首页    期刊浏览 2025年07月04日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Effects of welfare reform on women's voting participation.
  • 作者:Corman, Hope ; Dave, Dhaval ; Reichman, Nancy E.
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2017
  • 期号:July
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:I. INTRODUCTION

    The broad goal of the landmark welfare reform legislation in the United States in the 1990s was to reduce dependence on government benefits by promoting work, encouraging marriage, and reducing nonmarital childbearing. The legislation represented a convergence of dissatisfaction with the welfare system on both sides of the political spectrum, with welfare participation becoming viewed by many as a cause of dependence rather than a consequence of disadvantage. The key strategy for reducing dependence was to promote employment by imposing work requirements as a condition for receiving benefits as well as time limits on receipt of cash assistance. The basic argument was that labor force participation would break a "culture of poverty" by increasing self-sufficiency and reconnecting members of an increasingly marginalized underclass to the mainstream ideals of a strong work ethic and civic responsibility (Katz 2001).

    In terms of increasing employment of low-skilled women and decreasing welfare caseloads, welfare reform was deemed a great success, at least before the Great Recession hit at the end of 2007. Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF) caseloads declined by 50% between 1997 and 2001 alone, and over half of TANF cases are now "child only," meaning that adults in the household are not eligible (Loprest 2012). Employment rates of low-skilled mothers rose dramatically after the early 1990s, and there is strong consensus that welfare reform played a major role (Schoeni and Blank 2000; Ziliak 2006).

Effects of welfare reform on women's voting participation.


Corman, Hope ; Dave, Dhaval ; Reichman, Nancy E. 等


Effects of welfare reform on women's voting participation.

I. INTRODUCTION

The broad goal of the landmark welfare reform legislation in the United States in the 1990s was to reduce dependence on government benefits by promoting work, encouraging marriage, and reducing nonmarital childbearing. The legislation represented a convergence of dissatisfaction with the welfare system on both sides of the political spectrum, with welfare participation becoming viewed by many as a cause of dependence rather than a consequence of disadvantage. The key strategy for reducing dependence was to promote employment by imposing work requirements as a condition for receiving benefits as well as time limits on receipt of cash assistance. The basic argument was that labor force participation would break a "culture of poverty" by increasing self-sufficiency and reconnecting members of an increasingly marginalized underclass to the mainstream ideals of a strong work ethic and civic responsibility (Katz 2001).

In terms of increasing employment of low-skilled women and decreasing welfare caseloads, welfare reform was deemed a great success, at least before the Great Recession hit at the end of 2007. Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF) caseloads declined by 50% between 1997 and 2001 alone, and over half of TANF cases are now "child only," meaning that adults in the household are not eligible (Loprest 2012). Employment rates of low-skilled mothers rose dramatically after the early 1990s, and there is strong consensus that welfare reform played a major role (Schoeni and Blank 2000; Ziliak 2006).

A handful of studies have found that welfare reform reduced undesirable behaviors that have often been ascribed to "welfare as we knew it," providing some support for the mainstreaming argument. Kaestner and Tarlov (2006) found that welfare reform reduced women's binge drinking. Corman et al. (2013) found that welfare reform led to declines in illicit drug use among women at risk for relying on welfare, with some evidence indicating that the effects operate, at least in part, through work incentive policies. Corman, Dave, and Reichman (2014) found that welfare reform led to reductions in women's property crime. This emerging literature supports the widely embraced argument that welfare reform discourages antisocial behavior and suggests that disenfranchised women have been brought from the margins to the mainstream. However, as far as we know, the only studies that have directly tested the widely held assumption that welfare reform encourages mainstream behavior (other than work, which is required) have focused on marriage or non-marital fertility and have generally revealed weak or ambiguous effects (e.g., Blank 2002; Gennetian and Knox 2003; Grogger and Karoly 2005). To test the "culture of poverty" argument that making welfare much less of an option encourages personal and civic responsibility, it is necessary to go beyond marital status by considering direct measures of mainstream behavior.

In this article, we investigate the effects of welfare reform on voting, which is an important form of civic participation in democratic societies but a fundamental right that many citizens do not exercise. Exploiting changes in welfare policy across states and over time, and comparing relevant population subgroups within an econometric difference-in-differences (DD) framework, we use the November Current Population Survey (CPS) with the added Voting and Registration Supplement (VRS) to estimate the causal effects of welfare reform on women's voting registration and voting participation from 1990 to 2004, the period during which welfare reform unfolded. We explore the extent to which effects appear to have operated through employment as well as the extent to which effects varied by state political orientations and welfare strictness.

The findings from this study provide important information that promises to inform culture of poverty debates and provide a more complete picture of the effects of a major policy shift in the United States that is still very much in effect today. The findings also contribute to the political science literature on the determinants of voting by providing a strong test of the effects of work incentives (and, by inference, employment) on voting behavior.

II. BACKGROUND

A. Welfare Reform in the United States

The Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA) of 1996, often referred to as welfare reform, ended entitlement to welfare benefits under Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) and replaced the AFDC program with TANF block grants to states. Features of the legislation were time limits on cash assistance, work requirements as a condition for receiving benefits, stricter sanctions for noncompliance with work requirements and other program rules, stronger child support enforcement, and family caps that limited benefits for additional children. The broad goals of PRWORA were to reduce dependence on government benefits by promoting work, encouraging marriage, and reducing nonmarital childbearing.

Although welfare reform is often dated to the landmark 1996 PRWORA legislation, reforms actually started taking place in the early 1990s when the Clinton Administration greatly expanded the use and scope of "welfare waivers." Many policies and features of state waivers were later incorporated into PRWORA. However, PRWORA departed from its waiver precursors by imposing a "work first" approach that was designed not only to reduce welfare dependence, but also to reconnect members of an increasingly marginalized underclass to the mainstream ideals of a strong work ethic and civic responsibility (Katz 2001). PRWORA granted considerable discretion to states in establishing welfare eligibility and program rules. As a result, there is substantial state policy variation within the broad national regime of time-limited cash assistance for which work is required.

B. Employment, Welfare, and Voting

Glaeser, Laibson, and Sacerdote (2002) examined individual investments in activities that create "social capital," defined broadly as connections within social networks such as community organizations and religious institutions. Individuals choose to engage in such behaviors if the benefits outweigh the costs. By increasing employment, welfare reform may increase civic participation (including, perhaps, voting) by shifting women from the individualistic job of homemaker to more socially interactive occupations and increasing their participation in unions, but it could also decrease civic participation through an increase in the opportunity cost of time. Welfare reform may also increase civic participation as a result of the new normative climate of increased personal and civic responsibility. In terms of voting in particular, Feddersen (2004) offered theoretical reasons why individuals vote even though doing so imposes a cost and is unlikely to affect the outcome, one of which involves belonging to a social network that has a stake in the election's outcome.

The political science literature makes it very clear that education, employment, and income--all aspects of socioeconomic status--are strongly associated with political participation and voter turnout in particular (Verba, Schlozman, and Brady 1995). Most studies testing for causal relationships between socioeconomic status and political participation have focused on education, and there has been considerable debate about whether and in what contexts education causes political participation, sometimes operationalized as voting (e.g., Berinsky and Lenz 2011; Dinesen et al. 2016; Kam and Palmer 2008, 2011; Milligan, Moretti. and Oreopoulos 2004; Pelkonen 2012; Sondheimer and Green 2010). Moreover, studies of effects of education cannot be used to make inferences about effects of employment or income, as different aspects of socioeconomic status may operate in distinct ways--for example, education may impart knowledge about politics or a sense of civic obligation, employment may provide networks of information about politics and the importance of engagement, and income may foster investment in political outcomes. Strong evidence about effects of employment or income on political participation is scarce, and existing studies tend to focus on specific mechanisms rather than identify causal effects. For example, findings by Schur (2003). using data from two nationally representative U.S. household surveys conducted by the Rutgers Center for Public Interest Polling following the November elections in 1998 and 2000, suggest that being employed increases an individual's political activities through increased income, civic skills, political efficacy, and recruitment at work.

Few studies have attempted to estimate causal effects of welfare or cash assistance on voting or any other form of civic participation. However, a strand of political science literature suggests that citizens' experiences with social welfare programs can affect political participation by providing lessons in how citizens and government relate, giving recipients a stake in maintaining or enhancing program benefits, or providing resources that facilitate political action (Soss 1999; Bruch. Ferree. and Soss 2010). According to Soss (1999), clients experience a lack of power when dealing with welfare agencies, which translates to powerlessness in the face of government more generally and serves as a disincentive to vote. Recent findings by Sugie (2015)--that partners of incarcerated men are less likely to register and vote than similar partners of men who have not been incarcerated--are consistent with the scenario of marginalization through feelings of powerlessness in interactions with public institutions. This research suggests that welfare reform would increase women's political participation, including voting, by disconnecting them from a system that fosters feelings of powerlessness--unless there are offsetting effects (i.e., reduced stake in maintaining or enhancing program benefits or reduced resources that facilitate political action).

Based on the above framework. Swartz et al. (2009) investigated voter turnout among young women in Minnesota from the Youth Development Study in 1996 and 2000 and found that welfare recipients were less likely to vote in both elections than nonrecipients, suggesting that reducing welfare participation increases voting. However, the Youth Development study did not target poor women, and did not explicitly address the possibility that unobserved factors confounded the associations between welfare participation and voting. Thus, the observed negative associations between welfare participation and likelihood of voting cannot be interpreted as causal effects.

Baez et al. (2012) found that new recipients of a conditional cash transfer program in Colombia were more likely to vote than matched individuals whose incomes were just above the income threshold (and therefore did not receive the transfers) and to vote for the incumbent (under whose regime the cash transfer program was implemented) in the 2010 presidential election. The findings from this quasi-experimental study suggest that low-income women are more likely to vote when legislation has been passed that affects their cash benefits. However, it is not clear whether these findings would apply to the United States, where Edlund and Pande (2002) found that party preference is much more responsive to economic changes for middle-income women than for poor women.

Watson (2015) used British panel survey data to estimate the effects on civic participation of several pieces of legislation involving public income support for unmarried parents. The first legislative change imposed quarterly work-focused interviews for unmarried parents whose youngest child was 14 years old or more. Subsequent legislative changes made unmarried parents with children 5 years of age or older ineligible for cash assistance as single parents, and required them to enter the unemployed pool with obligations of attendance at fortnightly interviews. Using DD analyses, Watson found that the requirement that parents of older children engage in a quarterly work-focused interview had no effect on voting, but that the requirement of frequent interviews for parents of children 5 years old or more had a negative effect on voting. It is not clear whether these findings, which suggest that stricter welfare policies (such as work requirements) would decrease voting among welfare recipients who do not leave the rolls, would apply in the United States.

A qualitative study of community leaders found that the time constraints of complying with TANF requirements reduce community-building activities on the part of women (Jennings 2001). This finding stands in contrast with the literature on socioeconomic status and voting participation, which suggests that employment increases voting but has not focused on the important but specific population of women at risk for relying on welfare. On the other hand, Anderson, Curtis, and Grabb (2006) found that civic participation of American women decreased during the 1990s while it increased in other developed countries, and speculated that increasing time commitment to paid work alongside declining levels of public support may be responsible. However, the links between welfare, employment, and civic participation in the United States were not empirically established in that study. Moreover, voting--which the authors did not study--is likely to impose fewer time constraints than would other forms of civic engagement.

III. DATA

We use data from the November CPS with the added VRS for the years 1990 through 2004, which span the implementation of welfare reform. The general CPS is a monthly nationally representative survey of over 50,000 households that collects detailed information on labor force participation as well as sociodemographic characteristics of each household member.

The VRS takes place bi-annually at the end of November, in even-numbered years when Congressional elections occur. Thus, every second supplement takes place during a presidential election, when voting turnout is higher (DeSilver 2014). The survey asks household members if they are eligible to vote, whether they had registered to vote by the election that occurred that month, and whether they had voted in that election.

The VRS has several key strengths and is particularly well-suited for addressing our research question. First, it was designed and conducted to produce comprehensive national data on voter characteristics, participation, and trends in the United States. In contrast, administrative datasets include no information on individuals who are not registered to vote, contain limited demographic information on those who are registered, are not available for all states, and often are not available for long enough time periods to ascertain trends. Second, the VRS has a high response rate and the largest sample of any survey used to measure voting participation, allowing us to maximize statistical power. Other national surveys (e.g.. General Social Survey, American National Election Studies--ANES, and Cooperative Congressional Election Study) either have much smaller samples or are limited to periods subsequent to the implementation of welfare reform. Third, while it has long been recognized that individuals may overstate their voting participation, this bias is minimal in the VRS compared to other surveys. For example, the 2012 VRS turnout rate was 61.8%, compared to 58.6% from actual ballots, while the ANES reported a turnout rate of 78% in 2012 (U.S. Election Project 2016a). Although the VRS has never been subjected to a voter validation study, which compares respondents' reports about whether they voted with local registration and voting records, it consistently produces more accurate estimates of turnout than other surveys, including ANES (Pew Center on the States 2012), which reportedly has been unable to locate the voting records of a sizable percentage of its respondents (McDonald 2007). In this study, we focus on women who are at least 21 years old and up to age 49, a group that is both eligible to vote and likely to have minor children living in their household. Of those, we only include women who are citizens and thus eligible to register to vote.

We initially follow the standard in the welfare reform literature by using state-specific and time-varying indicators for both AFDC waivers and TANF (Blank 2002). Twenty-nine states enacted AFDC waivers, across various months, from 1992 to 1996 (see Appendix, Table A1). We use a dichotomous variable that equals 1 if a statewide waiver was in place before November of that year that substantially altered the nature of AFDC with respect to time limits, sanctions, or work requirements. We also use a dichotomous indicator for whether, before November of that year, the state had implemented TANF. The data on whether states had waivers and when they enacted TANF come from U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1999). Although the new welfare regime is very much in effect today, our observation window coincides with, and exploits, maximum policy and implementation change.

We separately consider voting in any election, which can take place every 2 years, and voting in presidential elections, which can take place every 4 years. The latter is the more relevant measure of engagement for our study because (1) as indicated earlier, voting rates are much lower in congressional elections than in presidential elections, and (2) within congressional elections, voting rates are highest for individuals who are age 65 years and older. non-Hispanic white, have high levels of education, and have relatively high incomes (File 2015)--individuals not at all likely to rely on welfare. Thus, the more relevant margin for potential effects of welfare reform on voting would be presidential elections.

Because presidential elections are more relevant for our study than off-year elections and occur only every 4 years, separate measures of AFDC waivers and TANF are based on very few elections. We thus also use a single measure of Any Welfare Reform implementation that has also been used in the relevant literature (e.g., Dave et al. 2011) and is defined as either a major AFDC waiver or TANF in a given state and year. Most notably, only two states (Michigan and New Jersey) implemented waivers before the 1992 presidential election and these were implemented in October 1992 when the election process was well underway, while 28 states implemented waivers before the 1996 presidential election (see Appendix, Table Al). As such, separate waiver effects would almost exclusively reflect the 1996 presidential election (Clinton's re-election), which had a historically low voter turnout (U.S. Census Bureau 2012). Thus, the single measure of Any Welfare Reform is our preferred measure for this study. Nevertheless, we also show some estimates using the separate measures of AFDC waivers and TANF in order to map the study to the existing literature but urge the reader to interpret the separate effects, particularly those for AFDC waivers, with caution. Other advantages of the single measure of Any Welfare Reform are that it facilitates ease of discussion and comparison across models and preserves statistical power for subsequent stratification analyses.

IV. METHODS

We employ a quasi-experimental research design--akin to a pre- and post-comparison with treatment and control groups--in conjunction with multivariate regression methods, broadly referred to as DD models, to estimate the effects of welfare reform on women's voting behavior. We conduct numerous specification checks and tests to investigate the validity of the identification assumptions underlying our methodology, the robustness of our results, and patterns across subgroups of mothers.

The basic model can be expressed as follows, where Y refers to the outcome for the ;th individual residing in state s at time t:

(1) [Y.sub.ist] = [[alpha].sub.1] + [[pi].sub.1] (AFDC [Waiver.sub.st]) + [[pi].sub.2] ([TANF.sub.st]) + [X.sub.ist] [beta] + [Z.sub.st][delta] + [State.sub.s][lambda] + [Year.sub.t] [phi] + [[epsilon].sub.ist].

AFDC Waiver and TANF are dichotomous variables indicating whether a major waiver or TANF had been implemented. (1) X represents a vector of individual characteristics (age, age-squared, race, Hispanic origin, marital history including widowed/divorced/separated and never married, number of children in the household, number of adults in the household, and metropolitan statistical area--MSA residence), and Z represents a vector of state-level characteristics (current and 1-year lagged state unemployment rate, current and 1-year lagged state personal income per capita, log female population, state poverty rate, state minimum wage, 1--and 2-year lagged welfare caseloads, percentages of the state legislature that were Democrat/Republican, Republican governor, Democratic governor, and registration/voting rates of males). (2) We do not control for education, employment, or family income in the baseline specification since prior work has shown that education and employment, which are associated with income, were affected by welfare reform (e.g., Dave, Corman, and Reichman 2012; Ziliak 2006) and are potential pathways by which welfare reform may affect voting behaviors. A full set of state (State) and year (Year) fixed effects are included to capture unobserved time-invariant state-specific factors, as well as overall national trends. In the above specification, [[alpha].sub.1], [[pi].sub.1], [[pi].sub.2], [beta], [delta], [lambda], and [phi] represent the vector of parameters to be estimated.

Identification in this DD framework comes from comparing changes in women's voting participation in states that have implemented welfare reform to changes in states that have not yet done so, with the implicit assumption being that the latter are a valid counterfactual for the former (i.e., in the absence of welfare reform, trends in women's voting participation would be parallel across the "treatment" and control states). However, this "parallel trends" assumption is unlikely to hold owing to a multitude of time-varying state-specific factors that may be related to voting behavior. That is, the coefficients of [[pi].sub.1], and [[pi].sub.2] may represent not only effects of welfare reform, but also effects of other state-specific trends that affect voting behavior over the time period in which welfare reform was implemented.

We address the issue of potentially confounding state-specific trends by adding another "difference"--comparing women at risk for relying on welfare (target group) and similar women who are much less at risk for relying on welfare (comparison group)--and estimating difference-in-difference-in-differences (DDD) models as specified in Equation (2) below. Target represents a dichotomous indicator equal to one if the individual is in the target group and zero if the individual is in the comparison group. (3)

(2) [Y.sub.ist] = [alpha]' + ([[alpha].sub.1] - [[alpha].sup.*.sub.1]) [Target.sub.i] + ([[pi].sub.1] - [[pi].sup.*.sub.1]) (AFDC [Waiver.sub.st] * [Target.sub.i]) + ([[pi].sub.2] - [[pi].sup.*.sub.2]) ([TANF.sub.st] * [Target.sub.i]) + [[pi].sup.*.sub.1] (AFDC [Waiver.sub.st]) + [[pi].sup.*.sub.2] ([TANF.sub.st]) + [X.sub.ist] [beta]' + [Z.sub.st] [delta]' + [State.sub.s] [lambda]' + [Year.sub.t] [phi]' + [[eta].sub.ist].

The choice of target and comparison groups is integral to a valid implementation of the DDD methodology. Identifying the target group--individuals who are at risk of relying on public assistance--is relatively straightforward; welfare recipients have traditionally come from low-educated unmarried-parent households. The assumption necessary for the DDD effect to represent an unbiased estimate is that in the absence of welfare reform, unobserved state-varying factors would affect the target and comparison groups similarly. If this assumption is valid, then [[pi].sup.*.sub.1], and [[pi].sup.*.sub.2] will capture the effects of any unmeasured trends that coincided with welfare reform and were also related to voting. In other words, the basic welfare reform indicators do not provide (and are not intended to provide) estimates of the effects of welfare reform implementation on voting outcomes among women exposed to welfare reform. The estimates of interest, which do this job, are those for the interaction terms between the welfare reform indicators and Target group indicator.

In our main analyses, we compare unmarried women ages 21-49 that have a high school education or less and live with children (target group) to two alternative comparison groups: (1) unmarried women with no children in the same age and education groups, and (2) married mothers in the same age and education groups. These comparison groups have been validated in prior work on the effects of welfare reform on women's education (Dave et al. 2011; Dave, Corman. and Reichman 2012), drug use (Corman et al. 2013), and crime (Corman, Dave, and Reichman 2014) and in the broader welfare reform literature. We assess the sensitivity of our findings to the use of these two different comparison groups, as well as to the use of three additional alternative comparison groups consisting of unmarried mothers ages 21-49 with higher levels of education.

After establishing baseline estimates from DDD specifications, we consider potentially confounding factors that may be correlated with both the implementation of welfare reform and voting behaviors. In particular, we consider voting legislation that coincided, to some extent, with the implementation of welfare reform. The National Voter Registration Act (NVRA) of 1993 was designed to ease the process of registering to vote and maintaining registration by requiring states to allow individuals to register when they applied for or renewed a driver's license and when they visited an office providing public assistance to the poor or disabled (U.S. Department of Justice 2015). Because women in our target group were more likely than women in the comparison groups to rely on welfare, the NVRA could have disproportionately affected their voting behavior through more interactions with public assistance offices.

Six states already had liberal registration practices in effect when the NVRA was passed and the other states were required to implement the law in 1995 (with 1996 representing the first national election under this new regime). Although the NVRA was designed to increase voter turnout, there is mixed evidence on its effect. Knack (1995) found a lagged and positive effect of motor voter duration for states that were early adopters. However, Knack (1999), who focused on the 1996 election, and Brown and Wedeking (2006), who focused on elections through 2004 found no effects of these laws when controlling for past state election turnout. This evidence suggests that the NVRA legislation would not confound our estimated effects of welfare reform on voting. Nevertheless, we assess the sensitivity of our estimates to controlling for when each state implemented the NVRA. (4)

We further control for state-specific linear trends and, more flexibly, include State*Year indicators instead of NVRA implementation. The State*Year indicators account for all observed and unobserved state-specific factors and thus also address concerns about policy endogeneity--the possibility that the timing of welfare reform implementation in states is a function of time-varying state-specific factors. We also address the issue of potentially different underlying trends in outcomes between the target and comparison groups by including an interaction between a linear trend and the target group prior to policy implementation.

Next, we assess differential effects across relevant state-level margins--namely, the dominant political party of the state legislature and strictness of the state's welfare regime. Poor unmarried women tend to favor Democrats (Pew Research Center 2015) and may be more invested in the political process in states with party dominance that aligns with their political leanings. The latter analyses indirectly inform the extent to which the policy effects are driven by shifts in employment by considering a dose--response check--that is, whether the observed policy effects are larger in states that had a more stringent push toward employment as part of their welfare regimes. We supplement these models by directly assessing the role of employment and family income in mediating the observed effects of welfare policy on voting participation.

In supplementary models, we allow for potential lagged effects, as welfare reform may not affect behavior immediately. For example, if employment is the main mechanism through which welfare reform affects voting, women need time to find jobs and adjust their behavior in response to the new situation. We thus estimate models that allow for 6- and 12-month lags between welfare reform implementation and voting responses.

The relative timing of elections and the rollout of welfare reform suggest a number of additional specification checks. Specifically, we assess sensitivity of our estimates to sequentially dropping the 1996, 2000, and 2004 elections, to ensure that our findings are not being driven by any one presidential election, as well as to excluding African American women from the sample, to address potential confounding effects of sharp increases in black voter turnout since the 1996 presidential election (Taylor 2013), which occurred just months after the enactment of PRWORA. As a placebo test, we estimate effects of welfare reform on voting outcomes among women in states that implemented welfare reform relatively late (post September 1996), for whom we would not expect welfare reform implementation to affect voting behaviors during the 1992 and 1996 presidential elections. As another placebo test, we estimate effects of welfare reform on voting in the 1996 election among women in the seven states that implemented welfare reform in September and October of 1996, for whom the welfare reform happened too late to have any effects on voting.

We also assess the robustness of our estimates to alternative comparison groups based on education. In addition to our two main comparison groups (unmarried women with no children and a high school education or less, and married mothers with a high school education or less), we alternatively compare how welfare reform affected voting participation of the target group (unmarried mothers with a high school education or less) relative to each of the following comparison groups: unmarried mothers with some college but not a college degree, mothers with any college education (degree or not), and mothers with at least a college degree.

V. RESULTS

Table 1 shows mean percentages that registered and voted by year for the target group and our two primary comparison groups--(1) unmarried childless women ages 21-49 with a high school education or less, and (2) married mothers in the same age and education groups. For (1), the average difference between the target and comparison group in the percent registered to vote in the pre-welfare reform years (1990 and 1992) was about 4 percentage points, while the average difference in the post-welfare reform years (1998 to 2004) was zero. Thus, the difference in the percent registered decreased. The corresponding differences for voting were about 7 percentage points in the pre-welfare reform period and about 3 percentage points in the post-welfare reform years. For (2), the average difference between the target and comparison groups in the percent registered to vote in the pre-welfare reform years was about 13 percentage points, and this difference decreased to 10 percentage points in the post-welfare reform period. The corresponding difference in percentage that voted was about 2.5 percentage points. These mean differences are suggestive of "positive" effects of welfare reform on voting behavior of women at risk for welfare reliance (i.e., smaller declines for the target group). However, these differences may be confounded by other changes occurring over the period, and the multivariate DDD models in subsequent tables address this concern.

Similar patterns are evident in Figures la and 1 b and Figures 2a and 2b, for our target group (unmarried mothers age 21-49 with at most a high school education) and the two primary comparison groups. The time series in these figures correspond to numbers of years before and after welfare reform was implemented in the woman's state of residence. (5) Before welfare reform, women in the target group were less likely to register and to vote than those in the comparison groups. However, as welfare reform was implemented, the target group appeared to exhibit behavior more like that of the comparison groups (particularly the first). (6) This possible narrowing of the differences in registration and voting patterns between women most at risk of welfare receipt and similar women who were unlikely to be impacted by welfare policy, even without conditioning on any other factors, is suggestive that welfare reform may have attenuated decreases in voting among low-educated unmarried mothers. However, as for the differences in means, these trends may be confounded by other changes.

A downward trend in voting participation is also evident in Figures 2a and 2b over the pre-policy period. While voting turnout generally follows national trends, there is considerable variation across states in the magnitudes (and sometimes the direction) of the trend (U.S. Election Project 2016b). For example, national trends indicate a decrease of 6.4 percentage points between 1992 and 1996, years during which welfare reform was implemented. This average trend masks considerable heterogeneity across states--for example, the decline during the same period was more than twice as high in Utah (13.8 percentage points) and close to zero in Wyoming (0.6 percentage points). Based on our CPS sample, national trends account for 40% of the observed variation in voting participation. Thus, there is considerable variation in voting trends across states, driven by observable and unobservable state-specific factors. The multivariate DDD models in subsequent tables address the concern that the effects of welfare reform may be confounded by such state trends.

From our November CPS data, we also found that employment increased much more substantially for our target group than for either of the comparison groups after the implementation of welfare reform. Specifically, we compared the percentages of each group that were employed before and after welfare reform was implemented in their state of residence. In unadjusted results, the employment rate of the target group grew 7.5 percentage points relative to comparison group 2 and 18.2 percentage points relative to comparison group l. (7) This difference, which was expected based on past literature, provides further validation of our target and comparison groups. Also validating, more generally, is that in Table 1, we can see that for all low-educated women in the relevant age range, both registration and voting were higher in presidential election years than in nonpresidential election years.

The top panel of Table 2 presents regression results from linear probability models predicting voting behavior using our first comparison group (unmarried women with no children). The bottom panel of the same table presents corresponding estimates using the second comparison group (married mothers with at most a high school education). In both panels, the estimates in the first two columns are for "registered to vote" as the dependent variable; those in the next two columns are for "voting in any even-numbered year," those in the fifth column are for "voting in a presidential election year," and those in the last column are for "voting in a non--presidential even-numbered year" (congressional election). For the first two outcomes there are two sets of regressions. The first corresponds to Equation (2), wherein AFDC waivers and TANF are allowed to have separate effects. The second combines AFDC waivers and TANF into one indicator--Any Welfare Reform. For Models 5 and 6. we present results only for Any Welfare Reform, our preferred measure for this article for reasons discussed earlier.

These DDD estimates are consistent with the trends presented in Table 1 and the figures, and indicate that welfare reform was associated with smaller decreases in registration and voting among women exposed to welfare reform compared to those who had similar characteristics but were less exposed. Model 1 in Table 2 (top panel) suggests that TANF attenuated declines in registration and voting by 3.5 and 2.7 percentage points, respectively, but that the AFDC waivers had no effect. However, as indicated earlier, the separate estimates for AFDC waivers and TANF. particularly the former, should be interpreted with caution because they are based on few elections. Using the same comparison group and the single measure of Any Welfare Reform (our preferred measure for this study), we find that welfare reform attenuated decreases in registration and voting by 2.9 and 1.9 percentage points, respectively, and that, as expected, the effects on voting were much stronger in presidential election years (2.7 percentage points). These estimates translate to effect sizes of 6.0, 7.0. and 6.4% relative to the baseline means for registration, voting in any election, and voting in a presidential election, respectively, for the target group. (8)

The results are similar when using the other comparison group (Table 2, bottom panel), although the AFDC waivers as well as TANF were associated with registration and voting (and statistically significant for the former). Results using the single measure of Any Welfare Reform, our preferred measure for this study, suggests that welfare reform attenuated voting registration decreases by about 2.7 percentage points (Model 2), voting in any election by 2.3 percentage points (Model 4), and voting in a presidential election by 3.9 percentage points, with the last translating to about a 9.2% effect relative to the baseline mean.

The magnitudes in Table 2 are plausible given that similar specifications using both comparison groups find increases in employment on the order of 6-10 percentage points among the target group of women (reported in footnote 7). If we assume that employment is the main channel by which welfare reform affected voting, this would suggest a marginal "treatment-on-the-treated" effect of employment on voting of 0.19 to 0.36, (9) which is the imputed instrumental variables (IV) estimate using the indicator for Any Welfare Reform as an IV for employment. While employment is likely the primary channel of effect, welfare reform may also impact other determinants of voting behavior, such as educational investments, income, labor supply at the intensive margin, and the normative climate. To the extent to which this is the case, this imputed IV effect would overstate the impact of employment on voting. Nevertheless, we present it here as an upper bound estimate of the effect of employment on voting, and also to gauge the credibility of the magnitude. This estimated marginal effect of employment on voting compares to the observed average propensity to vote, conditional on employment, of 0.40 among the target group prior to welfare reform. The similarity between the two magnitudes is validating and also suggests that employment is a primary channel of effect underlying the link between welfare reform and voting. (10)

As indicated earlier, a key concern underlying the estimates in Table 2 relates to unobserved time-varying state factors that may be correlated with the timing of welfare reform and which may also impact voting participation. A related concern is that the comparison groups may not be perfect counterfactuals for the target group, and thus may not fully purge the effects of all unobserved time-varying state-specific factors. We address these concerns in the models shown in Table 3.

Results shown in the first column of Table 3 (Model 1) are the "baseline estimates" from Model 5 in Table 2 which use the single measure of Any Welfare Reform. One potentially important policy confounder, as described in the previous section, is the NVRA, which most states implemented in 1995 though several states had implemented similar provisions earlier. Model 2 controls for the implementation of the law or whether the state had implemented similar (or more liberal) provisions in the past. While 1996 was the first national election year under the NVRA, 14 states implemented welfare reform after the 1996 election, and 13 states had provisions similar to (or more liberal than) the NVRA prior to 1996. Thus, there is substantial variation in welfare reform implementation even after controlling for provisions of the NVRA. The estimated effects of Any Welfare Reform on voting participation are unaffected when introducing this control. Model 3 additionally controls for unobserved time-varying state factors by including state-specific linear trends, and the estimates are slightly smaller than those in Models 1 and 2. Model 4 controls for all observed and unobserved time-varying state factors through the inclusion of a full set of State*Year fixed effects instead of indicators for NVRA or state-specific linear trends. (11) The estimated effects of welfare reform are somewhat smaller in magnitude but remain statistically significant. As indicated earlier, saturating the model with State*Year fixed effects also addresses concerns about policy endogeneity.

Another empirical concern related to state trends is that within a given state, there may be differential outcome trends between the target and comparison groups. In Model 5, we control for any such differential pre-policy trends by including an interaction between a linear trend and the target group. When using the first comparison group (top panel), the estimated effect of Any Welfare Reform is smaller than that in the other specifications and marginally significant. When using the second comparison group (bottom panel), the estimated effect becomes larger than that in any of the other specifications and suggests a 5 percentage point relative increase (12) in voting participation; this compares to an estimated 4 percentage point effect in the baseline specification (Model 1) that does not control for the State*Year indicators or differential pre-policy trends. Given the general robustness of the estimates across all of these specifications and to preserve degrees of freedom, we use Model 1 from these tables as the baseline for comparison in subsequent specifications.

The results in Tables 2 and 3 consistently suggest that welfare reform is associated with a relative increase in voting participation, especially in presidential election years. These are mean effects realized over all states, weighted by the target population in each state. Table 4 assesses heterogeneity in these effects across relevant state margins. Models 1 and 2 (using comparison group 1) and 5 and 6 (using comparison group 2) stratify the sample based on whether the state's legislature had a Republican or a Democratic majority. As expected, we find that the relative increase in voting participation associated with welfare reform was driven primarily by Democratic states; in states with a Republican majority in the legislature, welfare reform is not associated with any significant change in voting behaviors. Models 3 and 4 (and Models 7 and 8) stratify the sample into strict/moderate versus weak work incentives based on the typology developed by Blank and Schmidt (2001) that incorporates various features of states' TANF programs (benefit generosity, earnings disregards, sanctions, and time limits) and categorizes states as strong, weak, or mixed in overall work incentives.

If our estimated effects of welfare reform on voting represent causal links and operate through employment (the first-order effect of welfare reform), we would expect the effects to be stronger in states that enacted stricter pro-employment policies under welfare reform. Owing to limited sample sizes upon stratification, standard errors inflate and render some of the estimates imprecise. However, the estimates are clearly larger in states with stronger employment-based incentives, suggesting that the effects of welfare reform operate, at least in part, through employment.

Table 5 directly assesses the mediating effects of employment as well as those of education and family income. Models 1 and 5 add employment status (an indicator for whether the woman is currently employed) to the baseline specifications (Model 5 in Table 2). The effects of welfare reform decline in magnitude, and as expected, current employment is positively associated with voting participation. Models 2 and 6 instead include categorical indicators for weekly hours worked, with nonemployment as the reference category. Models 3 and 7 further include the natural log of family income, and the final specifications (Models 4 and 8) add an indicator for high school completion. Comparing the estimated effects of welfare reform in Models 4 and 8 with those from the corresponding baseline models, we find that a large part of the effects of welfare reform on voting appears to be mediated by employment, income, and education--factors that prior studies found or suggest were affected by welfare reform. The estimates in Models 4 and 8 again suggest that employment and family income encourage voting participation, although conditional on employment, more working hours reduce voting participation, likely owing to time constraints. Higher educational attainment is also associated with voting participation. The mediation analyses in Table 5, which are consistent with the hypothesized effects, should be interpreted with caution since the mediators are endogenous and constitute what Angrist and Pischke (2009) refer to as "bad controls." (13) However, they provide a useful first look at hypothesized pathways.

Finally, we consider a number of different specification checks and placebo tests. We assess potential lagged effects in Table 6. Specifically, Models 1 and 2 (using comparison group 1) and 5 and 6 (using comparison group 2) allow for welfare reform to impact voting behavior with 6and 12-month lags, respectively. If there are no strong lagged effects, we would expect the DDD coefficients in these models to be substantially diminished in magnitude. However, the estimates remain relatively robust, and with respect to the 12-month lag. increase somewhat in magnitude (suggesting a 3.4 to 4 percentage point relative increase in voting participation), which suggests some persistence and some delay between implementation and changes in voting behavior.

Second, seven states implemented welfare reform in September and October of 1996 (Appendix, Table Al) and it would not be reasonable to expect any substantial effect of welfare reform on voting for these states during the 1996 presidential election. Particularly, if we were to find a substantive or significant effect of welfare reform for these states, this would suggest that our treatment effects are biased and reflective of differential trends in the reform-implementing states between the target and comparison groups. We perform this check in Models 3 and 7 (for comparison groups 1 and 2, respectively) in Table 6, and it is validating that we do not find any such effects for this group of states.

Third, for the 22 states and DC, which implemented welfare reform relatively late (post September 1996), it would not be plausible for welfare reform to affect voting during the 1992 and 1996 presidential elections. This placebo test, shown in Models 4 and 8 in Table 6, is akin to testing for significance of lead effects and it also informs if there are differential pre-policy trends between the treatment and comparison groups in late-implementing versus early-implementing states. It is again validating that the coefficients are statistically insignificant and close to zero. These results are consistent with Models 4 and 5 in Table 3, which also showed that our estimates were not sensitive to controlling for state-specific unobserved trends and controlling for differential (parametric) pre-policy trends between the target and control individuals.

In additional specification tests, we excluded individual presidential election years (to be sure that the results were not driven by any particular election) and excluded African Americans from the sample (to address potential confounding effects of sharp increases in black voter turnout since the 1996 presidential election). Appendix Table A2 reproduces the results from Model 1 in Table 3 for the full sample, as well as from specifications that sequentially drop observations from 1996, 2000, and the 2004 election cycles (presidential election years that took place after the implementation of welfare reform). While these results are suggestive of some heterogeneity in the magnitude of the welfare reform effects for the target group across elections, the estimates are relatively robust to the exclusion of the various presidential elections despite a loss of statistical power and we cannot reject the null that the effects are the same across specifications. These findings alleviate concerns that we do not have enough time variation in the implementation of welfare reform to look at presidential voting behavior, which only happens every 4 years.

Appendix Table A3 reproduces the results from Model 1 in Table 3, along with corresponding results after excluding African Americans from the sample. Though the decrease in sample sizes slightly reduces precision, the DDD estimates remain stable in terms of both direction and magnitude; they range from 2.0 to 2.9 and 2.2 to 5.6 percentage points for comparison groups 1 and 2, respectively, when we exclude African Americans, which compare to effects ranging from 2.0 to 2.7 and 2.5 to 5.1 percentage points, respectively, for the full sample. These results confirm that the relative increases in black voter turnout starting in 1996 did not confound our main estimates.

Finally, we assess the sensitivity of our estimates to additional comparison groups consisting of unmarried women with higher levels of education. These estimates are presented in Appendix Table A4. Models 1 and 2 reproduce the estimates from Model 1 in Table 3 based on our two main comparison groups--low-educated unmarried women with no children and low-educated married women with children (comparison groups generally ineligible for welfare). In Models 3 through 5, we alternately compare how welfare reform affected voting participation among low-educated unmarried mothers (target group) relative to unmarried mothers with some college though not a college degree (Model 3), mothers with any college education (degree or not) (Model 4), and mothers at least a college degree (Model 5). The coefficient for Any Welfare Reform remains negative and in the range of 5-6 percentage points in these models, indicative of the general downward trend in voting participation among higher-educated unmarried mothers. The DDD estimates all fall in the range of those of our two main comparison groups, suggesting a 3.1 to 3.4 percentage point relative increase in voting for the target group relative to these alternate comparison groups.

VI. CONCLUSION

This study found robust evidence that welfare reform in the United States in the 1990s, which coincided with ongoing declines in voter turnout, led to relative increases in women's voting on the order of 2 percentage points (for any even-year election) to 3-4 percentage points (presidential election), which translates to about a 6 to 9% effect relative to the baseline means. These robust findings suggest that welfare reform had pro-social effects on civic participation, as characterized by voting. We took great care to account for the methodological challenges inherent in our study, including the potential confounding effects of the NVRA of 1993, which coincided, to some extent, with the implementation of welfare reform. The effects were largely confined to presidential elections, were stronger in states in which the majority of state legislators were Democrats, were stronger in states with stronger work incentive policies, and appeared to operate through employment, education, and income.

Although we ruled out the possibility that the NVRA confounded our estimates, it is possible that this legislation played an indirect role in affecting voting behavior of women at risk of relying on welfare. Specifically, the "Motor Voter" feature of the NVRA required state motor vehicle agencies to incorporate voter registration into their driver's license, renewal, and change-of-address applications. The substantial increases in women's employment as a result of welfare reform may have increased voting registration, and potentially voting participation, through increased demand for cars (for which motor vehicle licenses are required) as a means of transportation to work. Interestingly, the percentage of female householders under the age of 35 in the United States who owned cars increased from 67.8% to 73.8% between 1993 and 2004, coinciding with the unfolding of welfare reform. Unfortunately, we are unable to directly test this mechanism with our data.

The findings from this study inform culture of poverty debates by providing a rigorous test of the widely embraced argument, on both sides of the political spectrum, that welfare reform brings women from the margins to the mainstream and encourages pro-social behavior. It complements previous studies finding that welfare reform reduced women's binge drinking, illicit drug use, and property crime (Corman, Dave, and Reichman 2014; Corman et al. 2013; Kaestner and Tarlov 2006). As far as we know, no previous population-based studies have investigated the causal effects of welfare policy in the United States on voting, on any other form of civic participation, or on any nontargeted mainstream behaviors more generally (targeted behaviors being working and marriage), and no such studies of which we are aware have found undesirable effects on nontargeted behaviors. As such, this study adds to the growing evidence that welfare reform encourages mainstream behavior and helps to provide a more complete picture of the effects of a major policy shift in the United States that is still very much in effect today and under which the next generation has been raised.

The findings from this study also contribute to the political science literature, in two ways. First, as indicated earlier, strong evidence about effects of employment or income on political participation is scarce or nonexistent. Our study contributes to this literature by exploiting a large-scale policy shift that resulted in substantial exogenous increases in employment and providing perhaps the strongest evidence yet that employment improves voter turnout. That said, the results cannot be generalized to groups other than women at risk for reliance on welfare in the United States and we are not able to explore potential mechanisms such as information networks at work. Second, our finding that welfare reform (which would reduce interactions with welfare agencies because it reduced welfare reliance) led to relative increases in voting among women at risk of relying on welfare than among similar women at much lower risk of relying on welfare (defined multiple ways) is consistent with the scenario proposed by Soss (1999) in which women's experiences with the welfare system discourage political participation. However, this evidence is indirect and thus only suggestive.

Future research is needed to further elucidate the micro-level processes linking welfare policy, welfare participation, employment, and voting.

APPENDIX
TABLE A1
Implementation Dates of Welfare Reform by State, United States

                  October 1992   September 1996   October 1992
                  to February      to January      to January
                      1997            1998            1998

                  AFDC Waiver         TANF        Any Welfare
                                                     Reform

Alabama                          November 96      November 96
Alaska                           July 97          July 97
Arizona           November 95    October 96       November 95
Arkansas          July 94        July 97          July 94
California        December 92    January 98       December 92
Colorado                         July 97          July 97
Connecticut       January 96     October 96       January 96
DC                               March 97         March 97
Delaware          October 95     March 97         October 95
Florida                          October 96       October 96
Georgia           January 94     January 97       January 94
Hawaii            February 97    July 97          February 97
Idaho                            July 97          July 97
Illinois          November 93    July 97          November 93
Indiana           May 95         October 96       May-95
Iowa              October 93     January 97       October 93
Kansas                           October 96       October 96
Kentucky                         October 96       October 96
Louisiana                        January 97       January 97
Maine                            November 96      November 96
Maryland          March 96       December 96      March 96
Massachusetts     November 95    September 96     November 95
Michigan          October 92     September 96     October 92
Minnesota                        July 97          July 97
Mississippi       October 95     July 97          October 95
Missouri          June 95        December 96      June 95
Montana           February 96    February 97      February 96
Nebraska          October 95     December 96      October 95
Nevada                           December 96      December 96
New Hampshire                    October 96       October 96
New Jersey        October 92     July 97          October 92
New Mexico                       July 97          July 97
New York                         November 97      November 97
North Carolina    July 96        January 97       July 96
North Dakota                     July 97          July 97
Ohio              July 96        October 96       July 96
Oklahoma                         October 96       October 96
Oregon            February 93    October 96       February 93
Pennsylvania                     March 97         March 97
Rhode Island                     May 97           May 97
South Carolina                   October 96       October 96
South Dakota      June 94        December 96      June 94
Tennessee         September 96   October 96       September 96
Texas             June 96        November 96      June 96
Utah              January 93     October 96       January 93
Vermont           July 94        September 96     July 94
Virginia          July 95        February 97      July 95
Washington        January 96     January 97       January 96
West Virginia     February 96    January 97       February 96
Wisconsin         January 96     September 97     January 96
Wyoming                          January 97       January 97

Source: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (1999).

TABLE A2
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in Presidential
Elections. Overall and Excluding Specific Presidential Election
Years

Specification          1           2           3            4

                               Excluding   Excluding    Excluding
Sample                All        1996         2000        2004

Comparison Group                   Comparison Group 1

Any Welfare        -0.049 **   -0.057 **   -0.065 ***   -0.050 **
Reform              (0.019)     (0.026)     (0.021)      (0.023)

Welfare            0.027 **    0.047 ***    0.023 *      0.026 *
Reform*Target       (0.011)     (0.013)     (0.013)      (0.013)

N                   15,669      11.826       12,323      12,034

Specification          5            6           7            8

                                Excluding   Excluding    Excluding
Sample                All         1996         2000         2004

Comparison Group                   Comparison Group 2

Any Welfare        -0.046 ***    -0.023     -0.046 ***   -0.041 ***
Reform              (0.015)      (0.022)     (0.016)      (0.015)

Welfare            0.039 ***    0.052 ***   0.052 ***     0.025 *
Reform*Target       (0.013)      (0.017)     (0.014)      (0.014)

N                    25,796      19,126       20,476       20.374

Notes: Estimates in columns 1 and 5 are from specification I in panels
a and b. respectively, in Table 3. Corresponding estimates excluding
specific presidential elections from the sample are presented in the
other columns.

TABLE A3
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in Presidential
Elections, Excluding African Americans from the Sample

Specification                           1           2           3

Comparison Group 1
Full sample
Welfare Reform * Target             0.027 **    0.027 **    0.026 **
                                     (0.011)     (0.011)     (0.011)
N                                    15,669      15,669      15,669

Comparison Group 1
Excluding African Americans
Welfare Reform * Target             0.029 **    0.029 **    0.029 **
                                     (0.013)     (0.013)     (0.013)
N                                    11,919      11,919      11,919

Comparison Group 2
Full sample
Welfare Reform * Target             0.039 ***   0.039 ***   0.039 ***
                                     (0.013)     (0.013)     (0.013)
N                                    25,796      25,796      25,796

Comparison Group 2
Excluding African Americans
Welfare Reform * Target             0.038 **    0.038 **    0.039 **
                                     (0.016)     (0.016)     (0.016)
N                                    22,078      22,078      22,078

Motor Voter law                        No          Yes         Yes
State linear trend                     No          No          Yes
State * Year indicators                No          No          No
Target * Linear pre-policy trend       No          No          No

Specification                          4           5

Comparison Group 1
Full sample
Welfare Reform * Target             0.023 *     0.020 *
                                    (0.011)     (0.011)
N                                    20,682     20,682

Comparison Group 1
Excluding African Americans
Welfare Reform * Target             0.023 *     0.020 *
                                    (0.013)     (0.012)
N                                    15,407     15,407

Comparison Group 2
Full sample
Welfare Reform * Target             0.025 **   0.051 ***
                                    (0.011)     (0.016)
N                                    35,482     35,482

Comparison Group 2
Excluding African Americans
Welfare Reform * Target              0.022     0.056 ***
                                    (0.014)     (0.019)
N                                    30,121     30,121

Motor Voter law                        No          No
State linear trend                     No          No
State * Year indicators               Yes         Yes
Target * Linear pre-policy trend       No         Yes

Notes: Each cell provides DDD estimates from a separate model
corresponding to specifications in Table 3.

TABLE A4
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in Presidential
Elections. Using Alternate Higher-education Comparison Groups

                          1                      2

Target Group         Unmarried Mothers with High School
                            Education or Less

                    Unmarried Women       Married Mothers
                    with No Children      with High School
                    and High School      Education or Less
Comparison         Education or Less        (comparison
Group             (comparison group 1)       group 2)

Any Welfare            -0.049 **            -0.046 ***
Reform                  (0.019)               (0.015)

Welfare Reform          0.027 **             0.039 ***
* Target                (0.011)               (0.013)

N                        15,669               25,796

                        3               4                 5

Target Group            Unmarried Mothers with High School
                               Education or Less

                    Unmarried        Unmarried        Unmarried
                  Mothers with        Mothers        Mothers with
                  Some College    with Any College    a College
Comparison        but No Degree   (degree or not)       Degree
Group

Any Welfare         -0.57 **         -0.050 **        -0.059 **
Reform               (0.024)          (0.020)          (0.027)

Welfare Reform        0.031            0.031           0.034 *
* Target             (0.023)          (0.019)          (0.020)

N                    15,142            17.236           11,309

Notes: Estimates in the first two columns are from Model 1 in panels
a and b, respectively, in Table 3. Corresponding estimates
using higher-education comparison groups of women ages
21-49 are presented in specifications 3-5.


ABBREVIATIONS

AFDC: Aid to Families with Dependent Children

ANES: American National Election Studies

CPS: Current Population Survey

DD: Difference-in-Differences

DDD: Difference-in-Difference-in-Differences

EDR: Election Day Registration

IV: Instrumental Variables

MSA: Metropolitan Statistical Area

NVRA: National Voter Registration Act

PRWORA: Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act

TANF: Temporary Assistance to Needy Families

VRS: Voting and Registration Supplement

doi: 10.1111/ecin.12433

Corman: Professor, Department of Economics. Rider University, Lawrenceville, NJ 08648. Phone 609-895-5559, Fax 609-896-5387, E-mail corman@rider.edu

Dave: Professor, Department of Economics, Bentley University, NBER & IZA, Economics, Waltham, MA 02452. Phone 781-891-2268. Fax 917-426-7015. E-mail ddave @ bentley.edu

Reichman: Professor, Department of Pediatrics, Rutgers University--Robert Wood Johnson Medical School, New Brunswick, NJ 08903, and University of Toronto, Institute of Health Policy, Management & Evaluation, Dalla Lana School of Public Health. Phone 732-235-7977, Fax 925-522-3345, E-mail reichmne@rwjms.rutgers.edu

REFERENCES

Anderson. R., J. Curtis, and E. Grabb. "Trends in Civic Association Activity in Four Democracies: The Special Case of Women in the United States." American Sociological Review, 71(3), 2006, 376-400.

Angrist, J., and J. S. Pischke. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's Companion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2009.

Baez, J. E., A. Camacho, E. Conover, and R. D. Zarate. "Conditional Cash Transfers, Political Participation, and Voting Behavior." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 6215, 2012.

Berinsky, A. J., and G. S. Lenz. "Education and Political Participation: Exploring the Causal Link." Political Behavior, 33(3), 2011, 357-73.

Blank, R. M. "Evaluating Welfare Reform in the United States." Journal of Economic Literature, 40(4), 2002, 1105-66.

Blank, R. M., and L. Schmidt. "Work, Wages, and Welfare," in The New World of Welfare, edited by R. M. Blank and R. Haskins. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. 2001.

Brown. R. D., and J. Wedeking. "People Who Have Their Tickets but Do Not Use Them: 'Motor Voter,' Registration, and Turnout Revisited." American Politics Research, 34(4), 2006, 479-504.

Bruch, S. K., M. M. Ferree, and J. B. Soss. "From Policy to Polity: Democracy, Paternalism, and the Incorporation of Disadvantaged Citizens." American Sociological Review, 75(2), 2010, 205-26.

Corman, H., D. Dave, D. Das, and N. E. Reichman. "Effects of Welfare Reform on Illicit Drug Use of Adult Women." Economic Inquiry, 51(1), 2013, 653-74.

Corman, H., D. Dave, and N. E. Reichman. "Effects of Welfare Reform on Women's Crime." International Review of Law and Economics, 40. 2014. 1-14.

Dave, D., N. E. Reichman, H. Corman. and D. Das. "Effects of Welfare Reform on Vocational Education and Training." Economics of Education Review, 30(6), 2011, 1399-415.

Dave, D., H. Corman, and N. E. Reichman. "Effects of Welfare Reform on Education Acquisition of Adult Women." Journal of Labor Research, 33(2), 2012, 251-82.

DeSilver, D. "Voter Turnout Always Drops Off for Midterm Elections, but Why? Facttank--News in the Numbers." Pew Research Center. 2014. Accessed February 7, 2016. http://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2014/ 07/24/voter-turnout-always-drops-off-for-midtermelections-but-why/

Dinesen, P. T., C. T. Dawes, M. Johannesson, R. Klemmensen, P. Magnusson, A. S. N0rgaard. I. Petersen, and S. Oskarsson. "Estimating the Impact of Education on Political Participation: Evidence from Monozygotic Twins in the United States, Denmark and Sweden." Political Behavior, 38, 2016, 579-601.

Edlund, L., and R. Pande. "Why Have Women Become Left-Wing? The Political Gender Gap and the Decline in Marriage." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 2002, 917-61.

Feddersen, T. J. "Rational Choice Theory and the Paradox of Not Voting." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 2004, 99-112.

File, T. "Who Votes? Congressional Elections and the American Electorate: 1978-2014, Population Characteristics, P20-577." U.S. Census Bureau. Washington, DC, 2015. Accessed March 10, 2016. https://www.census.gov/ content/dam/Census/library/publications/2015/demo/ p20-577.pdf.

Gennetian. L. A., and V. Knox. Staying Single: The Effects of Welfare Reform Policies on Marriage and Cohabitation. New York: MDRC.399, 2003.

Glaeser, E. L., D. Laibson, and B. Sacerdote. "An Economic Approach to Social Capital." Economic Journal, 112(483), 2002, F437-58.

Grogger, J., and L. A. Karoly. Welfare Reform: Effects of a Decade of Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2005.

Jennings, J. "Welfare Reform and Neighborhoods: Race and Civic Participation." The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 577, 2001, 94-106.

Kaestner, R., and E. Tarlov. "Changes in the Welfare Caseload and the Health of Low-Educated Mothers." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 25(3), 2006.623-43.

Kam, C. D.. and C. L. Palmer. "Reconsidering the Effects of Education on Political Participation." Journal of Politics, 70(3), 2008, 612-31.

--. "Rejoinder: Reinvestigating the Causal Relationship between Higher Education and Political Participation." Journal of Politics, 73(3), 2011, 659-63.

Katz, M. B. The Price of Citizenship: Redefining the American Welfare State. New York: Metropolitan Books, Henry Holt & Co., 2001.

Knack, S. "Does 'Motor Voter' Work? Evidence from State-level Data." Journal of Politics, 57(03), 1995, 796-811.

--. "Drivers Wanted: Motor Voter and the Election of 1996." PS: Political Science and Politics, 32(2), 1999, 237-43.

Loprest, P. J. "How Has the TANF Caseload Changed Over Time?" 2012. Accessed February 8. 2015. http:// www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/412565- How-Has-theTANF-Caseload-Changed-Over-Time.pdf

McDonald, M. "The True Electorate: A Cross-Validation of Voter Registration Files and Election Survey Demographics." Public Opinion Quarterly, 71(4), 2007, 588-602.

Milligan. K., E. Moretti. and P. Oreopoulos. "Does Education Improve Citizenship? Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom." Journal of Public Economics, 88(9-10), 2004, 1667-95.

National Council of State Legislatures. "Same Day Voter Registration." 2015. Accessed February 8, 2106. http:// www.ncsl.org/research/elections-and-campaigns/ same-day-registration.aspx

Pelkonen, P. "Length of Compulsory Education and Voter Turnout--Evidence from a Staged Reform." Public Choice, 150, 2012, 51-75.

Pew Center on the States. "Election Administration by the Numbers: An Analysis of Available Datasets and How to Use Them." 2012. Accessed June 19, 2016. http:// www.pewtrusts.org/~/media/legacy/uploadedfiles/pcs_ assets/2012/pewelectionsbythenumberspdf. pdf

Pew Research Center. "The Politics of Financial Insecurity: A Democratic Tilt. Undercut by Low Participation." 2015. Accessed February 7, 2016. http://www.peoplepress.org/files/20 15/01/1-8-15-Financial-.securityrelease.pdf

Schoeni, R. F., and R. M. Blank. "What Has Welfare Reform Accomplished? Impacts on Welfare Participation, Employment, Income. Poverty, and Family Structure." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7627, 2000.

Schur, L. "Employment and the Creation of an Active Citizenry." British Journal of Industrial Relations, 41(4), 2003, 751-71.

Sondheimer, R. M., and D. P. Green. "Using Experiments to Estimate the Effects of Education on Voter Turnout." American Journal of Political Science, 54(1), 2010, 174-89.

Soss, J. "Lessons of Welfare: Policy Design. Political Learning, and Political Action." American Political Science Review, 93(02), 1999, 363-80.

Sugie, N. F. "Chilling Effects: Diminished Political Participation among Partners of Formerly Incarcerated Men." Social Problems, 62, 2015, 550-71.

Swartz, T. T., A. Blackstone, C. Uggen, and H. McLaughlin. "Welfare and Citizenship: The Effects of Government Assistance on Young Adults' Civic Participation." The Sociological Quarterly, 50(4), 2009. 633-65.

Taylor, P. "The Growing Electoral Clout of Blacks Is Driven by Turnout, Not Demographics." Pew Social & Demographic trends, 2013. Accessed April 10, 2016. http:// www.pewsocialtrends.org/files/2013/01/2012_Black_ Voter_Project_revised_1-9.pdf.

U.S. Census Bureau. "Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2012." Section 7: Elections, 2012. Accessed February 7, 2016 http://www.census.gov/prod/ 2011 pubs/12statab/election.pdf.

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. "State Implementation of Major Changes to Welfare Policies, 1992-1998." Washington. DC: Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. 1999. Accessed Febraury 9, 2016. https://aspe.hhs.gov/basicreport/state-implementation-major -changes-welfare-policies-1992-1998.

U.S. Department of Justice. "About the National Voter Registration Act." 2015. Accessed February 8, 2016. http:// www.justice.gov/crt/about-national-voter-registration-act

U.S. Election Project. "CPS Vote Over-Report and NonResponse Bias Correction." 2016a. Accessed June 19, 2016. http://www.electproject.org/home/voter-turnout/ cps-methodology

--. "Voter Turnout National Turnout Rates, 1787-2012." 2016b. Accessed October 22, 2016. http://www.electproject.org/home/voter-turnout/voterturnout-data

Verba, S., K. L. Schlozman, and H. E. Brady. Voice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in American Politics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1995.

Watson, S. "Does Welfare Conditionality Reduce Democratic Participation?" Comparative Political Studies, 48(5), 2015, 645-86.

Ziliak, J. P. "Taxes, Transfers, and the Labor Supply of Single Mothers." Unpublished Working Paper No. 2006, 2006. Accessed February 5, 2016. http://www.nber.org/~confer/2006/URCf06/ziliak.pdf

(1.) We present the general model with separate estimates for AFDC waivers and TANF, as some of our models are specified that way. However, as indicated earlier, our preferred specifications use a single indicator of whether the state had implemented an AFDC waiver or TANF.

(2.) The legislature data are from several volumes of the Statistical Abstract of the United States. Composition of State Legislatures by Political Party Affiliation. Data on the Governor's party were obtained from the National Governors' Association. Male registration rates by state and year (from our CPS data) were included in models predicting women's registration, and male voting rates were included in models of women's voting.

(3.) We implemented the reduced-form DDD-based analysis rather than estimating IV models using the welfare reform measures as instruments for employment, because if welfare reform had any effect on voting through channels other than employment, welfare reform measures would be inappropriate IVs. That is, welfare reform would be correlated with the error term in the structural model linking employment to voting and it would thus violate the exclusion restriction. The reduced form DDD estimates, on the other hand, capture any and all channels, reinforcing or counteracting, through which welfare reform may affect the voting outcomes. That said, we do later impute and discuss the implied IV estimate as a reference point for the reduced form estimates.

(4.) In contrast, both Knack (1999) and Brown and Wedeking (2006) found that election day registration (EDR). another voting-related policy implemented by some states that was not required by the NVRA but was consistent with its intent, did increase voter turnout. Only three states implemented EDR during the rollout of welfare reform--Idaho and Wyoming in 1994 and New Hampshire in 1996 (National Council of State Legislatures 2015). Excluding these states from our analyses does not materially affect any of the estimates presented or referred to in this article.

(5.) A value of negative I corresponds to the 12-month period preceding the implementation of welfare reform in the woman's state, and a value of 0 corresponds to the first 12 months after welfare reform implementation.

(6.) Note that there could be up to a 2-year lag between the implementation of welfare reform and a congressional election, and there could be up to a 4-year lag between the implementation of welfare reform and a presidential election.

(7.) Some of this difference may be due to unobserved trends and economic conditions. The conditional DDD estimates on employment (discussed later), based on Equation (2). are 6.4 percentage points and 10.0 percentage points for groups 2 and 1, respectively (/; value = 0.000). which are consistent with the literature of the effects of welfare reform on employment.

(8.) The coefficient of the main indicator for Any Welfare Reform is negative and significant for presidential elections (Model 5 in Table 2), confirming the various unmeasured factors driving the general downward trend in voting participation among women coinciding with welfare reform that was evident in the figures (for non-presidential elections, the trends are generally positive). It is this presence of confounding trends that motivates our use of various control groups (women not at risk of being on public assistance) and the DDD framework to net out such state-specific time-varying unobserved characteristics. That is. in the absence of plausible control groups and the third "D." a DD model, which would just include the indicator for Any Welfare Reform and not the interaction, would lead to biased estimates of changes in voting behavior. That is, the estimates would, to a large extent, reflect the secular downward trend in voting among low-educated women. The fact that the estimate for Any Welfare Reform is negative and significant when considering presidential years but not significantly different from zero when considering all elections is not particularly surprising. and differences in fact are to be expected, as that estimate (which is not the estimate of interest for our study) reflects changes in a constellation of factors (including, but not limited to welfare reform) over different sets of years. The variability of estimates for this indicator when considering different election years does not compromise our inference that the estimates of the interaction term (which are net of all trends coinciding with welfare reform during the specified time period) were driven almost entirely by presidential year elections.

(9.) To get these numbers, we divide the coefficients in specification (5) in Table 2 by the growth in employment relative to the comparison group. That is .19 is obtained by dividing .019 by .10 and .36 is obtained by dividing .023 by .064. This is the Wald estimator for deriving the IV estimate in the case of a binary instrument.

(10.) We further assess the role of employment and other mechanisms below in Tables 4 and 5.

(11.) Note that all state/year variables drop out of the equation when state/year dummies are included.

(12.) For ease of exposition, we use the term "relative increase" to refer to a reduced decrease.

(13.) That is, labor supply, education, and income are themselves outcomes of welfare reform, and are also potentially correlated with unobserved factors in Equation (2). This may lead to a form of sample selection bias (Angrist and Pischke 2009) since, with the additional mediators, the effect of welfare reform is being estimated within sub-populations with the same level of the mediators (e.g.. the same education level or employment status) and sorting into these sub-populations is not random but likely a function of welfare reform.

Caption: FIGURE 1 Registered to Vote by Years Since Welfare Reform in Target Group Compared to Two Different Comparison Groups

Caption: FIGURE 2 Voted in Election by Years Since Welfare Reform in Target Group Compared to Two Different Comparison Groups
TABLE 1
Annual Rates of Voting Registration and Voting, 1990-2004

          Target Group           Comparison Group 1

        Unmarried Mothers      Unmarried Women with No
         with High School      Children and High School
        Education or Less       Education or Less

        Registered    Voted    Registered    Voted

1990       0.49        0.26       0.53        0.33
1992       0.56        0.42       0.60        0.49
1994       0.48        0.23       0.52        0.28
1996       0.57        0.35       0.59        0.41
1998       0.53        0.23       0.53        0.26
2000       0.59        0.39       0.58        0.41
2002       0.55        0.24       0.54        0.27
2004       0.63        0.46       0.62        0.48

        Comparison Group 2

         Married Mothers
         with High School
        Education or Less

        Registered    Voted

1990       0.62        0.41
1992       0.68        0.60
1994       0.61        0.38
1996       0.66        0.50
1998       0.65        0.36
2000       0.69        0.55
2002       0.65        0.37
2004       0.71        0.59

Note: All groups consist of women ages 21-49 who are
U.S. citizens.

TABLE 2
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Women's Registration
and Voting, Using (a) Comparison Group 1 and (b) Comparison Group 2

(a) Target Group:
Unmarried Mothers
with High School
Education or Less              Registered          Voted

Comparison Group 1:         Any          Any        Any
Unmarried Women with      Election    Election    Election
No Children and High        Year        Year        Year

School Education            (1)          (2)        (3)
or Less

AFDC Waiver                0.013                   0.023
                          (0.022)                 (0.014)

TANF                       -0.016                  -0.016
                          (0.018)                 (0.016)

AFDC Waiver*               -0.003                  -0.024
Target                    (0.016)                 (0.015)

TANF * Target            0.035 ***                0.027***
                          (0.010)                 (0.009)

Any Welfare                            -0.008
Reform                                 (0.014)

Any Welfare                           0.029 ***
Reform * Target                        (0.008)

N                          32,234      32,234      32,790

(a) Target Group:
Unmarried Mothers
with High School
Education or Less                        Voted

Comparison Group 1:        Any      Presidential   Nonpresidential
Unmarried Women with     Election     Election        Election
No Children and High       Year         Year            Year

School Education           (4)          (5)              (6)
or Less

AFDC Waiver

TANF

AFDC Waiver*
Target

TANF * Target

Any Welfare               -0.005     -0.049 **          0.037
Reform                   (0.012)      (0.019)          (0.025)

Any Welfare              0.019 **     0.027 **          0.010
Reform * Target          (0.008)      (0.011)          (0.011)

N                         32,790       15,669          17,121

(b) Target Group:
Unmarried Mothers
with High School
Education or Less              Registered          Voted

Comparison Group 2:         Any          Any        Any
Married Mothers with      Election    Election    Election
High School Education       Year        Year        Year
or Less                     (1)          (2)        (3)

AFDC Waiver                -0.012                  -0.018
                          (0.012)                 (0.012)

TANF                       0.001                  < 0.001
                          (0.015)                  (0.01)

AFDC Waiver * Target      0.042 **                 0.023
                          (0.016)                 (0.016)

TANF * Target             0.024 **                0.023 **
                          (0.010)                 (0.010)

Any Welfare Reform                     -0.006
                                       (0.011)

Any Welfare                           0.027 ***
Reform * Target                        (0.01)

N                          54,470      54,470      55.048

(b) Target Group:
Unmarried Mothers
with High School
Education or Less                       Voted

Comparison Group 2:         Any      Presidential   Nonpresidential
Married Mothers with     Election      Election        Election
High School Education      Year          Year            Year
or Less                     (4)          (5)              (6)

AFDC Waiver

TANF

AFDC Waiver * Target

TANF * Target

Any Welfare Reform        -0.013      -0.046 ***        0.026 *
                          (0.010)      (0.015)          (0.015)

Any Welfare              0.023 ***    0.039 ***          0.015
Reform * Target           (0.010)      (0.013)          (0.010)

N                         55,048        25,796          29,252

Notes: AFDC = Aid to Families with Dependent Children. TANF =
Temporary Assistance to Needy Families. All groups consist of women
ages 21-49 who are U.S. citizens. Coefficients from ordinary least
squares models are reported. State-clustered standard errors are
reported in parentheses. All models control for state and year
fixed effects and include the following covariates: age,
age-squared, race (black, other race), Hispanic, marital history
(widowed/divorced/separated, never married), number of children
<18, number of household members age 18+ years, MSA residence,
current and 1-year lagged state unemployment rate, current and 1
-year lagged state personal income per capita, log female
population, state poverty rate, state minimum wage, 1- and 2-year
lagged welfare caseloads, % state legislature Democrat/Republican,
Republican governor. Democrat governor, and registration/voting
rates of males. * p [less than or equal to]. 10; ** p [less than or
equal to]. 05; *** p [less than or equal to] .01.

TABLE 3
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in Presidential
Elections, Accounting for Differential Trends, Using
(a) Comparison Group 1 and (b) Comparison Group 2

(a)                   (1)          (2)          (3)

Any Welfare        -0.049 **    -0.053 **    -0.053 **
Reform              (0.019)      (0.020)      (0.023)

Welfare Reform*     0.027 **     0.027 **     0.026 **
Target              (0.011)      (0.011)      (0.011)

Motor Voter law        No          Yes          Yes

State linear           No           No          Yes
trend

State * Year           No           No           No
indicators

Target*Linear          No           No           No
pre-policy trend

N                    15,669       15,669       15,669

(a)                  (4)         (5)

Any Welfare
Reform

Welfare Reform*    0.023 **    0.020 *
Target             (0.011)     (0.011)

Motor Voter law       No         No

State linear          No         No
trend

State * Year         Yes         Yes
indicators

Target*Linear         No         Yes
pre-policy trend

N                   20,682     20,682

(b)                   (1)          (2)          (3)

Any Welfare        -0.046 ***   -0.049 ***   -0.052 ***
Reform              (0.015)      (0.014)      (0.015)

Welfare Reform     0.039 ***    0.039 ***    0.039 ***
* Target            (0.013)      (0.013)      (0.013)

Motor Voter law        No          Yes          Yes

State linear           No           No          Yes
trend

State * Year           No           No           No
indicators

Target* Linear         No           No           No
pre-policy trend

N                    25,796       25,796       25.796

(b)                  (4)         (5)

Any Welfare
Reform

Welfare Reform     0.025 **   0.051 ***
* Target           (0.011)     (0.016)

Motor Voter law       No         No

State linear          No         No
trend

State * Year         Yes         Yes
indicators

Target* Linear        No         Yes
pre-policy trend

N                   35,482     35,482

Notes: See Table 2. Target group consists of unmarried mothers with
a high school education or less, (a) Comparison group consists of
unmarried women with no children and a high school education or
less (comparison group 1). (b) Comparison group consists of
married mothers with a high school education or less (comparison
group 2). In each panel. Model 1 is identical to the corresponding
Model 5 in Table 2 and Models 2 through 5 add covariates to that
model as indicated. The coefficient for Any Welfare Reform is not
presented in Models 4 and 5 since it is perfectly collinear with
the State*Year fixed effects.

TABLE 4
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in
Presidential Elections, Heterogeneous Effects
Along Relevant State Margins

                             Comparison Group 1: Unmarried
                             Women with No Children and a
                            High School Education or Less

                     (1)           (2)          (3)          (4)

                    State         State         Work         Work
                 Legislature   Legislature   Incentives   Incentives
Sample           Republican    Democratic    Strong or       Weak
                                               Mixed

Any Welfare       -0.057 *      -0.062 *     -0.050 **      0.087
Reform             (0.031)       (0.031)      (0.022)      (0.051)

Welfare             0.015       0.034 **     0.033 ***      -0.019
Reform*Target      (0.018)       (0.015)      (0.011)      (0.055)

N                   5.669         9.144        13,852       1.817

                           Comparison Group 2: Married
                            Mothers with a High School
                                 Education or Less

                     (5)           (6)          (7)          (8)

                    State         State         Work         Work
                 Legislature   Legislature   Incentives   Incentives
Sample           Republican    Democratic    Strong or       Weak
                                               Mixed

Any Welfare        -0.015      -0.089 ***    -0.056 ***    0.098 **
Reform             (0.018)       (0.022)      (0.016)      (0.034)

Welfare             0.005       0.047 ***    0.051 ***      -0.051
Reform*Target      (0.035)       (0.016)      (0.013)      (0.042)

N                   9.448        14.926        22,591       3.205

Notes: See Table 2. Target group consists of unmarried mothers with
a high school education or less. Specification for all models in
this table correspond to Mode! 5 in Table 2. Models 1 and 5 include
state/year observations in which the percentage of state
legislators that were Republican was greater than 50%. Models 2 and
6 include state/year observations in which the percentage of state
legislators that were Democratic was greater than 50%. For
Nebraska, we use the corresponding percentages of national
legislators from that state, since no Nebraska state legislators
have official party affiliation (i.e.. they are all nonpartisan).

TABLE 5
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in Presidential
Elections and Potential Mediating Effects of Employment,
Income, and Education

                          Comparison Group 1: Unmarried
                          Women with No Children and a
                         High School Education or Less

                     (1)         (2)         (3)          (4)

Any Welfare       -0.047 **   -0.046 **   -0.049 ***   -0.049 ***
Reform             (0.019)     (0.019)     (0.018)      (0.018)

Welfare Reform      0.016       0.015      0.020 *       0.017
* Target           (0.011)     (0.011)     (0.012)      (0.012)

Employed          0.138 ***
                   (0.011)

Weekly hours                   0.052 *     0.058 *       0.048
< 10                           (0.028)     (0.030)      (0.030)

Weekly hours                  0.085 ***   0.070 ***    0.060 ***
10-20                          (0.019)     (0.019)      (0.019)

Weekly hours                  0.108 ***   0.075 ***    0.056 ***
20-30                          (0.016)     (0.015)      (0.016)

Weekly hours                  0.151 ***   0.010 ***    0.078 ***
30-40                          (0.011)     (0.011)      (0.011)

Weekly hours                  0.139 ***   0.078 ***    0.057 ***
> 40                           (0.018)     (0.017)      (0.017)

Ln family                                 0.075 ***    0.062 ***
income                                     (0.005)      (0.005)

High school                                            0.129 ***
graduate                                                (0.012)

N                  15,669      15.669       15,669       15,669

                             Comparison Group 2: Married
                             Mothers with a High School
                                 Education or Less

                     (5)          (6)          (7)         (8)

Any Welfare       -0.044 ***   -0.044 ***   -0.036 **   -0.037 **
Reform             (0.015)      (0.015)      (0.016)     (0.016)

Welfare Reform     0.033 **     0.033 **     0.023 *      0.018
* Target           (0.013)      (0.013)      (0.013)     (0.013)

Employed          0.085 ***
                   (0.008)

Weekly hours                   0.104 ***    0.095 ***   0.085 ***
< 10                            (0.022)      (0.022)     (0.023)

Weekly hours                   0.100 ***    0.077 ***   0.063 ***
10-20                           (0.01 1)     (0.011)     (0.011)

Weekly hours                   0.078 ***    0.052 ***   0.039 ***
20-30                           (0.011)      (0.011)     (0.010)

Weekly hours                   0.091 ***    0.045 ***   0.030 ***
30-40                           (0.009)      (0.008)     (0.008)

Weekly hours                   0.075 ***    0.027 **      0.012
> 40                            (0.013)      (0.012)     (0.012)

Ln family                                   0.102 ***   0.083 ***
income                                       (0.005)

High school                                             0.157 ***
graduate                                                 (0.010)

N                   25,796       25,796      23,740      23,740

Notes: See Table 2. Target group consists of unmarried mothers
with a high school education or less. Specification for all
models in this table correspond to Model 5 in Table 2, with
the addition of mediators indicated.

TABLE 6
Estimated Effects of Welfare Reform on Voting in Presidential
Elections, Lagged Effects and Placebo Checks

                       Comparison Group 1 Unmarried Women with No
                      Children and a High School Education or Less

                    All States              States that   All States
                                            Implemented
                                              Welfare
                                              Reform
                                            post-August
                                               1996

Sample              Elections:              Elections:    Elections:
                    1992, 1996, 2000,       1992 & 1996   1992 & 1996
                    2004

                       (1)         (2)          (3)           (4)

Any Welfare          0.027 *
Reform-lagged        (0.015)
6-months *
Target

Any Welfare                      0.034 **
Reform-lagged                    (0.016)
12-months *
Target

Any Welfare                                   -0.011
Reform *                                      (0.041)
Target

Post-1996                                                   -0.001
Welfare Reform                                              (0.021)
implementation *
Target

N                     15,669      15,669       3,469         8,688

                        Comparison Group 2 Married Mothers with a
                             High School Education or Less

                    All States               States that    All States
                                             Implemented
                                               Welfare
                                                Reform
                                             post-August
                                                 1996

Sample              Elections:                Elections:    Elections:
                  1992, 1996, 2000, 2004    1992 & 1996    1992 & 1996

                       (5)          (6)          (7)            (8)

Any Welfare         0.039 ***
Reform-lagged        (0.014)
6-months *
Target

Any Welfare                      0.040 ***
Reform-lagged                     (0.015)
12-months *
Target

Any Welfare                                     -0.032
Reform *                                       (0.037)
Target

Post-1996                                                     -0.004
Welfare Reform                                                (0.019)
implementation *
Target

N                     25.796      25,796        5,921         15.094

Notes: Coefficients from ordinary least squares models are
reported. State-clustered standard errors are reported in
parentheses. All models control for state and year fixed effects
and include the following covariates: age. age-squared, race
(black, other race), Hispanic, marital history
(widowed/divorced/separated, never married), number of children
<18. number of household members age 18+ years. MSA residence,
current and 1-year lagged state unemployment rate, current and
1-year lagged state personal income per capita, log female
population, state poverty rate, state minimum wage, 1- and 2-year
lagged welfare caseloads, % state legislature Democrat/Republican,
Republican governor. Democrat governor, and registration/voting
rates of males. * p [less than or equal to]. 10; ** p [less than or
equal to] .05; *** p [less than or equal to] .01.
COPYRIGHT 2017 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2017 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有