ESTIMATING MARKET POWER IN HOMOGENOUS PRODUCT MARKETS USING A COMPOSED ERROR MODEL: APPLICATION TO THE CALIFORNIA ELECTRICITY MARKET.
Orea, Luis ; Steinbuks, Jevgenijs
ESTIMATING MARKET POWER IN HOMOGENOUS PRODUCT MARKETS USING A COMPOSED ERROR MODEL: APPLICATION TO THE CALIFORNIA ELECTRICITY MARKET.
I. INTRODUCTION
Starting from seminal research works of Iwata (1974), Gollop and
Roberts (1979), and Appelbaum (1982), measuring the degree of
competition in oligopolistic markets has become one of the key
activities in empirical industrial organization. A large and growing
economic literature in New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO)
relies on structural models to infer what types of firm behavior
("conduct") are associated with prices that exceed marginal
costs. (1) A typical structural model based on the conduct parameter
approach for homogenous product markets starts with specifying a demand
function and writing down the first-order condition (FOC) of the
firm's static profit-maximization problem:
(1) P ([Q.sub.t]) - mc ([q.sub.it]) + P' ([Q.sub.t]) x
[q.sub.it] = 0,
where P([Q.sub.t]) is inverse demand, [Q.sub.t] =
[[SIGMA].sup.N.sub.i] [q.sub.it] is total industry's output,
[q.sub.it] is the firm's output in period t, mc([q.sub.it]) is the
firm's marginal cost, and [[theta].sub.it] is a "conduct"
parameter that parameterizes the firm's profit maximization
condition. Under perfect competition, [[theta].sub.it] = 0 and price
equals marginal cost. In static equilibrium, when [[theta].sub.it] =
1/[S.sub.it] (where [s.sub.it] denotes firm's market share of
output) we face a perfect cartel, and when 0 < [[theta].sub.it] <
1/[s.sub.it] various oligopoly regimes apply. (2) As the interpretation
of estimated conduct parameter 0 becomes more complicated in a dynamic
setting, (3) we interpret this parameter as a descriptive measure of the
firm's degree of market power based on a structural economic model
of the firm's behavior. (4)
This paper is concerned about econometric estimation of the conduct
parameter [[theta].sub.it] along with other cost and demand parameters.
The conduct parameter may vary across time as market conditions change,
and firms change their own pricing strategies. (5) As collusive
arrangements are unstable and might only be successful for short
periods, looking for evidence of collusion using averages over long time
periods might miss a lot of what is going on. Moreover, the conduct
parameter may also vary across firms as "there is nothing in the
logic of oligopoly theory to force all firms to have the same
conduct" (Bresnahan 1989, p. 1030). (6)
Obviously, allowing the conduct parameter to vary both by firms and
time series results in an overparameterized model. To avoid this
problem, empirical studies in structural econometric literature always
impose some restrictions on the way the value of conduct parameter
varies across firms and time. The overparameterization is typically
solved by estimating the average of the conduct parameters of the firms
in the industry (Appelbaum 1982; Wolfram 1999), reducing the time
variation into a period of successful cartel cooperation and a period of
price wars or similar breakdowns in cooperation (Porter 1983a), allowing
for different conduct parameters between two or more groups of firms
(Gollop and Roberts 1979), or assuming firm specific, but time
invariant, conduct parameters in a panel data framework (Puller 2007).
This study contributes to the NEIO literature by proposing a novel
econometric approach that deals with the overparameterization problem
and helps obtain the values of firms' conduct that vary across both
time and market participants. Instead of estimating the firm's
conduct as a common parameter together with other parameters defining
cost and demand, we propose treating firms' conduct
[[theta].sub.it] as a random variable. Our approach is based on a
composed error model, where the stochastic part is formed by two random
variables--a traditional error term, which captures random shocks, and a
random conduct term, which measures market power. The model is estimated
in three stages. (7) In the first stage, all parameters describing the
structure of the pricing Equation (1) are estimated using appropriate
econometric techniques. In the second stage, distributional assumptions
on random conduct term are invoked to obtain consistent estimates of the
parameters describing the structure of the two error components. In the
third stage, market power scores are obtained for each firm by
decomposing the estimated residual into a noise component and a
market-power component.
The distinctive feature of our approach is that it takes advantage
of the fact that the unobserved conduct term is assumed to be
non-negative, that is, [[theta].sub.it] is identified based on its
one-sided structural restriction imposed by the economic theory. This
allows us to obtain firm-specific market power estimates that vary
across both time and firms without any parametric constraints, except
for the distribution of the conduct parameter 0,;. (8) The flexibility
of our approach thus permits the estimated market-power scores to
represent many underlying, but unobserved, oligopoly equilibria. Though
the idea of identification of structural econometric models through
asymmetries in variance of error term is not new in applied econometric
literature, (9) to our knowledge one-sided nature (skewness) of conduct
parameter in oligopolistic industry settings is not examined explicitly
in most (if any) of the previous studies.
The proposed approach can also be viewed as belonging to the same
family as Porter (1983b), Brander and Zhang (1993), and Gallet and
Schroeter (1995) who estimate a regime-switching model where market
power enters in the model as a supply shock. As in our model, the
identification of market power in these studies relies on making
assumptions about the structure of unobservable error term. However,
while previous papers estimated the pricing relationship (1) assuming
[[theta].sub.it] = [[theta].sub.t] , to be a discrete random variable
that follows a bimodal distribution ("price wars" vs.
"collusion"), here [[theta].sub.it] varies both across firms
and over time and is treated as a continuous random term. Therefore,
while the switching regression models can only be estimated when there
are discrete "collusive" and "punishment" phases
that are either observable or could be inferred from the data, our model
can be estimated in absence of regime switches. (10) The continuous
nature of our conduct random term thus allows us to capture gradual
changes in firm's degree of market power." In this sense, our
model can be viewed as the continuous counterpart of the discrete
regime-switching models.
Another feature that distinguishes our paper from previous studies
is the attempt to estimate a double-bounded distribution that imposes
both lower and upper theoretical bounds (i.e., 0 [less than or equal to]
[[theta].sub.it] [less than or equal to] 1/[S.sub.it]) to a continuous
random conduct term. To achieve this objective we have explored the
stochastic frontier literature, (12) and adapted the doubly truncated
normal distribution recently introduced by Almanidis, Qian, and Sickles
(2010) to our framework. (13) To our knowledge, this study is among the
first applications of stochastic frontier models for estimating market
power. The only other known papers to do so are Huang, Chiang, and Chao
(2017b) and Huang, Liu, and Kumbhakar (2017a), which use a copula-based
stochastic frontier method to model the correlation between cost
efficiency and market power. (14)
Our paper differs from the above two papers in two aspects. First,
our paper uses a double-truncated distribution to impose a theoretical
upper bound to the market power error term, while Huang, Liu, and
Kumbhakar (2017a) and Huang, Chiang, and Chao (2017b) do not impose any
upper bound to 0it. Second, we are using nonparametric (engineering)
estimates of firms' marginal costs based on the unit costs
associated to different production technologies, and hence our empirical
strategy does not rely on estimating a cost function aiming to measure
firms' marginal costs. Both approaches have advantages and
disadvantages. For instance, Genesove and Mullin (1994), Clay and
Troesken (2003), and Kim and Knittel (2006) show that market power
estimates might be strongly biased due to inaccurate estimates of
marginal costs. When firms' marginal costs are not observed, they
must be inferred from previous estimates of the utilities' cost
function. The traditional Translog function provides a second-order
approximation to the underlying cost function, but only a first-order
approximation to the underlying marginal costs (see Jamasb, Orea, and
Pollitt 2012), which is highly inaccurate. On the contrary, the use of
nonparametric estimates of firms' marginal costs based on
engineering approach assumes that firms are fully efficient. Thus, our
present estimation framework ignores the potential correlation between
cost/profit inefficiency and market power. (15)
We illustrate the model with an application to the California
electricity generating market between April 1998 and December 2000. This
industry is an ideal setting to apply our model because there were high
concerns regarding market power levels in California restructured
electricity markets during that period, and detailed price, cost, and
output data are available as a result of the long history of regulation
and the transparency of the production technology. This data set allows
us to compute directly hourly marginal cost and residual demand
elasticities for each firm. We can therefore avoid complications from
estimating demand and cost parameters and focus our research on market
power, avoiding biases due inaccurate estimates of marginal cost and
residual demand. Hence, this data set provides a proper framework to
discuss methodological issues and to apply the empirical approach
proposed in the present paper. In addition, the robustness of our data
has been extensively tested in previous studies focusing on market power
in the California electricity market (e.g., Joskow and Kahn 2002;
Borenstein, Bushnell, and Wolak 2002; Wolak 1999; Wolak 2003; and Puller
2007).
Our empirical results are compared to a well-known study of Puller
(2007), which employs fixed-effect regression approach to obtain
firm-specific conduct parameter averages over three periods between July
1, 1998 and November 30, 2000. In the first stage we estimate
firm-specific conduct parameter averages, which are very similar to
findings of Puller (2007). This result demonstrates that both approaches
are, in practice, equivalent or interchangeable for estimating
time-invariant firm-specific market power scores. In a panel data
setting, our methodology has a significant advantage over fixed-effects
regression approach in that we can analyze changes in firm's market
conduct over time. The analysis of firm-specific conduct parameters
suggests that realization of market power varies over both time and
firms, and rejects the assumption of a common conduct parameter for all
firms. Estimated firm-specific conduct parameters generally tend to move
in the same direction across time, suggesting that the potential for
exercising market power across all firms varies as market conditions
change.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Section II we
describe the empirical specification of the model. In Section III we
discuss the three-stage procedure to estimate the model. The empirical
illustration of the model using California electricity data is described
in Section IV and Section V concludes.
II. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION
The traditional structural econometric model of market power is
formed by a demand function and a pricing equation. Because we are
interested in the estimation of industry or firm-specific market power
scores, we only discuss here the estimation of the pricing Equation (1),
conditional on observed realization of residual demand. (16) If the
demand function parameters are not known, they should be estimated
jointly with cost and market power parameters.
In this section, we develop a simple model where firms sell
homogenous products (e.g., kilowatt-hours of electricity) and choose
individual quantities each period so as to maximize their profits. Our
model is static as we assume that firms maximize their profits each
period without explicit consideration of the competitive environment in
other periods. (17) Firm i's profit function in period t can be
written as:
(2) [[pi].sub.it] = P([Q.sub.t]) x [q.sub.it] - C
([q.sub.it],[alpha]),
where [alpha] is a vector of cost parameters to be estimated. We
assume that firms choose different quantities each period and their
marginal cost varies across firms and over time.
In a static setting, the firm's profit maximization problem
is.
(3) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
The FOCs of the static model are captured by Equation (1), that is:
[P.sub.t] = mc ([q.sub.it], [alpha]) + [q.sub.it] x
[[theta].sub.it],
where mc([q.sub.it] [alpha]) stands for firm's marginal cost,
[g.sub.it] = [P.sub.t] [q.sub.it]/[Q.sub.t][[eta].sup.D.sub.it] and
[[eta].sup.D.sub.it] = P' ([Q.sub.t]) [P.sub.t]/[Q.sub.t] is the
(observed) elasticity of product demand. The stochastic specification of
the above FOCs can be obtained by adding the error term, capturing
measurement and optimization errors:
(4) [P.sub.t] = mc [[q.sub.it], [alpha]) + [g.sub.it] x [Q.sub.it]
+ [v.sub.it].
Instead of viewing firms' behavior as a structural parameter
to be estimated we here treat firms' behavior as a random variable.
While retaining standard assumption that the error term [v.sub.it] is
i.i.d. and symmetric with zero mean, we also assume that
[[theta].sub.it] follows a truncated distribution that incorporates the
theoretical restriction that 0 [less than or equal to] [q.sub.it] [less
than or equal to] 1/[S.sub.it]. The distinctive feature of our model is
that the stochastic part is formed by two random variables--the
traditional symmetric error term, [v.sub.it], and a one-sided random
conduct term, [g.sub.it], x [[theta].sub.it] that reflects the market
power. The restriction that the composed error term is asymmetric (as
[[theta].sub.it] (is one-sided distributed) allows us to obtain separate
estimates of [[theta].sub.it] and [v.sub.it] from an estimate of the
composed error term.
III. ESTIMATION STRATEGY
We now turn to explaining how to estimate the pricing relationships
presented in the previous section. Two estimation methods are possible:
a method-of-moments (MM) approach and maximum likelihood (ML). The MM
approach involves three stages. In the first stage, all parameters
describing the structure of the pricing equation (i.e., cost, demand,
and dynamic parameters) are estimated using appropriate econometric
techniques. In particular, because some regressors are endogenous, a
generalized method of moments (GMM) method should be employed to get
consistent estimates in this stage. (18) This stage is independent of
distributional assumptions on either error component. In the second
stage of the estimation procedure, distributional assumptions are
invoked to obtain consistent estimates of the parameter(s) describing
the structure of the two error components, conditional on the
first-stage estimated parameters. In the third stage, market power
scores are estimated for each firm by decomposing the estimated residual
into an error-term component and a market-power component.
The ML approach uses ML techniques to obtain second-stage estimates
of the parameters) describing the structure of the two error components,
conditional on the first-stage estimated parameters. It can be also used
to estimate simultaneously both types of parameters, if the regressors
in the pricing equation are exogenous. In this case, the ML approach
combines the two first stages of the MM approach into one.
While the first stage is standard in the NEIO literature, the
second and third stages take advantage of the fact that the conduct term
is likely positively or negatively skewed, depending on the
oligopolistic equilibrium that is behind the data generating process.
Models with both symmetric and asymmetric random terms of the form in
Section II have been proposed and estimated in the stochastic frontier
analysis literature (see Fried, Knox Lovell, and Schmidt 2008; Kumbhakar
and Lovell 2000).
While economic theory imposes both lower and upper theoretical
bounds to the random conduct term, the skewness of its distribution is
an empirical issue. Oligopolistic equilibrium outcomes often yield
skewed conduct random terms where larger (collusive) conduct parameter
values are either less or more probable than smaller (competitive)
conduct values. For instance, the dominant firm theory assumes that one
(few) firm(s) has enough market power to fix prices over marginal cost.
This market power is, however, attenuated by a fringe of (small) firms
that do not behave strategically. (19) The most important characteristic
of this equilibrium is that the modal value of the conduct random term
(i.e., the most frequent value) is close to zero, and higher values of
[[theta].sub.it] are increasingly less likely (frequent). In other
markets all firms might be involved in a perfect cartel scheme. In such
a cartel equilibrium, firms usually agree to sell "target"
quantities, and the resulting market price is the monopoly price, which
is associated with the maximum conduct value, for example,
[[theta].sub.it] = 1/[S.sub.it] Smaller values of [[theta].sub.it] are
possible due, for instance, to cheating behavior. (20) This means that
the modal value of the conduct random term in this equilibrium is one,
with smaller values of [[theta].sub.it] increasingly less likely. That
is, firm conduct is negatively skewed. In general, similar equilibria
that yield asymmetric distributions for the firm-conduct parameter with
modal values close to zero or to the number of colluding firms may also
arise. While the above examples of asymmetry are across firms, the
firm-conduct can be also negatively skewed over time if a particular
degree of competition (collusion) in the market occurs more frequently.
This could happen, for example, due to different length of high and low
demand periods that are found to affect the degree of market competition
(e.g., Green and Porter 1984 and Rotemberg and Saloner 1986).
A. First Stage: Pricing Equation Estimates
Let us denote the average of the conduct parameters of the firms in
the industry as [theta] = E([[theta].sub.it]). If we now add and
subtract [g.sub.it][theta] from Equation (4), the pricing equation to be
estimated can be rewritten as:
(5) [P.sub.t] = mc ([q.sub.it], [alpha]) + [g.sub.it] * [theta] +
[g.sub.it] * {[[theta].sub.it] - [theta]} + [v.sub.it] [equivalent to]
mc ([q.sub.it], [alpha]) + [g.sub.it] * [theta] + [[epsilon].sub.it]
where [alpha] is the vector of cost parameters and
[[epsilon].sub.it] a composed error term:
(6) [[epsilon].sub.it] = [v.sub.it] + [g.sub.it] x
{[[theta].sub.it] - [theta]}.
As we explain above, in Equation (6) the composed error term,
[[epsilon].sub.it], comprises of a traditional symmetric error term,
[v.sub.it], and a one-sided random conduct term, [g.sub.it].
{[[theta].sub.it] - [theta]}, which reflects the market power.
The possible endogeneity of some regressors will lead to least
squares being biased and inconsistent. This source of inconsistency can
be dealt with by using GMM. Note that the parameter estimates can still
be inconsistent as in our second-stage we assume that
E([[theta].sub.it]) is firm and time specific. This is because the upper
truncation of [[theta].sub.it] depends on the firm's market share,
and [[theta].sub.it] is heteroscedastic itself. To achieve consistent
estimates it is critical to ensure that chosen instruments do not
include determinants of [[theta].sub.it]. (21)
Though first-step GMM parameter estimates are consistent, they are
not efficient by construction because the [[epsilon].sub.it]s' are
not identically distributed. Indeed, assuming that [[theta].sub.it] and
[v.sub.it] are distributed independently of each other, the second
moment of the composed error term can be written as:
(7) E([[epsilon].sup.2.sub.it])= [[sigma].sup.2.sub.v] +
[g.sup.2,sub.it] * [[sigma].sup.2.sub.[theta]],
where [mathematical expression not reproducible]. Equation (7)
shows that the error in the regression indicated by Equation (5) is
heteroscedastic. Therefore an efficient GMM estimator is needed. (22)
Suppose that we can find a vector of m instruments [M.sub.it] that
satisfy the following moment condition:
(8) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
The efficient two-step GMM estimator is then the parameter vector
that solves:
(9) ([??], [??]) = arg min
[[[SIGMA].sub.i][[SIGMA].sub.t][m.sub.it]([alpha],[theta])]'[W.sup.-1] [[[SIGMA].sub.i][[SIGMA].sub.t][m.sub.it]([alpha],[theta])],
where W is an optimal weighting matrix obtained from a consistent
preliminary GMM estimator. This optimal weighting matrix can take into
account both heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation of the error term.
B. Second Stage: Variance Decomposition
The pricing Equation (5) estimated in the first stage is equivalent
to standard specification of a structural market power econometric
model, where an industry-average conduct is estimated (jointly with
other demand and cost parameters in most applications). As we mentioned
earlier in this section, our paper aims to exploit the asymmetry of the
random conduct term [[theta].sub.it] to get firm-specific market power
estimates in the second and third stages. Because, as it is customary,
we are going to assume that the noise term [v.sub.it] follows a normal
distribution, this implies that the composed error term in Equation (6)
is also asymmetrically distributed.
In the second stage of the estimation procedure, distributional
assumptions are invoked to obtain consistent estimates of the
parameter(s) describing the variance of [theta] and [v.sub.it] (i.e.,
[sigma][theta] and [[sigma].sub.v]), conditional on the first-stage
estimated parameters. This stage is critical as it allows us to
distinguish variation in market conduct, measured by
[[sigma].sub.[theta]], from variation in demand and costs, measured by
[[sigma].sub.v]. Given that we are going to assume a particular
distribution for the conduct term, both variances can be estimated using
ML. The ML estimators are obtained by maximizing the likelihood function
associated to the error term [[epsilon].sub.it] = [v.sub.it] +
[g.sub.it] * {[[theta].sub.it] - [theta]} that can be obtained from an
estimate of the first-stage pricing Equation (5).
The second-stage model can be also estimated by MM that relies on
the second and third moments of the error term [[epsilon].sub.it] in
Equation (5). This approach takes advantage of the fact that, while the
second moment provides information about both and [[sigma].sub.v], the
third moment only provides information about the asymmetric random
conduct term. In the empirical application (Section IV) we only report
the results using the ML approach for both theoretical and practical
reasons. First, Olson, Schmidt, and Waldman (1980) showed using
simulation exercises that the choice of the estimator (ML vs. MM)
depends on the relative values of the variance of both random terms and
the sample size. When the sample size is large (as in our application)
and the variance of the one-sided error component is small, compared to
the variance of the noise term, ML outperforms MM. Second, the MM
approach has some practical problems. As it is well known in the
stochastic frontier literature, neglected heteroscedasticity in either
or both of the two random terms causes estimates (here, the market power
scores) to be biased. Kumbhakar and Lovell (2000) pointed out that only
the ML approach can be used to address this problem. Another practical
problem arises when, in homoscedastic specifications of the model, the
implied ce becomes sufficiently large to cause [[sigma].sub.v] < 0,
which violates the assumptions of the econometric theory.
Whatever the approach we choose in the present stage, we need to
choose a distribution for [[theta].sub.it] The chosen distribution for
the random conduct term reflects the researcher's beliefs about the
underlying oligopolistic equilibrium that generates the data. Therefore,
different distributions for the conduct random term can be estimated to
test for different types of oligopolistic equilibrium. The pool of
distribution functions is, however, limited as we need to choose a
simple distribution for the asymmetric term to be able to estimate the
empirical model, while satisfying the restrictions of the economic
theory. The need for tractability prevents us from using more
sophisticated distributions that, for instance, would allow us to model
industries formed by two groups of firms with two different types of
behavior, that is, an industry with two modes of the conduct term.
The distribution for the asymmetric term adopted in this study is
the double-bounded distribution that imposes both lower and upper
theoretical bounds on the values of the random conduct term, that is, 0
[less than or equal to] [[theta].sub.it] [less than or equal to]
1/[S.sub.it]. In doing so, we follow Almanidis, Qian, and Sickles
(2010), who propose a model where the distribution of the inefficiency
(here, the conduct) term is a normal distribution
N([mu],[[sigma].sub.v]) that is truncated at zero on the left tail and
at 1/[S.sub.it] on the right tail. (23,24) Regarding the noise term, we
will assume that [v.sub.it] follows a normal distribution with zero mean
and standard deviation (SD) [[sigma].sub.v]. The model can then be
estimated by maximizing a well-defined likelihood function associated to
the error term that can be obtained from an estimate of the first-stage
pricing equation:
(10) [mathematical expression not reproducible].
Note that this residual term is the observed counterpart of:
(11) [[epsilon].sub.it] = [v.sub.it] + [g.sub.it] *
([[theta].sub.it] E([[theta].sub.it])).
When [[theta].sub.it] follows the doubly truncated normal
distribution introduced by Almanidis, Qian, and Sickles (2010), the
likelihood function associated to Equation (11) can be written as:
(12) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
where [mathematical expression not reproducible]
It should be noted that [[??].sub.it] depends on the expected value
of the conduct term, that is, E([[theta].sub.it]). In principle, this
expected value is unknown. To deal with this issue we can follow two
alternative empirical strategies. The first strategy relies on the
assumed distribution for the conduct term. Indeed, if [[theta].sub.it]is
assumed to follow a doubly truncated normal distribution, the expected
value of the conduct term can be written as:
(13) [mathematical expression not reproducible].
The above likelihood function in Equation (11) can then be
maximized once we have replaced the expected value of the conduct term
with the mathematical expression of E([[theta].sub.it]) in Equation
(13). It should be noted that there are neither new parameters to be
estimated nor first-stage parameters in this equation. This equation
also indicates that, regardless whether [[sigma].sub.[theta]] is
homoscedastic or heteroscedastic, the expected value of the conduct term
is observation specific as it depends on firms' market shares.
The second strategy to replace the expected value of the conduct
term in Equation (11) relies on the estimated parameters of the
first-stage pricing equation. In this case, the expected value
E([[theta].sub.it]) is simply replaced with our first-stage estimate of
the conduct parameter, that is, [??]. Note that in this strategy the
expected value of the conduct term is restricted to be common to all
firms, or time invariant if firm-specific conduct parameters are
estimated. The advantage of this strategy is that the estimated
expectation does not depend on distributional assumptions on [v.sub.it]
and [[theta].sub.it].
As we have mentioned earlier, neglected heteroscedasticity in
either or both of the two random terms produces biased estimates of the
market power scores. To address this problem, we propose estimating our
model allowing for firm-specific and/or heteroscedastic random terms. In
particular, we extend the classical homoscedastic model by assuming that
variation in the error term is an exponential function of an intercept
term, the day-ahead forecast of total demand and its square (i.e., FQ,
[FQ.sup.2]), that are included in the model in order to capture possible
demand-size effects, and a vector of days-of-the-week dummies (DAY).
These variables allow for time-varying heteroscedasticity in the error
term. In addition, firm-specific dummy variables (FIRM) are included to
test whether variation of the error term is correlated with
(unobservable) characteristics of firms/observations. Therefore, the
variation in the noise term can be written in logs as (25):
(14) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
Regarding the conduct random term, we assume that both its mean and
its variance are firm and time specific. This is achieved by modeling
[[sigma].sub.[theta]] as an exponential function of several covariates.
(26) Because the upper bounds are firm-specific, we should expect a
higher variation in [[theta].sub.it] for those firms with lower market
share, and vice versa. For this reason, we include sit as a determinant
of variation in market conduct and we expect a negative coefficient for
this variable. Since Porter (1983a), who estimates a regime-switching
model, there is a large tradition in the empirical industrial
organization literature that extended Porter's model by adding a
Markov structure to the state (i.e., discrete) random variable capturing
periods of either price wars or collusion (see, for instance, Ellison
1994, and Fabra and Toro 2005). Under this structure, the regimes are
not independent and they are correlated over time, so that a collusion
state today can be likely to lead to another collusion state next day.
Although imposing an autoregressive structure on the conduct term
[[theta].sub.it] might be a more realistic assumption, in this study we
still assume that [[theta].sub.it] is independent over time. There are
two reasons for doing so. First, in our model, random conduct parameter
[[theta].sub.it] varies across both firms and over time, and is treated
as a continuous random term that, in addition, it is truncated twice.
This makes it difficult to allow for correlation over time in the random
conduct term. In a finite-state framework, the model can be estimated by
maximizing the joint likelihood function of [v.sub.it] and
[[theta].sub.it] if a Markov structure is not imposed. When this
structure is added, the computation of the likelihood function of the
model is much more complicated because it necessities to integrate out
[[theta].sub.il], ... , [[theta].sub.ilt]. Several filtering methods
have been proposed (e.g., Hamilton 1989) to make tractable the
likelihood function, and to jointly estimate the hidden states and the
parameters of the model. As pointed out by Emvalomatis, Stefanou, and
Lansink (2011), these filtering methods cannot be easily adapted to a
continuous and non-negative random variable. For instance, the
traditional Kalman filtering techniques cannot be used in our framework
when the latent variable (here [[theta].sub.it]) is not normally
distributed, and a one-to-one, nonlinear transformation of
[[theta].sub.it] should be used before putting 0,r in an autoregressive
form. It is clearly out of scope of the present paper to extend the
proposed approach to double truncated random variables. Second, Alvarez
et al. (2006) pointed out that we can still get consistent parameter
estimates if the correlation of unobserved conduct term over time is
ignored. The justification is based on a quasi-ML argument, where the
density of a firm's efficiency score at time t, could still be
correctly specified, marginally with respect to the efficiency score in
previous periods.
Although we do not explicitly incorporate autoregressive
specification of unobserved conduct term [[theta].sub.it], we do attempt
to control for observed past behavior in some target variables. (27) In
particular, and following Fabra and Toro's (2005) application to
the Spanish electricity market, we include the lagged first-difference
of market shares, that is, [DELTA][S.sub.it - 1] = [s.sub.it-i] -
[S.sub.it-2], as a target variable. A negative value of
[DELTA][S.sub.it-1], indicates that other strategic rivals have got
yesterday a higher market share than the day before. If the increase in
rivals' market share is taken as a signal of weakness of a
potential tacit collusion arrangement among firms, it might encourage
firm i to behave more aggressive next day. If this is the case, we
should expect a positive sign of the coefficient associated to this
variable. (28)
Hence, our final specification of the conduct variation is:
(15) ln [[sigma].sub.[theta],it] = [[upsilon].sub.0] +
[[upsilon].sub.1][S.sub.it] +[[upsilon].sub.2] + [DELTA][S.sub.it-1]+
[N.summation over (i=2)][[??].sub.i] x [FIRM.sub.i].
C. Third Stage: Obtaining Firm-Specific Market Power Estimates
In the third stage, we obtain the estimates of market power for
each firm. From previous stages we have estimates of [[epsilon].sub.it]
= [v.sub.it] + [g.sub.it] x ([[theta].sub.it] - E([[theta].sub.it])) or,
in other words, of [[??].sub.it] = [[epsilon].sub.it] +
[g.sub.it]E([[epsilon].sub.it]) = [v.sub.it] + [g.sub.it] x
[[theta].sub.it] which obviously contain information on
[[theta].sub.it]. The problem is to extract the information that
[[??].sub.it] contains on [[theta].sub.it]. Jondrow et al. (1982) face
the same problem in the frontier production function literature and
propose using the conditional distribution of the asymmetric random term
(here [??][[theta].sub.it] = [g.sub.it] x [[theta].sub.it]) given the
composed error term (here [[??].sub.it]). The best predictor of the
conduct term is the conditional expectation E
([[??].sub.it][parallel][[??].sub.it]) (see Kumbhakar and Lovell 2000).
(29) Given our distributional assumptions, Almanidis, Qian, and Sickles
(2010) show that the analytical form for E
([[??].sub.it][parallel][[??].sub.it]) can be written as follows (30):
(16) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
where [[??].sub.it] = [[mu] x [[sigma].sup.2.sub.v] + [[??].sub.it]
[([g.sub.it][[sigma].sub.[theta]]).sup.2]]/[[sigma].sup.2.sub.it] and
[[bar.[sigma]].sub.it] = ([g.sub.it][[sigma].sub.[theta]])
[[sigma].sub.v]/[[sigma].sub.it]
Once we have a point estimator for [[??].sup.2.sub.it], a point
estimator for the conduct parameter [[theta].sub.it] (hereafter
[[??].sub.it]) can be obtained using the identity [[theta].sub.it]
[equivalent to] [[??].sub.it]/[g.sub.it] That is, [[??].sub.it] =
E([[??].sub.it] [parallel][[??].sub.it]) /[g.sub.it]. (31,32)
IV. EMPIRICAL APPLICATION TO CALIFORNIA ELECTRICITY MARKET
In this section, we illustrate the proposed approach with an
application to the California electricity generating market. This market
was opened to competition in 1998 allowing firms to compete to supply
electricity to the network. The wholesale prices stayed at
"normal" levels from 1998 to May 2000, and then skyrocketed
during summer and fall 2000, resulting in the breakdown of the
liberalized electricity market by the end of 2000. While the California
electricity crisis was a complex situation affected by a number of
factors, such as poor wholesale market design, absence of long-term
contracting, unexpected increase in generation input costs, and hike in
end-use electricity demand due to unusually hot weather, a number of
studies pointed to the evidence of significant market power in this
restructured market. (33)
Our empirical application analyzes the competitive behavior of five
strategic large firms from Puller's (2007) study of monopoly power
in California restructured electricity markets using the same sample
period (from April 1998 to November 2000). Following Borenstein,
Bushnell, and Wolak (2002), Kim and Knittel (2006), and Puller (2007),
we define five large firms that owned fossil-fueled generators (AES,
DST/Dynegy, Duke, Reliant, and Southern) as "strategic" firms,
that is, pricing according to Equation (5). The competitive fringe
includes generation from nuclear, hydroelectric, and small independent
producers, and imports from outside California. Puller (2007, p. 77)
argues that these suppliers were either relatively small or did not face
strong incentives to influence the price.34 Other studies (Borenstein et
al. 2008; Bushnell and Wolak 1999), however, find that competitive
fringe occasionally did have incentives to act strategically and bid
elastic supply and demand schedules to counter exercise of market power
by the strategic firms. Because electricity storage is prohibitively
costly, [[upsilon].sub.0] both strategic and non-strategic firms had to
produce a quantity equal to demand at all times. (36) The five large
firms and a competitive fringe interacted daily in a market where
rivals' costs were nearly common knowledge, which created strong
incentives for tacit collusion (Puller 2007). And the residual demand
for electricity was highly inelastic, which, given institutional
weaknesses of California Power Exchange (PX), allowed individual firms
to raise prices unilaterally (Wolak 2003).
We first carry out a standard econometric exercise and estimate
consistently by GMM the parameters of the pricing Equation (5). In
particular, and in order to be sure that our first stage is sound, we
try to reproduce Puller's (2007) results, using the same data set,
and the same specification for the pricing Equation (5), and the same
set of dependent and explanatory variables. (37)
After estimating the parameters of the pricing equation, we carry
out the second and third stages assuming particular distributions for
the conduct random term, all of them imposing the conduct term to be
positive and less than the inverse of firms' market shares.
A Pricing Equation and Data
Following Puller (2007, eq. 3) the pricing equation to be estimated
in the first stage of our procedure is:
(17) [(P - mc).sub.it] = [alpha] x [CAPBIND.sub.it] + [theta].
([P.sub.t] [q.sub.it]/[Q.sup.S.sub.strat,t])/[[eta].sup.D.sub.strat,t] +
[[epsilon].sub.it],
where [alpha] and [theta] = E([[theta].sub.it]) are parameters to
be estimated, P, is market price, [mc.sub.it] is firm's marginal
costs, [q.sub.it] is firm's output, [CAPBIND.sub.it] is a dummy
variable that is equal to 1 if capacity constraints are binding and
equal to 0 otherwise, [Q.sup.S.sub.strat] is total electricity supply by
the strategic firms, and [[eta].sup.D.sub.strat,t] is the elasticity of
residual hourly demand function of the five strategic firms.
We use hourly firm-level data on output and marginal cost. As in
Puller (2007), we focus on an hour of sustained peak demand from 5 to 6
p.m. (hour 18) each day, when intertemporal adjustment constraints on
the rate at which power plants can increase or decrease output are
unlikely to bind. Following Borenstein, Bushnell, and Wolak (2002), we
calculate the hourly marginal cost of fossil-fuel electricity plants as
the sum of marginal fuel, emission permit, and variable operating and
maintenance costs.38 We assume the marginal cost function to be constant
up to the capacity of the generator. A firm's marginal cost of
producing one more megawatt hour of electricity is defined as the
marginal cost of the most expensive unit that it is operating and that
has excess capacity.
Our measure of output is the total production by each firm's
generating units as reported in the Continuous Emissions Monitoring
System (CEMS), that contains data on the hourly operation status and
power output of fossil-fueled generation units in California. We use the
PX day-ahead electricity price, because 80%-90% of all transactions
occurred in the PX. Prices vary by location when transmission
constraints between the north and south bind. (39) Most firms own power
plants in a single transmission zone, so we use a PX zonal price.
For comparison purposes we also replicate Puller's (2007)
residual demand elasticity estimates to compute the expected value of
the random conduct term. Puller (2007) computes residual demand
elasticity as
(18) [[eta].sup.D.sub.strat,t] =
[??][Q.sup.S.sub.fringe]/[Q.sup.S.sub.strat,t],
where [Q.sup.S.sub.fringe] is electric power supply by the
competitive fringe, and [??] = [P.sub.t]/[P'.sub.t]
[Q.sup.S.sub.fringe,t] is the price elasticity of the fringe supply.
obtain the estimates of [??] from Puller (2007, Table 3, p. 83). Table 1
reports the summary statistics for all these variables.
Figure 1 shows calculated price-cost margins. This figure is almost
identical to Figure 1 in Puller (2007), and shows that margins vary
considerably over sample period. They are also higher during the third
and fourth quarters of each year, when total demand for electricity is
high.
B. Pricing Equation Estimates
This section describes estimation results of pricing Equation (5),
which result in the first-stage parameter estimates. We consider
different specifications, estimation methods, and time periods. First,
we estimate Equation (5) using elasticities of residual demand,
calculated based on PX data and based on Puller's (2007) estimates.
Second, we allow for output to be an endogenous variable as the error
term [[epsilon].sub.it] in Equation (5) could include marginal cost
shocks that are observed by the utility. (40) To account for endogeneity
of output we estimate Equation (5) by the ordinary least squares (OLS),
treating [P.sub.t] x [q.sub.it]/[Q.sup.S.sub.strat,t] (hereafter
[x.sub.it]) as exogenous variable, and by GMM using instruments for
[x.sub.it]. We use three
instruments for [x.sub.it]: the inverse of the day-ahead forecast of
total electricity output, 1/F[Q.sub.t], the dummy variable for binding
capacity constraints, [CAPBIND.sub.it] and firm's nameplate
generation capacity, [k.sub.it]. (41) The first two instruments are from
Puller (2007). (42) We assume that firm's generation capacity is
orthogonal to the error term because it can be viewed as a quasi-fixed
variable, independent of current levels of operation. We then perform
Hansen's (1982) J test, F-test for weak instruments (Staiger and
Stock 1997) and Hausman's (1978) specification test to test for
over-identifying restrictions, instruments' strength, and
consistency of the OLS estimates. Finally, we estimate Equation (5) over
two periods described in Puller (2007). The first period from July 1998
to April 1999 covers four strategic firms (AES, DST/Dynegy, Duke, and
Reliant). The second period from May 1999 to November 2000 covers five
strategic firms following Southern entry. (43)
Table 2 summarizes the specification, estimation, and fit of the
pricing Equation (5) over the periods analyzed in Puller (2007). The
results of Hansen's J test and F-test for weak instruments indicate
that the chosen instruments are generally valid, (44) whereas
Hausman's (1978) specification test indicates that the OLS results
are biased and inconsistent. The size of this OLS bias (measured by the
difference between OLS and GMM estimates) is large indicating a
significant correlation between the term [x.sub.it] and unobserved error
term. All estimated values of the conduct parameter are statistically
significant from zero. The GMM estimates of the conduct parameter, the
GMM estimated values of the conduct parameter are a bit smaller in both
periods to Puller's (2007) estimate of 0.97. However, the
difference from Puller's (2007) estimate is not statistically
significant, in the first period. It should be finally noted that
Coelli's (1995) tests indicate that the estimated residuals in both
periods do not follow a normal distribution and, in particular, that the
distribution of the estimated residual are positive skewed. This result
suggests the presence of a one-sided error term in Equation (5), as
expected given our specification of the composed error term in Equation
(6).
C. Variance Decomposition
Once all parameters of the pricing Equation (5) are estimated, we
can get estimates of the parameters describing the structure of the two
error components included in the composed random term [[epsilon].sub.it]
(second stage). Conditional on these parameter estimates, market power
scores can be then estimated for each firm by decomposing the estimated
residual into a noise component and a market-power component (third
stage). Following the discussion in Section III.B, to obtain the
estimates of the parameters describing the structure of error components
we first need to specify the distribution of the unobserved random
conduct term. We must also impose both lower and upper theoretical
bounds on the values of the random conduct term, that is, 0 [less than
or equal to] [[theta].sub.it] [less than or equal to] 1/[S.sub.it] To
achieve this objective, we use the truncated half normal distribution
model introduced by Almanidis, Qian, and Sickles (2010) that allows us
to impose both theoretical restrictions. (45)
In the empirical application we thus use two empirical strategies
to deal with the expected value of the conduct random term, which in
principle is unknown. The first strategy uses the mathematical
expression in Equation (13), and the second strategy relies on the
first-stage estimate of the conduct parameter [??]. The results based on
both of these strategies are summarized in the tables and figures below.
Table 3 describes the parameter estimates of the model describing
the structure of [[theta].sub.it] (and [v.sub.it] (i.e.,
[[sigma].sub.[theta]] and [[sigma].sub.v]) based on different
identification strategies and across different time periods, conditional
on the first-stage estimated parameters. Corrected standard errors have
been computed using the "sandwich form" expression suggested
by Alvarez et al. (2006) to allow for the fact that [[theta].sub.it] is
likely not independent over time, as it is actually assumed in our
specification. These authors point out that the estimated standard
errors, calculated under the assumption of independence observations,
will not be correct if independence does not hold.
In all cases, the variance of the conduct term is lower than the
variance of the traditional error term. This outcome indicates that both
demand and cost random shocks, which are captured by the traditional
error term, explains most of the overall variance of the composed error
term, [[sigma].sub.[epsilon]]. In all models we reject the hypothesis of
homoscedastic variation in both the noise term and the conduct term.
Many of the day-of-the-week dummy variables are statistically
significant in most periods. As expected, variation in conduct decreases
with firms' market shares, [S.sub.it]. The coefficient of the
target variable [DELTA][S.sub.it-1] is not significant in all periods
and using either the Equation (13) or the first-stage estimate of the
conduct parameter. This result is robust to the inclusion of other
alternative variables to capture the influence of the past behavior on
the present market conduct, such as week-differences and other lags of
the first-differences of market shares. The coefficient of dummy for DST
in the conduct term part of the model has a large positive and
significant coefficient in the first period. This result and the fact
that the average market share of DST in the first period is much less
than the average market share of its rivals explain our subsequent
finding that DST market power scores are much higher than those obtained
for the other strategic firms.
D. Firm-Specific Market Power Scores
Based on the previous estimates, the third stage allows us to
obtain firm-specific market power scores. Table 4 provides the
arithmetic average scores of each firm obtained using ML estimates of
the doubly truncated normal model. For comparison purposes we also
report the firm-specific estimates of Puller (2007).
Table 4 illustrates several interesting points that are worth
mentioning. First, like in Puller (2007), the estimated firm-level
values of the conduct parameter are closer to Cournot ([[theta].sub.it]
= 1) than to static collusion ([[theta].sub.it] = 1/[S.sub.it]) across
all specifications. A notable exception is DST, whose average market
power score is much larger than the other averages during this period.
Puller (2007, p. 84) finds similar result and argues that from these
high conduct parameter estimates may result from incomplete quantity
data for some of Dynegy's small peaker units. We do not, however,
find an increase in market power if we compare the average values in the
first period with those obtained in the second, regardless of which
empirical strategy we have used to deal with the expected value of the
conduct term.
Second, we find notable differences among utilities in terms of
market power. This suggests that assuming a common conduct parameter for
all firms is not appropriate. For instance, firms with smaller market
shares (e.g., DST) have consistently higher market power scores, whereas
firms with larger market shares (e.g., Duke) have consistently lower
market power scores, compared to other firms. This result is somehow
expected as the upper bound of the firm-market power scores is inversely
related to firms' market power. On the other hand, the estimated
differences in market power simply indicate that the traditional
first-stage parameter estimates can be interpreted as the industry
average market power, and hence it tends, as any average variable, to
overweight the market power of larger firms and underweight the market
power of smaller firms.
Third, as illustrated in Figure 2, our approach based on the
estimated distribution of the random conduct yields similar
time-invariant firm-specific market power scores to those estimated
using a fixed-effect regression approach over subperiods analyzed in
Puller (2007). This result demonstrates that both approaches are, in
practice, equivalent or interchangeable for estimating time-invariant
firm-specific market power scores.
Fourth, Figures 3A and 3B show the histograms of all the estimated
market power scores. (46) Analyzing the skewness of the estimated market
power scores is not easy because, as Wang and Schmidt (2009) pointed
out, a conditional expectation is a shrinkage estimator that tends to
attenuate the asymmetry of the observed distribution. Despite this, some
of the distributions in these figures are highly skewed. To examine this
issue in detail, we provide in Table 5 several tests of normality of the
estimated market power scores for the whole industry (including DST) and
for each firm separately. The numbers in this table suggest that we can
reject the null hypothesis of normality. Moreover, the positive values
of these tests indicate that all distributions are positively skewed,
regardless we have modeled the expected value of [[theta].sub.it] using
Equation (13) or the expected value of the conduct term is replaced with
the first-stage estimate of E([[theta].sub.it]).
Fifth, in a panel data setting the most important advantage of our
methodology over fixed-effects regression approach employed in Puller
(2007) is that we can analyze changes in market conduct over time.
Because our approach does not impose the restrictions on the temporal
path of these scores they are allowed to change from one day to another.
In Figures 4A, 4B, 5A, and 5B we show the temporal evolution of the
average market power scores of the four/five strategic firms during the
periods analyzed in the present paper. (47) Our results indicate that
the estimated firm-specific conduct parameters do vary significantly
across time. Notwithstanding these differences, firm-specific conduct
parameters generally tend to move in the same direction across time. The
notable exception is Duke, whose market strategies are occasionally
different from other firms. Puller (2007) notes that there is a
widespread belief that Duke violated California electricity market rules
and forward-contracted some of its production, which in part explains
observed Duke's conduct. The results are very robust to the choice
of the empirical strategy to identify the expected value of
[[theta].sub.it] (see Section IV.C).
Figures 4A and 4B show the intertemporal variation in estimated
conduct parameters over the period from July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999.
These figures show that during this period firms electricity pricing
were at or slightly below Cournot levels. The most notable exception is
DST/Dynegy, whose conduct was well above Cournot level during summer
1998 and close to full collusion in winter 1998/1999. As explained
above, high estimates of the conduct parameter for DST during these
periods may reflect the bias from incomplete generation asset data for
this firm. Another notable observation is rapid increase in the conduct
term for Reliant and DST in winter 1998/1999.
Figures 5A and 5B show the intertemporal variation in estimated
conduct parameters over the period from April 16, 1999 to May 30, 2000
following the entry of Southern. These figures demonstrate that
firms' pricing strategies are still close to Cournot levels for
most of this period. On average, over this period, the new entrant
Southern tends to have a higher value of the estimated conduct
parameter, whereas Duke tends to have a lower value of the estimated
conduct parameter. Firms' pricing strategies exhibit a larger
variation during this period. For example, the market conduct of
Southern increases above Cournot levels in summer 1999, and the market
conduct of Southern, Reliant, and AES increases above Cournot levels in
winter 1999. The results show that the conduct parameter of all firms
(and most notably DST) increases above Cournot levels during the
notorious price run-up period of summer 2000. These findings are
consistent with earlier studies of market power in California
electricity market. Joskow and Kahn (2002), for example, find evidence
of the strategic withholding of capacity by some generating firms during
summer 2000. As regards Southern, though pricing strategy is above
Cournot levels, it is not different from its strategy in summer 1999.
The important advantage of having time-varying and firm-specific
conduct parameters is that they contribute to better understanding of
firm-specific effects of a variety of external factors that impacted the
market during California electricity crisis. These include, among other
factors, changes of FERC price caps, variation in natural gas prices
resulting from disruptions in gas supply, and the costs of NOx permits
affected by the number of available pollution credits (Sweeney 2002).
Figures 5A and 5B illustrate the regulatory changes in FERC price
caps, which have effectively acted as a cap on PX prices. As of October
1999 this cap was set to $750 per MWh and was not binding until the
summer of 2000. After the ISO lowered the cap twice in 2000Q3 it began
to play a significant role in the firms' ability to exercise market
power (Puller 2007). Figures 5A and 5B show that the market power scores
of AES and DST have considerably increased over the period of higher
price caps in October 1999 to August 2000, whereas the market power
scores of other firms were less affected. Tightening the price caps in
August 2000 has lowered market power scores for all market participants.
Figures 6 and 7 demonstrate correlations between market power
scores and NOx permit prices and natural gas prices, respectively.
Figure 6 shows that Duke and Southern market power scores are positively
correlated with NOx permit prices, whereas other three firms show little
(if any) correlation between market power scores and NOx permit prices.
Figure 7 shows that Duke and Southern market power scores are positively
correlated with natural gas prices, DST market power scores are
negatively correlated with natural gas prices, whereas Reliant and AES
market power scores are not correlated with natural gas prices. These
results indicate that variations in regulatory policies and input prices
have indeed affected strategic behavior of at least some market
participants.
E. Robustness Analyses
In order to examine the robustness of our results, we summarize in
this section the results that have been obtained using alternative
specifications of the basic model discussed in previous sections. In
particular, in addition to the firm-specific market power estimates of
Puller (2007) and our previous third-stage market power scores, Table 6
reports the firm-specific market power scores when: (a) we exclude those
hours in which capacity binds; (b) we allow for firm-specific conduct
parameters in the first-stage pricing equation; (c) the upper bound of
the market power random term is time invariant; and (d) the demand
elasticities are computed using PX data. Table 6 provides all these
scores either using the mathematical expression in Equation (13) or the
first-stage estimate of 9.48
The estimated coefficient of the capacity binding variable in Table
2 is very noisy. Conditional on capacity being binding, the shadow value
associated to this restriction might be quite different as it likely
depends on observed and unobserved market conditions. For this reason,
it is interesting to examine the results excluding those hours in which
capacity binds and therefore the FOC does not hold. While the GMM
estimate of 9 is 9.96 for the first period, it is 9.81 for the second
period. As the first-stage estimates of the conduct parameter in both
periods are quite similar to that obtained using our previous model that
include the capacity binding variable, the computed market power scores
are also comparable to the previous ones. Therefore, our results are
robust to the existence of heterogeneous shadow values associated to the
capacity binding restriction.
The second robustness analysis involves estimating the conduct
parameter at the firm level in the first-stage pricing equation, in
order to account for heterogeneity across firms. This model reproduces
the fixed-effect strategy used by Puller (2997). In this case, both
first- and third-stage market power scores are provided in Table 6. This
model allows us to examine whether those firms with larger conduct terms
every period (e.g., DST) might appear "by surprise" as being
above the unconditional mean because in the first stage we use a common
conduct parameter for all firms. That could generate biases on how the
market power scores are being estimated (conditional expectation) in the
second and third stages of our procedure. Again our firm-specific
first-stage market power estimates are consistent with those obtained by
Puller using also a fixed-effect treatment of the conduct parameters,
the average market power scores are akin to those obtained using the
basic (common conduct parameter) model. Just the average market power
score for DST in the first period is a bit less than the previous ones.
The next issue that is examined in this section is the potential
endogeneity of the upper bound of the doubly truncated random term. Our
upper bound is determined by the economic theory, but it not clear from
an econometric point of view whether this bound is endogenous or
exogenous as it endogenously changes over time. To examine this issue we
have re-estimated the basic model using a time-invariant upper bound.
Instead of using the inverse of the contemporaneous market shares, that
is, 1/[S.sub.it], in this model we use the inverse of the firm-specific
averages of their contemporaneous market shares, that is,
1/[[bar.S].sub.i] where [[bar.S].sub.i] =
1/T[[SIGMA].sup.T.sub.t=1][s.sub.it]. The computed firm-specific
averages are likely exogenous variables because the effect of a single
contemporaneous market share on [[bar.S].sub.i] is negligible due to the
large number of observations of each firm, and because firms' size
is mostly predetermined in the onset of the liberalization process.
Overall, the average market power scores of this model are quite similar
to those obtained using the basic model, except for DST in the first
period of the sample that once again decreases. (49)
Finally, in Table 6 we show the average market power scores that
are obtained using a different approach to compute the elasticity of the
residual demand function of the five strategic firms. This is because
Puller (2007) does not observe actual residual demand schedules.
Instead, he estimates the supply function of competitive fringe, and
calculates the slope of the fringe supply, "which has the same
magnitude but opposite sign of the slope of the residual demand faced by
the five strategic firms" (Puller 2007, p. 78). This is problematic
because Puller's (2007) estimates are correct if and only if all
fringe firms bid competitive schedules. This assumption is questioned by
a number of studies. Instead we use the estimates of residual demand
elasticities based on actual bids from PX as suggested by Wolak (2003).
(50)
Similar to our basic model our first-stage conduct parameter
estimates are closer to Cournot than to static collusion. While the GMM
estimate of [??] is 0.71 for the first period, it is 1.11 for the second
period. Therefore, the first-stage estimate of the conduct parameter in
the first (second) period is a bit smaller (larger) than that obtained
using our previous model based on Puller's demand elasticity.
Regarding the computed market power scores in Table 6, the results are
highly consistent with our previous model based on Puller's demand
elasticity when the GMM estimate of [??] is used to deal with the
expected value of the conduct term when estimating the structure of both
[v.sub.it] and [S.sub.it] [[theta].sub.it] random terms. They are also
comparable to the previous ones when the mathematical expression in
Equation (13) is used to model in the second stage the expected value of
the conduct term, except for DST in the first period. Indeed, while the
other market power levels in this period are highly consistent with our
previous scores, we find a zero market power score for DST. (51) Frutos
and Fabra (2012) show in a residual demand framework that the FOC of
profit maximization in Equation (1) only holds for those firms setting
the price. They also show that non price-setters behave "as
if' they were price-takers. The zero market power score for DST can
then be justified from a theoretical point of view if DST has normally
behaved as a price-taker firm and bid at marginal cost.
V. CONCLUSIONS
This study contributes to the literature on estimating market power
in homogenous product markets. Our econometric approach allows for the
value of estimated conduct parameter to vary across both firms and time.
We estimate a composed error model, where the stochastic part of the
firm's pricing equation is formed by two random variables: the
traditional error term, capturing random shocks, and a random conduct
term, which measures the degree of market power. The model can be
estimated in three stages. While the first stage of our model is similar
to the previous literature, the second and the third stages allow us to
distinguish variation in market power from volatility in demand and
cost, and get firm-specific market power scores, conditional on the
first-stage parameter estimates.
Treating firms' conduct as a random parameter helps solving
the over-parameterization problem in the continuous time. The second and
third stages of our procedure allow us to identify groups of suspected
cartel members, "maverick" firms, or changes in mark-ups which
cannot be explained by "normal" random shocks. In this sense,
the proposed procedure can be viewed as a collusive screening procedure.
Other advantages of our approach are its applicability to
cross-sectional or short data sets. Moreover, firm-specific market power
estimates can be obtained just using cross-sectional data sets because
our approach relies on distributional assumptions. Our approach is also
useful in a panel data setting when the assumption of time-invariant
conduct is not reasonable. In addition, by imposing upper bound on the
value of estimated conduct parameter we ensure that estimated market
power scores are always consistent with the economic theory.
The main distinctive feature of our approach is that model
identification is based on the assumption that the conduct term follows
a one-sided distribution, which, to our best knowledge, has not been
previously used in the empirical industrial organization literature.
Another feature that distinguishes our paper from previous studies is
the attempt to estimate a double-bounded distribution that imposes both
lower and upper theoretical bounds to a continuous random conduct term.
To achieve this objective, we adapt one of the most recent stochastic
frontier models in production economics to our framework. To our
knowledge, this is the first time the stochastic frontier models are
used to measure market power.
We illustrate the proposed approach with an application to the
California wholesale electricity market using a well-known data set from
Puller (2007). After estimating the parameters of the pricing equation,
we implement the second and third stages based on the truncated normal
distribution, which imposes both lower and upper theoretical bounds on
the values of the random conduct term. Similar to the findings of Puller
(2007) our estimated average firm-level values of the conduct parameter
are closer to Cournot than to static collusion across all samples and
specifications. This result demonstrates that both approaches are, in
practice, equivalent or interchangeable for estimating time-invariant
firm-specific market power scores. The analysis of firm-specific conduct
parameters suggests that realization of market power varies over both
time and firms, and rejects the assumption of a common conduct parameter
for all firms.
There are several interesting extensions of the proposed model than
can be explored in the future. (52) First, if firms are not fully
efficient, our price equation should include a cost inefficiency term in
addition to the noise and conduct terms. Estimating a model with 2
one-sided error terms is not trivial. Promising strategies could be
using copula-based methods, or using different distributions for the
cost and conduct terms (e.g., homoscedastic vs. heteroscedastic).
Second, it would be interesting to examine whether the model could be
estimated without distributional assumptions on the conduct term, using
similar semiparametric specifications to Tran and Tsionas (2009) and
Parmeter, Wang and Kumbhakar (2017). Third, our model prevents
zeroconduct values from occurring. In this case, a zero inefficiency
stochastic frontier (ZISF) model of Kumbhakar, Parmeter, and Tsionas
(2013) could be estimated. More details on this model can be found in
Rho and Schmidt (2015). The socalled ZISF model would allow us to
distinguish between firms that tend to behave as perfectly competitive
firms (i.e., tend to be "fully efficient") and firms that, for
some reasons, do have market power. A ZISF-market power specification of
our model would also permit to identify the determinants of being a
perfectly competitive firm. Regulators or policy makers might find the
latter information very useful to design measures aiming to promote
competitive behavior in the homogenous products market.
ABBREVIATIONS
CEMS: Continuous Emissions Monitoring System
FOC: First-Order Condition
GMM: Generalized Method of Moments
ML: Maximum Likelihood
MM: Method of Moment
NEIO: New Empirical Industrial Organization
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
PX: California Power Exchange
ZISF: Zero Inefficiency Stochastic Frontier
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12539
Online Early Publication December 19, 2017
REFERENCES
Abreu, D., D. Pearce, and E. Stacchetti. "Optimal Cartel
Equilibria with Imperfect Monitoring." Journal of Economic Theory,
39(1), 1986, 251-69.
Almanidis, P., J. Qian, and R. Sickles. "Bounded Stochastic
Frontiers with an Application to the US Banking Industry:
1984-2009." Unpublished manuscript, Rice University. 2010. Accessed
November 28, 2017. http://
www.uh.edu/~cmurray/TCE15/Papers/Almanidis.pdf
Alvarez, A., C. Amsler, L. Orea, and P. Schmidt. "Interpreting
and Testing the Scaling Property in Models Where Inefficiency Depends on
Firm Characteristics." Journal of Productivity Analysis, 25(3),
2006, 201-12.
Appelbaum, E. "The Estimation of the Degree of Oligopoly
Power." Journal of Econometrics, 19(2-3), 1982, 287-99.
Borenstein, S. "The Trouble with Electricity Markets:
Understanding California's Restructuring Disaster." Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 16(1), 2002, 191-211.
52. We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting some of these
extensions.
Borenstein, S., and N. L. Rose. "Competition and Price
Dispersion in the US Airline Industry." Journal of Political
Economy, 102(4), 1994,653-83.
Borenstein, S., J. B. Bushnell, and F. A. Wolak. "Measuring
Market Inefficiencies in California's Restructured Wholesale
Electricity Market." American Economic Review, 92(5), 2002,
1376-405.
Borenstein, S., J. B. Bushnell, C. R. Knittel, and C. Wolfram.
"Inefficiencies and Market Power in Financial Arbitrage: A Study of
California's Electricity Markets." Journal of Industrial
Economics, 56(2), 2008, 347-78.
Brander, A. J., and A. Zhang. "Dynamic Oligopoly Behavior in
the Airline Industry." International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 11(3), 1993, 407-35.
Bresnahan, T. "Empirical Studies of Industries with Market
Power," in Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 2, Chapter 17,
edited by R. Schmalensee and R. Willig. Amsterdam, The Netherlands:
North-Holland, 1989, 1011-57.
Bushnell, J. B., and F. A. Wolak, "Regulation and the Leverage
of Local Market Power: Reliability Must-Run Contracts in the California
Electricity Market." POWER Working Paper No. PWP-070, University of
California Energy Institute, 1999.
Clay, K., and W. Troesken. "Further Tests of Static Oligopoly
' Models: Whiskey, 1882-1898." Journal of Industrial
Economics, 51(2), 2003, 151-66.
Coelli, T. "Estimators and Hypothesis Tests for a Stochastic
Frontier Function: A Monte Carlo Analysis." Journal of Productivity
Analysis, 6(3), 1995, 247-68.
Corts, K. "Conduct Parameters and the Measurement of Market
Power." Journal of Econometrics, 88(2), 1999, 227-50.
Das, A., and S. C. Kumbhakar. "Markup and Efficiency of Indian
Banks: An Input Distance Function Approach." Empirical Economics,
51(4), 2016, 1689-719.
Delis, M. D.. and E. G. Tsionas. "The Joint Estimation of
Bank-Level Market Power and Efficiency." Journal of Banking and
Finance, 33(10), 2009, 1842-50.
Ellison, G. "Theories of Cartel Stability and the Joint
Executive Committee." RAND Journal of Economics, 25(1), 1994,
37-57.
Emvalomatis, G., S. E. Stefanou, and A. O. Lansink. "A
Reduced-Form Model for Dynamic Efficiency Measurement: Application to
Dairy Farms in Germany and the Netherlands." American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, 93(1), 2011, 161-74.
Fabra, N., and J. Toro. "Price Wars and Collusion in the
Spanish Electricity Market." International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 23(3-4), 2005, 155-81.
Figuieres, C., A. Jean-Marie, N. Querou, and M. Tidball. Theory of
Conjectural Variations. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing, 2004.
Fried, H., C. A. Knox Lovell, and S. S. Schmidt. The Measurement of
Productive Efficiency and Productivity Growth. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 2008.
Frutos, M.-A., and N. Fabra. "How to Allocate Forward
Contracts: The Case of Electricity Markets." European Economic
Review, 56(3), 2012,451 -69.
Gallet, A. G., and J. R. Schroeter. "The Effects of the
Business Cycle on Oligopoly Coordination: Evidence from the U.S. Rayon
Industry." Review of Industrial Organization, 10(2), 1995, 181-96.
Genesove, D., and W. Mullin. "Testing Static Oligopoly Models:
Conduct and Cost in the Sugar Industry, 1890-1914." RAND Journal of
Economics, 29(2), 1994, 355-77.
Gollop, D., and M. Roberts. "Firm Interdependence in
Oligopolistic Markets." Journal of Econometrics, 10(3),
1979,313-31.
Green, E. J., and R. H. Porter. "Noncooperative Collusion
under Imperfect Price Information." Econometrica, 52(1), 1984,
87-100.
Hamilton, J. D. "Analysis of Time Series Subject to Changes in
Regime." Journal of Econometrics, 45(1-2), 1989, 39-70.
Hansen, L. P. "Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method
of Moments Estimators." Econometrica, 50(4), 1982, 1029-54.
Hausman, J. A. "Specification Tests in Econometrics."
Econometrica, 46(6), 1978, 1251-71.
Huang, T.-H., N.-H. Liu, and S. C. Kumbhakar. "Joint
Estimation of the Lerner Index and Cost Efficiency Using Copula
Methods." Empirical Economics, 2017a, https:// doi
.org/10.1007/s00181 - 016-1216- z.
Huang, T.-H., D.-L. Chiang, and S.-W. Chao. "A New Approach to
Jointly Estimating the Lerner Index and Cost Efficiency for Multi-Output
Banks under a Stochastic Meta-Frontier Framework." Quarterly Review
of Economics and Finance, 65, 2017b, 212-26.
Itaya, J.-I., and M. Okamura. "Conjectural Variations and
Voluntary Public Good Provision in a Repeated Game Setting."
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 5(1), 2003,51-66.
Itaya, J.-I., and K. Shimomura. "A Dynamic Conjectural
Variations Model in the Private Provision of Public Goods: A
Differential Game Approach." Journal of Public Economics, 81(1),
2001, 153-72.
Iwata, G. "Measurement of Conjectural Variations in
Oligopoly." Econometrica, 42, 1974, 949-66.
Jamasb, T., L. Orea, and M. Pollitt. "Estimating Marginal Cost
of Quality Improvements: The Case of the UK Electricity Distribution
Companies." Energy Economics, 34(5), 2012, 1498-506.
Jaumandreu, J., and J. Lorences. "Modelling Price Competition
across Many Markets (An Application to the Spanish Loans Market)."
European Economic Review, 46(1), 2002, 93-115.
Jondrow, J., C. A. K. Lovell, S. Materov, and P. Schmidt. "On
the Estimation of Technical Efficiency in the Stochastic Frontier
Production Function Model." Journal of Econometrics, 19(2/3), 1982,
233-38.
Joskow, P. L., and E. Kahn. "A Quantitative Analysis of
Pricing Behavior in California's Wholesale Electricity Market
during Summer 2000." Energy Journal, 23, 2002, 1-35.
Kim, D. W., and C. R. Knittel. "Biased in Static Oligopoly
Models? Evidence from the California Electricity Market." Journal
of Industrial Economics, 54(4), 2006, 451-70.
Koetter, M., and T. Poghosyan. "The Identification of
Technology Regimes in Banking: Implications for the Market
Power-Fragility Nexus." Journal of Banking and Finance, 33(8),
2009, 1413-22.
Koetter, M., J. W. Kolari, and L. Spierdijk. "Enjoying the
Quiet Life under Deregulation? Evidence from Adjusted Lerner Indices for
U.S. Banks." Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(2),
2012,462-80.
Kole, S., and K. Lehn. "Deregulation and the Adaptation of
Governance Structure: The Case of the U.S. Airline Industry."
Journal of Financial Economics, 52(1), 1999, 79-117.
Kumbhakar, S. C., and C. A. K. Lovell. Stochastic Frontier
Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.
Kumbhakar, S. C., C. F. Parmeter, and E. G. Tsionas. "A Zero
Inefficiency Stochastic Frontier Model." Journal of Econometrics,
172(1), 2013, 66-76.
Lewbel, A. "Using Heteroscedasticity to Identify and Estimate
Mismeasured and Endogenous Regressor
Models." Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 30(1),
2012, 67-80.
Li, Q. "Estimating a Stochastic Production Frontier When the
Adjusted Error Is Symmetric." Economics letters, 52(3), 1996,
221-28.
Nevo, A. "Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal
Industry." Econometrica, 69(2), 2001, 307-42.
Newbery, D. "Predicting Market Power in Wholesale Electricity
Markets." Working Paper No. 2009/03, European University Institute,
2009.
Olson, J. A., P. Schmidt, and D. M. Waldman. "A Monte Carlo
Study of Estimators of Stochastic Frontier Production Functions."
Journal of Econometrics, 13(1), 1980, 67-82.
Parmeter, C. F., and S. C. Kumbhakar. "Efficiency Analysis: A
Primer on Recent Advances." Foundations and Trends in Econometrics,
7(3-4), 2014, 191-385.
Parmeter, C. F., H.-J. Wang, and S. C. Kumbhakar.
"Nonparametric Estimation of the Determinants of
Inefficiency." Journal of Productivity Analysis, 47(3), 2017,
205-21.
Perloff, J. M., L. Karp, and A. Golan. Estimating Market Power and
Strategies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007.
Porter, R. H. "A Study of Cartel Stability: The Joint
Executive Committee, 1880-1886." Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2),
1983a, 301-14.
--. "Optimal Cartel Trigger Price Strategies." Journal of
Economic Theory, 29(2), 1983b, 313-38.
Puller, S. "Pricing and Firm Conduct in California's
Deregulated Electricity Market." Review of Economics and
Statistics, 89(1), 2007, 75-87.
--. "Estimation of Competitive Conduct When Firms Are
Efficiently Colluding: Addressing the Corts Critique." Applied
Economics Letters, 16(15), 2009, 1497-500.
Reiss, P. C., and F. A. Wolak. "Structural Econometric
Modeling: Rationales and Examples from Industrial Organization."
Handbook of Econometrics, 6, 2007, 4280-370.
Rho, S., and P. Schmidt. "Are All Firms Inefficient?"
Journal of Productivity Analysis, 43(3), 2015, 327-49.
Rigobon, R. "Identification through Heteroskedasticity."
Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 2003, 777-92.
Rotemberg, J. J., and G. A. Saloner. "Supergame-Theoretic
Model of Price Wars during Booms." American Economic Review, 76,
1986, 390-407.
Staiger, D., and J. H. Stock. "Instrumental Variables
Regression with Weak Instruments." Econometrica, 65(3), 1997,
557-86.
Stigler, G. J. "A Theory of Oligopoly." Journal of
Political Economy, 72(1), 1964, 44-61.
Sweeney, J. The California Electricity Crisis. Stanford, CA: Hoover
Institution Press, 2002.
Tran, K. C., and E. G. Tsionas. "Estimation of Nonparametric
Inefficiency Effects Stochastic Frontier Models with an Application to
British Manufacturing." Economic Modelling, 26(5), 2009, 904-9.
Verbeek, M. A Guide to Modern Econometrics. 1st ed. Chichester, UK:
John Wiley and Sons, 2000.
Von der Fehr, N.-H. M., E. S. Amundsen, and L. Bergman. "The
Nordic Market: Signs of Stress?" The Energy Journal, 26,
2005,71-98.
Wang, W. S., and P. Schmidt. "On the Distribution of Estimated
Technical Efficiency in Stochastic Frontier Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 148(1), 2009, 36-45.
Wolak, F. A. "Measuring Unilateral Market Power in Wholesale
Electricity Markets: The California Market, 1998-2000." American
Economic Review, 93(2), 2003, 425-30.
--. "Lessons from the California Electricity Crisis," in
Electricity Deregulation Choices and Challenges, edited by J. M. Griffin
and S. L. Puller. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2005.
Wolfram, C. D. "Measuring Duopoly Power in the British
Electricity Spot Market." American Economic Review, 89(4), 1999,
805-26.
Woo, C. K, A. Olson, I. Horowitzc, and S. Lu. "BiDirectional
Causality in California's Electricity and Natural-Gas
Markets." Energy Policy, 34(15), 2006, 2060-207.
LUIS OREA and JEVGENIJS STEINBUKS *
* The authors would like to express their sincere gratitude to Ben
Hobbs for his invaluable help and support. They are extremely grateful
to Steve Puller and Carolyn Berry for helping them with getting CEMS and
California PX bidding data, and to Chiara Lo Prete for assisting them
with computation of residual demand elasticities based on PX bidding
data. They also thank William Greene, David Newbery, Jacob LaRiviere,
Shaun McRae, Mar Reguant, Peter Schmidt, two anonymous reviewers, and
the participants of the 3rd International Workshop on Empirical Methods
in Energy Economics, the 9th Annual International Industrial
Organization Conference, the Spanish Economic Association Annual
Congress, and the American Economic Association Annual Meetings for
their helpful comments and suggestions. Responsibility for the content
of the paper is the authors' alone and does not necessarily reflect
the views of their institutions, or member countries of the World Bank.
J.S. appreciates the financial support from the UK Engineering and
Physical Sciences Research Council, grant "Supergen FlexNet."
L.O. is grateful for financial assistance for this work provided by the
Regional Government of the Principality of Asturias in conjunction with
FEDER (Grant FC-15-GRUPIN14-048). Orea: Professor, Department of
Economics, School of Economics and Business, University of Oviedo,
33006, Oviedo, Spain. Phone +34 985106243, Fax +34 985236670, E-mail
lorea@uniovi.es Steinbuks: Economist, Development Research Group, The
World Bank, Washington, DC 20433. Phone 202 473-9345, Fax 202 522-2714,
E-mail jsteinbuks@worldbank.org
(1.) For an excellent survey of other approaches to estimating
market power in industrial organization literature, see Perloff, Karp,
and Golan (2007).
(2.) In a symmetric equilibrium, the upper bound of inequality 0
< [[theta].sub.it] < 1/[S.sub.it] would be equal to the number of
firms, N.
(3.) Some studies interpret conduct parameter as a
"conjectural variation," that is, how rivals' output
changes in response to an increase in firm i's output. It is also
sometimes argued that the conjectural variation parameter results from
the reduced form of a more complex dynamic game, such as a tacit
collusion game (e.g., Itaya and Shimomura 2001; Itaya and Okamura 2003;
Figuieres et al. 2004, and references therein). Other studies (Bresnahan
1989; Reiss and Wolak 2007) argue that with the exception of a limited
number of special cases (e.g., perfect competition, Cournot-Nash, and
monopoly) there is no satisfactory economic interpretation of this
parameter as a measure of firm behavior. Sorting out between these
theoretical complications is beyond the scope of this study.
(4.) Newbery (2009) argues that more theoretically attractive
models, such as, for example, supply function equilibrium models, pose
formidable practical and conceptual problems if they are to be used for
market monitoring, and even more so in quasi-judicial investigations of
the kind conducted by competition authorities. On the other hand more
simple descriptive measures based on the Cournot model of oligopolistic
competition, such as, for example, price-cost margins or Herfindahl
Hirshman Index are inconsistent with empirical evidence. High market
shares and low elasticities may lead to very high price-cost mark-ups
that are considerably higher than observed (e.g., Von der Fehr,
Amundsen, and Bergman 2005).
(5.) As the problem of repeated oligopoly interaction has received
greater attention, the estimation of time-varying conduct parameters
that are truly dynamic has become an issue. Indeed, Stigler's
(1964) theory of collusive oligopoly implies that, in an uncertain
environment, both collusive and price-war periods will be seen in the
data (see for instance Green and Porter 1984 and Rotemberg and Saloner
1986, who predict opposite relationships between prices/mark-ups and
demand evolution). Moreover, Abreu, Pearce, and Stacchetti (1986) find
that in complex cartels the length of price wars (i.e., changes in
conduct parameter) is random because there are "triggers" for
both beginning a price war and for ending one. It is therefore difficult
to impose plausible structural conditions and estimate firms'
conduct over time.
(6.) In many treatments of oligopoly as a repeated game, firms
expect deviations from the collusive outcome. Firms expect that if they
deviate from the collusive arrangement, others will too. This
expectation deters them from departing from their share of the collusive
output. Because these deviations are unobserved in an uncertain
environment, each firm might have its own expectation about what would
happen if it deviates from collusive output.
(7.) As in Porter (1983b), Brander and Zhang (1993), and Gallet and
Schroeter (1995), Maximum Likelihood techniques can be used to estimate
all parameters of the model in a unique stage. However this does not
allow us to address the endogeneity issues that appear when estimating
the pricing equation (1).
(8.) Although the model does not require asymmetry of the one-sided
distribution to be identified (see Li 1996), our specification of the
conduct term allows for different degrees of asymmetries in the
distribution of [[theta].sub.it].
(9.) See Rigobon (2003), Lewbel (2012), and references therein.
(10.) The regime switches only occur when a firm's quantity is
never observed by another firm and, hence, deviations cannot be directly
observed. This is not the case in the electricity generating industry
analyzed in the empirical section as market participants had access to
accurate data on rivals' real-time generation.
(11.) Kole and Lehn (1999) argue that for many firms the
decision-making apparatus is slow to react to changes in the market
environment within which it operates, due to the costs to reorient
decision-makers to a new "game plan." In particular, the
existing culture or the limited experience of the firm in newly
restructured markets may be such that enhancing market power may not be
immediately possible. In addition, we would also expect gradual changes
in firms' conduct in a dynamic framework if firms are engaging in
efficient tacit collusion and are pricing below the static monopoly
level, and when there is a high persistence in regimes (Ellison 1994).
(12.) For a comprehensive survey of this literature, see Kumbhakar
and Lovell (2000), Fried, Knox Lovell, and Schmidt (2008), and Parmeter
and Kumbhakar (2014).
(13.) As pointed out by an anonymous reviewer, an alternative
distribution would be to use the uniform distribution, as proposed by Li
(1996). We cannot use this specification in our setting because the
upper limit of the uniform distribution is set by the economic theory,
and it is not a parameter to be estimated as in Li (1996). As the
variance of the inefficiency (market power) term is attached to the
upper limit of the uniform distribution, this distribution does not
allow for heroscedastic specifications. From an economic view, it is
also worth mentioning that the uniform distribution assumes that all
market power values are equally probable, and this might prevent
obtaining industry outcomes where most market power scores are similar,
such as in all-inclusive collusion outcomes or when all firms are
competing, say, a la Cournot.
(14.) Delis and Tsionas (2009), Koetter and Poghosyan (2009),
Koetter, Kolari, and Spierdijk (2012), and Das and Kumbhakar (2016) also
estimate market power within a model that uses stochastic frontier
analysis, but in these papers, the use of stochastic frontier analysis
is only to recover cost inefficiency first, and then determine its
impact on market power.
(15.) Ignoring that firms might be pricing to reflect their
inefficiencies is likely more important in applications where the
products are heterogeneous and firms set their own prices (see Huang,
Chiang, and Chao 2017b, p. 4).
(16.) This is the strategy followed, for instance, by Brander and
Zhang (1993), Nevo (2001), and Jaumandreu and Lorences (2002).
(17.) Corts (1999) argues that traditional approaches to estimating
the conduct parameter from static pricing equations yield inconsistent
estimates of the conduct parameter if firms are engaged in an effective
tacit collusion. The robustness of the conduct parameter approach
depends, in addition, on the discount factor and the persistency of the
demand. Puller (2009) derives and estimates a more general model that
addresses the Corts critique. The results from estimating the more
general model for the California market yielded estimates very similar
to the static model. This similarity comes from the fact that
"California market [can be] viewed as an infinitely repeated game
with a discount factor between days very close to 1" Puller (2007,
p. 84). Our empirical application to California electricity market as a
static model is therefore sufficient for estimating market power
consistently.
(18.) The GMM estimator has the additional advantage over ML in
that it does not require a specific distributional assumption for the
errors, which makes the approach robust to non-normality and
heteroscedasticity of unknown term (Verbeek 2000, p. 143).
(19.) This partial collusion equilibrium is reasonable in markets
with many firms, where coordination among all firms is extremely
difficult to maintain as the number of firms in the collusive scheme is
too high or other market characteristics (e.g., markets with
differentiated products) make coordination too costly.
(20.) It is well known that secret price cuts (or secret sales) by
cartel members are almost always a problem in cartels. For instance,
Ellison (1994) finds that secret price cuts occurred during 25% of the
cartel period and that the price discounts averaged about 20%. Also see
Borenstein and Rose (1994).
(21.) We thank William Green and Peter Schmidt for clarifying this
point. An alternative approach to addressing endogeneity problem is
replacing [theta] with a formula measuring the (conditional) expectation
of [[theta].sub.it]. This empirical strategy has two shortcomings.
First, it implies assuming a particular distribution for
[[theta].sub.it]. This assumption is made in the second stage of our
procedure, not in our current first stage. And second, as this
expectation term is nonlinear, this empirical strategy prevents using
standard GMM estimators as in this case the GMM estimation becomes a
nonlinear optimization problem where an explicit matrix result does not
exist.
(22.) In our application we also allow both [v.sub.it] and
[[theta].sub.it] be heteroscedastic, which further reinforces the use of
an efficient GMM estimator.
(23.) Note that, for notational ease, we use o9 to indicate
hereafter the standard deviation of the pretruncated normal
distribution, and not the standard deviation of the post-truncated
variable [[theta].sub.it] as before.
(24.) An important caveat in estimating doubly truncated normal
models is whether it is globally identifiable. Almanidis, Qian, and
Sickles (2010) show that identification problems may arise when both the
mean and the upper-bound of the pretruncated normal distribution are
estimated simultaneously. Fortunately, these problems vanish in a
structural model of market power because the upper-bound is fixed by the
theory and it does not need to be estimated in practice.
(25.) In our empirical application we have scaled the day-ahead
forecast of total demand dividing it by its sample mean in order to put
all explanatory variables in a similar scale.
(26.) An anonymous reviewer has correctly noted that we are
modeling the variance (not the mean) of the pretruncated normal
distribution. But, it should be taken into account that at the end we
are modeling the mean (and the variance) of [[theta].sub.it] as it is a
function of the variance of the original pretruncated normal
distribution.
(27.) Since these variables in a regime-switching framework mainly
affect the probability of starting a price war, they are labeled as
"trigger" variables or "triggers." We prefer using
the term "target" because in our model we do not have
collusion and price-war regimes, and hence we do not have to estimate
transition probabilities from one discrete regime to another.
(28.) We have also included other variables in order to capture the
influence of past observables on actual market conduct. In particular,
we have also used week-differences and other lags of the
first-differences of market shares. Following Ellison (1994) we have
also created more sophisticated target variables, such as deviations
with respect to predicted value, using the average of the same variable
for the previous 7 days. The results were almost the same as those
obtained using [DELTA][S.sub.it-1].
(29.) Both the mean and the mode of the conditional distribution
can be used as a point estimator for the conduct term [[??].sub.it].
However, the mean is, by far, the most employed in the frontier
literature.
(30.) For notational ease, we ignore in Equation (16) that both
[[sigma].sub.v] and [[sigma].sub.[theta]] are heteroscedastic.
(31.) Although [[??].sub.it] is the minimum mean squared error
estimate of [[theta].sub.it], and it is unbiased in the unconditional
sense [E ([[??].sub.it] - [[theta].sub.it]) = 0], it is a shrinkage of
[[theta].sub.it] toward its mean (Wang and Schmidt 2009). An implication
of shrinkage is that on average we will overestimate 0it when it is
small and underestimate 0it when it is large. This result, however,
simply reflects the familiar principle that an optimal (conditional
expectation) forecast is less variable than the term being forecasted.
(32.) As pointed out by an anonymous reviewer, it is worth
mentioning that our estimates of market power may not be invariant to
scale because we are using prices and marginal costs in levels.
(33.) For excellent surveys of the California electricity market
restructuring disaster, see Borenstein (2002), Sweeney (2002), and Wolak
(2005).
(34.) Specifically, Puller (2007) argues that independent and
nuclear units were paid under regulatory side agreements, so their
revenues were independent of the price in the energy market. The owners
of hydroelectric assets were the same utilities that were also buyers of
power and had very dulled incentives to influence the price. Finally,
firms importing power into California were likely to behave
competitively because most were utilities with the primary
responsibility of serving their native demand and then simply exporting
any excess generation.
(35.) One of the ways of storing electricity for load balancing is
through pumped-storage hydroelectricity. The method stores energy in the
form of water, pumped from a lower elevation reservoir to a higher
elevation. Low-cost off-peak electric power is used to run the pumps.
During periods of high electrical demand, the stored water is released
through turbines to produce electric power. In California, there is a
significant amount of hydropower including some pumped storage.
Notwithstanding relative abundance pumped storage in California, its
potential for load balancing is limited as hydropower schedules are
relatively fixed in part due to environmental (low flow maintenance,
etc.) rules.
(36.) Modeling of market power in wholesale electricity markets
becomes more complex if firms forward-contract some of their output. As
Puller (2007, p. 85) notes, in the presence of unobserved contract
positions the estimate of conduct parameters would be biased. This was
generally not an issue in California wholesale electricity market during
sample period. As Borenstein (2002, p. 199) points out, "Although
the investor owned utilities had by 2000 received permission to buy a
limited amount of power under long-term contracts, they were [... ]
still procuring about 90 percent of their "net short" position
[...] in the Power Exchange's day-ahead or the system
operator's real-time market." Puller (2007, p. 85) argues that
"there is a widespread belief that in 2000 Duke forward-contracted
some of its production." If data on contract positions were
available, one could correct this bias by adjusting infra-marginal sales
by the amount that was forward-contracted. Unfortunately, as in earlier
studies on market power in the California wholesale electricity market
the contract positions are not observable in our data set.
(37.) Careful description of the data set can be found in the
technical appendix of Puller (2007, pp. 86-87).
(38.) We do not observe the spot prices for natural gas for
California hubs in 1998 and 1999, and use prices from Henry Hub instead.
The difference between natural gas prices between these hubs before 2000
(for which we have the data available) was relatively small (see Woo et
al. 2006, p. 2062, Fig. 2).
(39.) An important implication of transmission congestions is that
they cause the slope of residual demand to differ for firms in the north
and south of California. Puller (2007) estimated his model based on a
subsample of uncongested hours and found smaller conduct parameter
estimates relative to full sample (though his qualitative conclusions
did not change). Our choice of residual demand elasticities based on PX
data (see below) captures the effect of transmission constraints.
(40.) Puller (2007) makes a similar point.
(41.) Time variation in nameplate capacity is mostly due to
acquisitions of fossil-fuel electric plants from divested utilities. For
more details, see Borenstein et al. (2002, p. 1381).
(42.) Puller (2007) adopts the day-ahead forecast of total
electricity output, rather than its inverse. We do not use the day-ahead
forecast of total electricity output here as an instrument because it
failed Hansen's (1982) J test. Notwithstanding this difference, the
economic interpretation of using this instrument is the same as in
Puller (2007).
(43.) Puller (2007) also reports estimates for the period from June
2000 to November 2000, which covers the price run-up preceding collapse
of California liberalized electricity market. We chose not report these
estimates because though the incentives of some market participants
changed during this period (Borenstein et al. 2008), the market
structure itself was not fundamentally different.
(44.) Chosen instruments fail Hansen's J test at 5% level of
significance over the period from July 1998-April 1999 using residual
demand elasticities calculated based on Puller's (2007) estimates.
(45.) For robustness grounds, several specifications of the doubly
truncated normal model were estimated in previous versions of this
paper, corresponding to different levels of [mu], that is, the mean of
the pretruncated random term. In practice, this implies moving the mass
of the distribution to the right and closer to 1/s. The Akaike
information criterion showed that the preferred level of truncation is 0
across all specifications, so the conduct random term is better modeled
using a half normal distribution that assumes zero modal value of
[[theta].sub.it]. It is important to note here that the distribution of
estimated market power is not the same as the assumed half-normal
distribution for [[theta].sub.it] because the market power estimator is
a shrinkage estimator of [[theta].sub.it] (see Wang and Schmidt 2009).
In other words, although the modal value of a half normal distribution
is zero, the average (industry) market power level is not restricted to
be close to zero in practice.
(46.) We have excluded DST in the histograms of the first period
because the estimated market power scores for this firm were much larger
than the scores of the remainder firms. The following normality analyses
are robust to the inclusion or exclusion of this firm from the sample.
(47.) To smooth the variation across time, we report the rolling
30-day average of the estimated conduct parameters.
(48.) The full set of first- and second-stage parameter estimates
of all estimated models is available upon request from the authors.
(49.) As the economic theory does not back imposing a time
invariant upper bound, the observed differences in market power scores
for DST are likely due to both empirical (i.e., endogeneity) and
theoretical problems. In this sense, it should be pointed out that this
result might also have to do with the theoretical issue that is to be
mentioned later on in this section.
(50.) It is important to point out that because suppliers had the
opportunity to sell their capacity in the CAISO ancillary services
markets and the real-time energy market, calculated residual demand
elasticities may differ from actual ones. Unfortunately, we do not have
the data for these markets. However, given that PX market accounted for
85% of all electricity delivered in the CAISO control area, whereas
CAISO's real-time market accounted for just 5% (Borenstein,
Bushnell, and Wolak 2002), the ancillary services market was very small,
and there was no substantial divergence between PX and ISO market
clearing prices for the most of the time covered in this study
(Borenstein et al. 2008) we believe our calculations provide a
reasonable approximation of actual residual demand elasticities.
(51.) This somewhat awkward result is caused by the fact that the
second-stage coefficient of the DST dummy variable determining the
variance of [[theta].sub.it] is negative and extremely large. Another
awkward result of the second stage of this model has to do with the
coefficient of sit. Indeed, while we expect a negative value for this
coefficient due to the upper bound of [[theta].sub.it] is inversely
related with firms' market share, we have found a positive effect.
Caption: FIGURE 1 Price-Cost Margins in Hour 18 (July 3, 1998 to
November 30, 2000)
Caption: FIGURE 2 Comparison of Market Power Scores
Caption: FIGURE 3 Histograms of the Market Power Scores. (A)
Modeling the Expected Value of [[theta].sub.it]. (B) Using the
First-Stage Estimate of E([[theta].sub.it])
Caption: FIGURE 4 Firm-Specific Conduct Parameter Estimates. (A)
Modeling the Expected Value of 8.,. (B) Using the First-Stage Estimate
of E([[theta].sub.it])
Caption: FIGURE 5 Firm-Specific Conduct Parameter Estimates. (A)
Modeling the Expected Value of 9/r. (B) Using the First-Stage Estimate
of E([[theta].sub.it])
Caption: FIGURE 6 Correlations of NOx Permit Price and Market Power
Scores. Modeling the Expected Value of [[theta].sub.it]
Caption: FIGURE 7 Correlations of Natural Gas Price and Market
Power Scores. Modeling the Expected Value of [[theta].sub.it]
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics (Hour 18)
Mean Standard
Deviation
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
Price ([P.sub.t]) 35.2 21.0
Marginal cost ([mc.sub.it]) 26.6 3.1
Margin ([P.sub.t] - [mc.sub.it]]) 8.6 21.0
[CAPBIND.sub.it] 0.05 0.22
Capacity ([k.sub.it]) 2,463 1,054
Output ([q.sub.it]) 813 844
Market demand ([Q.sub.it]) 30,395 4,146
Elasticities based on Puller (2007) 2.12 1.33
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
Price ([P.sub.it]) 61.2 68.4
Marginal cost ([mc.sub.it]) 42.7 22.9
Margin ([P.sub.t]-[mc.sub.it]) 18.4 57.3
[CAPBIND.sub.it] 0.05 0.21
Capacity ([k.sub.it]) 2,955 769
Output ([q.sub.it]) 1,223 793
Market demand ([Q.sub.it]) 30,604 3,658
Elasticities based on Puller (2007) 1.02 0.68
Min Max Obs
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
Price ([P.sub.t]) 4.9 180.4 864
Marginal cost ([mc.sub.it]) 19.5 33.7 864
Margin ([P.sub.t] - [mc.sub.it]]) -25.0 158.6 864
[CAPBIND.sub.it] 0.00 1.00 864
Capacity ([k.sub.it]) 670 3,879 864
Output ([q.sub.it]) 0 3,720 864
Market demand ([Q.sub.it]) 20,057 43,847 864
Elasticities based on Puller (2007) 0.56 10.77 864
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
Price ([P.sub.it]) 9.5 750.0 2,300
Marginal cost ([mc.sub.it]) 22.3 214.5 2,300
Margin ([P.sub.t]-[mc.sub.it]) -33.4 697.1 2,300
[CAPBIND.sub.it] 0.00 1.00 2,300
Capacity ([k.sub.it]) 1,020 3,879 2,300
Output ([q.sub.it]) 0 3,317 2,300
Market demand ([Q.sub.it]) 22,076 42,404 2,300
Elasticities based on Puller (2007) 0.35 5.26 2,300
TABLE 2
Pricing Equation Estimates. Dependent Variable:
[(P-mc).sub.it]; Method: OLS and Two-step GMM (a)
July 1, 1998 to
April 15, 1999
Number of Strategic
Firms: 4
Explanatory Variables Coefficient OLS GMM (b)
[CAPBlND.sub.it] [alpha] -4.98 * 11.28 ***
(2.64) (3.89)
[x.sub.it] = [P.sub.t] [theta] 1.41 *** 0.93 ***
[q.sub.it]/[[eta].sup.D (0.05) (0.10)
.sub.strat't] [Q.sup.S
.sub.strat,t]
Observations 864 864
Mean of the dependent 8.56 8.56
variable
Standard error of residuals 13.14 14.23
Normality test (c) 50.85 ***
Hausman test (c) 32.25 ***
Hansen test (c) 0.666
Test for weak 226.5 ***
instruments (c)
April 16, 1999 to
November 30, 2000
Number of Strategic
Firms: 5
Explanatory Variables OLS GMM (b)
[CAPBlND.sub.it] -5.16 28.36 ***
(4.13) (4.95)
[x.sub.it] = [P.sub.t] 1.36 *** 0.82 ***
[q.sub.it]/[[eta].sup.D (0.03) (0.06)
.sub.strat't] [Q.sup.S
.sub.strat,t]
Observations 2300 23t)u
Mean of the dependent 18.43 18.43
variable
Standard error of residuals 27.83 34.4
Normality test (c) 135.6 ***
Hausman test (c) 120.8 ***
Hansen test (c) 0.712
Test for weak 412.5 ***
instruments (c)
(a) HAC Standard errors robust to heteroscedasticity
and autocorrelation in parenthesis.
(b) Instruments: [CAPBIND.sub.it], [k.sub.it], 1/F[Q.sub.t],
where FQ is day-ahead forecast of total (perfectly inelastic)
demand and [k.sub.it] is capacity.
(c) While the normality test (Coelli 1995) follows a standard
normal distribution, both Hausman and Hansen tests follow a
[chi square] distribution with 1 degree of freedom.
The Hausman test is sometimes based in only one parameter
in order to provide a positive value. The test for weak
instruments follows F distribution with 2 and (obs-3)
degrees of freedom.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%.
TABLE 3 Second-stage Parameter Estimates
(Robust Standard Errors in Parenthesis)
Modeling the Expected
Value of the Conduct Term
July 1998 to April 1999 to
Component/Parameter April 1999 November 2000
Intercept 1.40 *** (0.11) 1.97 *** (0.05)
F[Q.sub.t] -0.02 (0.67) -1.15 *** (0.24)
0.5 * F[Q.sub.t.sup.2] 11.41 *** (3.16) 2.44 (1.98)
[D.sub.DST] 0.29 *** (0.07) 0.12 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.Duke] -0.16 *** (0.01) 0.51 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.Reliant] 0.06 (0.04) 0.03 * (0.02)
[D.sub.Southern] -0.27 *** (0.02) -0.38 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.tuesday] 0.10 (0.07) 0.31 *** (0.16)
[D.sub.Wednesday] 0.64 *** (0.04) 0.15 ** (0.07)
[D.sub.thursday] 0.52 *** (0.05) 0.20 *** (0.03)
[D.sub.friday] 0.02 (0.11) -0.01 (0.09)
[D.sub.Saturday] 0.25 *** (0.05) 0.08 * (0.04)
[D.sub.Sunday] 0.10 *** (0.03) 0.13 *** (0.04)
Asymmetric component, [[sigma].sub.[theta]]
Intercept 0.08 (0.22) 0.05 (0.18)
[s.sub.it] -0.19 (0.64) 0.14 (0.62)
[D.sub.DST] 1.76 *** (0.17) 0.49 *** (0.11)
[D.sub.Duke] 0.04 * (0.02) 0.14 *** (0.03)
[D.sub.Reliant] 0.09 (0.08) -0.09 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.Southern] -0.31 *** (0.07) 0.09 *** (0.00)
[s.sub.it-1-][s.sub.it]-2 0.74 (0.51) 0.28 (0.75)
Mean log-likelihood -3.386 -4.023
Observations 864 2300
Using the First-Stage
Estimate of the Conduct Term
July 1998 to April 1999 to
Component/Parameter April 1999 November 2000
Intercept 1.15 *** (0.08) 1.88 *** (0.04)
F[Q.sub.t] -1.73 *** (0.50) -1.32 *** (0.31)
0.5 * F[Q.sub.t.sup.2] 11.92 *** (3.49) 3.40 *** (1.43)
[D.sub.DST] 0.03 *** (0.01) 0.29 *** (0.01)
[D.sub.Duke] -0.17 ** (0.04) 0.43 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.Reliant] 0.10 *** (0.02) 0.05 *** (0.01)
[D.sub.Southern]
[D.sub.tuesday] 0.23 *** (0.05) 0.25 ** (0.11)
[D.sub.Wednesday] 0.74 *** (0.04) 0.18 *** (0.07)
[D.sub.thursday] 0.57 *** (0.04) 0.23 ** (0.04)
[D.sub.friday] -0.23 (0.15) -0.09 (0.07)
[D.sub.Saturday] 0.32 ** (0.13) 0.07 (0.04)
[D.sub.Sunday] 0.18 (0.13) 0.15 *** (0.05)
Asymmetric component, [[sigma].sub.[theta]]
Intercept 0.78 *** (0.23) 1.22 *** (0.16)
[s.sub.it] -2.59 *** (0.76) -6.47 *** (0.82)
[D.sub.DST] 1.69 *** (0.20) -0.15 ** (0.06)
[D.sub.Duke] 0.43 *** (0.19) -0.07 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.Reliant] 0.16 *** (0.06) -0.04 *** (0.02)
[D.sub.Southern]
[s.sub.it-1-][s.sub.it]-2 0.16 (0.44) -0.18 (0.26)
Mean log-likelihood -3.244 -3.927
Observations 864 2300
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%;
*** significant at 1%.
TABLE 4
Firm-Specific Conduct Parameter Estimates
Market Share
([s.sub.it])
Standard
Firm Mean Deviation
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.28 0.15
DST 0.07 0.08
Duke 0.48 0.20
Reliant 0.19 0.10
Industry average
Industry average (excl. DST)
First-stage mean
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 0.17 0.09
DST 0.12 0.05
Duke 0.31 0.12
Reliant 0.20 0.07
Southern 0.20 0.08
Industry average
First-stage mean
Modeling the
Expected Value of
[[theta].sub.it]
Mean Standard
Firm Deviation
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.74 0.38
DST 4.61 2.27
Duke 0.67 0.41
Reliant 0.91 0.46
Industry average 1.73
Industry average (excl. DST) 0.70
First-stage mean 0.93
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 0.78 0.37
DST 1.18 0.61
Duke 0.68 0.40
Reliant 0.70 0.34
Southern 0.75 0.38
Industry average 0.82
First-stage mean 0.82
Using the FirstStage
Estimate of
[[theta].sub.it]
Mean Standard Puller
Firm Deviation (2007)
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.92 0.53 0.99
DST 6.88 4.57 5.15
Duke 0.83 0.56 1.02
Reliant 1.29 0.74 1.48
Industry average 2.48 2.16
Industry average (excl. DST) 0.91 1.05
First-stage mean 0.93 0.97
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 1.02 0.70 0.82
DST 1.11 0.65 1.75
Duke 0.49 0.53 0.81
Reliant 0.76 0.47 1.01
Southern 0.94 0.54 1.21
Industry average 0.86 1.12
First-stage mean 0.82 0.97
TABLE 5
Normality Tests of the Market Power Scores (a)
Modeling the Using the
Expected First-Stage
Value of Estimate of E
[[theta].sub.it] [[theta].sub.it]
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
All firms 32.01 *** 34.90 ***
AES 9.56 *** 8.97 ***
DST 8.99 *** 9.53 ***
Duke 9.45 *** 9.86 ***
Reliant 10.11 *** 9.44 ***
April 16, 1999 to May 30, 2000
All firms 30.70 *** 32.99 ***
AES 11.78 *** 14.31 ***
DST 12.89 *** 13.51 ***
Duke 13.96 *** 20.38 ***
Reliant 12.06 *** 14.24 ***
Southern 12.20 *** 12.27 ***
(a) The normality test introduced by Coelli (1995)
follows a standard normal distribution.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%;
*** significant at 1%.
TABLE 6
Robustness Analyses. Average Market Power Scores
Second Stage
Modeling the
Expected Value
Firm-Specific of [Q.sub.it]
Estimate of
Puller [[theta].sub.i] Basic Capacity
Firm (2007) (First Stage) Model No Binding
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.99 0.88 0.74 0.81
DST 5.15 4.69 4.61 4.61
Duke 1.02 0.94 0.67 0.63
Reliant 1.48 1.35 0.91 0.96
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 0.82 0.96 0.78 0.87
DST 1.75 1.45 1.18 1.19
Duke 0.81 0.48 0.68 0.67
Reliant 1.01 0.85 0.70 0.74
Southern 1.21 0.95 0.75 0.80
Second Stage Modeling the
Expected Value of [Q.sub.it]
Firm-Specific Elasticities
Estimate Time-Invariant Based on
Firm [[theta].sub.i] Upper Bound PX Data
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.75 0.67 0.80
DST 3.62 2.99 0.02
Duke 0.69 0.65 0.65
Reliant 0.90 0.97 0.84
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 0.77 0.76 1.39
DST 1.01 1.18 1.42
Duke 0.78 0.68 1.20
Reliant 0.69 0.70 1.28
Southern 0.71 0.76 1.30
Second Stage Using the First-Stage
Estimate of [Q.sub.it]
Firm-Specific
Basic Capacity Estimate
Firm Model No Binding [[theta].sub.i]
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.92 0.97 0.92
DST 6.88 7.01 6.92
Duke 0.83 0.85 0.84
Reliant 1.29 1.32 1.30
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 1.02 1.02 1.01
DST 1.11 1.10 1.11
Duke 0.49 0.49 0.47
Reliant 0.76 0.76 0.76
Southern 0.94 0.94 0.92
Second Stage Using the
First-Stage Estimate
of [Q.sub.it]
Elasticities
Time-Invariant Based on
Firm Upper Bound PX Data
July 1, 1998 to April 15, 1999
AES 0.97 0.83
DST 4.41 4.28
Duke 0.79 0.79
Reliant 1.34 1.16
April 16, 1999 to November 30, 2000
AES 1.02 0.98
DST 1.11 0.73
Duke 0.47 0.49
Reliant 0.76 0.66
Southern 0.94 1.39
COPYRIGHT 2018 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.