour, would still have rich levels of
glucose. To avoid confusion, our terminology as to how we interpret
abstention and how we define nonabstention is presented next.
Henceforth, we define those who abstained from any consumption of
aliments as those who did not have anything to eat or drink (not even a
sip of water) for at least 7 hours, and we define those who did not
abstain from any consumption of aliments as those who had something to
eat or drink (even a sip of water) in the last 2 hours. (8) A total of
eight participants had something to eat or drink in the last 7 hours,
but did not have anything to eat or drink for more than 2 hours and were
thus taken out of the sample. (9) The experimental instructions are
provided in Appendix S1.
To ensure that samples were randomly drawn and that the same
experimental conditions were maintained across sessions we had to make
the following design choices. As stated earlier, the night session
during Ramadan took place at 10:30 p.m. At that time very few women work
at the factory. We were thus compelled to eliminate women from the
experimental sessions altogether to safeguard against a sampling bias.
Although we precluded female participants, the recruitment of male
participants was otherwise done randomly. Furthermore, to maintain
comparability across sessions, we had to ensure the same number of hours
of alimentary abstention during the day experiments. We were thus led to
conduct the day experiments at different times. During Ramadan, the
experiment took place at 1:00 p.m., whereas outside Ramadan the
experiment took place at 1:30 p.m. On July 16, 2014 the sunrise took
place at 6:00 a.m. Given that the experiment took place at 1:00 p.m., it
is safe to assume that (Ramadan-observant) participants had been fasting
for at least 7 hours. To have meaningful comparison to the Ramadan day
session, we therefore had to conduct the experiment of March 5, 2015 at
1:30 p.m. right before lunch in order to ensure an alimentary abstention
of, also, at least 7 hours (recall the day shift starts at 6:30 a.m.).
To secure a large number of participants abstaining from any intake of
aliments, on that day, we forewent serving the snack at 10:00 a.m. and
kept the canteen closed for the entire day. Additionally, by announcing
and keeping the canteen closed for the entire day, we ensured that money
had no immediate value in any of the sessions (recall that during
Ramadan the canteen is kept closed). Nevertheless, some workers still
consumed (home-made) aliments. (10) Workers who had consumed aliments
within the last 2 hours on that day were compared to the nightshift
workers of the Ramadan session that took place at 10:30 p.m. The sunset
on July 14, 2014 was at 8:21 p.m. The night shift workers had their
dinner right after the sunset. This ensures a 2-hour window to consume
aliments during Ramadan, which is comparable to the window allowed
outside of Ramadan.
III. GENERAL HYPOTHESES
We formulate three general hypotheses. The first hypothesis
examines the differences in transfer, outside of Ramadan, when
manipulating dictators' alimentary abstention. Specifically, we
hypothesize that, outside Ramadan, abstaining dictators will transfer
less money to recipients relative to dictators who do not abstain.
Existing physiological literature establishes that individuals with
higher blood glucose levels are more giving than individuals with
depleted glucose levels (Aaroe and Petersen 2013). Along the same lines,
Harel and Kogut (2015) indicate that people tend to be more generous
when satisfied than when actively experiencing a visceral need, such as
hunger.
HYPOTHESIS 1: Outside Ramadan, abstaining dictators transfer less
money to recipients relative to dictators who do not abstain.
The second hypothesis aims to investigate the effect on
dictators' transfers, during Ramadan, of the interaction between
alimentary abstention and the religious observance of Ramadan, where
fasting is part of the ritual. During Ramadan, we hypothesize that the
combination of the two will make religious principles more salient, and
thus observant dictators in the midst of their fast will increase
significantly their transfers relative to observant dictators who have
had their evening meal. Indeed, existing experimental literature finds
evidence that priming religion causes subjects to identify more with
their religion and affects their decisions. Lambarraa and Riener (2012),
for instance, manipulate the saliency of Islamic values in their field
experiments in Morocco to investigate the effect on charitable giving.
The authors use the Arabic language (in lieu of the French language) to
prime participants' religiosity, and find that donations increase
significantly.
HYPOTHESIS 2: In Ramadan, observant dictators in the midst of their
fast transfer more money to recipients relative to observant dictators
who have had their evening meal.
The third hypothesis serves as a direct test of the impact of the
religious observance of Ramadan on dictators' transfers. We
conjecture that the observance of Ramadan is salient enough to cause
dictators who have had their evening meal to transfer more to recipients
relative to dictators, outside of Ramadan, who do not abstain.
HYPOTHESIS 3: Observant dictators who have had their evening meal
in Ramadan transfer more money to recipients relative to dictators,
outside of Ramadan, who do not abstain.
IV. RESULTS
The three hypotheses are formally tested next. Each hypothesis is
matched with the corresponding result; that is, result i is a report on
the test of hypothesis i.
A. Descriptive Statistics
We first report descriptive statistics on the raw experimental
data. Based on the calendar date and time and the participants'
responses in the questionnaire, participants were classified into six
groups: four Ramadan groups and two outside-of-Ramadan groups. The four
groups during Ramadan are: (1) observant, postdinner, (2) nonobservant,
postdinner, (3) observant, mid-fast, and (4) nonobservant, mid-fast. The
two groups outside of Ramadan are: (5) abstained from any aliments, and
(6) did not abstain from any aliments. In Table 2, we report the
frequency and percentage for each monetary transfer of the decision
makers by group. To simplify the exposition, the transfers are displayed
in terms of the number of notes out of a total of 10 notes. The
histograms are displayed in Figure 2. Note that the mean payoff can be
calculated by subtracting the mean transfer from the endowment and
adding up the show-up fee.
By the strictest economic principle of self-serving economic
agents, an individual should transfer nothing to an anonymous recipient.
That principle we can reject outright. Even in our most extreme group,
the abstaining dictators outside of Ramadan, the mean is 3.07 notes.
Next, relaxing the self-serving principle, outside Ramadan, abstaining
dictators are predicted to transfer fewer notes to recipients than
nonabstaining dictators. Indeed, those who abstained from any aliments
transferred on average 3.07 notes to recipients, whereas dictators who
did not abstain transferred 4.49 notes. During Ramadan, for the
observant participants, the trend is reversed: dictators in the mid-fast
session gave on average 6.35 notes to recipients in contrast to
dictators in the postdinner session who transferred 4.64 notes (i.e.,
the difference in giving is 1.71 notes).
B. Analysis
We perform next statistical analysis to investigate the effect of
the treated variables on the dictators' transfers. First, we
conduct a number of regressions on transfer. The first three models are
Tobit regressions where observations are left censored at 0 and right
censored at 10. The fourth model is an ordinary least squares (OLS)
regression. As our base in the regressions, we take the transfer of the
nonabstaining dictators outside of Ramadan. The estimates of the four
models are displayed in Table 3. Second, we present the p values of the
pairwise comparisons of the distribution of transfers using the
Kruskall-Wallis Rank test (see the analysis of Feltovich 2003 for the
appropriateness of the latter test), where the [H.sub.0] states that
there are no differences across the selected groups. The results of the
Kruskall-Wallis Rank test with ties are displayed in Table 4. In Panel A
of Table 4, we report the comparisons in the transfers between
abstaining and nonabstaining dictators outside of Ramadan, mid-fast and
postdinner dictators who are observant in Ramadan, and mid-fast and
postdinner dictators who are nonobservant in Ramadan. In Panel B of
Table 4, we investigate the differences in transfer across nonabstaining
dictators outside of Ramadan, postdinner dictators who are observant in
Ramadan, and postdinner dictators who are nonobservant in Ramadan. (11)
The first hypothesis examines the differences in transfer, outside
of Ramadan, when manipulating dictators' alimentary abstention. The
coefficient of the variable "Abstained" in Table 3 is negative
and significant in all regressions. Therefore, we can confirm that,
outside Ramadan, decision makers who abstained from any consumption of
aliments transfer less money to recipients relative to decision makers
who did not abstain. This is also reflected in Panel A of Table 4 where
the [H.sub.0] is rejected at the 5% level. In line with the findings of
Harel and Kogut (2015), our first main result is formalized as follows.
RESULT 1. Outside Ramadan, abstaining dictators transfer
significantly less money to recipients relative to nonabstaining
dictators.
The second hypothesis aims to investigate the effect on
dictators' transfers, during Ramadan, of the interaction between
alimentary abstention and the religious observance of Ramadan, where
fasting is part of the ritual. The estimates of the variable
"Mid-Fast x Observant x Ramadan" in Table 3 are positive,
significant, and large enough to reverse the trend observed outside of
Ramadan. The comparison with nonobservant participants at Panel A of
Table 4 rules out a time-of-the-day effect (afternoon vs. nighttime).
These findings culminate in our second main result.
RESULT 2. In Ramadan, postdinner, observant dictators transfer
significantly less money to recipients relative to observant dictators
in the midst of their fast. On the other hand, the difference in
behavior between nonobservant, mid-fast dictators and nonobservant,
postdinner dictators is not significant.
The third hypothesis tests the direct impact of the religious
observance of Ramadan on dictators' transfers. Table 3 indicates,
contrary to our conjecture in Section III, that Ramadan by itself,
without the interaction with alimentary abstention, has no significant
effect on transfer despite the fact that all respondents identified
themselves as practicing Muslims and an important tenet of Muslim life
is giving. A close look at Panel B in Table 4 reveals that the amount
given by those who did not abstain outside of Ramadan is not
significantly different from the amount given by either observant or
nonobservant post-dinner dictators in Ramadan. Furthermore, note that
the amount given by observant and nonobservant dictators who had their
evening meal during Ramadan is not statistically different. Therefore,
the religious observance of Ramadan in itself does not seem to be strong
enough to guide more generous transfers without the interaction with the
ritual of fasting.
RESULT 3. Dictators during Ramadan who had their evening meal and
dictators outside of Ramadan who did not abstain from any consumption of
aliments transfer the same amount of money to recipients. This result is
insensitive to whether the dictator in Ramadan is observant or
nonobservant.
A final result gleaned from Table 3 is that transfers increase with
age, which corroborates earlier findings of Hinde and Groebel (1991). In
fact, in a recent study, List (2011) collected data from the Center on
Philanthropy Panel Study and found that not only charitable giving
increases with age, but also that giving as a percentage of the
household income increases with age. In conjunction with another
finding, whereby giving to various causes is largely unaffected by the
state of the economy, the author conjectures that a plausible reason for
the increase in giving could be social insurance and/or ensuring a
peaceful afterlife (p. 165).
V. DISCUSSION
Our first main result confirms that the cue of hunger makes one
more primal and self-preserving. However, our second main result
highlights that the mode of self-preservation weakens in the presence of
a more profound internal cue. Specifically, the interaction between
alimentary abstention and religious observance overrides
self-preservation and promotes instead generosity in accordance with the
principles of Muslim life. This pattern in behavior is parallel to that
of normal-weight and obese shoppers as documented in Tom (1983). The
author finds that normal-weight shoppers over purchase when hungry,
whereas obese and hungry shoppers exhibit a more constrained behavior.
Similar to our first main result, the cue of hunger makes normal-weight
shoppers more self-preserving, which leads them to excessive shopping.
On the other hand, obese and hungry shoppers are better able to resist
tempting purchases (see also Nisbett and Kanouse 1969) as their profound
crusade to lose weight takes precedence over their cue of hunger. In the
words of Baumeister, Heatherton, and Tice (1994), "the feeling of
hunger ... paradoxically gives them solace, since it tells them they are
being successful at avoiding calories" (177).
The two aforementioned results also contribute to the ongoing
debate on whether prosocial behavior is intuitive (and automatic) or
deliberative (and slower). On one hand, Rand, Greene, and Nowak (2012)
in their high-impact study view prosocial behavior (cooperation to be
precise) as being governed by a dual-process mechanism that pits a fast
and intuitive system favoring prosocial behavior against a slower system
of reflection that weighs the available options. Using reaction times to
distinguish between intuitive and deliberative responses, they find that
in the public-goods games, subjects who contribute less to the public
good respond more slowly, whereas faster respondents contribute more
toward the provision of the public good. Rand, Greene, and Nowak (2012)
interpret these findings as suggesting that intuitive responses are more
prosocial. On the other hand, Krajbich et al. (2015) caution against
using reaction-time differences to distinguish between response types.
Specifically, the authors argue that which response is faster depends
critically on the parameters of the decision problem. Similar to the
study of Krajbich et al. (2015), we are also skeptical with respect to
the conclusions in the study of Rand, Greene, and Nowak (2012). Although
our study does not base its findings on reaction times, our results
suggest that reflection (i.e., the interaction between alimentary
abstention and religious observance that overrides self-preservation) is
the culprit behind increased prosocial behavior.
Finally, our third main result indicates that increased prosocial
behavior is limited to the critical hours of the fasting ritual, where
the religious observance of Ramadan interacts with the ritual of
fasting. A plausible explanation may be that the night-time Ramadan
hours are less strongly associated with religion and religious
activities, such as Zakat. The fact that a moral self can be transiently
activated is also demonstrated in the study of Shu et al. (2012), where
the authors find that signing at the beginning rather than at the end of
a self-report makes ethics salient, and significantly reduces
dishonesty.
VI. CONCLUDING REMARKS
We presented evidence that alimentary abstention is related to
lower prosocial behavior outside of a religious observance in accordance
with the existing literature. However, during the religious month of
Ramadan, where fasting is part of the ritual, observant dictators in the
midst of their fast exhibit more prosocial behavior than those who have
had their evening meal. It is important to note that increased prosocial
giving cannot be attributed to alimentary abstention alone, but may be
associated with the fact that alimentary abstention occurs during the
time period where religious observance is most salient (and it also
happens to coincide with fasting). We also find an increase in transfers
with age, which is in line with existing literature (see Hinde and
Groebel 1991; List 2011).
Ramadan fasting is the longest period of abstention of any major
religion and affects a large portion of the world population with likely
a substantial economic impact on the world economy. Indeed, Campante and
Yanagizawa-Drott (2015) find that longer Ramadan fasting has a negative
effect on output growth in Muslim countries, but increases the
subjective well-being of Muslims. The current evidence suggests that the
economic impact needs to be better understood in light of prosocial
implications.
ABBREVIATION
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
REFERENCES
Aaroe, L., and M. B. Petersen. "Hunger Games: Fluctuations in
Blood Glucose Levels Influence Support for Social Welfare."
Psychological Science, 24(12), 2013, 2550-6.
Andreoni, J., and J. H. Miller. "Giving According to GARP: An
Experimental Test of the Consistency of Preferences for Altruism."
Econometrica, 70(2), 2002, 737-53.
Bardsley, N. "Dictator Game Giving: Altruism or
Artefact?" Experimental Economics, 11, 2008, 122-33.
Barro, R. J., and R. M. McCleary. "Religion and Economic
Growth across Countries." American Sociological Review, 68, 2003,
760-81.
Baumeister. R. F., T. F. Heatherton, and D. M. Tice. Losing
Control: How and Why People Fail at Self-Regulation. Boston: Academic
Press, 1994.
Branas-Garza, P. "Poverty in Dictator Games: Awakening
Solidarity." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 60,
2006, 306-20.
--. "Promoting Helping Behavior with Framing in Dictator
Games." Journal of Economic Psychology, 28, 2007, 477-86.
Burnham, T. C. "Engineering Altruism: A Theoretical and
Experimental Investigation of Anonymity and Gift Giving." Journal
of Economic Behavior and Organization, 50, 2003, 133-44.
Campante, F., and D. Yanagizawa-Drott. "Does Religion Affect
Economic Growth and Happiness? Evidence from Ramadan." Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 130(2), 2015, 615-58.
Carpantier, J.-F., and A. Litina. "Dissecting the Act of God:
An Exploration of the Effect of Religion on Economic Activity."
Mimeo, Center for Research in Economic Analysis, University of
Luxembourg. 2014.
Clingingsmith, D., A. I. Khwaja, and M. Kremer. "Estimating
the Impact of the Hajj: Religion and Tolerance in Islam's Global
Gathering." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 2009, 1133-70.
Danziger, S., J. Levav, and L. Avnaim-Pesso. "Extraneous
Factors in Judicial Decisions." Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences, 108(17), 2011, 6889-92.
Feltovich, N. "Nonparametric Tests of Differences in Medians:
Comparison of the Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney and Robust Rank-Order
Tests." Experimental Economics, 6(3), 2003, 273-97.
Forsythe, R., J. L. Horowitz, N. E. Savin, and M. Sefton.
"Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments." Games and
Economic Behavior, 6(3), 1994, 347-69.
Gailliot, M. T. "Energy and Psychology." Global Journal
for Research Analysis, 4(7), 2015, 253-55.
Gailliot, M. T., and R. F. Baumeister. "The Physiology of
Willpower: Linking Blood Glucose to Self-Control." Personality and
Social Psychology Review, 11 (4), 2007, 303-27.
Gailliot, M. T., R. F. Baumeister, C. N. DeWall, J. K. Maner, E.
Ashby Plant, D. M. Tice. L. E. Brewer, and B. J. Schmeichel.
"Self-Control Relies on Glucose as a Limited Energy Source:
Willpower Is More Than a Metaphor." Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 92, 2007, 325-36.
Haley, K. J., and D. M. T. Fessier. "Nobody's Watching?
Subtle Cues Affecting Generosity in an Anonymous Economic Game."
Evolution and Human Behavior, 26, 2005, 245-56.
Harel, I., and T. Kogut. "Visceral Needs and Donation
Decisions: Do People Identify with Suffering or with Relief?"
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 56, 2015, 24-29.
Hinde, R. A., and J. Groebel. Cooperation and Prosocial Behavior.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Karaagaoglu, N., and S. Yiicecan. "Some Behavioral Changes
Observed Among Fasting Subjects, Their Nutritional Habits and Energy
Expenditure in Ramadan." International Journal of Food Sciences and
Nutrition, 51(2), 2000, 125-34. '
Koch, A. K., and H.-T. Normann. "Giving in Dictator Games:
Regard for Others or Regard by Others?" Southern Economic Journal,
75, 2008, 223-32.
Krajbich, I., B. Bartling, T. Hare, and E. Fehr. "Rethinking
Fast and Slow Based on a Critique of Reaction-Time Reverse
Inference." Nature Communications, 6, 2015, 7455 EP.
Lambarraa, F., and G. Riener. "On the Norms of Charitable
Giving in Islam: A Field Experiment." Mimeo, Dusseldorf Institute
for Competition Economics, HeinrichHeine-Universitat Dusseldorf, 2012.
List, J. A. "On the Interpretation of Giving in Dictator
Games." Journal of Political Economy, 115, 2007, 482-93.
--. "The Market for Charitable Giving." Journal of
Economic Perspectives 25(2), 2011, 157-80.
McCleary, R. M., and R. J. Barro. "Religion and Economy."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 2006, 49-72.
Nisbett, R., and D. E. Kanouse. "Obesity, Food Deprivation,
and Supermarket Shopping Behavior." Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 12(4), 1969, 289-94.
Rand, D. G., J. D. Greene, and M. A. Nowak. "Spontaneous
Giving and Calculated Greed." Nature, 489, 2012, 427-30.
Shu, L. L., N. Mazar, F. Gino, D. Ariely, and M. H. Bazerman.
"Signing at the Beginning Makes Ethics Salient and Decreases
Dishonest Self-Reports in Comparison to Signing at the End."
Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 109(38), 2012,
15,197-200.
Tom, G. "Effect of Deprivation on the Grocery Shopping
Behavior of Obese and Nonobese Consumers." International Journal of
Obesity, 7(4), 1983, 307-11.
Yamagishi. T., and T. Kiyonari. "The Group as the Container of
Generalized Reciprocity." Social Psychology Quarterly, 63(2), 2000,
116-32.
Ziaee, V., M. Razaei, A. Zahra, H. Shaikh, Y. Rahim, L.
Yarmohammadi, F. Bozorgi, and J. Behjati. "The Changes of Metabolic
Profile and Weight during Ramadan Fasting." Singapore Medical
Journal, 47(5), 2006, 409-14.
Zizzo, D. "Experimenter Demand Effects in Economic
Experiments." Experimental Economics, 13(1), 2010, 75-98.
--. "Do Dictator Games Measure Altruism?," in Handbook on
the Economics of Philanthropy, Reciprocity and Social Enterprise, edited
by L. Bruni and S. Zamagni. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2013, 108-11.
Zizzo, D., and P. Fleming. "Can Experimental Measures of
Sensitivity to Social Pressure Predict Public Good Contribution?"
Economics Letters, 111, 2011, 239-42.
SUPPORTING INFORMATION
Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online
version of this article:
Appendix S1. Experimental Instructions
Figure S1. Age Distribution by Group
Figure S2. Monthly Wage Distribution by Group
ERNAN E. HARUVY, CHRISTOS A. IOANNOU and FARNOUSH GOLSHIRAZI *
* The paper has benefited greatly from the comments of Shai
Danziger, Raymond O'Brien, Alexis Antoniades, Manos Mentzakis,
Carmine Ornaghi, Miltos Makris, Abbas Zabihzadeh, Mohammad Reza Abedi,
Jean-Yves Pitarakis, Hamid Taher Neshat Doost, and Mohammad Ali
Mazaheri. Finally, we are indebted to the editor, Martin Gervais, and
two anonymous referees for their insightful comments, which
significantly improved the paper. The research was supported by the
research funds from the Strategic Research Development Fund of the
University of Southampton and the University of Texas at Dallas. The
usual disclaimer applies.
Haruvy: Professor, Marketing Program, Jindal School of Management,
University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, TX 75083. Phone 972 883 5819,
Fax 972 883 5819, E-mail eharuvy@utdallas.edu
Ioannou: Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University
of Southampton, Southampton, SO 17 1BJ, UK. Phone 0044 789 557 8835, Fax
0044 238 059 3131, E-mail christos.a.ioannou@gmail.com
Golshirazi: MPhil Candidate, Department of Economics, University of
Oxford, Oxford, OX1 3UQ. UK. Phone 0044 790 968 5566, Fax 0044 186 527
1089, E-mail farnoush.golshirazi@univ.ox.ac.uk
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12480
(1.) Campante and Yanagizawa-Drott (2015) identify three ways in
which religious practices constrain believers and thereby affect
economic outcomes. First, they require a tradeoff between time and
resources that are then unavailable for production. Second, they can
affect directly productivity either by limiting social interactions with
nonbelievers or by imposing dietary restrictions. Third, they may shape
beliefs and values that affect economic decisions.
(2.) Some notable exceptions are the studies of Clingingsmith,
Khwaja, and Kremer (2009) and Campante and Yanagizawa-Drott (2015).
(3.) This setup has been used extensively in the literature to test
the basic economic premise of individuals behaving in their own
self-interest. Experimental results, contrary to this premise, have
indicated that only a minority of dictators keep the entire endowment to
themselves (Forsythe et al. 1994). Researchers (see, for instance,
Andreoni and Miller 2002) have attributed this behavior to prosocial
preferences.
(4.) This date was placed in between the religious festivity of Eid
Milad un Nabi that was celebrated on January 8, 2015 and the religious
festivity of Lailat al Miraj that was celebrated on May 13, 2015.
(5.) In a series of recent publications in economics, caution was
urged in drawing inferences on the Dictator games when mapping
laboratory evidence to the field (Bardsley 2008; List 2007; Zizzo 2010,
2013; Zizzo and Fleming 2011). The aforementioned studies posit that
dictators' behavior could instead be driven by experimenter demand
effects. Moreover, the presence of experimenter demand effects could be
amplified as a result of different cues (Branas-Garza 2006, 2007;
Burnham 2003; Haley and Fessler 2005; Koch and Normann 2008). While
experimenter demand effects may have an impact on subjects'
decisions, any such effects should be constant across sessions;
consequently, they merit no real concern to the interpretation of our
results.
(6.) We felt compelled to impose these (nonstandard) assumptions to
eliminate possible confounding effects that could arise due to
expectations of generalized reciprocity (Yamagishi and Kiyonari 2000).
(7.) Socially, there is no taboo in admitting lapses in fasting,
for medical, travel, or other reasons during Ramadan. Hence, we had no
difficulty in getting a large minority portion of the sample admitting
to not fasting during Ramadan without fear or stigma. This was not the
case with participants outside of Ramadan. Placing the question more
broadly did not sit well with respondents; hence, all participants
reported observing the Ramadan fast.
(8.) In other words, participants who said "Yes" to Q5 in
the questionnaire and either said "Less than 1 hour" or
"Between 1 and 2 hours" since their last consumption in Q7
were labeled as "did not abstain" from any alimentary intake.
(9.) The three of the eight participants took part in the July 16,
2014 session. All three participants were non-Ramadan observant: the two
participants who reported between 3 and 4 hours having elapsed since
their last consumption transferred 3 and 5 notes, respectively, to the
recipients, whereas the other participant who reported more than 4 hours
transferred 5 notes to the recipient. The other five participants took
part in the March 5, 2015 session, and all self-reported to be Ramadan
observant: the two participants who reported between 2 and 3 hours
having elapsed since their last consumption transferred 3 and 5 notes,
respectively, to recipients, whereas the other three participants who
reported more than 4 hours transferred 4, 5, and 5 notes, respectively,
to recipients.
(10.) In the questionnaire, these workers self-reported to have
eaten in the last 7 hours food items, such as one or two slices of
toast, oranges, biscuits, bread and cheese, and to have drunk mostly tea
and water.
(11.) The median tests performed on the equality of the medians
confirm the stated results.
Caption: FIGURE 1 Age and Monthly Wage Distribution of the
Factory's Labor Force
Caption: FIGURE 2 Transfers by Group: (a) Ramadan, Observant,
Postdinner, (b) Ramadan, Nonobservant, Postdinner, (c) Ramadan,
Observant, Mid-Fast, (d) Ramadan, Nonobservant, Mid-Fast, (e) Outside of
Ramadan, Abstained, (f) Outside of Ramadan, Did Not Abstain.
TABLE 1
Characteristics of the Experimental Sessions
No. of
No. of Ramadan
Date Time Participants Observants
July 14, 2014 10:30 p.m. 80 47
July 16, 2014 1:00 p.m 77 52
March 5, 2015 1:30 p.m. 75 75
Took Place No. Who
During Abstained
Date Ramadan? from Aliments
July 14, 2014 Yes 0
July 16, 2014 Yes 52
March 5, 2015 No 28
Notes: In the first two columns, we provide
information on the calendar date and time of
the sessions. In the third column, we provide
the total number of participants. The fourth column
indicates the number of participants who observed the
Ramadan fast as self-reported in the questionnaire.
The fifth column indicates whether the session took place
during the month of Ramadan or not. The last column indicates
the number of participants who abstained from any consumption
of aliments in the last 7 hours as self-reported in the
questionnaire.
TABLE 2
Summary Statistics
Panel A
In Ramadan
Observant
Mid-Fast Postdinner
Transfer Frequency Percent Frequency Percent
0 3 5.77 5 10.64
1 1 1.92 0 0.00
2 4 7.69 7 14.89
3 4 7.69 4 8.51
4 4 7.69 3 6.38
5 11 21.15 20 42.55
6 2 3.85 0 0.00
7 0 0.00 0 0.00
8 2 3.85 0 0.00
9 0 0.00 0 0.00
10 21 40.38 8 17.02
Obs. 52 47
Mean 6.35 4.64
Std. Dev. 3.42 2.95
Panel A
In Ramadan
Nonobservant
Mid-Fast Postdinner
Transfer Frequency Percent Frequency Percent
0 3 12.00 0 0.00
1 1 4.00 1 3.03
2 8 32.00 11 33.33
3 1 4.00 7 21.21
4 0 0.00 0 0.00
5 7 28.00 11 33.33
6 0 0.00 0 0.00
7 0 0.00 0 0.00
8 0 0.00 0 0.00
9 0 0.00 1 3.03
10 5 20.00 2 6.06
Obs. 25 33
Mean 4.20 3.88
Std. Dev. 3.39 2.29
Panel B
Outside of Ramadan
Abstained Did Not Abstain
Transfer Frequency Percent Frequency Percent
0 4 14.29 7 14.89
1 4 14.29 1 2.13
2 6 21.43 6 12.77
3 2 7.14 3 6.38
4 1 3.57 1 2.13
5 10 35.71 18 38.30
6 0 0.00 3 6.38
7 0 0.00 1 2.13
8 0 0.00 0 0.00
9 0 0.00 0 0.00
10 1 3.57 7 14.89
Obs. 28 47
Mean 3.07 4.49
Std. Dev. 2.34 3.05
Note: In the two panels, we report the frequency
and percentage for each monetary transfer of the
decision makers by group.
TABLE 3
Regressions on Transfer
Variables (1) (2)
Intercept 5.12 *** 4.46 ***
Abstained (0.30) (0.62)
-2.34 *** -1.68 *
Ramadan (0.85) (1.01)
0.85
Mid-Fast x (0.71)
Observant x Ramadan
Postdinner x Ramadan
Postdinner x
Observant x Ramadan
Age
Observations 232
Variables (3) (4)
Intercept 4.46 *** 1.40
Abstained (0.60) (1.43)
-1.67 * -1.24 *
Ramadan (0.97) (0.71)
-0.15 -0.04
Mid-Fast x (1.01) (0.74)
Observant x Ramadan 2.89 *** 2.07 ***
Postdinner x Ramadan (1.01) (0.72)
-0.33 -0.51
(1.07) (0.79)
Postdinner x 0.76 0.79
Observant x Ramadan
Age (0.91) (0.67)
0.09 **
(0.04)
Observations
Notes: A dictator's transfer is the dependent
variable. The first three models are Tobit regressions.
Twenty-two observations were left censored at 0 and 44
observations were right censored at 10. The fourth model
is an OLS regression. As a base, we used nonabstaining
dictators outside of Ramadan. "Abstained" is a dummy
variable that takes the value of 1 if the dictator
outside Ramadan abstained from any intake of aliments
and 0 otherwise, "Ramadan" is a dummy variable that
takes the value of 1 if the dictator is in Ramadan
and 0 otherwise, "Mid-Fast x Observant x Ramadan"
is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the
dictator is an observant who is in the midst of his
fast in Ramadan and 0 otherwise, "Postdinner x Ramadan"
is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the
dictator had his evening meal in Ramadan and 0 otherwise,
and "Postdinner x Observant x Ramadan" is a dummy variable
that takes the value of 1 if the dictator is an observant
who had his evening meal in Ramadan and 0 otherwise. The
variable "Age" corresponds to the age of the dictator.
All standard errors are reported in parentheses.
* Significant at 10%, ** significant at 5%,
*** significant at 1%.
TABLE 4
Kruskall-Wallis Rank Tests on Transfer
Panel A
[Transfer.sub.i]
[not equal to]
Alternative Hypothesis: [Transfer.sub.j]/p Values
Outside of Ramadan
Abstained versus Did not abstain 0.04
In Ramadan
Observant 0.02
Mid-Fast versus Postdinner
Nonobservant 0.83
Mid-Fast versus Postdinner
Panel B
[Transfer.sub.i]
[not equal to]
Alternative Hypothesis: [Transfer.sub.j]/p Values
Outside of Ramadan, Did not abstain 0.25
versus In Ramadan, Nonobservant,
Postdinner
Outside of Ramadan, Did not abstain 0.95
versus In Ramadan, Observant,
Postdinner
In Ramadan, Observant, Postdinner 0.17
versus In Ramadan, Nonobservant,
Postdinner
Notes: We utilize the Kruskall-Wallis Rank tests (with
ties) to determine any differences (i [not equal to] j)
in the transfer across the selected groups. In Panel A,
we report the p values of the comparison in the transfers
between abstaining and nonab-staining participants outside
of Ramadan, mid-fast and post-dinner dictators who are
observant in Ramadan, and mid-fast and postdinner
dictators who are nonobservant in Ramadan. In Panel B,
we report the p values of the comparison in the transfers
across nonabstaining dictators outside of Ramadan,
postdinner dictators who are observant in Ramadan, and
post-dinner dictators who are nonobservant in Ramadan.
COPYRIGHT 2018 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.