首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Bilateral oligopoly in pollution permit markets: experimental evidence.
  • 作者:Schnier, Kurt ; Doyle, Martin ; Rigby, James R.
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:July
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:We experimentally investigate behavior in a bilateral oligopoly using a supply function equilibria model discussed by Klemperer and Meyer (1989), Hendricks and McAfee (2010), and Malueg and Yates (2009). We focus on the role that market size and the degree of firm heterogeneity have on the market equilibrium. Our results indicate that subjects within the experiment recognize the strategic incentives in a bilateral oligopoly, but they do not exploit these incentives to the exact magnitude predicted by theory. We find weaker support for predicted market outcomes, as market efficiency does not depend on market size, and in some cases buyers or sellers are more successful at extracting the rents from the market. (JEL L13, Q5, C9)

    I. INTRODUCTION

    Pollution permit markets have been applied to a wide variety of pollution problems. Recently, there has been quite a bit of interest in optimizing the scale of these markets (Wiliams 2003; Krysiak and Schweitzer 2010; Yates et al. 2013). When a market is optimized with respect to scale, the polluting firms are divided up into zones and firms may trade emissions only with other firms in their zone. In a given zone, there may be a small number of buyers and sellers, and if so, then all market participants in the zone, not just the buyers or just the sellers, exert market power. This market structure is called a bilateral oligopoly. In general, the strategic incentives inherent in bilateral oligopoly lead to a reduction in trade between firms relative to a competitive benchmark. For pollution permit markets, this reduction in trade has a cost (firms must expend more resources to reduce emissions) as well as a benefit (there are fewer localized damage hot spots). These effects tend to cancel out, implying that the bilateral oligopoly performs about as well overall as a competitive market (Yates et al. 2013). So a regulator need not be overly concerned if it turns out that a zone contains only a small number of firms, at least according to theory.

Bilateral oligopoly in pollution permit markets: experimental evidence.


Schnier, Kurt ; Doyle, Martin ; Rigby, James R. 等


Bilateral oligopoly in pollution permit markets: experimental evidence.

We experimentally investigate behavior in a bilateral oligopoly using a supply function equilibria model discussed by Klemperer and Meyer (1989), Hendricks and McAfee (2010), and Malueg and Yates (2009). We focus on the role that market size and the degree of firm heterogeneity have on the market equilibrium. Our results indicate that subjects within the experiment recognize the strategic incentives in a bilateral oligopoly, but they do not exploit these incentives to the exact magnitude predicted by theory. We find weaker support for predicted market outcomes, as market efficiency does not depend on market size, and in some cases buyers or sellers are more successful at extracting the rents from the market. (JEL L13, Q5, C9)

I. INTRODUCTION

Pollution permit markets have been applied to a wide variety of pollution problems. Recently, there has been quite a bit of interest in optimizing the scale of these markets (Wiliams 2003; Krysiak and Schweitzer 2010; Yates et al. 2013). When a market is optimized with respect to scale, the polluting firms are divided up into zones and firms may trade emissions only with other firms in their zone. In a given zone, there may be a small number of buyers and sellers, and if so, then all market participants in the zone, not just the buyers or just the sellers, exert market power. This market structure is called a bilateral oligopoly. In general, the strategic incentives inherent in bilateral oligopoly lead to a reduction in trade between firms relative to a competitive benchmark. For pollution permit markets, this reduction in trade has a cost (firms must expend more resources to reduce emissions) as well as a benefit (there are fewer localized damage hot spots). These effects tend to cancel out, implying that the bilateral oligopoly performs about as well overall as a competitive market (Yates et al. 2013). So a regulator need not be overly concerned if it turns out that a zone contains only a small number of firms, at least according to theory.

Optimizing permit markets with respect to scale offers promise for the design of future permit markets. But regulators may be reluctant to put these insights into practice and create a zone with a small number of buyers and sellers without assurances that the resulting market will behave according to theoretical predictions. Toward that end, we conduct the first experimental test of a bilateral oligopoly utilizing a supply function equilibria market structure. Using varying market sizes and cost heterogeneity, we find that subjects within the experiment recognize the strategic incentives in a bilateral oligopoly. However, we find weaker support for predicted market outcomes as the overall market efficiency does not appear to depend on market size. Our cautious conclusion is that permit markets that are optimized for scale should generally perform as predicted.

In comparison to other market structures (e.g., monopoly, monopsony, bilateral monopoly, oligopoly, or oligopsony), bilateral oligopoly has received surprisingly little attention. Virtually all of the extent literature is theoretical. Hendricks and McAfee (2010) use extensions of Klemperer and Meyer's (1989) supply function equilibria models to characterize bilateral oligopoly equilibria in a single market. Weretka (2011) uses similar techniques to analyze a general equilibrium setting. Bjornerstedt and Stennek (2001) do not use supply function equilibria, but rather analyze sequential bilateral bargaining between market participants in a network structure. Lange (2012), Malueg and Yates (2009), and Wirl (2009) have all studied bilateral oligopoly in the specific context of pollution permit markets. These papers are conceptually similar in that they all use techniques related to supply function equilibria. There are some differences in their exact structure, however, and here we focus on the model in Malueg and Yates (2009).

The key feature of the Malueg and Yates (2009) model is a net-trade function, which specifies how many permits the firms are willing to buy and sell at various prices. Firms select a net-trade function and then submit it to a market maker. The market maker selects the market price such that overall net trades are zero. Firms take the behavior of the market maker into account, of course, when they select their net-trade functions. Malueg and Yates (2009) describe the resulting equilibrium. Compared to the competitive outcome, a given firm in the bilateral oligopoly equilibrium makes an adjustment that depends on both the number of firms in the market and the variance of firms' abatement costs. This adjustment increases as the number of firms decreases and it increases as the cost variance increases. These theoretical predictions provide the foundation for our experimental analysis.

Although the literature on bilateral oligopoly is relatively small, the underlying supply function equilibria technique has been the subject of considerable theoretical and empirical analysis. Interestingly, there has been little in the way of experimental testing of supply function equilibria. (1) Perhaps, one reason for this is that supply function equilibria markets have been typically applied to electricity markets. There are two salient features of these markets that may help to explain why these markets have not been experimentally investigated. First, market participants have a strong incentive to learn about the market process because they are buying or selling the primary commodity for their firm. Second, there is rapid feedback due to the fact that the market operates on a daily time scale. Given these features, it has been argued that traders will quickly learn and react to the economic incentives in the market and as a result there should likely be good agreement between theory and actual behavior (Green and Newbery 1992). Therefore, the value of an experimental investigation of a similar market may be low.

These features, however, are unlikely to be found in pollution permit markets. In most of these markets, the commodity being traded is not the primary output of the firm. For example, a waste water treatment plant manager is likely to be more concerned about the successful operation of their plant rather than the subtleties of the market for nitrogen emissions. In addition, and perhaps more importantly, the feedback is slow due to the long time scales of the market. Many pollution permit markets operate on a yearly basis, if not longer (Holland and Moore 2013). Thus traders may take a long time to develop expertise within the market. This is often the case for many environmental compliance markets (e.g., carbon offsets, Clean Water Act compensatory mitigation), as these markets typically involve infrequent market transactions (e.g., land developer needing wetland credits once every few years, or possibly just once). Given this, it is natural to question whether or not actual permit markets with a small number of buyers and sellers will function as predicted by theory. Economic experiments in a laboratory are ideally suited to answer questions of this type. (2) If subjects do not behave according to theory, then this suggests that similar behavior may be exhibited in actual permit markets and may persist for some time.

Our results indicate that both buyers and sellers understand and exploit the opportunity to exert market power by manipulating their net-trade functions, although the evidence is stronger for buyers than for sellers, and the magnitude of the effects are different than predicted by theory. We generally find good agreement with the predictions for comparative statics with respect to the number of firms and the cost variance. As the cost variance increases, the high cost (low cost) firms increase (decrease) their indifference price between being a buyer or a seller of permits and, more importantly, their behavior increasingly deviates from the competitive equilibrium. Similarly, as the number of firms decreases, their behavior increasingly deviates from the competitive equilibrium. We also analyze the overall market outcomes. Counter to theoretical predictions, we find that market efficiency does not depend on market size, and there are circumstances where either buyers or sellers are successfully able to generate more profits than the other. However, overall the benefits to buyers and sellers are for the most part balanced.

II. THEORETICAL MODEL

There are n firms that trade pollution permits. The total endowment of permits is fixed at W. Each firm i is given an endowment of permits [w.sub.i] with [summation][w.sub.i] = W. Firm i has a quadratic abatement cost as a function of emissions of pollution [e.sub.i] (1)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],

For interior levels of emissions, Firm i's marginal abatement cost is

=[C'.sub.i] = [[theta].sub.i] - [e.sub.i].

The minus sign is introduced because the abatement cost function is defined with respect to emissions rather than abatement. The business-as-usual level of emissions is [[theta].sub.i]. This corresponds to what the firm would emit if there were no regulations.

The market price is defined through net-trade functions. A net-trade function for a given firm is piecewise linear in the market price and contains one parameter a, that is selected by the firm. The net-trade function v, for firm i is

(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

Equation (2) specifies how many permits firm i is willing to buy (sell) as a function of the market price p. Firms select the intercept of the net-trade function, but the slope is fixed at one. Firms are not allowed to sell a quantity of permits that is greater than their initial endowment. The net-trade function is shown in Figure 1. As illustrated in this figure, a, has a useful interpretation as the price at which subjects are indifferent between buying and selling permits. Let [??] = l/n [summatin][a.sub.i] denote the average of the firms' choices of [a.sub.i].

The firms report the net-trade functions to the market maker. The market maker selects the equilibrium price such that the aggregate net trade function ([summation][v.sub.i]) is equal to zero. This equilibrium price can be found by applying a simple algorithm. The first step is to determine a candidate market price p = [??]. If, at this price, all firms are on the negatively sloped part of their net-trade function, then the candidate price is in fact the market price. If not, then collect all firms that are not on the negatively sloped part and group them into the exceptions group. The next candidate market price is determined by

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

Then test to see if there are any new exceptions with this candidate market price. If not, then the candidate price is the market price. If yes, then add the new exceptions to the exceptions group and repeat until there are no new exceptions. (3)

Once the market price is specified, a firm's net-trade function combined with their permit endowment determines their pollution emissions:

[e.sub.i] = [v.sub.i] + [w.sub.i]

For example, if the net-trade function, evaluated at the market price, is positive then the firm buys permits in the market and thus they are able to emit more pollution than their initial endowment. In the case that the net-trade function is negative the firm becomes a seller of permits and their emission levels are lower than their permit endowment.

Firms exert market power through their choice of [a.sub.i]. In particular, firms realize that the value of [a.sub.i] they select will influence the market price. In our experiment, each firm receives a fixed payment [[pi].sub.i] for participating in the market. (4) The payoff to firm i is equal to this payment minus the abatement cost and permit expenditures:

[V.sub.i] = [[pi].sub.i] - ([C.sub.i] ([v.sub.i] + [w.sub.i]) + p[v.sub.i]).

Firm i selects [a.sub.i] to maximize this expression.

In our model, the abatement cost function is truncated at business as usual emissions and the net-trade function is truncated at the price [??] = [w.sub.i] + [a.sub.i] (the price at which the firm is just willing to sell all of their permit endowment). Malueg and Yates (2009) consider a slightly different model in which these functions are not truncated. They show that there is a unique interior Nash equilibrium for the choice of [a.sub.i]. In this interior Nash equilibrium, a given firm's emissions of pollution are not greater than business-as-usual and the market price is not more than [??]. This equilibrium will still be an equilibrium in our model with truncated functions, but its uniqueness is now an open question. In the Appendix, we show there cannot actually be any equilibria on the truncated portions of the abatement cost functions and net-trade functions, so that the interior Nash equilibrium described by Malueg and Yates (2009) is indeed the unique equilibrium in our model.

The equilibrium value for [a.sub.i] is given by

(3) [a.sup.*.sub.i] = [a.sup.c.sub.i] + [[DELTA].sub.i],

where

[a.sup.c.sub.i] = [[theta].sub.i] - [w.sub.i]

is the competitive outcome, (5) and

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

is an adjustment term (again, we use the tilde to represent averages across all firms). According to Equation (3), firms make an adjustment to the competitive outcome that depends on the difference between their own marginal abatement costs at the permit endowment ([[theta].sub.i] - [w.sub.i]) and the average marginal abatement cost at the permit endowment ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]). Firms that have higher-than-average marginal costs expect to purchase permits, so they want to reduce their net-trade function to put downward pressure on prices. Hence they adjust [a.sub.i] below the competitive outcome. The magnitude of this adjustment decreases in n so that as n approaches infinity, the equilibrium specified by Equation (3) approaches the competitive outcome.

In a traditional model of market power, the market price is often a good indicator of the degree of market power. For example, in an oligopoly, when firms have greater market power the price is further from marginal production cost. This will not be the case in bilateral oligopoly. Buyers are trying to put downward pressure on prices, and sellers are trying to put upward pressure on prices. Under the assumptions of the model, the net effect of these efforts cancel. The market price in equilibrium is:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

This is the same as the competitive price.

To characterize the degree of market power in bilateral oligopoly, we turn to another measure: the variance in marginal abatement costs at the permit endowment. Let

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

If the endowment is such that marginal abatement costs are equal across all firms, then var([theta] - w) = 0. In this case, the adjustment from the competitive outcome in Equation (3) is zero. In other words, firms do not exert any market power. If the endowment is such that there is great variation in marginal abatement costs, then var([theta] - w) is large. In this case, on average, the adjustment from the competitive solution in Equation (3) is large and firms exert significant market power.

The welfare loss in an oligopoly model is due to the increase in price and the decrease in the quantity of production relative to the competitive outcome. In this bilateral oligopoly model, there is no price distortion, but there remains an output distortion. Malueg and Yates (2009) show that the quantity of trade is lower in bilateral oligopoly than in competition.

III. EXPERIMENTAL ENVIRONMENT

In our experiment, subjects play the role of firms in the theory described above. We now describe the experimental environment. Section III.A focuses on the experimental design that we use to test six research hypotheses that arise from the aforementioned theory. Section III.B discusses the experimental procedures used to execute our design and the testing of our research hypotheses.

A. Experimental Design and Hypothesis

We employ two treatment variables and a three-by-three design. The first treatment variable is n, the number of subjects in a given market. This variable takes on three values: 4, 8, and 16. The second treatment variable is var([theta] - w), the variance of the marginal abatement costs at the permit endowment. This variable also takes on three values: 0, [sigma].sup.2], and 4[[simgma].sup.2]. Under the endowment rule discussed below, var([theta] - w) simplifies to become a function of [theta] only. To further simplify, we allow for only two values for [theta], and assign these values to an equal number of subjects. This effectively segregates the subjects into two equal size groups: high cost subjects and low cost subjects. Although it is possible for a high cost subject to be a seller of permits (if, for example, the price of permits is quite high), we would ordinarily expect high cost subjects to be buyers and low cost subjects to be sellers. So we refer to them using these terms, denoted by the subscript b ands respectively. The values for [[theta].sub.b] and [[theta].sub.s] vary according to the var([theta] - w) treatment, as specified in Table 1. In the first row of this table, all subjects have identical costs at the permit endowment and we would expect to get the competitive outcome. In the second and third rows, the values for [[theta].sub.h] and [[theta].sub.s] are equal deviations above and below the value in the first row.

We also have several nontreatment parameters. Each of these are a function of [[theta].sub.i]. Subjects are given an initial permit endowment equal to half of their business-as-usual emissions: [w.sub.i] - [[theta].sub.i]/2. The constant [A.sub.i] in each abatement cost function is selected such that the abatement cost function is zero at the business-as-usual emissions (6): [A.sub.i] = (1/2) ([[theta].sup.2.sub.i]). Finally, the constant it,? is selected so that each subject receives the same no-trade payoff, k, that we set equal to five within the experiment. (7) So we have [[pi].sub.i] = [kappa] + ([[theta].sup.2.sub.i]/8).

Our first four research hypotheses focus on the individual decisions of subjects within the experiment. The theoretical predictions that underlie these hypotheses are based on Equation (3). In particular, this equation identifies the value of [a.sub.i] selected by the players as a function of the competitive outcome and the adjustment from the competitive outcome. The predicted values for buyers are given in Table 2 and for sellers in Table 3. Our first hypothesis directly investigates these values.

Experimental Hypothesis 1. The [a.sub.i] selected by buyers and sellers are given by Tables 2 and 3.

The next three hypotheses are based on comparative statics across treatments. As can be seen from Tables 2 and 3, the var([theta] - w) treatment variable affects both the competitive outcome and the adjustment term, but the number of subjects only affects the adjustment term. As a consequence, we utilize two hypotheses for the var([theta] - w) treatment and one for the number of subjects treatment.

Experimental Hypothesis 2. As var([theta] - w) increases, the [a.sub.i] selected by buyers (sellers) increases (decreases).

This hypothesis addresses whether subjects understand the structure of the market, but it does not discriminate between strategic and competitive behavior. For example, a buyer may simply select a high indifference price because they have high costs, not because they want to manipulate the market. As seen from Table 2, a buyer that does behave strategically will shade their indifference price below the competitive outcome to put downward pressure on the market price.

The third and fourth research hypotheses discriminate between strategic and competitive behavior.

Experimental Hypothesis 3. As var([theta] - w) increases, the magnitude of the adjustments from the competitive outcome ([DELTA] = [a.sub.i] - [a.sup.c.sub.i]) selected by buyers and sellers increases.

Experimental Hypothesis 4. For the nonzero variance cases, as the number of subjects increases, the magnitude of the adjustments from the competitive outcome ([[DELTA].sub.i] = [a.sub.i] - [a.sup.c.sub.i]) decreases for both buyers and sellers. For the zero-variance cases, as the number of subjects increases, the adjustments stay fixed at zero.

Our final two hypotheses focus on the overall market outcomes. When the cost variance is nonzero, theory indicates that as the market size increases the market should converge toward the competitive equilibrium. This implies that the market should become more efficient as the market size increases, relative to the perfectly competitive market. When the cost variance is zero, the market size has no impact on market efficiency. Combining these theoretical predictions generates our fifth research hypothesis.

Experimental Hypothesis 5. For the nonzero variance cases, the market efficiency (relative to perfect competition) increases with the size of the market. For the zero variances cases, the market efficiency is constant.

Owing to the symmetric nature of the [theta]'s used in the experiment (see Table 1), neither the buyers or sellers should be able to exhibit more market power relative to each other. This implies that the split in total profit between the buyers and sellers should be equal regardless of the market size or the variance in cost, generating our sixth research hypothesis.

Experimental Hypothesis 6. The share of profits is evenly split between buyers and sellers independent of variance and market size.

The following section outlines the experimental design utilized to test our six research hypotheses.

B. Experimental Procedures

The experiments were conducted at the Experimental Economics Center (ExCEN) in the Andrew Young School of Policy Studies at Georgia State University. A total of 380 students participated in the experiment spread across the nine treatments. In the market size of 4 and 8 treatments there were 32 students enrolled, except for the zero variance treatment when the market size was four. In this case only 28 students were enrolled (seven groups of four). For the market size of 16 treatments there were 64 subjects enrolled, split across two experimental sessions. A higher number of subjects were recruited for the market size of 16 to increase the number of market-level observations for our investigation of hypotheses 5 and 6. All of the subjects were recruited using an email database that randomly selects eligible students for recruiting. All experiments were conducted using computer terminals with each student randomly assigned to a treatment.

Upon entering the ExCEN laboratory subjects were instructed to sit at a specific computer terminal within the laboratory, where a copy of the instructions was waiting for them to review. (8) Prior to beginning the experiment the instructions were read orally to each group in detail and they completed five rounds of practice followed by a survey to determine how well the subjects understood the experimental treatments. During the five practice rounds the subjects were instructed that they were participating in a market with computer-generated decisions and the purpose of the practice was to familiarize themselves with the experiment software. In the case that the subjects did not answer one of the survey questions correctly, the question was highlighted and the subjects were informed of the correct answer. Following completion of the practice rounds the subjects were asked whether or not they had any additional questions regarding the experiment. After answering any additional questions they entered the experimental treatment.

In the treatment portion of the experiment the subjects were randomly paired in each of the 20 periods into the specified market size. In addition, there were an equal number of buyers and sellers within each group and one's type remained constant throughout the entire experiment. The setting was context neutral in that subjects were told that they needed a permit for each unit of production, but this production was not tied to pollution.

At the beginning of each period, subjects were informed of their personal cost function as well as those for the other subjects in the experiment and the total number of subjects within their market. Conditional on this information they were asked to submit their individual supply functions (determined by their selection of a,). An example of the decision screen presented to the subjects is illustrated in Figure 2. The software dynamically illustrated how their selection of a, and the market price would affect their expected net permit purchases, fixed payment from operating, costs of operating, permit expenditures, and total profits. In particular, the selection of [a.sub.i] was done by manipulating a sliding tab near the bottom left of the screen. For any given position of the sliding tab, a table on the right of the screen displayed the monetary information as a function of various market prices. In addition, a graph showed the subject's net-trade function and indicated price regions in which the subject would be a buyer or seller of permits. Once subjects selected a final value for [a.sub.i], the market equilibrium was calculated and they were informed of the market clearing price and their experimental earnings.

Earnings within the experiment were based on their cumulative returns within the experiment over the 20 periods. Subjects could also look at the history of all their previous actions and the resulting market outcomes at any time during the experiment. Each experimental dollar earned in the experiment was converted assuming that 1 experimental dollar equaled 0.25 US Dollars. In addition to their experimental earnings, the subjects were paid a five dollar show-up fee for their participation. The average subject payment within the experiment was 32.68 US Dollars, including the show-up fee.

IV. RESULTS

Prior to investigating our primary research hypotheses it is important to illustrate that subjects varied their behavior depending on their role as a buyer or seller as well as the treatment environment. Figure 3 illustrates buyer and seller choices of [a.sub.i] for each experimental treatment. The buyer and seller decisions for the zero variance cases, far left column of the figure, are nearly identical and focused close to the value of five, the equilibrium prediction. As the variance increases, moving from the left column to the right column, the divergence in the buyer and seller selection of a, becomes more evident. The buyers' distribution shifts upward on the price axis, while the sellers' distribution shifts downward. By the time the variance reaches its largest value of 4[[sigma].sup.2] there is a clear distinction between buyer and seller decisions.

Table 4 illustrates the average and standard deviation of [a.sub.i] within each treatment broken down by whether or not the subject was a buyer, b, or a seller, s. We have elected to illustrate the descriptive statistics for all 20 periods, the last 15 periods and the last ten periods to illustrate the stability of subject decisions within the experiment. Although the standard deviation does decrease as we shorten the time window, the average values of a, are not statistically different, assuming the same treatment and subject type.

The data in Table 4, in conjunction with the visual evidence from Figure 3, suggest that buyers behave different than sellers, and these differences depend on the various treatments. Formal statistical tests verify this observation. We first test for differences between buyer and seller behavior within the same treatment. Table A1 shows the results of Mann-Whitney, t, and Komolgorov-Smirnov tests of equivalent [a.sub.i] selections for buyers and sellers. For the nonzero variance treatments, we would expect the behavior of the buyers and sellers to be different, which suggests that the tests should give statistically significant results. As shown in Table Al, this does indeed occur. For the zero variance treatments, we would expect the behavior of the buyers and sellers to be the same, which suggests that the tests should give statistically insignificant results. This generally occurs, although the test results for the market size of 8 are mixed.

Next we investigate whether or not subject behavior differs across the experimental treatments. Here we conduct three paired analyses of distributional equivalence. The first compares the buyers across treatments, the second compares the sellers across treatments and the last one compares the buyers and sellers across treatments. For each analysis, we conducted Mann-Whitney, t, and Komolgorov-Smirnov tests. The results are shown in Tables A2, A3, and A4. For the zero variance cases, the tests are almost in complete agreement with theory, with only a few cases of mixed evidence. The results are similarly strong for the nonzero variance cases. There are only few instances in which the evidence is mixed, and one instance in which all three tests indicate a statistically insignificant difference (sellers, variance of 4[[sigma].sup.2], market size of 4 vs. 8). Having validated differences between buyers and sellers across treatments, we now turn to examining our research hypotheses.

A. Hypotheses for Individual Behavior

To test our first research hypothesis that the subjects' selection of at matches the predicted value, we use a series of Wilcoxon rank-sum tests (see Tables A5 and A6). First we consider buyers. For buyers there is only one case where their selection of a, accords with the theoretical predictions. This occurs when variance of zero is paired with market size of 16 (z-statistic is -0.369). However, when we conduct a parametric t-test for this treatment the test statistic indicates that the decisions are statistically different from our predictions (t-statistic is -3.586). (9) Therefore, these results indicate that the buyers' selection of at does not accord with our theoretical predictions. The selection of [a.sub.i], for the sellers accords with our theoretical predictions of at more often than with the buyers. The cases in which the sellers' selection of [a.sub.i] matches the theory are variance of zero paired with market size of 4, 8, and 16, as well as variance of 4[[sigma].sup.2] paired with market size of 8. (10)

Given that neither the buyers' or sellers' behavior perfectly accords with the theoretical predictions of [a.sub.i], an important question is whether or not their selection of [a.sub.i] reflects strategic behavior. Alternatively, subjects might not recognize their ability to influence prices. If this is indeed the case, then the actual [a.sub.i] would be closer to the competitive prediction [a.sup.c.sub.i]. To distinguish between strategic and competitive behavior, we conducted an additional test for the six nonzero variance cases. (11) We computed the midpoint between the theoretically predicted at and the competitive alternative [a.sup.c.sub.i] and then created a difference variable, [d.sub.i] by subtracting the midpoint from the subject's selection of [a.sub.i]

For buyers, the predicted value of a, is smaller than [a.sup.c.sub.i]. If they follow a strategy closer to the strategic prediction, then we would expect [d.sub.i] to be statistically negative. If they follow a strategy closer to the competitive prediction, then we would expect [d.sub.i] to be statistically positive. This pattern reverses for the sellers because their predicted [a.sub.i] is greater than [a.sup.c.sub.i].

To test for significance, we utilize a series of Wilcoxon rank-sum tests. For the buyers, all test statistics for [d.sub.i] are statistically negative (z-statistics range from -4.826 to -10.073). This indicates that buyers behave closer to the strategic prediction than the competitive alternative. For the sellers, in three of the six cases the test statistics for d; are not significant at the 95th percentile. These cases occur when the variance of [[sigma].sup.2] is paired with a market size of 4 (z-statistic is -0.659), when the variance of 4[[sigma].sup.2] is paired with a market size of 8 (z-statistic of 1.693), and when the variance of 4[[sigma].sup.2] is paired with a market size of 16 (z-statistic of -1.827). In these cases, the sellers' behavior is not statistically distinguishable from either the strategic prediction or the competitive alternative. The test statistics in the remaining cases indicate that sellers are closer to the strategic prediction when variance of [[sigma].sup.2] is paired with market size of 16 (z-statistic is 6.295), (12) but sellers behave closer to the perfectly competitive predictions when the variance of 4[[sigma].sup.2] is paired with a market size of 4 (z-statistic of -2.308) and when the variance [[sigma].sup.2] is paired with market size of 8 (z-statistic is -3.560).

Taken together, the tests of our first hypothesis provide strong evidence that buyers internalize the strategic incentives present and manipulate the price via their selection of [[sigma].sup.i] but not to the same extent as predicted by theory. The evidence for sellers is somewhat mixed. For three of the cases the sellers' behavior is not distinguishable from either the strategic or competitive predictions, and in one case they behave closer to the strategic predictions. However, in the remaining two cases they behave closer to the competitive predictions. Overall, this suggests that sellers are less able to internalize the strategic incentives present within the decision environment. Additional insight into strategic behavior and the differences between buyers and sellers will be provided below in the analysis of our third and fourth hypotheses.

Turning now to comparative statics, our second research hypothesis is that as var([theta] - w) increases, the [[sigma].sub.i] selected by buyers (sellers) increases (decreases). Evidence in favor of this hypothesis can be easily seen in both the descriptive statistics (Table 4) and the visual representation of the data (Figure 3). More rigorous evidence is based on a series of two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum tests comparing the selections of [[sigma].sub.i], across the different variance levels holding the market size constant. The results from these tests are contained in Table 5. All of the test statistics confirm our second hypothesis. The negative and statistically significant z-statistics for the buyers indicate that as the variance increases (holding the market size constant) the subject's selection of [[sigma].sub.i], increases. The positive and statistically significant z-statistic for the sellers indicates the opposite; as the variance increases the sellers selection of at decreases. The combined evidence offers strong support for our second research hypothesis and confirms that the subjects realize that when they have higher (lower) costs, they should increase (decrease) their indifference price.

Our third and fourth research hypotheses shed additional light on the issue of whether or not subjects act strategically to manipulate the market price. They are based on changes in [[DELTA].sub.i] across treatments. To test these hypotheses, we calculated [[DELTA].sub.i] for each subject's decision within the experiment, as illustrated in Table 6. The third research hypothesis states that as var([theta] - w) increases, the magnitude of the adjustments from the competitive outcome ([[DELTA].sub.i] = [a.sub.i] - [a.sup.c.sup.i]) selected by buyers and sellers increases. The fourth research hypothesis states that, for nonzero variance cases, as the number of subjects increases, the magnitude of the adjustments from the competitive outcome selected by buyers and sellers decreases. Evidence in favor of both hypotheses is illustrated in Table 6, although it appears to be stronger for buyers than sellers.

To more formally investigate the third hypothesis, a series of two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum tests were conducted comparing all [[DELTA].sub.i]'s holding the subject market size constant. The z-statistic for each of these tests is illustrated in Table 7. Our prior for all of the comparisons is that the z-statistics for the buyers should all be positive and statistically significant, whereas they should be negative and statistically significant for the sellers. For all of the comparisons made for the buyers the z-statistics match up with our priors. For the sellers this is not always true. When the market size is 4 the comparison between a variance of [[sigma].sup.2] and 4[[sigma].sup.2] indicates that the [[DELTA].sub.i]'s are not statistically significant from each other, but the sign on the difference is as expected. This is also true when the market size is 8 and we compare the zero variance case with [[sigma].sup.2]. Finally, the test statistic for the comparison between [[sigma].sup.2] and 4[[sigma].sup.2] when the market size is 16 indicates that differences are statistically significant but the differences are of the opposite expected sign. These results indicate the behavior of the buyers perfectly accords with our theoretical predictions, whereas for sellers there are a few exceptions.

The formal comparison of the fourth hypothesis utilizes a series of two-sample Wilcoxon ranksum tests comparing the magnitude of the [[DELTA].sub.i]'s across the different market sizes holding the variance constant. For the nonzero variance cases, a negative and statistically significant z-statistic supports our fourth research hypothesis. The test statistics are illustrated in Table 8. For the zero variance cases, the results for the sellers perfectly agree with the theory as none of the test statistics are statistically significant. For the buyers this is also true when comparing the market size of 4 and 8, but the difference is marginally significant (90th percent level) when comparing the market size of 4 and 16 and is statistically significant and negative when comparing the market size of 4 and 16. Therefore, buyers do tend to lower their [[DELTA].sub.i] as the market size increases but sellers do not. For the nonzero variance cases, theory suggests that the magnitude of [[DELTA].sub.i] decreases as market size increases. When the variance is [[sigma].sup.2] the z-statistics indicate that buyers do tend to decrease the magnitude of their [[DELTA].sub.i]'s as the market size increases, except when comparing the market size of 4 and 8. For sellers, the statistically significant and positive z-statistic when comparing the market size of 4 and 8 is the opposite of our prediction, but the other comparisons are consistent with our predictions. When the variance is 4[[sigma].sup.2] the test statistics perfectly accord with our theoretical predictions for buyers, but do not for any of the comparisons conducted for the sellers. Once again we see good agreement with the theory for buyers and weaker agreement for sellers.

The results in Tables 7 and 8 show some asymmetries in the behavior of buyers and sellers in selecting [[DELTA].sub.i], even though the experiment was constructed so that they would have symmetric strategic incentives. One possible explanation for these differences is that the buyers in the experiment tend to "overshoot" the predicted [[DELTA].sub.i] whereas the sellers tend to "undershoot" it. This can be seen by comparing the predicted [[DELTA].sub.i]'s in Tables 2 and 3 with the actual [[DELTA].sub.i]'s in Table 6. In a number of cases the buyers nearly double the predicted [[DELTA].sub.i] whereas the sellers rarely meet the predicted [[DELTA].sub.i] and in some cases the magnitude of [[DELTA].sub.i] is very small and not of the expected sign. However, buyers also possess a higher standard deviation for [[DELTA].sub.i]. Therefore, it is not entirely clear that this asymmetry implies an advantage for the buyers in the market. This will be more formally investigated in our sixth research hypothesis.

In summary, the evidence from testing hypotheses 3 and 4 confirms and reinforces the evidence from testing hypothesis 1. So we conclude, with the caveat that the evidence is stronger for buyers than sellers, that subjects generally understood and acted upon the strategic incentives in the experiment, but not to the degree predicted by theory.

B. Hypotheses for Overall Market Outcomes

Our final two research hypotheses focus on the market outcomes of efficiency and the distribution of profits. The latter is critically determined by the observed market price. Figure 4 illustrates the market price by variance and market size. The average market price by treatment over all time periods and the last ten periods is shown in Table 9. Recall that the predicted market price is 5 for all cases. The price in the zero-variance cases is relatively stable across time but it is generally increasing in the nonzero variance cases as the market size increases.

Figure 5 shows the observed market efficiency. Market efficiency was calculated for each treatment by estimating the ratio of total profits earned to the profits that would be earned if everyone behaved according to the perfectly competitive outcome. (13) The temporal patterns of market efficiency do not necessarily have to follow those found for the market price. Efficiency is determined by the trades that occur within the market. So, for example, it is possible that some subjects end up with too many permits and others with too few, all the while preserving the predicted equilibrium price. Indeed, we do find a difference in these temporal patterns; market efficiency increases as the experiment progresses for all variance cases, not just the nonzero cases (see Table 10).

Our fifth research hypothesis is that as the market size increases so too does the level of market efficiency. This can be seen by changes in the predicted [[DELTA].sub.i] as the number of subjects increases (see Tables 2 and 3). This results in an increased number of permit trades which enhance market efficiency. The graphical results and descriptive statistics for all the periods, as well as the last ten periods, do not consistently support our research hypothesis. To more rigorously investigate our hypothesis we conducted a series of two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum tests under the hypothesis that as the market size increases so too will the market efficiency, holding the variance constant. Given the changes in market efficiency as the experiment progresses we have elected to use just the last ten periods of each treatment. The results from these tests are contained in Table 11.

For the zero-variance case we predict that the market efficiency should not vary with market size. The z-statistics support this hypothesis for two cases but indicate that the market efficiency is actually greater when the market size is 8 versus 16.14 When the variance increases to [[sigma].sup.2] the results indicate that market efficiency does increase when the market size increases from 4 to 14 8, but the efficiency when the market size is 16 is not greater than 4 and the differences between the market size of 8 and 16 indicate that the efficiency is greater when the market size is 8. Finally, when the variance is 4[[sigma].sup.2] the test results indicate that the market efficiency does not increase between the market size of 4 and 8 and 4 and 16, but it does between 8 and 16. On the whole, these results provide little support for our fifth research hypothesis. A possible explanation for these results is that the expected change in market efficiency as the market size increases is relatively small. Within the experiment the expected change in efficiency as the market size increases within the experiment is at most 2.5 percentage points (going from a market size of 4 to perfect competition with a variance of 4[[sigma].sup.2]) with many of the expected differences being much lower. As a result of this the expected differences are too small to be observed in the data given the high variation in the intra-treatment efficiency scores. This variation generates the inconsistent pattern observed in our test statistics. In any event, the test statistics do not support our fifth research hypothesis.

Our final hypothesis focuses on how the profits are split between the buyers and sellers. By construction, buyers and sellers are symmetrically placed on either side of the market. Therefore, the profits should be identical whether subjects behave strategically or competitively. To investigate this we determined the total profits earned for each period of the experiment and then determined the average percentage of those earnings that were earned by the buyers. The results are illustrated in Figure 6. There is considerably more variation in the percentage of profits earned by buyers when the market size is 4 versus the other market sizes. As the market size increases the percentage becomes more stable and tightens around the even split. This is a result of the "thinness" of the market. In a market size of 4 there are only two buyers and two sellers and a poor decision by either of the two (buyers or sellers) can generate a substantial swing in the profits. When the market size increases, a poor decision, although damaging at the individual level, is dampened at the market level.

Given the observed average market prices reported earlier, we would expect that the buyers earned a larger split of the profits except when the market size is 16 and the variance is 4[[sigma].sup.2]. However, given the substantial variation that exists in the observed equilibrium price and the reported fractions observed in Figure 6, a more rigorous investigation is required. Due to the sizable differences in market efficiency as each experiment progressed, discussed earlier (see Figure 5), we have elected to focus our test of hypothesis six on the data observed in the last ten periods of each experimental treatment. To do so we conducted a series of two-sample Wilcoxon rank-sum tests within each treatment to determine whether or not the buyers or sellers earned a larger portion of the profits using period specific information versus the percentages reported in Figure 6. The results from these tests are illustrated in Table 12.

The z-statistics indicate that five of the nine test statistics support our sixth hypothesis that there is no statistical difference in the split between the buyers' and sellers' profits. The remaining test statistics are split where two indicate that buyers exceed sellers and another two indicate the opposite. The two environments where the sellers outperformed the buyers were when the variance was 4[[sigma].sup.2] and the market size was 8 and when the variance was zero and the market size was 16. The two markets where the buyers outperformed the sellers occurred when the variance was 4[[sigma].sup.2] and the market size was 4 and when the variance was [[sigma].sup.2] and the market size was 8. With the exception of the two instances when the sellers outperformed the buyers, the signs of these results are in agreement with the observations about market prices discussed earlier. (15) In total, the results indicate that the split on profits was predominantly balanced, with a few situations in which buyers outperformed sellers and vice versa. However, the differences that did arise were not systematic.

V. CONCLUSION

This research represents the first detailed study of a supply function equilibria bilateral oligopoly market using experimental economic methods. By systematically varying the number of firms as well as the variance in cost, we determined that subjects respond to the strategic incentives inherent in this market structure. The magnitude of the strategic behavior exhibited by subjects, however, does not perfectly accord with theory. In general, buyers tend to overshoot their strategic incentives whereas sellers tend to undershoot them. Perhaps, as a consequence, our results tend to be stronger for buyers than sellers. The results for the overall market outcomes did not agree with theory. The observed market efficiency did not increase with the market size and there were cases where buyers outperformed the sellers and vice versa. However, for the most part the revenues earned by buyers and sellers in the market were balanced.

From a policy perspective, these results represent a necessary first step in investigating behavior within a bilateral oligopoly. Given the increasing interest in applying pollution markets to localized pollution problems like nitrogen emissions from waste water treatment plants, it is imperative that we develop a better understanding of the bilateral oligopoly market structure. Should the supply function equilibria market be utilized in pollution markets, the long temporal delays in market feedback necessitate that we study the market's comparative statistics with respect to market characteristics before incurring the social, political, and pecuniary costs of their utilization. By investigating how market size and firm heterogeneity affect the market equilibrium we have provided policymakers with information on the primary factors that may impact the market equilibrium.

More formally, our research has indicated that although participant behavior does not perfectly accord with our strategic predictions, participant behavior does accord with their expected responses with respect to the market's comparative statistics. This provides a degree of confidence in the potential utilization of this market structure to manage environmental pollution. Furthermore, given the prevalence of market mechanisms in environmental compliance, markets adding this mechanism to the suite of options may expand a regulator's capacity for market-based environmental management. Perhaps, a productive next step would be to further investigate the apparent differences in the behavior of buyers and sellers documented in our study to determine if these results are robust to alternative market environments. However, our findings do provide important policy-relevant findings that may be informative for future pollution markets.

ABBREVIATION

ExCEN: Experimental Economics Center

doi: 10.1111/ecin.12087

APPENDIX

Proof that there cannot be an equilibrium on the truncated portions of abatement costs and net-trade functions.

From Malueg and Yates (2009), we know there exists a unique interior Nash Equilibrium ([a.sup.*.sub.i], [a.sup.*.sub.2], ..., [a.sup.*.sub.n]) such that pollution levels are less than or equal to business-as-usual and the price is less than or equal to [??]. We now show that there cannot be another equilibrium on the truncated portions of the abatement costs and net-trade functions. First consider abatement cost functions. Suppose there exists another equilibrium ([a.sup.t.sub.1], [a.sup.t.sub.2], ..., [a.sup.t.sub.n]) and at this equilibrium at least one subject j has emissions of pollution that exceed business as usual. Then this subject could lower their [a.sub.j], buy less permits, and reduce pollution at no extra cost. Clearly, they would be better off, which contradicts the definition of an equilibrium.

Now consider the net-trade function. Suppose there exists another equilibrium ([a.sup.t.sub.1], [a.sup.t.sub.2], ..., [a.sup.t.sub.n]) and at this equilibrium at least one subject j is on the truncated portion of their net-trade function. A small change in [a.sub.j] would have no effect on the market price and net-trades (because this subject would still be in the exceptions group). Hence any value for [a.sub.j] such that at the equilibrium price subject j is on the truncated portion of the net-trade function would be an equilibrium choice for player j (given, of course, the choices of the other players). In particular, consider the choice [a.sup.s.sub.j] such that [v.sub.j] = [a.sup.s.sub.j] - p = -[w.sub.j]. The subject is just on the boundary of the truncated portion of the net-trade function. So we still have ([a.sup.t.sub.1], [a.sup.t.sub.2], ..., [a.sup.s.sub.j], ..., [a.sup.t.sub.n]) as an equilibrium. But, this equilibrium is now interior, contradicting the uniqueness of (a.sup.*.sub.1], [a.sup.2.sub.2], ..., [a.sup.*.sub.n]).

SUPPORTING INFORMATION

Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online version of this article:

Appendix S1. Experiment Instructions.

TABLE A1
Test of Equality in Distribution within Treatments: Buyers Versus
Sellers

Exp 1                                 0.510
Group = 4, Var = 0                    0.997
                                      0.982
Exp 2                                 0.033
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.223
                                      0.022
Exp 3                                 0.438
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.619
                                      0.713
Exp 4                                 0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000
                                      0.000
Exp 5                                 0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000
                                      0.000
Exp 6                                 0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000
                                      0.000
Exp 7                                 0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000
                                      0.000
Exp 8                                 0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000
                                      0.000
Exp 9                                 0.000
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000
                                      0.000

Notes: Cells represent p values for tests of equality of distribution
between buyers and sellers within experiment. The first line of each
cell are p values resulting from a Mann-Whitney test; the second line
of the cell are p values from a t-test; and the final line of each
cell is the p value from a Kolmogorov-Smirnov test.

TABLE A2
Test of Equality in Distribution Across Experiment: Buyers

                                     Exp 1   Exp 2   Exp 3

Exp 1                                 ...    0.781   0.875
Group = 4, Var = 0                    ...    0.500   0.202
                                      ...    0.065   0.045
Exp 2                                0.781    ...    0.037
Group = 8, Var = 0                   0.520    ...    0.985
                                     0.065    ...    0.016
Exp 3                                0.875   0.037    ...
Group =16, Var = 0                   0.500   0.985    ...
                                     0.045   0.016    ...
Exp 4                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 6                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 7                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 9                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group =16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000

                                     Exp 4   Exp 5   Exp 6

Exp 1                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 2                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 3                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group =16, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 4                                 ...    0.133   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      ...    0.003   0.000
                                      ...    0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                0.133    ...    0.001
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.003    ...    0.630
                                     0.000    ...    0.000
Exp 6                                0.000   0.001    ...
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.630    ...
                                     0.000   0.000    ...
Exp 7                                0.001   0.049   0.136
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.001   0.336   0.475
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.011   0.006
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 9                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group =16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000

                                     Exp 7   Exp 8   Exp 9

Exp 1                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 2                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 3                                0.000   0.000   0.000
Group =16, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 4                                0.001   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.001   0.000   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                0.049   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.336   0.011   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 6                                0.136   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]    0.475   0.006   0.000
                                     0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 7                                 ...    0.003   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     ...    0.131   0.000
                                      ...    0.003   0.000
Exp 8                                0.003    ...    0.022
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.131    ...    0.001
                                     0.003    ...    0.021
Exp 9                                0.000   0.022    ...
Group =16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.001    ...
                                     0.000   0.021    ...

Notes: Cells are p-values for tests of equality of distribution
between experiments conditional on being a buyer. The first line of
each cell are p-values resulting from a Mann-Whitney test; the second
line of the cell are p-values from a t-test; the final line of each
cell is the p-value from a Kolmogorov-Smimov test.

TABLE A3
Test of Equality in Distribution Across Experiment: Sellers

                                      Exp 1   Exp 2   Exp 3

Exp 1                                  ...    0.220   0.684
Group = 4, Var = 0                     ...    0.672   0.735
                                       ...    0.056   0.250
Exp 2                                 0.220    ...    0.331
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.672    ...    0.344
                                      0.056    ...    0.622
Exp 3                                 0.684   0.331    ...
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.735   0.344    ...
                                      0.250   0.622    ...
Exp 4                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 6                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 7                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 9                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000

                                      Exp 4   Exp 5   Exp 6

Exp 1                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 2                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 3                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 4                                  ...    0.001   0.469
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]       ...    0.329   0.012
                                       ...    0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                 0.001    ...    0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.329    ...    0.000
                                      0.000    ...    0.000
Exp 6                                 0.469   0.000    ...
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.012   0.000    ...
                                      0.000   0.000    ...
Exp 7                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 9                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000

                                      Exp 7   Exp 8   Exp 9

Exp 1                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 2                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 3                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 4                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 6                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 7                                  ...    0.910   0.005
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]      ...    0.730   0.007
                                       ...    0.172   0.025
Exp 8                                 0.910    ...    0.010
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.730    ...    0.012
                                      0.172    ...    0.000
Exp 9                                 0.005   0.010    ...
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.007   0.012    ...
                                      0.025   0.000    ...

Notes: Cells are p values for tests of equality of distribution
between experiments conditional on being a seller. The first line of
each cell are p values resulting from a Mann-Whitney test; the second
line of the cell are p values from a t-test; the final line of each
cell is the p value from a Kolmogorov-Smirnov test.

TABLE A4
Test of Equality in Distribution Across Experiment Between Buyers and
Sellers

                                      Exp 1   Exp 2   Exp 3

Exp 1                                  ...    0.610   0.211
Group = 4, Var = 0                     ...    0.534   0.733
                                       ...    0.060   0.057
Exp 2                                 0.053    ...    0.161
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.667    ...    0.068
                                      0.011    ...    0.200
Exp 3                                 0.357   0.775    ...
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.506   0.210    ...
                                      0.129   0.660    ...
Exp4                                  0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 6                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 7                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 9                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000

                                      Exp 4   Exp 5   Exp 6

Exp 1                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 2                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 3                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp4                                   ...    0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]       ...    0.000   0.000
                                       ...    0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                 0.000    ...    0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000    ...    0.000
                                      0.000    ...    0.000
Exp 6                                 0.000   0.000    ...
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000    ...
                                      0.000   0.000    ...
Exp 7                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 9                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000

                                      Exp 7   Exp 8   Exp 9

Exp 1                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 2                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = 0                    0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 3                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = 0                   0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp4                                  0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 5                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 6                                 0.000   0.000   0.000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]     0.000   0.000   0.000
                                      0.000   0.000   0.000
Exp 7                                  ...    0.000   0.000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]      ...    0.000   0.000
                                       ...    0.000   0.000
Exp 8                                 0.000    ...    0.000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     0.000    ...    0.000
                                      0.000    ...    0.000
Exp 9                                 0.000   0.000    ...
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]    0.000   0.000    ...
                                      0.000   0.000    ...

Notes: Cells are p values for tests of equality of distribution
between experiments. Columns are conditional on being a buyer, rows
are conditional on being a seller. The first line of each cell are p
values resulting from a Mann-Whitney test; the second line of the
cell are p values from a t-test; the final line of each cell is the p
value from a Kolmogorov-Smimov test.

TABLE A5
Wilcoxon Rank-Sum Test and t-Tests of Theoretical Equivalence for
Buyers

                                      [a.sub.i]--       [a.sub.i]--
                                     [a.sub.i] = 0  [a.sup.c.sub.i] = 0

Exp 1                                   0.0192            0.0192
Group = 4, Var = 0                     (0.1219)          (0.1219)
Expv2                                   0.0042            0.0042
Group = 8, Var = 0                     (0.0016)          (0.0016)
Exp 3                                   0.7222            0.7222
Group = 16, Var = 0                    (0.0004)          (0.0004)
Exp 4                                   0.0008            0.0000
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]       (0.0000)          (0.0000)
Exp 5                                   0.0074            0.0000
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]       (0.0000)          (0.0000)
Exp 6                                   0.0080            0.0000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      (0.0000)          (0.0000)
Exp 7                                   0.0000            0.0000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]      (0.0000)          (0.0000)
Exp 8                                   0.0000            0.0000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]      (0.0000)          (0.0000)
Exp 9                                   0.0000            0.0000
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     (0.0000)          (0.0000)

Wilcoxon rank-sum test on top and t-test in parentheses below.

TABLE A6
Wilcoxon Rank-Sum Test and t-Tests of Theoretical Equivalence for
Sellers

                                      [a.sub.i]--       [a.sub.i]--
                                     [a.sub.i] = 0  [a.sup.c.sub.i] = 0

Exp 1                                   0.1473            0.1473
Group = 4, Var = 0                     (0.1518)          (0.1518)
Exp 2                                   0.8086            0.8086
Group = 8, Var = 0                     (0.2505)          (0.2505)
Exp 3                                   0.1542            0.1542
Group = 16, Var = 0                    (0.0008)          (0.0008)
Exp 4                                   0.0001            0.0046
Group = 4, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]       (0.0009)          (0.4885)
Exp 5                                   0.0000            0.1840
Group = 8, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]       (0.0000)          (0.4465)
Exp 6                                   0.0001            0.0000
Group = 16, Var = [[sigma].sup.2]      (0.0000)          (0.0000)
Exp 7                                   0.0000            0.0000
Group = 4, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]      (0.0000)          (0.0001)
Exp 8                                   0.1495            0.0000
Group = 8, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]      (0.5281)          (0.0000)
Exp 9                                   0.0009            0.3784
Group = 16, Var = 4[[sigma].sup.2]     (0.0481)          (0.3079)

Wilcoxon rank-sum test on top and t-test in parentheses below.


REFERENCES

Bjomerstedt, J., and J. Stennek. "Bilateral Oligopoly." The Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Working Paper No. 555, 2001.

Brandts, J., P. Pezanis-Christou, and A. Schram. "Competition with Forward Contracts: A Laboratory Analysis Motivated by Electricity Market Design." The Economic Journal, 118, 2007, 192-214.

Green, R. J., and D. M. Newbery. "Competition in the British Electricity Spot Market." Journal of Political Economy, 100(5), 1992, 929-53.

Hendricks, K., and R. P. McAfee. "A Theory of Bilateral Oligopoly." Economic Inquiry, 48, 2010, 391-414.

Holland, S., and M. Moore. "Market Design in Cap and Trade Programs: Permit Validity and Compliance Timing." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 66(3), 2013, 671-87.

Klemperer, P. D., and M. A. Meyer. "Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly Under Uncertainty." Econometrica, 57, 1989, 1243-77.

Krysiak, F., and P. Schweitzer. "The Optimal Size of a Permit Market." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 60, 2010, 133-43.

Lange, A. "On the Endogeneity of Market Power in Emissions Markets." Environmental and Resource Economics, 52, 2012, 573-83.

Malueg, D., and A. Yates. "Bilateral Oligopoly, Private Information, and Pollution Permit Markets." Environmental and Resource Economics, 43, 2009, 413-32.

Weretka, M. "Endogenous Market Power." Journal of Economic Theory, 146, 2011, 2281-306.

Williams, R. III. "Cost Effectiveness vs. Hotspots: Determining the Optimal Size of Emission Permit Trading Zones." University of Texas at Austin, Working Paper, 2003.

Wirl, F. "Oligopoly Meets Oligopsony: The Case of Permits." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 58, 2009, 329-37.

Yates, A. J., M. Doyle, J. R. Rigby, and K. E. Schnier. "Market Power, Private Information, and the Optimal Scale of Pollution Permit Markets for North Carolinaos Neuse River." Resource and Energy Economics, 35(3), 2013, 256-76.

(1.) An exception is Brandts, Pezanis-Christou, and Schram (2007) who include a supply function equilibria case in one of their experiments. They do not, however, provide a robust investigation of the properties of the supply function equilibria.

(2.) Alternatively, one might consider a field experiment. But at a yearly time scale, it would take decades to generate the amount of data that can be generated in a few laboratory hours. Moreover, over such a long time period it would be extremely likely that other confounding factors would arise that would complicate the analysis of the market.

(3.) Within the experiment the exception rule was utilized approximately 41% of the time, with the largest percentage occurring when the market size is the largest (16 subjects).

(4.) Using profit maximization, rather than cost minimization, facilitates the experimental analysis. The fixed payment [[pi].sub.i], is different from a show up fee, as it is firm specific and depends on the values of the other experimental parameters.

(5.) The competitive outcome can be found by assuming that the firms ignore the effect of their choices on the market price.

(6.) [A.sub.i] solves [C.sub.i]([[theta].sub.i]) = 0.

(7.) [[pi].sub.i] solves [[pi].sub.i] - [C..sub.i] ([w.sub.i]) = [[pi].sub.i] - ([A.sub.i] - [[theta].sub.i][w.sub.i] + (1/2)([w.sup.2.sub.i])) = [kappa].

(8.) A copy of the instructions can be obtained from K.S.

(9.) The f-tests generate one other counterfactual to the Wilcoxon rank-sum tests for buyers and that is when a variance of zero is paired with market size of 4.

(10.) All of these are robust to a parametric test except when variance of zero is paired with market size of 16.

(11.) The three cases where the sellers followed the strategic predictions were all for the zero variance case. When the variance is zero we cannot differentiate between strategic behavior and perfect competition because the theoretical predictions are identical. Therefore, we must focus on the nonzero variance cases to determine whether or not the buyers/sellers behave closer to the strategic predictions or those under perfect competition.

(12.) If we use the 90th percentile as our threshold of statistical significance there are two situations where sellers' behavior more closely follows the strategic predictions. The second treatment is when the variance is 4[[sigma].sup.2] and the market size is 8.

(13.) The predicted market efficiency varies depending on the variance and market size. When the variance is zero the predicted market efficiency is one. When the variance is the predicted market efficiency is 99.16, 99.79, and 99.95% when the market size is 4, 8, and 16, respectively. When the variance is 4 of 2 the predicted market efficiency is 97.60, 99.40, and 99.85% when the market size is 4, 8. and 16, respectively.

(14.) The z-statistics comparing the market sizes of 4 and 8 as well as 8 and 16 are statistically significant at the 90th percent level.

(15.) The exception seem to be driven by the high degree of heterogeneity in the profits earned by buyers in the market. In a number of cases, buyers actually sold permits and this led to a large loss for those individual subjects.

KURT SCHNIER, MARTIN DOYLE, JAMES R. RIGBY and ANDREW J. YATES *

* This research was supported by NSF grant numbers 0909275, 0908679, and 0909056.

Schnier: Professor of Economics, School of Humanities, Social Sciences and Arts, University of California, Merced, CA 95343. Phone +l-(209) 205-6461, Fax (209) 228-4007, E-mail kschnier@ucmerced.edu

Doyle: Professor of River Science and Policy, Nicholas School of the Environment, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708. Phone +1-919-613-8026, Fax (919) 613-8070, E-mail martin.doyle@duke.edu

Rigby: Research Hydrologist, USDA-ARS National Sedimentation Laboratory, Oxford, MS 38655. Phone +1-(662) 232-2951, Fax (662) 281-5706, E-mail jr.rigby @ars.usda.gov

Yates: Assistant Professor, Economics/Curriculum for the Environment and Ecology, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, NC 27599. Phone 919-966-2385, Fax 919-966-4986, E-mail ajyates@email.unc.edu

TABLE 1 Values for Buyers and Sellers

var([theta]--w)    [[theta].sub.b]   [[theta].sub.s]

0                        10                10
[[sigma].sup.2]         12.5               7.5
4[[sigma].sup.2]         15                 5

TABLE 2
Experimental Design and Predictions: Buyers' Values for [a.sub.1] =
[a.sup.c.sub.i] + [[DELTA].sub.i]

                          n: Number of Subjects in Market

                                         4

                   [a.sub.i]   [a.sup.c.sub.i]   [[DELTA].sub.i]

var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                      5              5                 0
[[sigma].sup.2]      5.93           6.25              -0.32
4[[sigma].sup.2]     6.87            7.5              -0.63

                          n: Number of Subjects in Market

                                         8

                   [a.sub.i]   [a.sup.c.sub.i]   [[DELTA].sub.i]

var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                      5              5                 0
[[sigma].sup.2]      6.09           6.25              -0.16
4[[sigma].sup.2]     7.19            7.5              -0.31

                          n: Number of Subjects in Market

                                        16

                   [a.sub.i]   [a.sup.c.sub.i]   [[DELTA].sub.i]

var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                      5              5                 0
[[sigma].sup.2]      6.17           6.25              -0.08
4[[sigma].sup.2]     7.34            7.5              -0.16

TABLE 3
Experimental Design and Predictions: Sellers' Values for
[a.sub.i] = [a.sup.c.sub.i] + [[DELTA].sub.i]

                          n: Number of Subjects in Market

                                         4

                   [a.sub.i]   [a.sup.c.sub.i]   [[DELTA].sub.i]

var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                      5              5                 0
[[sigma].sup.2]      4.07           3.75              0.32
4[[sigma].sup.2]     3.13            2.5              0.63

                          n: Number of Subjects in Market

                                         8

                   [a.sub.i]   [a.sup.c.sub.i]   [[DELTA].sub.i]

var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                      5              5                 0
[[sigma].sup.2]      3.91           3.75              0.16
4[[sigma].sup.2]     2.81            2.5              0.31

                          n: Number of Subjects in Market

                                        16

                   [a.sub.i]   [a.sup.c.sub.i]   [[DELTA].sub.i]

var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                      5              5                 0
[[sigma].sup.2]      3.83           3.75              0.08
4[[sigma].sup.2]     2.66            2.5              0.16

TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics: Subject Choice Variable a, (Broken Down by
All 20 Periods, Last 15 Periods, and Last 10 Periods)

                                                Market Size

                                                  4: b, s

                                          M      SD     M      SD
Periods 1 -20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.89   1.21   4.89   1.30
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.38   1.82   3.81   1.42
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   5.86   1.87   2.81   1.35
Periods 6-20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.97   1.11   4.91   1.19
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.57   1.70   3.75   1.19
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.16   1.71   2.69   1.16
Periods 11-20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.89   0.93   4.88   1.15
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.86   1.21   3.80   1.10
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.23   1.61   2.68   1.15

                                                Market Size

                                                  8: b, s

                                          M      SD     M      SD
Periods 1 -20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.83   0.95   4.93   1.09
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.75   1.17   3.72   0.79
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.11   2.29   2.77   1.08
Periods 6-20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.91   0.73   4.95   0.94
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.88   1.11   3.70   0.61
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.26   2.16   2.76   0.99
Periods 11-20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.94   0.69   4.98   0.80
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.91   0.91   3.67   0.52
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.37   2.08   2.80   0.96

                                                Market Size

                                                  16: 6,s

                                          M      SD     M      SD
Periods 1 -20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.83   1.20   4.86   1.05
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    5.79   1.36   4.01   1.13
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.54   1.76   2.55   1.35
Periods 6-20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.90   1.02   4.96   0.94
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    6.03   0.98   4.06   0.92
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   6.93   1.45   2.36   1.28
Periods 11-20
  var([theta]--w):    0                  4.89   0.89   4.94   0.76
  Variance of costs   [[sigma].sup.2]    6.13   0.82   4.03   0.91
                      4[[sigma].sup.2]   7.06   1.20   2.22   1.27

TABLE 5
Comparison of [[alpha].sub.i], 's Across Treatments Holding Market
Size Constant: z-Statistic

Variance Comparison                     Buyers    Sellers

Market size: 4
  0 > [[sigma].sup.2]                   -7.153    12.677
  0 > 4[[sigma].sup.2]                  -7.563    16.215
  [[sigma].sup.2] > 4[[sigma].sup.2]    -3.461    11.630
Market size: 8
  0 > [[sigma].sup.2]                   -13.454   16.789
  0 > 4[[sigma].sup.2]                  -12.566   18.509
  [[sigma].sup.2] > 4[[sigma].sup.2]    -6.562    12.821
Market size: 16
  0 > [[sigma].sup.2]                   -17.933   17.495
  0 > 4[[sigma].sup.2]                  -18.601   25.819
  [[sigma].sup.2] > 4[[sigma].sup.2]    -11.152   20.608

TABLE 6
Descriptive Statistics: [[DELTA].sub.i] 's (Broken Down by Buyers [b]
and Sellers [5])

                             Market Size

                               4: b, s

                      M       SD       M       SD

Periods 1-20 var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                  -0.1120   1.28   -0.1116   1.30
[[sigma].sup.2]    -0.8692   1.82    0.0551   1.42
4[[sigma].sup.2]   -1.6357   1.87    0.3053   1.36

                             Market Size

                               8: b, s

                      M       SD       M       SD

Periods 1-20 var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                  -0.1688   0.95   -0.0702   1.09
[[sigma].sup.2]    -0.5042   1.17   -0.0340   0.80
4[[sigma].sup.2]   -1.3858   2.29   0.2718    1.08

                             Market Size

                              16: b, s

                      M       SD       M       SD

Periods 1-20 var([theta]--w): Variance of costs

0                  -0.1703   1.20   -0.1389   1.05
[[sigma].sup.2]    -0.4614   1.36    0.2672   1.13
4[[sigma].sup.2]   -0.9561   1.76    0.0544   1.35

TABLE 7
Comparison of [[DELTA].sub.i] 's Across Treatments Holding Market
Size Constant: z-Statistic

Variance Comparison                     Buyers   Sellers

Market size: 4
  0 > [[sigma].sup.2]                   4.766    -3.768
  0 > 4[[sigma].sup.2]                  10.447   -4.464
  [[sigma].sup.2] > 4[[sigma].sup.2]    5.804    -1.027
Market size: 8
  0 > [[sigma].sup.2]                   6.038    -0.882
  0 > 4[[sigma].sup.2]                  8.233    -2.894
  [[sigma].sup.2] > 4[[sigma].sup.2]    4.658    -3.469
Market size: 16
  0 > [[sigma].sup.2]                   4.684    -8.276
  0 > 4[[sigma].sup.2]                  9.037    -2.057
  [[sigma].sup.2] > 4[[sigma].sup.2]    5.541     4.113

TABLE 8
Comparison of [[DELTA].sub.i] 's Across Treatments Holding Variance
Constant: z-Statistic

Market Size Comparison        Buyers   Sellers

Variance = 0
  4 > 8                       -0.278   -1.227
  4 > 16                      -1.708   -0.408
  8 > 16                      -2.089    0.971
Variance = [[sigma].sub.2]
  4 > 8                       -1.501    3.390
  4 > 16                      -3.634   -0.724
  8 > 16                      -3.202   -5.086
Variance = 4[[sigma].sub.2]
  4 > 8                       -2.972    0.113
  4 > 16                      -5.717    2.794
  8 > 16                      -2.297    2.580

TABLE 9
Average Market Price by Variance and Market Size

Variance                 0          [[sigma].sup.2]   4[[sigma].sup.2]

Market Size        4     8     16    4     8     16    4     8     16

All time periods  4.89  4.88  4.85  4.60  4.73  4.91  4.43  4.53  4.75
Last ten periods  4.89  4.96  4.92  4.84  4.79  5.08  4.55  4.67  4.93

TABLE 10
Average Market Efficiency by Variance and Market Size

Variance                 0          [[sigma].sup.2]   4[[sigma].sup.2]

Market Size        4     8     16    4     8     16    4     8     16

All time periods  88.5  90.1  88.4  81.2  91.9  87.6  82.1  79.1  86.1
Last ten periods  92.3  95.3  93.4  91.0  95.7  93.8  88.3  83.1  93.7

TABLE 11
Comparison of Efficiency Across Treatments Holding Variance Constant:
z-Statistic.

                                         Variance

Market Size Comparison     0      [[sigma].sup.2]   4[[sigma].sup.2]

4 > 8                    -1.871       -2.550              1.539
4 > 16                    1.898        0.582             -1.342
8 > 16                    3.878        4.234             -3.002

TABLE 12
Comparison of Buyer and Sellers Profits within Each Treatment:
z-Statistic ([H.sub.0] Is That the Profit for Sellers Is Equal
to the Profit for Buyers)

                               Variance

Market Size     0      [[sigma].sup.2]   4[[sigma].sup.2]

4             0.767        -0.589             -4.494
8             -0.447       -3.570             3.002
16            1.963         1.771             1.058
COPYRIGHT 2014 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2014 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有