Lawyers in venture capital contracting: theory and evidence.
Bengtsson, Ola ; Bernhardt, Dan
Lawyers in venture capital contracting: theory and evidence.
Real-world financial contracts are sometimes so complex that it can
be difficult to understand their exact payoff consequences. We develop
and test a theoretical model of a venture capitalist (VC) negotiating
with an entrepreneur who may overweigh or underweigh the payoff
consequences of contractual downside protection (DP). A lawyer with
expertise in venture capital can inform the entrepreneur about these
consequences, but less expert (but otherwise high quality) lawyers
cannot. We determine how a VC's decision to include DP is affected
by the expected quality of the entrepreneur's project, the
entrepreneur's experience, and the VC expertise of his/her legal
counsel. We show that the VC's incentive to include unnecessary DP
declines in expected project quality. Indeed, for inexperienced
entrepreneurs involved with high-quality projects, VCs prefer that the
entrepreneur's counsel has VC expertise. This implies that, when
negotiating with inexperienced entrepreneurs, VCs who invest in
high-quality companies should be more likely to negotiate with
entrepreneurs who employ lawyers with VC expertise. We document broad
empirical support for the model, and provide evidence against competing
explanations. (JEL L24, G24, K12, LI4, L24)
I. INTRODUCTION
Downside protection (DP), which provides one contracting party
proportionately larger payoffs in bad states of the world, is a
prevalent feature of real-world financial contracts. A large literature
motivates various forms of DP by deriving them as optimal solutions to
moral hazard and adverse selection problems. These frictions are clearly
present in many important contracting settings. Yet, there could be
other reasons why contracts so often include DP.
Traditionally, economists presume that, although the contracting
parties may not know each other's unobserved type (e.g., ability),
they do understand the payoff implications of negotiated contract terms.
However, in many settings, the premise that all contracting parties
understand the payoff implications of all contract terms is implausible.
Tirole (2009, 265) observes that "thinking about contingencies,
designing covenants, and seeing through their implications is
costly." He then explores the implications of cognition costs in
contracting between parties who are unaware, and know that they are
unaware.
We build on a related observation. We recognize that in some
contexts, there are vast differences in how accurately the contracting
parties can forecast the payoff consequences of complex contract terms.
We study venture capital (VC) investment, where comprehension
differences between the contracting parties--the venture capitalist (VC)
and entrepreneur--are acute. VC contracts include a myriad of esoteric
and intricate cash flow contingencies (Bartlett 1995; Hart 2001; Kaplan
and Stromberg 2003; Metrick and Yasuda 2010): VCs are well-versed about
these contingencies, as they repeatedly negotiate contracts and observe
their outcomes. In contrast, entrepreneurs, whose attention is focused
on innovation, often lack a detailed understanding of these terms when
they negotiate their first VC contracts. As a result, otherwise
identical entrepreneurs can come to very different assessments of the
payoff implications of a cash flow contingency. In turn, those different
assessments can lead them to reach very different conclusions about the
attractiveness of a proposed contract.
We investigate the consequences of these observations both
theoretically and empirically. In our theoretical model, a VC and
entrepreneur negotiate a financial contract for which "extra"
DP is sometimes, but not always, necessary to mitigate the relevant
moral hazard. VCs understand the payoff implications of DP, but
entrepreneurs may not unless they are represented by legal counsel with
VC expertise. Expert (as opposed to high quality) counsels understand
the implications of contract terms, and can level the playing field for
entrepreneurs by explaining, evaluating and benchmarking contract terms.
(1) A VC can offer a contract with unnecessary DP, hoping to extract
surplus from a mis-informed entrepreneur. A VC can also choose to inform
the entrepreneur by introducing him/her to an expert legal counsel. VCs
know an entrepreneur's experience and his/her counsel's VC
expertise. Hence, a VC can identify a subset of entrepreneurs who
correctly evaluate the payoff implications of DP. In particular, when a
VC negotiates a contract with a novice entrepreneur represented by an
inexpert legal counsel, the VC understands that the entrepreneur may
misprice the payoff consequences of this added DP. However, the VC does
not know whether the novice entrepreneur would underweigh, overweigh, or
correctly weigh these consequences.
It follows that a VC should internalize the possibility that an
entrepreneur may misprice DP. If a VC believes an entrepreneur is likely
to under-weigh the adverse payoff consequences of DP, he/she may
introduce such contingencies, even when those contingencies can,
themselves, subsequently distort incentives. The VC's offer may
combine this DP with a slightly smaller equity position, which
entrepreneurs can correctly price since its payoff consequences are
clear. With this contract, a VC can increase both his/her own payoff
from a given contract at the expense of an underweighting entrepreneur,
and raise the likelihood that the entrepreneur accepts the offer.
Conversely, offering a contract with DP to an overweighting entrepreneur
may lead to rejection of a contract that is in everyone's interest
to accept. Conversations with VCs indicate that contract negotiations
frequently break down even when the VC believes there is positive
surplus for both parties. This points to the economic costs introduced
by asymmetries in the comprehension of the VC and entrepreneur of the
consequences of contract terms, and to the real economic value that
lawyers with VC expertise can provide.
We derive the conditions that need to hold for a VC to introduce
unnecessary DP. Consistent with our empirical results pertaining to
legal counsel expertise and VC contract design, the model predicts that
VCs propose unnecessary DP only to novice entrepreneurs whose legal
counsel lacks VC expertise. The model also demonstrates how the quality
of an entrepreneur's company affects a VC's trade-off for
proposing contracts with more DP. We show that when the expected surplus
at stake from successfully contracting is not too high, a VC may have an
incentive to design a contract with added DP that only appeals to
entrepreneurs who underweigh the payoff consequences of DP. Indeed, a VC
may be able to extract profits from a project that has a negative net
present value.
However, when the potential surplus is higher, the opportunity cost
to a VC of having an entrepreneur who overweighs the payoff consequences
of DP reject an offer is higher. As a result, a VC may endogenously
include less DP for more promising projects. For especially valuable
projects, the opportunity costs of failed negotiations can be such that
when extra DP is necessary, VCs want to deal with entrepreneurs who
understand the payoff consequences. That is, sometimes unusual levels of
DP are necessary to alleviate moral hazard, but to design a contract
with the requisite protection that would appeal to most overweighting
entrepreneurs, a VC would have to cede a large equity stake.
In this situation, a VC would like to credibly inform the
entrepreneur about the payoff implications of DP in order to increase
the likelihood that he/she accepts the contract. Credibly recommending
legal counsel with expertise in VC contracting to entrepreneurs is one
way to do this. In this way, differences in information about DP emerge
endogenously. That is, we provide a theoretical rationale for why
high-quality companies backed by inexperienced entrepreneurs should be
more likely to be represented by law firms with VC expertise in their
negotiations (as opposed to being represented by higher-quality law
firms that lack VC-specific expertise).
We then test the predictions of the model. We analyze 908 U.S. VC
contracts. We first document the wide variety of complicated cash flow
contingencies in these contracts. (2) We then uncover several novel
findings relating the expertise of the entrepreneur's legal counsel
to contract design. We first show that entrepreneurs represented by law
firms with more VC-specific expertise negotiate contracts with fewer
VC-friendly cash flow contingencies. This result is robust and survives
a large battery of controls. Importantly, we find no difference in DP
for entrepreneurs advised by better (rather than more expert) law firms.
Those "better," but nonexpert, law firms have more general
expertise, as measured by law firm revenues, number of lawyers, gross
profit margin, revenue per lawyer, or entry salary for new associates,
and charge more for their services. Such law firms have good negotiation
skills, but limited understanding of the cash flow contingencies in VC
contracts. This indicates that (a) our finding that inexperienced
entrepreneurs with inexpert lawyers negotiate contracts with more
VC-friendly terms is not due to expert law firms being more skilled at
negotiations; and (b) the correlation with lawyer VC expertise rather
than lawyer quality strongly suggests rent extraction from unknowing
entrepreneurs rather than the outcome of efficient contracting.
An analysis of each separate contingency reveals that a
lawyer's expertise only matters for those terms that have
particularly complicated payoff consequences. Concretely, we find no
association between lawyer expertise and the inclusion of liquidation
preference, which is a relatively straightforward contract term. This
emphasizes that it is the entrepreneur's limited understanding of
contract terms that drives our results. In particular, alternative
rationales would have to account for why an expert lawyer matters only
for complicated forms of DP.
We further find that the VC-specific expertise of the law firm
matters less for entrepreneurs who previously negotiated VC contracts.
For these experienced entrepreneurs, their law firm's VC expertise
has no impact on the extent of DP. This suggests that learning-by-doing
can substitute for the VC expertise of legal counsel: entrepreneurs can
come to understand the payoff implications of DP via their legal counsel
or via their own past experiences. (3)
We then document that when negotiating with inexperienced
entrepreneurs, VCs who invest in high-quality companies are more likely
to negotiate with entrepreneurs who employ lawyers with VC expertise. In
sharp contrast, we find no evidence of assortive matching between VCs
who invest in high-quality companies and entrepreneurs who employ
lawyers with more general expertise. Because lawyers with more general
expertise charge more for their services, this finding is inconsistent
with the competing rationale for matching that high-quality
entrepreneurs exhibit stronger willingness to pay for expert counsel.
Rather, as predicted by our model, the assortive matching arises because
VCs want to help match high-quality entrepreneurs with expert counsels
to avoid negotiation breakdowns with otherwise-uninformed entrepreneurs.
Our finding that DP is virtually unrelated to lawyer general expertise
is evidence that matching is not based on willingness to pay or on
complementarities in inputs. This should not be surprising: overall
legal fees represent a small transaction cost for almost any
entrepreneur. Interviews with lawyers and VCs also contradict the
premise that willingness to pay is an important real-world
consideration.
Our paper contributes to the theoretical work that investigates the
limitations under which financial contracts are written. In particular,
our paper adds to the incomplete contracting literature that
investigates the influence of cognition costs on contract design
(Anderlini and Felli 1994, 1999, 2004; Dye 1985; Tirole 2009). We also
contribute to the literatures that study how intermediaries--such as
banks, VCs, and initial public offering (IPO) underwriters--overcome
informational frictions. Our paper is one of the few to provide
theoretical and empirical evidence on how intermediaries mitigate
information asymmetries related to the contract design, and adds to the
small set of legal studies that have large samples and examine the
economic role of lawyers (Ashenfelter, Bloom, and Dahl 2013; Block and
Stiebler 1987; Coates 2001; Harcourt 2000; Vronsky 2012). Finally, we
contribute directly to the growing literature that studies the
determinants of VC contracts (Bengtsson and Ravid 2009; Bengtsson and
Sensoy 2011; Bottazzi, Hellmann, and Da Rin 2009; Cornelli and Yosha
2003; Gompers 1998; Kaplan, Martel, and Stromberg 2007; Kaplan and
Stromberg 2003, 2004; Lemer and Schoar 2005; Sahlman 1990; Suchman
1994). While previous studies have investigated how company
characteristics, VC characteristics, or institutional factors affect
contract design, our paper shows how contracts are influenced by the
expertise of an entrepreneur's legal counsel.
The paper is organized as follows. Section II describes the design
of VC contracts, discusses reasons why entrepreneurs may find it
difficult to understand their implications, and explains the roles of
legal counsels. Section III presents our theoretical model. Sections IV
and V describe the data and present our empirical findings. Section VI
concludes. II.
II. BACKGROUND CHARACTERISTICS
A. Design of VC Contracts
VC contracts are relational agreements that include a myriad of
complicated contractual terms that determine the allocation of control
and cash flow rights in different states of the world. Suchman (1994)
finds that contracts have evolved toward more standardized templates, so
that contracts differ largely in which terms are included, rather than
in how specific terms are structured. Sahlman (1990), Gompers (1998),
and Kaplan and Stromberg (2003) characterize the typical VC contract
template. VCs typically receive convertible preferred stock with
attached cash flow contingencies such as liquidation preferences,
cumulative dividends, redemption rights, and antidilution protection.
Cumulative dividends and liquidation preference jointly specify the
fixed amount that VCs have the right to receive before distributions to
other shareholders. Participation rights, which are attached to about
half of contracts that use preferred equity, increase VC payoffs by
giving the VC both a repayment of invested capital and a fraction of the
remaining common equity (double dipping). Redemption rights give VCs the
right to sell shares back to the company following a predetermined
schedule. Antidilution protection gives VCs rights to additional shares
if the company secures follow-up investment when the company valuation
has declined (down round). Contracts may also include pay-to-play
provisions, according to which VCs retain certain contractual rights
only if they invest in follow-up financing rounds.
B. Complexity of VC Contracts
The joint payoff implications of different cash flow contingencies
in VC contracts hinge sensitively on their finely interrelated details.
To illustrate, consider a VC investment of $5 million in which the VC
holds a 30% equity stake. If the company sold for $20 million after 3
years, the VC would receive $6 million if the contract gave VCs
"plain" convertible preferred stock. The VC's payoff
would be $13.9 million, or 70% of the selling price, if the contract
gave the VC preferred stock with participation rights, a 2X liquidation
preference and 8% compounding cumulative dividends: these additional
cash flow contingencies raise the VC's payoff by $8 million. If,
however, the VC instead received a 60% equity stake, this difference
would shrink to $4.5 million ($12 million for convertible preferred
versus $16.5 million for participating preferred). Moreover, the VC only
receives payoffs from participation rights if the selling price is below
the automatic conversion enterprise value. This example illustrates one
way in which the payoff implications of DP are interlinked in truly
complex ways.
C. Entrepreneur's Understanding
Inexperienced entrepreneurs face steep hurdles when trying to
understand contract implications. An entrepreneur must first decipher
the financial meanings of cash flow contingencies such as
"narrow-based weighted-average anti-dilution." Although there
are books and web-pages devoted to explaining how VC contracts work,
these sources provide imprecise and incomplete explanations that do not
reveal the exact payoff consequences. These consequences are hard to
compute because expected payoffs depend on the probability distribution
over company outcomes, investment amounts and share prices in different
rounds, type of preferred stock, cumulative dividends, and other deal
features.
Entrepreneurs must also understand how contracts evolve. Most
companies receive multiple rounds of financing, and terms are often
renegotiated if new investors set this as a precondition (Bengtsson and
Sensoy, forthcoming) or companies are sold (Broughman and Fried 2010).
Finally, an entrepreneur must forecast what should go into a
contract, and what other VCs might offer. The broad variation in the
structure of negotiated contracts (Bengtsson and Ravid 2009; Bengtsson
and Sensoy 2011; Gompers 1998; Kaplan and Stromberg 2003, 2004) makes it
harder for entrepreneurs to assess whether a proposed contract is
reasonable.
D. VCs' Understanding
Unlike entrepreneurs, VCs are well-versed with the consequences of
cash flow contingencies. Zarutskie (2010), and Bengtsson and Hsu (2010)
find that most VC partners hold MBA degrees from top universities and
that many have prior work experience in finance. VC partners have seen
how different cash flow contingencies affect realized payoffs at company
exit events: the average VC in our sample makes a dozen investments per
year, also participates in failed negotiations, and has about two
decades of experience.
E. How Legal Counsels Help Entrepreneurs
As we formally model, the inability of some entrepreneurs to
understand the payoff consequences of DP may entice VCs to propose
excessive investor-friendly cash flow contingencies (i.e., unnecessary
DP). An entrepreneur would not trust a VC's advice on contract
terms because VCs have incentives to mislead. This opens up a role for
external advisers--legal counsels with expertise in VC contracts. Such
legal counsels can describe the exact meanings and consequences of cash
flow contingencies. One lawyer describes this process: "Invariably,
there are provisions ... that the entrepreneur either did not understand
completely or simply did not devote enough attention to. As the cliche
goes, the devil is always in the details and the reality is that this is
precisely where and when a good attorney will add value." (Aspatore
Books Staff 2008, 114).
A legal counsel can also give his/her opinion about what represents
a reasonable "market" contract. The counsel can convey which
contingencies are non-standard and are particularly favorable to a VC.
Even if the counsel does not know the exact payoff consequences, but
only whether a contingency is necessary, he/she can shape an
entrepreneur's assessment. In turn, this can discourage a VC from
trying to extract rents via unnecessary contingencies. One lawyer
explains this; "Simply put, if someone on the other side of the
table argues that a certain deal term we are asking for is not market or
standard and I disagree, I am going to call them on it ... my experience
provides some currency in the negotiation process" (Aspatore Books
Staff 2008, 120). Finally, counsels who have observed the evolution and
renegotiation of contracts can convey this knowledge to clients.
F. Importance of Counsel Expertise
A legal counsel's role of informing an entrepreneur about the
payoff implications of DP differs from the routine task of translating
negotiated agreements into the required legal documents. A counsel can
only provide this information if he/she has personal experience with the
specific contracts used in VC investments, or if he/she works at a law
firm with that accumulated institutional knowledge.
It is not always easy for an uninformed entrepreneur to identify
(a) a counsel's expertise and (b) the importance of that expertise
for negotiating contracts. Concretely, an entrepreneur may know that a
well-trained lawyer, for example, one from a top legal firm, may help
translate terms into legal definitions that will hold in court. However,
an entrepreneur may not recognize that a lawyer with VC-specific
expertise may help him/her evaluate the payoff consequences of
negotiable terms. As a result, some uninformed entrepreneurs select
inexpert lawyers.
III. THE MODEL
In this section, we model the strategic calculus of a VC
negotiating contracts with entrepreneurs, some of whom do not fully
understand the implications of contractual DP. We derive how
entrepreneur's characteristics--the quality of his/her project,
his/her experience, and the expertise of his/her legal counsel--affects
the VC's proposed DP.
In the model, entrepreneurs employ legal counsels who help them
interpret and negotiate cash flow contingencies. Legal counsels with VC
expertise correctly interpret and value DP clauses. Such clauses are
sometimes necessary to mitigate moral hazard. However, while equity
shares are easily understood and valued by all parties, DP is not.
Uninformed, inexperienced entrepreneurs must rely on their legal
counsels to value DP. Expert counsels always value DP correctly, while
inexpert ones do not.
Formally, our model distinguishes three types of inexperienced
entrepreneurs with inexpert legal counsels: a type p entrepreneur
properly values DP, a type u entrepreneur under-weighs the payoff
consequences of DP, and a type o entrepreneur overweighs the payoff
consequences. We determine how the presence of these three types of
entrepreneurs influences the DP the VC offers, and how the ex ante
expected quality of an entrepreneur's project affects the VC's
decisions.
We consider an entrepreneur with a project that requires one unit
of external venture capital finance to go forward. The opportunity cost
of the capital to the VC is R. The project is indexed by its ex ante
expected quality, q, and possible moral hazard, [zeta] [member of]
{0,1}. Here, [zeta] = 1 indicates the presence of a moral hazard issue
that must be addressed, and [zeta] = 0 indicates that there is no moral
hazard. Let d [member of] {0,1} index whether the contract features DP
that mitigates the moral hazard problem. Thus, d = 1 indicates that the
contract includes DP, and d = 0 indicates that the contract is a pure
equity contract. If funded, the project pays [pi] = qg[([zeta],
d).sub.[epsilon]], where [epsilon] is distributed according to a
continuous density f with connected support, where [epsilon] [greater
than or equal to] 0 and E[[epsilon]] = 1. The VC knows q and [zeta]. For
simplicity, we assume that g(0,0) = 1 (a normalization), g(1,0) = 0 and
g(1,1) = g(0,1) = 1 - [delta], where [delta] is positive, but small.
These payoffs indicate that "uncontrolled" moral hazard
destroys project payoffs, but that moral hazard can largely be mitigated
by DP. We focus on the case where [delta] [right arrow] 0, so that DP
only slightly distorts actions in other ways. Hence, introducing
unnecessary DP--choosing d = 1 when [zeta] = 0--has only small costs.
Finally, when [zeta] = 1, the potential consequences of moral hazard are
severe enough that it is optimal to introduce DP. Thus, DP is necessary
when [zeta] = 1, but unnecessary when [zeta] = 0.
A. Interpretation
In practice, VCs always have some moral hazard concerns. Indeed,
our data reveal that contracts always include some DP. For example,
contracts always have a convertible equity component with at least 1X
liquidation preference. In terms of our model, one should interpret d =
0 as a contract that includes "standard" DP, and d = 1 as a
contract that includes "extra" DP (e.g., 2X liquidation
preference), that is only sometimes required to mitigate
"extra" moral hazard. The other structure imposed just ensures
that (1) when there is an "extra" moral hazard problem, it is
optimal for a VC to add DP and (2) "unnecessary" DP has some
cost, so that it is not socially optimal to include.
If the entrepreneur rejects the VC's offer, he/she receives an
outside alternative that pays qz. We assume that z > 0 is distributed
according to the cdf H(*) with associated density h(*) on
(0,[infinity]). That is, the entrepreneur's outside alternative
depends on his/her "ability" or project quality, reflecting
either that the entrepreneur may find a second source of funding, or
that a more able entrepreneur who can create better projects, is
generally more productive, with higher opportunity costs. The
realization of the value of the entrepreneur's outside alternative,
z, is private information to him/her.
A contract is a pair {s,d}, where 5 is the share of project payoffs
that the VC receives when the project payoffs, [pi], are sufficiently
high. When d = 0, the VC just receives his/her equity share s of project
payoffs. When d= 1, the VC's share is [rho]([pi]|s, d) = max
{[??]([pi]),s}, where [rho]{[pi]|s,d)[pi] is non-decreasing in [pi], and
[??]([pi]) is a weakly decreasing continuous function of [pi], strictly
decreasing and differentiable once profits exceed some minimum level
[[pi].bar]. That is, DP gives the VC a higher share when project payoffs
are lower, but it does not drop off so quickly that the VC prefers lower
realizations of profits to higher ones. Hence, the interests of the VC
and entrepreneur are aligned in that they both prefer higher profit
realizations. The entrepreneur receives the residual share of project
payoffs, 1 - [rho]([pi]|s, d). Without loss of generality, we focus on
entrepreneurs of sufficient quality, q, that the VC can identify a
contract that provides him/her an expected payoff that covers his/her
capital investment. We also assume that the expected payoffs of DP do
not cover the VC's investment--the VC will always choose s > 0.
Entrepreneurs are either informed or not. Entrepreneurs who have
past experience or who employ expert legal counsels understand the
payoff consequences of DP. In contrast, inexperienced entrepreneurs who
employ inexpert counsels may not. In this way, the knowledge of an
expert counsel can substitute for an entrepreneur's lack of
experience. In essence, we assume that an entrepreneur may have trouble
in distinguishing a counsel who is an expert in VC contracting from one
who is not. The VC can distinguish whether the entrepreneur is
experienced, and whether his/her legal counsel is an expert. Without
loss of generality, we focus on informed and uninformed entrepreneurs,
and ignore the reasons underlying why the entrepreneur is informed. We
let i [member of] {0,1} index whether the entrepreneur is informed.
Here, i = 1 indicates that the entrepreneur is informed, and i = 0
indicates that he/she is uninformed.
We contemplate three types of uninformed entrepreneurs: those who
properly weight the consequences of DP, believing [[??].sub.p]([pi]) =
[??]([pi]); those who optimistically underweigh the consequences,
[[??].sub.u]([pi]) [less than or equal to] [??]([pi]); and those who
pessimistically overweigh the consequences with [[??].sub.0]([pi])
[greater than or equal to] [??]([pi]). These inequalities can be weak
for [pi] [less than or equal to] [[pi].bar], but are strict for [pi]
> [[pi].bar]. We index these types of entrepreneurs by t [member of]
{p,u,o}, with associated probabilities of [p.sub.p], [p.sub.u], and
[p.sub.o]. Consistent with DP, we assume that [[??].sub.t]([pi]) is
weakly decreasing in [pi], differentiable for [pi] > [[pi].bar].
The timing of the game is as follows: given q, [zeta], and i, the
VC offers a contract {s,d}. Then, given {s,d}, q, [zeta], and the
realization of his/her outside alternative, z, the type t entrepreneur
chooses whether to accept (a = 1) or reject (a = 0) the contract. If
accepted, the project pays off, and the contract determines payments to
the VC and entrepreneur. If rejected, the VC receives zero, and the
entrepreneur receives his/her outside alternative, qz.
We will also contemplate the possibility that given q, [zeta], and
i = 0, the VC can introduce the entrepreneur to expert legal counsel.
This captures the idea that while an entrepreneur may not trust a
VC's assertions about DP, an entrepreneur would accept the
assessment of a legal counsel, who has no direct conflict of interest,
and who has reputational capital at stake. In this way, we endogenize
the information status of the entrepreneur. This allows us to make sense
of the observation that some VCs dislike the uncertainty created when
entrepreneurs are represented by inexpert legal counsels, and will try
to guide them to expert counsel.
B. Analysis
Optimization by a type t entrepreneur with a project of quality q
implies that he/she accepts contract {s,0} if and only if
[[integral].sub.[epsilon]](1-s) q[member of]f([epsilon])d[epsilon]
[greater than or equal to] qz; and that he/she accepts contract {s,1} if
and only if [[integral].sub.[epsilon]](1-[[rho].sub.t](q[epsilon]))(1 -
[delta])q[epsilon]f([epsilon]) d[epsilon][greater than or equal to]qz.
Let [[alpha].sub.t](s,d;q) be the probability of acceptance:
[[alpha].sub.t] (s, 0; q) = H ([[integral].sub.[epsilon] (1 - s)
[epsilon]f ([epsilon]) d[epsilon])
and [[alpha].sub.t] (s, 1; q)
= H([[integral].sub.[epsilon]] (1 - [[rho].sub.t](g[epsilon]))
(1-[delta])[epsilon]f([epsilon])d[epsilon]).
Because all entrepreneurs correctly evaluate the payoff
consequences of pure equity contracts, each type of entrepreneur is
equally likely to accept a contract that does not have DP. Moreover, the
entrepreneur's quality does not affect the probability that he/she
accepts a given equity contract, as quality affects equally both project
payoffs and the value of his/her outside alternative. In sharp contrast,
for a contract with DP and equity share s, the likelihood that an
entrepreneur accepts rises with his/her quality q. That is, the marginal
impact of increasing q on the probability of acceptance by a type t
entrepreneur is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [[pi].sub.t](s) is the highest profit realization for which a
type t entrepreneur believes DP is relevant, that is,
[[??].sub.t]([[pi].sub.t](s)) = s. Intuitively, DP affects high-quality
entrepreneurs by less because they are less likely to have low project
payoffs. (4)
The VC's expected payoff from a contract without DP (when DP
is not necessary) is then
[[alpha].sub.p] (s, 0; q) [sq - R].
The VC's expected payoff from a contract with DP is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We begin the analysis with the observation that the VC offers a
contract with DP to an informed entrepreneur if and only if it is
required to mitigate moral hazard.
PROPOSITION 1. VCs offer contracts with d=1 to informed
entrepreneurs if and only if [zeta]=1
Intuitively, unnecessary DP destroys surplus, and since the
entrepreneur is informed, the VC would be the party that incurs the
costs associated with reduced surplus.
When the social costs of unnecessary DP are small, that is, when
[delta] [right arrow] 0 we can provide necessary and sufficient
conditions for the VC to offer unnecessary DP to an uninformed
entrepreneur with a quality q project. In the notation below,
[s.sup.*.sub.1] is the optimal equity share chosen by the VC when he/she
offers DP.
PROPOSITION 2. Suppose that i = 0 and [zeta] = 0. Then as [delta]
[right arrow] 0, the VC offers unnecessary DP, d = 1, if and only if
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The VC loses when he/she offers DP to entrepreneurs who overweigh
the payoff consequences of DP, but gains when he/she offers it to those
who optimistically underweigh the payoff consequences. The result says
that for unnecessary DP to be optimal, the proportion of uninformed
entrepreneurs who optimistically underweigh the adverse payoff
consequences of DP must be sufficiently high relative to the fraction of
entrepreneurs who pessimistically overweigh the consequences, and hence
are less likely to accept a contract with DP.
The flip side of Proposition 2 is that sometimes there will be
moral hazard that must be addressed by DP for the project to have value.
Proposition 2 then provides necessary and sufficient conditions for a VC
to have an incentive to introduce an uninformed entrepreneur to expert
legal counsel who can correctly evaluate the DP:
COROLLARY 1. Suppose that DP is necessary, that is, [zeta] = 1.
Then as [delta] [right arrow] 0, the VC's expected payoff is higher
if the entrepreneur is informed than uninformed if and only if
inequality (1) is reversed, that is, if and only if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
When the outside opportunity z is uniformly distributed, we can
relate differences in the likelihood of acceptance directly to the
differences in beliefs about the payoff consequences of DP as
(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
We now show that for plausible parameterizations, the right-hand
side of equation (3) exceeds that of (2). That is, DP reduces the
willingness of pessimistic overweighters to accept a contract by more
than it raises the willingness of optimistic underweighters, that is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In particular, when the outside alternative is uniformly
distributed, and the extent of overweighting equals the extent of
underweighting for a given profit level (the difference can vary with
[pi]), that is,
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
But then when this is so, the condition in Equation (1) of
Proposition 2 for the VC to offer unnecessary DP only holds when
[p.sub.u] > [p.sub.o]: for the VC to want to offer unnecessary DP
there must be significantly more optimistic type u entrepreneurs who
underweigh the adverse payoff consequences of DP than pessimistic type o
entrepreneurs who overweigh the consequences. The following is
immediate.
PROPOSITION 3. Suppose the outside alternative z is uniformly
distributed and that [delta] [right arrow] 0. Then there exists a [mu]
> 0 such that if
E0 [[??].sub.o] ([pi]) - [[rho].sub.p] ([pi]) [greater than or
equal to] [[??].sub.p] ([pi]) - [[??].sub.u] ([pi]) - [mu], [for
all][pi],
the VC only offers unnecessary DP when more entrepreneurs
optimistically underweigh their payoff consequences than overweigh them,
that is, [p.sub.u] > [p.sub.o]
Intuitively, the perceived impact of DP persists for more and
higher values of profits for a pessimistic overweighter, with a
corresponding greater impact on the probability of acceptance. Hence,
not pricing DP correctly has a bigger (negative) impact on the
probability of acceptance by a pessimistic overweighter than the
positive impact on the probability of acceptance by an optimistic
underweighter. Consequently, there must be substantially more
underweighting entrepreneurs than overweighting ones for a VC to want to
introduce unnecessary DP.
A similar result would obtain if entrepreneurs, rather than being
uncertain about the payoff consequences of DP, were overly optimistic or
overly pessimistic about the probability of low payoff states in which
DP bites, with optimism predominating. Puri and Robinson (2007) find
that many entrepreneurs are overly optimistic about their companies.
Rewriting Equation (1), it is optimal for a VC to offer unnecessary
DP if and only if
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The attractiveness of unnecessary DP falls with quality as long as
equity terms [s.sub.1] do not decline too sharply with q. To see this,
observe that if we augment condition E0 with [[??]'.sub.t] =
[??]', for t = o, p, u, then we can describe when the incentives to
offer unnecessary DP fall as the ex ante quality of the
entrepreneur's project rises. Differentiating the left-hand side of
Equation (5) with respect to q, and observing that the Leibnitz terms
drop out, reveals that this incentive falls with q as long as the equity
share that the VC demands is not too sensitive to q and [p.sub.u]
>> [p.sub.0]:
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
This expression reveals that some minimal structure is required for
the optimality of unnecessary DP to fall with quality. In particular,
with no DP, we have s' < 0; the VC demands smaller equity shares
from better entrepreneurs because he/she is more concerned that better
entrepreneurs will reject an offer (the opportunity cost of rejection is
higher). Hence, if the payoff consequences of DP are arbitrarily small,
then [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is positive.
However, in the more plausible setting in which DP has significant
payoff consequences, that is, in which [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is sufficiently negative, the attractiveness of
unnecessary DP falls with quality as long as there are enough
underweighters of DP relative to overweighters. We believe that this
scenario in which DP has significant payoff consequences is the relevant
one; and in this case, Equation (6) becomes negative, implying that the
attractiveness of unnecessary DP falls with quality.
We now provide an intuitive argument for why a VC's desire to
offer unnecessary DP falls with the ex ante quality of the
entrepreneur's project, one that hinges only on an elasticity-based
comparison. As such, it is robust to concerns that DP takes many
different forms and, in practice, explicit functional forms are unclear.
Using prime to denote the derivative with respect to q, consider the
following elasticity condition on acceptance probability differences:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Condition E1 says that an increase in q has a greater percentage
increase on the acceptance probability difference for underweighters
than for overweighters. Under the conditions in Proposition 3, the
denominators in this elasticity comparison are ordered,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
so E1 holds as long the derivative differences in the numerators
are close.
PROPOSITION 4. Suppose that condition E1 holds and z is uniformly
distributed. Then for [delta] [right arrow] 0 if the VC offers
unnecessary DP to some entrepreneur qualities but not others, his/her
decisions reflect a cutoff rule. That is, there exists a [q.sup.*] such
that a VC optimally offers unnecessary DP to entrepreneurs of quality q
< [q.sup.*], but not to higher-quality entrepreneurs with q >
[q.sup.*]. Further, for q < [q.sup.*], the VC prefers to deal with
inexperienced entrepreneurs who are represented by inexpert legal
counsels, whereas the preference is reversed for q > [q.sup.*].
C. Other Role of Expert Legal Counsel
Finally, we argue that the qualitative result that VCs will not
offer unnecessary DP to entrepreneurs represented by expert legal
counsels extends when counsels only know whether the DP is unnecessary,
but do not know the exact payoff implications. As long as unnecessary DP
introduces any distortions in behavior, the legal counsel and
entrepreneur can understand that if it is offered, the VC must be
gaining at their expense (total surplus is reduced, and VC optimization
implies that he/she would only introduce unnecessary DP if he/she
gained). As a result, the legal counsel should guide the entrepreneur to
hold pessimistic views about the payoff consequences; and a VC does not
want to offer unnecessary DP to pessimistic entrepreneurs.
D. Empirical Predictions
We now describe three central predictions of our model that we
test. The first prediction follows from Propositions 1-3: entrepreneurs
agree to less DP if they have expert legal counsel. The second
prediction is that the negative association between DP and legal counsel
expertise should be less pronounced for entrepreneurs with more
experience at VC contract negotiations because those entrepreneurs learn
about the payoff consequences via past experience. The third prediction
is that for inexperienced entrepreneurs, higher-quality companies should
match with expert legal counsels. This positive assortive matching
follows because as entrepreneur quality rises, the opportunity cost that
a VC incurs when an overweighting entrepreneur rejects a proposed
contract rises. As a result, when project quality is high enough, the VC
wants to introduce the entrepreneur to expert counsel.
IV. DATA
A. Sample Construction
Data on VC contracts are difficult to obtain. To address the
questions posed in our paper we collaborated with VCExperts, a company
that analyzes VC data, and use mandatory legal filings to collect a
large and representative sample of VC contracts. A limitation of the
data is that it lacks comprehensive information on control rights.
Although cost and time considerations preclude extracting legal filings
from all recent venture-backed companies, our sample is random in the
sense that we do not systematically extract contracts for certain types
of entrepreneurs, companies, VCs, or legal counsels. Our final sample
includes contracts from 908 unique companies. The sample size is far
larger than those considered by other researchers (Broughman and Fried
2010; Gompers 1998; Kaplan and Stromberg 2003, 2004; Suchman 1994). (5)
We match each contract with its corresponding financing round in
Venture Economics to obtain variables that capture company, VC, and
round characteristics. We complement this data with hand-collected
information on backgrounds of company founders. As the summary
statistics in Table 1 illustrate, the sample is a good representation of
the VC industry, with about half of all companies being headquartered in
California and two-thirds operating in either the life science or
high-technology industries. One company in four has a founder who
previously started a venture-backed company, and 7% have a founder who
previously started a venture-backed company that realized an IPO. The
average company is 4 years old, has raised 1.8 prior rounds of financing
and receives $12.3 million in the contract round. About half of the lead
VCs are headquartered in California, and the average number of VCs in
the round is 4.3. The average lead VC has 21 years of experience and has
invested in 237 portfolio companies prior to the contract negotiation:
most VCs have had ample experience at contract negotiations and have
observed the ultimate payoff implications of many combinations of cash
flow contingencies.
B. Contractual Cash Flow Contingencies
We code each contract along six important cash flow contingencies:
cumulative dividends, liquidation preference, participation,
antidilution rights, redemption, and pay-to-play. These six
contingencies jointly determine the extent of the DP: these
contingencies are especially favorable to VCs when company performance
is bad (see Kaplan and Stromberg 2003). We use the coding scheme in
Bengtsson and Sensoy (2011): we code redemption rights as 0 or 1 and the
other cash flow contingencies as 0, 1, or 2 based on how much DP they
provide a VC. Table 2 outlines the coding scheme and presents statistics
on the frequency of each contingency. A higher-value means that a
contract provides more DP. We then aggregate the six cash flow
contingency variables into a downside protection index (DPI). DPI can
take any value between 0 and 11, where 0 is a contract that has a
minimum of VC-friendly contingencies (i.e., the weakest DP) and 11 is a
contract that includes all possible contingencies (i.e., the strongest
DP). The average DPI is 4.64 and the standard deviation is 1.54.
This simple summation index has the virtue of being more
transparent than other aggregations. One can contemplate two concerns
with it. First, summing cash flow contingencies may not account for the
possibility that the relative weighting of contingencies depends on many
company- and contract-specific factors, including the probability
distribution over outcomes. Obviously, the data do not exist to account
for such factors. Importantly, our findings also hold when we
disaggregate and look at individual cash flow contingencies. Second, one
might believe that pay-to-play should not be incorporated into the index
because it primarily governs relationships between VCs investing in
different rounds. We include pay-to-play in DPI because it determines
when VCs retain other contingencies (e.g., anti-dilution and cumulative
dividends) that are important for DP. Our robustness analysis shows that
excluding pay-to-play from DPI does not alter the relationship between
DP and legal counsel expertise. We also show that this relationship is
robust to excluding redemption rights from DPI.
C. Legal Counsel Expertise
We identify the law firm or self-employed lawyer who represents
each sample company using company web-pages, law firm web-pages, data
from VCExperts, and legal filings. The sample only includes companies
for which we can identify an outside legal counsel. Because large
established law firms are more likely to publish data on the companies
they represent than self-employed lawyers, our sample is tilted toward
venture-backed companies counseled by large law firms. This, however, is
unlikely to affect our cross-sectional analysis of how contract design
varies with a lawyer's expertise.
Because we cannot identify the names of individual lawyers, we
conduct our analysis at the law firm level. The data on the expertise
and reputation of legal counsel are supplemented with hand-coded law
firm characteristics.
We use four different proxies to measure a counsel's expertise
on VC transactions. The first proxy, and in our view the best, is the
number of companies in the sample that are advised by the legal counsel.
(6) The two most represented law firms are Wilson, Sonsini, Goodrich,
and Rosati, and Cooley, Godward, Kronish LLP, which together counsel
almost a quarter of all sample companies. Our second proxy for VC
expertise is whether the counsel is one of the 19 law firms ranked as
top counsel for U.S. VC transactions by two publishers of law firm
intelligence: Chambers and Partners and Legal 500. Most companies in the
sample (63%) are represented by top-ranked counsel. The third proxy is
whether the company has a branch office in or around Silicon Valley (51%
of all companies), and the fourth proxy is whether the company has a
self-reported practice area specialized on either VC or emerging
innovative companies (87% of all companies). The data on law firms are
collected in 2007, save for our first proxy which we compute using the
full sample period. The final sample includes 189 unique legal counsels.
We find that all four proxies for lawyer expertise are positively
correlated with each other, confirming that they capture a similar
dimension of expertise.
While our focus is on a counsel's specialized expertise on VC
investments, we also collect data on a counsel's general expertise.
This allows us to compare contracts associated with counsels who are
high-quality lawyers (in general terms) but lack VC expertise. Our
expectation is that such counsels should not be associated with less DP.
We use several general expertise measures to rule out other possible
explanations for our results. The ALM Research database provides
information on law firm revenues, number of lawyers, gross profit
margin, revenue per lawyer, and entry salary for new associates. Because
ALM Research only tracks the 200 largest U.S. law firms, ranked by
revenues, we can only measure the legal counsel's expertise in
detail for 76% of the companies in the sample. Although three-quarters
of all venture-backed companies use a top 200 law firm, only 5% are
represented by a top 10 firm, and 17% by a top 25 firm.
We do not have data on which law firm represents a VC in our
sample. However, as discussed earlier, VCs have extensive experience
with the payoff consequences of negotiable terms, so the expertise of
their legal counsel should not affect their choices of contract terms.
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
A. Univariate Analysis
We begin with a univariate comparison of how a contract's DP
relates to the expertise of the company's counsel. Table 3 reports
the mean value of DP for subsamples formed on counsel expertise.
Differences in DP between subsamples are tested with a Wilcoxon rank-sum
test.
Consistent with our prediction that expert legal counsels should
reduce DP for inexperienced entrepreneurs, Panel A shows that average
DPI is lower for counsels with more VC expertise. This impact is
statistically significant and economically meaningful for each proxy
used to measure counsel VC expertise. To illustrate, DPI is 4.36 for
companies represented by the "most expert" legal counsel based
on a combination of our four proxies (i.e., a counsel who advises more
than the sample median number of companies, is top ranked, and has both
a VC practice area and a branch office in Silicon Valley). DPI is 5.17
for companies represented by the "least expert" legal counsel
(who advise fewer than the sample median number of companies, is not top
ranked, and has neither a VC practice area nor a branch office in
Silicon Valley). The difference, 0.81 DPI units, represents about
one-half of the standard deviation of DPI. To highlight that the
association between counsel VC expertise and DPI does not depend on how
we construct DPI, Panel B presents results for each cash flow
contingency. For each contingency, contracts negotiated by the
"most expert" legal counsel have less DP than those negotiated
by the "least expert" counsel. These differences are
statistically significant except for liquidation preference and
pay-to-play. We posit that the coefficient on liquidation preference is
insignificant because liquidation preference has relatively
straightforward payoff consequences. As a result, most entrepreneurs
understand its implications. That the impact of counsel expertise only
matters for hard-to-understand DP is hard for alternative explanations
to reconcile. A likely reason for why the coefficient on pay-to-play is
insignificant is that this term affects the payoff split between VCs (in
different rounds) and not the split between the entrepreneur and VCs.
The association between counsel VC expertise and DPI does not hinge on
our aggregation method. In particular, our qualitative findings are
reinforced when pay-to-play is excluded.
Panel C compares DPI across subsamples formed using proxies for a
counsel's general expertise/quality. In important contrast to our
results on VC expertise, the level of general expertise is not
associated with significantly less DPI. The sole exception is
"Counsel General Entry Salary": law firms that pay new
associates more have less DP. However, this difference ceases to be
significant in multivariate tests that include a counsel's VC
expertise and control variables. The fact that the legal counsel's
general expertise does not correlate with contract design supports our
thesis that it is the specific VC expertise of counsels that affect the
inclusion of cash flow contingencies in a contract. That is, more
general counsel knowledge about contracts, or higher general reputation
or general expertise of a counsel does not improve contract terms.
B. Multivariate Analysis
To address the possibility that our univariate findings may be
biased due to correlation of DPI with company or VC characteristics, we
run multivariate ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions with DPI as
the dependent variable. (7) Table 4 presents results of multivariate
regressions that include different proxies for counsel VC expertise as
independent variable. The regressors include as controls key variables
such as company age, amount invested in round, number of VCs investing
in round, whether the founder is a serial founder, whether the founder
is a serial founder whose previous company went public in an IPO, and
whether the founder is a serial founder whose previous company was
acquired. We also control for VC experience (measured by its number of
portfolio company investments), whether the VC firm and company are
located in the same state, and whether the VC was organized as an
independent private partnership (versus a corporate, financial, etc.
VC). (8) The regressions also include as fixed effects: VC location
(California, Massachusetts, Texas, New York, and other states), company
location (state), company industry (Venture Economics 10-grouping
classification), year of investment round, and round number. To adjust
for potential cross-correlation within a counsel, all regressions
cluster residuals by counsel. (9)
Specifications 1-4 and 5-8 are identical save that specifications
5-8 include fixed effect controls. The negative and significant
coefficient estimates reveal that the univariate relationship between
counsel VC expertise and DPI holds even after controlling for variables
that have empirically been shown to influence the investor-friendliness
of VC contracts. In unreported regressions, we find that DPI
monotonically declines between quintiles of counsel VC expertise.
The coefficient estimates on the lawyer expertise proxies vary from
0.16 to 0.47 across the regression models in Table 4, which correspond
to between 10% and 31% of one standard deviation of DPI. We also find a
large increase in predictive power from using the lawyer expertise
variables. For example, in the regression with our full battery of
controls, the adjusted R-squared rises from 21.94% without the lawyer
variable to 23.67% with the lawyer variable. This increase in R-squared
far exceeds the 0.12% increase from including round amount and is of
similar magnitude to the 1.99% increase from including VC experience,
both of which are significant determinants of DPI. These comparisons
indicate that our results are both economically and statistically
significant.
Table 5 presents results of multivariate regressions that, in
addition to the proxy for counsel VC expertise ("Counsel VC # of
Deals"), include different proxies for counsel general expertise.
These regressions have the same control variables and fixed effects as
Table 4, but their coefficients are not reported for brevity. Confirming
our finding from the univariate analysis, the coefficient on counsel VC
expertise remains negative and statistically significant, while
coefficients on all proxies for counsel general expertise are
statistically insignificant.
C. Robustness
In unreported tests, we validate the robustness of the association
between counsel VC expertise and DP. These regressions include
"Counsel VC # of Deals," "Counsel General AmLaw Top
25," with the same controls and fixed effects as in Tables 4 and 5.
We also find that the coefficient on our main proxy for counsel VC
expertise "Counsel VC # of Deals" remains negative and
significant after controlling for "Counsel VC Office in Silicon
Valley." This shows that the effect we estimate for lawyer
expertise is distinct from the regional effects documented by Bengtsson
and Ravid (2009).
Another series of unreported tests included additional controls
that capture omitted VC or company characteristics. The coefficient on
"Counsel VC # of Deals" remains negative and significant when
we include VC fixed effects, which absorbs any time-invariant VC
characteristic. The results are also qualitatively unchanged when we
include the pre-money valuation of the round (which is reported for
about half of our sample). Although this variable absorbs much
unobserved heterogeneity in company quality and risk, it is also
intrinsically correlated with DPI, because terms and pricing are
determined jointly during contract negotiations. For this reason, we do
not include it in our reported specifications. Third, the results are
qualitatively unchanged when we include dummies that capture the outcome
of the company (IPO, Merger/Acquisition, Other). The outcome is a proxy
for a company's ex ante quality, but it may also be endogenously
correlated with DPI.
Our qualitative findings do not depend on how we aggregate
individual cash flow contingencies to DPI. When we exclude pay-to-play
or redemption rights, we find significantly less DP for legal counsels
with more VC expertise. We also corroborate the univariate analyses for
each separate cash flow contingency, running a probit regression for
each contingency, recoded as a binary measure of DP. The impact of legal
counsel expertise is unaffected save for the regression using redemption
rights, where the coefficient remains negative, but not significant.
We also explore different subsamples based on the counsel's VC
expertise. DPI decreases in counsel VC expertise even if we exclude the
largest counsel, Wilson, Sonsini, Goodrich, and Rosati. The results also
hold if we include either counsels above or counsels below the sample
median level of counsel VC expertise. So, too, the results hold if we
restrict the sample to large counsels (e.g., the largest 200 U.S. law
firms) or to smaller counsels. Thus, the association between counsel VC
expertise and downside protection is not due to the behavior of a few
selected counsels.
We split the sample by geographical area and year of financing
round. Within each subsample, DPI falls with counsel VC expertise, but
not with counsel general expertise. Thus, the association between
counsel VC expertise and DP holds broadly throughout the VC industry.
We split the sample based on the riskiness of the project. The idea
behind this split is to test the expectation that lawyers matter more
for risky projects, because the contracts for such projects have greater
payoff consequences. We classify a project as risky if it is in the
internet-specific, or computer software or services industries. Our
analysis of historical outcomes, using Venture Economics data, shows
that these segments are riskier in the sense that low fractions of
funded companies achieve a successful IPO outcome. We find that the
coefficient estimate on "Counsel VC # of Deals" is greater for
risky than for safer projects. However, the difference is not
statistically significant, probably because our proxy for risk is so
imperfect.
We also split the sample based on whether the VC continued to
finance the company or not (see Cumming and Dai 2013 for an analysis of
VC switching). One might expect to find a stronger effect on lawyer
expertise for the subsample of continued VC financing, as the VC could
also benefit from unnecessary DP in future rounds due to cross-round
inertia in VC contracting (Bengtsson and Sensoy, forthcoming). In
contrast, discontinued financing (i.e., switching) means that the
benefit of DP only comes from the current round contract, and any
distortions in actions from unnecessary DP persist. Consistent with this
expectation, we find that the coefficient on lawyer expertise is more
negative for continued VC financing. However, the difference is not
statistically significant.
D. Multivariate Analysis of Entrepreneur Experience
In our model, an experienced entrepreneur's own understanding
of DP can substitute for legal counsel expertise. This suggests that the
association between counsel VC expertise and DP should be less
pronounced if an entrepreneur has past experience negotiating VC
contracts. The entrepreneur has such experience if he/she raised VC
financing before, either for his/her current company or for a
venture-backed company that he/she, by virtue of being a serial
entrepreneur, previously founded.
To investigate the substitution between counsel VC expertise and
entrepreneur experience, we interact counsel VC expertise with the dummy
"Follow-up Round," which equals 1 if the contract is from a
follow-up round and is 0 if from a first round. Specifications 1-4 in
Table 6 present results for this interaction variable, formed for each
proxy for counsel VC expertise. Specifications 5-8 present results for
the interaction between counsel VC expertise and "Serial
Founder." All specifications include the same controls and fixed
effects as Specification 1 of Table 5. The interaction variables are
positive and generally significant: the negative association between
counsel VC expertise and DPI is less pronounced for experienced
entrepreneurs. Indeed, for experienced entrepreneurs, the VC expertise
of counsel has no impact on the extent of DP: a counsel's VC
expertise and the entrepreneur's own understanding are indeed
substitutes. (10)
E. Multivariate Analysis of Counsel Matching
Our model also predicts endogenous matching between legal counsels
and entrepreneurs. Specifically, for inexperienced entrepreneurs,
higher-quality companies should match with legal counsels with more VC
expertise. To investigate this, we run a multivariate regression with
lawyer expertise as dependent variable and a measure of company quality
as an independent variable. To do this, we must confront the challenge
of obtaining a reliable measure of company quality prior to VC funding.
Accounting or detailed performance data for private venture-backed firms
do not exist. Further, company valuation should not be used because it
is a negotiated term that is endogenously related to the other
negotiated contract terms.
We use two proxies for company quality. The first proxy,
"Round Amount," captures how much money the company raises
from VCs in the round. Analyses of historical Venture Economics data
show that companies that raise more aggregate financing are far more
likely to have successful exits in the form of IPO or
acquisition--better firms can raise more money. As Table 4 shows,
"Round Amount" correlates negatively with DPI, consistent with
this variable measuring company quality. The second set of proxies is
the reputation of the lead VC, as measured by "(log) VC
Experience," and "VC IPO Ratio" (we also use "(log)
VC Age" and "VC Fund Sequence" in untabulated tests).
Sorensen (2007) finds that companies financed by more reputable VCs are
more likely to have successful exits, and he shows that this is partly
due to their better pre-financing quality. (11) We extend his finding of
positive assortive matching between company quality and VC reputation,
by testing whether there is also positive assortive matching between
counsel expertise and VC reputation.
Table 7 presents the results on matching. We control for company
age, and include fixed effects for VC firm location, company location,
company industry, year of investment round, and round number. All
regressions cluster residuals by counsel. Specifications 1-3 are OLS
regressions with "Counsel VC # of Deals" as the dependent
variable. We document a strong positive relationship between legal
counsel VC expertise and company quality. Qualitatively similar results
obtain in specifications 4-12, which use our other proxies for legal
counsel VC expertise as the dependent variable. Thus, the data are
consistent with endogenous assortive matching because VCs want
higher-quality entrepreneurs to be represented by knowledgeable counsel
in order to reduce the likelihood that negotiations break down due to
misunderstandings over payoff implications.
F. Competing Explanation of Counsel Matching
A possible competing explanation--distinct from our model--is that
the results reflect operational complementarities between entrepreneur
quality and counsel VC expertise. Better entrepreneurs may gain more
from having better lawyers because they anticipate situations (other
than contract negotiations with VCs) where high-quality legal help
matters. For example, better entrepreneurs may need to use more complex
patenting/licensing agreements, and their companies may be more likely
to go public or be acquired. (12)
Our model suggests that it may not be necessary for experienced
entrepreneurs to match with legal counsels with more VC expertise, as
via their experience the entrepreneurs can come to learn the payoff
consequences of VC contract terms. In contrast, operational
complementarities would suggest that experienced entrepreneurs should be
more likely to employ counsel with VC expertise, since experienced
entrepreneurs are of higher quality than first-time entrepreneurs. Also,
our model demonstrates that there should be no matching between
higher-quality companies and counsels with more general expertise,
because such lawyers do not inform entrepreneurs about the payoff
consequences of cash flow contingencies. In contrast, operational
complementarities would suggest assortive matching should emerge for
measures of legal quality other than VC expertise, because better
entrepreneurs can gain more from having better lawyers help them with
various legal tasks.
We run a series of unreported regressions that test the competing
theory of operational complementarities regressing the legal
counsel's VC expertise on "Serial Founder," "Serial
Founder with IPO," and "Serial Founder with Merger," all
of which capture the entrepreneur's experience level. We control
for company age, and include fixed effects for VC location, company
location, industry, round year, and round number. In all specifications
the relationship between the counsel's VC expertise and the
entrepreneur's experience is insignificant. We also investigate
whether there is matching between a legal counsel's general
expertise and company quality, using the same methodology as in Table 7.
Uniformly, we find no significant relationship between general expertise
and company quality. We conclude that the pattern of matching is
consistent with our model, but difficult to reconcile with theories
based on operational complementarities.
We do not test why some entrepreneurs match with inexpert lawyers
who cannot give them good advice on contract terms. However, our
findings on contracts and matching do shed light on this question. We
have shown that some entrepreneurs fail to understand the consequences
of DP. This suggests that some entrepreneurs may fail to understand that
the choice between an expert and inexpert lawyer can affect the
negotiated contract. Moreover, identifying an expert lawyer need not be
easy. The idiosyncratic nature of different entrepreneurial projects
makes it difficult for an entrepreneur to evaluate whether a contract
negotiated by a lawyer was a good one. Further, indirect indicators of a
lawyer's expertise are imperfect. In particular, the quality of a
law firm (and the price charged for legal advice) is minimally
correlated with a lawyer's VC expertise, and a good, but inexpert,
lawyer is not associated with reduced DP. That is, it is not enough for
an inexperienced entrepreneur to identify a "good law firm."
Entrepreneurs may also choose lawyers for other reasons. DP does
not matter if a company goes public because VC contracts include an
"Automatic conversion" provision that cancels most protections
given to a VC in this event. As a result, entrepreneurs who believe
their companies are likely to have IPOs may choose inexpert lawyers
because they care more about other factors (see Cumming 2008).
G. Other Observations
Our model predicts that DP decreases with company quality.
Accordingly, it can provide a complementary explanation for the
empirical findings of Gompers (1998) and Kaplan and Stromberg (2003,
2004) that VC contracts include less DP for high-quality companies.
These papers posit that their findings reflect agency problems that vary
with company characteristics. Our model shows that VCs may strategically
choose not to include "extra" DP for higher-quality companies,
because the cost of an overweighting entrepreneur rejecting the
investment is higher. Further, VCs may strategically suggest expert
lawyers to better entrepreneurs.
Finally, one prediction of the model, which cannot be tested with
our data, is that entrepreneurs with higher-quality companies should be
less likely to experience break-downs in contract negotiations. This
prediction follows both because VCs endogenously are less likely for
higher-quality entrepreneurs to include contract terms that the
entrepreneurs do not understand, and because VCs optimally choose to
introduce higher-quality entrepreneurs to expert legal counsels who can
explain the payoff consequences of contract terms to them. VCs do this
for better entrepreneurs in order to avoid incurring the high
opportunity cost of rejection. In contrast, VCs do not make such
introductions to entrepreneurs with lower-quality companies. This
increases the likelihood that negotiations break down. Rather, VCs offer
these entrepreneurs less attractive contracts with more DP that may
appeal to those who underweigh the adverse payoff consequences, but are
more likely to be rejected by less optimistic entrepreneurs. This
mechanism adds a friction to the VC market that is conceptually distinct
from agency and adverse selection problems.
VI. CONCLUSION
Our paper begins with the observation that not all contracting
parties may understand the payoff implications of all financial contract
terms. We develop and test a theoretical model of this in the venture
capital setting, where contracts are particularly complicated. We show
that the presence of entrepreneurs who may not fully understand DP can
induce a VC to propose unnecessary DP. By doing so, the VC can
expropriate an "optimistic" entrepreneur, who underweighs the
consequences of DP, even though they may sometimes negotiate with a
"pessimistic" entrepreneur, who overweighs those consequences,
and hence would be excessively likely to reject a contract with DP. We
explore this trade-off, and observe that this trade-off vanishes when
the entrepreneur is represented by an expert legal counsel. That is, we
predict that expert legal counsel should be associated with less DP,
unless the entrepreneur is experienced and therefore need not rely on
expert advice. We also predict that the cost to the VC of having a
pessimistic entrepreneur reject a contract rises with the
entrepreneur's quality. As a result, the VC offers better
entrepreneurs contracts with less DP. Indeed, if the quality of the
entrepreneur's company is high, we predict that the VC has an
endogenous incentive to recommend expert counsel to the entrepreneur,
giving rise to assortive matching between entrepreneurial quality and
the VC expertise of their counsel.
We confirm these predictions for a novel sample of 908 VC
contracts. Because these associations are derived based on the
counsel's VC-specific expertise and not on the counsel's
general expertise, we can rule out alternative explanations that are
based on a lawyer's bargaining power or negotiation skills. One
could think of ways other than counsel expertise to identify informed
entrepreneurs. For example, entrepreneurs whose companies are older may
have more knowledge about complicated contracts. However, older
companies likely differ in many other ways that affect contracting: the
conceptual advantage of our identification strategy is that expert
counsels can clearly provide information about DP, but such expertise
seems not to matter along other dimensions. By documenting how the use
of DP varies systematically with an entrepreneur's legal adviser,
and the assortive matching of entrepreneur quality along VC but not
general expertise dimensions, we add to a small but growing literature
on the determinants of VC contracts. These insights may be more broadly
relevant in contracting settings that feature complicated contract
terms.
The key feature of VC contracting that makes cognition costs matter
is that each entrepreneurial project is idiosyncratic, with its own
distinct set of issues and incentives. This means that the optimal
contract will hinge sensitively on the project in ways that an
inexperienced entrepreneur is unlikely to understand. This means that
the optimal contract must be tailored to the particular circumstances,
making it difficult to determine whether a contract is appropriate.
To see the importance of this feature, observe that in a
franchising setting, an inexperienced franchisee may also not understand
some incentives. But a potential franchisee does understand that each
franchise is in a similar boat. Hence, to determine whether he/she is
being exploited, a franchisee only has to verify whether he/she is
receiving the same contract as others. As a result, a franchisee can
draw the correct inferences about a contract, so a lack of understanding
does not matter. Cognition issues would also not be relevant in repeated
intermediary supply contracting between sophisticated firms. There, the
initial stakes are likely low, and so the gain from exploitation is
small, and repetition speeds learning. In contrast, cognition issues can
affect contracting over strategic alliances or negotiating book and
movie rights. Like entrepreneurship, these settings are complex, with
idiosyncratic high stakes and substantial uncertainty about what should
be done and about what payoffs will be, where, for example, Google may
know far more than its "partner."
ABBREVIATIONS
DP: Downside Protection
DPI: Downside Protection Index
IPO: Initial Public Offering
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
VC: Venture Capitalist
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12088
APPENDIX
Proof of Proposition 1
Suppose that [zeta] = 0. Note that for any contract {[s.sub.1], 1}
(with DP, there exists a contract, {[s.sub.0], 0} without DP that is
payoff equivalent for the VC given that the contracts are accepted by
:he entrepreneur:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
implying that the probability the entrepreneur accepts contract
{[s.sub.1], 1} is strictly less,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Hence, if [zeta] = 0, and i = 1, the VC chooses d = 0. That d = 1
if [zeta] = 1 is immediate.
Proof of Proposition 2.
Consider the pure equity contract, {[s.sub.0], 0} that is payoff
equivalent for the VC to {[s.sup.*.sub.1[, 1} given that it is accepted
by the entrepreneur. As [delta] [right arrow] 0, note that
[[alpha].sub.t] ([s.sup.*.sub.1], 1; q) [right arrow] [[alpha].sub.t]
([s.sub.0]; 0; q). The VC prefers the contract with DP only if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
As [delta] [right arrow] 0, the left-hand side goes to
[[summation].sub.t[member of]{u,p,o}][p.sub.t][[alpha].sub.t]
([s.sup.*.sub.1], 1; q)
[[integral].sub.[epsilon]][s.sub.0]q[epsilon]f([epsilon])d[epsilon],
implying that the VC prefers the contract with DP only if
[[summation over (t[member of]{u,p,o}] [p.sub.t][[alpha].sub.t]
([s.sup.*.sub.1], 1; q) > [[alpha].sub.p]{[s.sub.0], 0; q) =
[[alpha].sub.p] ([s.sup.*.sub.1], 1;q).
Subtracting [[alpha].sub.p] ([s.sup.*.sub.1], 1; q) from both sides
delivers the result. To see that the implication goes the other way,
consider the optimal pure equity contract {[s.sup.*.sub.0], 0}, and let
([s.sub.1], 1) be the payoff-equivalent contract. Then as [delta] [right
arrow] 0, the VC prefers the contract without DP only if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Hence, {[s.sup.*.sub.0], 0} is preferred only if
[summation over (t[member of]{u,p,o}]
[p.sub.t][[alpha].sub.t]([s.sub.1], 1; q) < [[alpha].sub.i]
([s.sup.*.sub.0], 0;q).
Subtracting [[alpha].sub.i] ([s.sup.*.sub.0], 0; q) from both sides
yields the result.
Proof of Proposition 4.
When [delta] [right arrow] 0, [q.sup.*] solves
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
To establish the single-crossing property, suffices to show that at
[q.sup.*],
(A2) [p.sub.u] ([[alpha].sub.u] ([s.sup.*.sub.1] (q), 1; q) -
[[alpha].sub.p] ([s.sup.*.sub.1](q), 1; q))' < [p.sub.o]
([[alpha].sub.p] ([s.sup.*.sub.1](q), 1; q) - [[alpha].sub.o]
([s.sup.*.sub.1](q), 1;q))'.
Substitute for--at using Equations (Al) into (A2) yields
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
which holds by elasticity condition El.
REFERENCES
Aspatore Books Staff. Analyzing VC Deal Terms: Leading Lawyers on
Structuring Term Sheets, Developing Negotiation Strategies, and
Assessing Risks. Boston: Aspatore Books, 2008.
Anderlini, L., and L. Felli. "Incomplete Written Contracts:
Undescribable States of Nature." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
109, 1994, 1085-124.
--. "Incomplete Contracts and Complexity Costs." Research
in Economics, 58, 1999, 3-30.
--. "Bounded Rationality and Incomplete Contracts."
Theory and Decision, 46, 2004, 23-50.
Ashenfelter, 0., D. Bloom, and G. Dahl. "Lawyers as Agents of
the Devil in a Prisoner's Dilemma Game: Evidence from Long Run
Play." NBER Working Paper 18834, 2013.
Bartlett, J. Equity Finance: Venture Capital, Buyouts,
Restructurings and Reorganizations. New York: John Wiley & Sons,
1995.
Bengtsson, O., and D. Hsu. "How Do Venture Capital Partners
Match with Startup Founders?" SSRN Working Paper 1568131, 2010.
Bengtsson, O., and S. Ravid. "The Importance of Geographical
Location and Distance on Venture Capital Contracts." SSRN Working
Paper 1331574, 2009.
Bengtsson, O., and B. Sensoy. "Investor Abilities and
Financial Contracting: Evidence from Venture Capital." Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 20, 2011, 472-502.
--. Forthcoming. "Changing the Nexus: The Evolution and
Renegotiation of Venture Capital Contracts." Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis.
Block, R., and J. Stiebler. "The Impact of Attorneys and
Arbitrators on Arbitration Awards." Industrial and Labor Relations
Review, 40, 1987, 543-55.
Bottazzi, L., T. Hellmann, and M. Da Rin. "What Is the Role of
Legal Systems in Financial Intermediation? Theory and Evidence."
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 18, 2009,559-98.
Broughman, B., and J. Fried. "Renegotiation of Cash Flow
Rights in the Sale of VC-Backed Firms." Journal of Financial
Economics, 95, 2010, 384-99.
Coates, J. "Explaining Variation in Takeover Defenses: Blame
the Lawyers." California Law Review, 89, 2001, 1301-421.
Comelli, F., and O. Yosha. "Stage Financing and the Role of
Convertible Securities." Review of Economic Studies, 70,2003,1-32.
Cumming, D. J. "Contracts and Exits in Venture Capital
Finance." Review of Financial Studies, 21, 2008, 1947-82.
Cumming, D. J., and N. Dai. "Why Do Entrepreneurs Switch Lead
Venture Capitalists?" Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37,
2013, 2013-17.
Cumming, D. J., and S. A. Johan. "Preplanned Exit Strategies
in Venture Capital." European Economic Review, 52, 2008, 1209-41.
Dye, R. "Costly Contract Contingencies." International
Economic Review, 26, 1985, 233-50.
Gompers, P. "An Examination of Convertible Securities in
Venture Capital Investments." Working Paper, 1998.
Harcourt, M. "How Attorney Representation and Adjudication
Affects Canadian Arbitration and Labor Relations Board Decisions."
Journal of Labor Research, 21, 2000, 149-59.
Hart, O. "Financial Contracting." Journal of Economic
Literature, 39, 2001, 1079-100.
Kaplan, S., and P. Stromberg. "Financial Contracting Meets the
Real World: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Capital Contracts."
Review of Economic Studies, 70, 2003,281-316.
Kaplan, S., and P. Stromberg. "Characteristics, Contracts, and
Actions: Evidence from Venture Capitalist Analyses." Journal of
Finance, 59, 2004, 2177-210.
Kaplan, S., F. Martel, and P. Stromberg. "How Do Legal
Differences and Experience Affect Financial Contracts?" Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 16, 2007, 273-311.
Lerner, J., and A. Schoar. "Does Legal Enforcement Affect
Financial Transactions? The Contractual Channel in Private Equity."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 2005, 223-46.
Metrick, A., and A. Yasuda. Venture Capital and the Finance of
Innovation. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, 2010.
Puri, M., and D. Robinson. "Optimism and Economic
Choice." Journal of Financial Economics, 86. 2007, 71-99.
Sahlman, W. "The Structure and Governance of Venture Capital
Organizations." Journal of Financial Economics, 27, 1990,473-521.
Sorensen, M. "How Smart Is Smart Money? A Two-Sided Matching
Model of Venture Capital." Journal of Finance, 62, 2007, 2725-62.
Suchman, M. "On Advice of Counsel: Law Firms and Venture
Capital Funds as Information Intermediaries in the Structuration of
Silicon Valley." Doctoral dissertation, Stanford University, 1994.
Tirole, J. "Cognition and Incomplete Contracts." American
Economic Review, 99, 2009, 265-94.
Vronsky, P. "Venture Capital Law Firms: An Analysis of Equity
Investments and Networks, " in Oxford Handbook of Venture Capital,
Chapter 20, edited by D. J. Cumming. New York: Oxford University Press,
2012, 602-26.
Zarutskie, R. "The Role of Top Management Team Human Capital
in Venture Capital Markets: Evidence from First-Time Funds."
Journal of Business Venturing, 25, 2010, 155-72.
(1.) As one lawyer who specializes on VC investments observes,
"in the majority of situations, the [entrepreneur] client will not
understand most of the deal terms that are being proposed. Therefore, it
is up to me to explain [...]. Indeed, there is generally a big
difference in what VCs understand and what your typical entrepreneur
understands going into a venture capital deal" (Aspatore Books
Staff 2008, 45).
(2.) A limitation is that our data lack information about control
rights.
(3.) Cumming and Johan (2008) also find that the experience of the
entrepreneur affects contracting. In their sample of European VC
investments, experienced entrepreneurs are more likely to get financed
with common equity, which has no DP. Further, experienced entrepreneurs
are not significantly more likely to employ lawyers with VC expertise,
reinforcing that complementarities between entrepreneur quality and
lawyer VC expertise do not drive our empirical findings.
(4.) This result indicates that our model can be distinguished from
search-based explanations for the positive correlation between q and
having a good legal counsel, in which an increase in q raises the
benefit of an expert legal counsel, so that better entrepreneurs search
harder for expert legal counsels. DP, whether necessary or not, has a
smaller impact on better entrepreneurs. Thus, a search-based explanation
would require that expert legal counsels provide services other than
just evaluating DP, and better entrepreneurs would have to value those
services by more.
(5.) Our 908 contracts represent about half of the 1,804 contracts
in Bengtsson and Ravid (2009). Our sample is smaller for two reasons.
First, we study only contracts for which we can identify legal counsels.
Second, to avoid issues with cross-correlated standard errors, we
restrict our sample to one contract per company--our results are robust
to including multiple contracts for a company.
(6.) This measure of lawyer expertise persists over time. The
correlation for number of advised companies in 2005-2008 (our sample
period) and 2001-2004 is very high.
(7.) The results remain qualitatively similar if we instead use
ordered logit regressions.
(8.) In untabulated robustness tests, we use other measures of VC
experience, such as the age of the firm and the prior success rate of
its investments. We also include separate dummies for corporate VCs,
financial VCs, and government-related VCs. Results on lawyer experience
remain unchanged.
(9.) The results remain qualitatively similar if we instead cluster
on industry, year, or company location.
(10.) Cumming and Johan (2008) have a related finding: experienced
entrepreneurs are more likely to be financed with common equity than
preferred equity, which gives them less contractual DP.
(11.) Sorensen also finds that VC reputation correlates with
successful exits because higher-quality VCs are better able to add value
and monitor their portfolio companies. Arguably, if such post-investment
treatment adds more to better firms, this may reinforce the importance
of matching between entrepreneurs and their legal counsels.
(12.) The equity value of high-quality companies does not directly
influence matching, because law firms advising venture-backed companies
currently receive compensation in cash and not company stock. Prior to
the "dot-com crash" of the early 2000s (which is before our
sample period), equity compensation was more common.
OLA BENGTSSON ([dagger]) and DAN BERNHARDT *
* We thank Murillo Campello, Rafael da Matta, Dirk Hackbarth,
Yelena Larkin, and Berk Sensoy, and seminar participants at
DePaul/Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Cornell University. Indiana
University, Lund University, Research Institute of Industrial Economics,
Law and Society Meeting, and American Law and Economics Conference for
helpful comments. We are grateful to VCExperts and Joseph Bartlett for
access to the contract data, and to Neely Tang and Bonny Lee for
valuable research assistance. All remaining errors are our own.
([dagger]) Shortly after this paper was accepted, Ola Bengtsson was
diagnosed with leukemia. Ola passed away on January 5, 2014. Ola will be
missed by everyone.
Bengtsson: Department of Economics, Lund University.
Bernhardt: Department of Economics and Department of Finance,
University of Illinois; Department of Economics, University of Warwick,
U.K. Phone 217-244-5708, Fax 217-244-6678, E-mail danber@illinois.edu;
M.D.Bemhardt@warwick.ac.uk
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics
Number of Standard
Observations Mean Deviation
Counsel VC Expertise Counsel VC 908 39 40
number of deals
Counsel VC top ranked 908 0.63 0.48
Counsel VC practice area 908 0.87 0.33
Counsel VC office in Silicon 908 0.51 0.50
Valley
Counsel General Expertise 908 0.05 0.21
Counsel General AMLaw Top 10
Counsel General AMLaw Top 25 908 0.17 0.38
Counsel general revenue (000s) 694 554,000 338,000
Counsel general lawyers 701 706 401
Counsel general entry salary 653 151,714 12,136
Counsel general revenue/lawyer 694 761.437 93,697
Counsel general gross profit 694 0.36 0.07
margin
Contract DP
Downside protection index (DPI) 908 4.64 1.54
Other Variables
Pre-money valuation (000s) 507 51,400 63.600
Round number 908 2.81 1.58
Total round amount (000s) 908 12,200 13,300
Number of VCs in round 908 4.31 2.64
Company in California 908 0.49 0.50
High technology industry 908 0.39 0.49
Life science industry 908 0.30 0.46
Serial founder 908 0.24 0.43
Serial founder with IPO 908 0.07 0.25
Company age 908 4.07 2.72
VC in California 908 0.50 0.50
VC and company in same state 908 0.49 0.50
VC partnership 908 0.81 0.39
VC experience 908 136 164
VC age 908 15 11
VC IPO ratio 908 0.15 0.08
Minimum Maximum
Counsel VC Expertise Counsel VC 1 114
number of deals
Counsel VC top ranked 0.00 1.00
Counsel VC practice area 0.00 1.00
Counsel VC office in Silicon 0.00 1.00
Valley
Counsel General Expertise 0.00 1.00
Counsel General AMLaw Top 10
Counsel General AMLaw Top 25 0.00 1.00
Counsel general revenue (000s) 99,000 1,620,000
Counsel general lawyers 162 3,082
Counsel general entry salary 100,000 160,000
Counsel general revenue/lawyer 413,352 1,051,020
Counsel general gross profit 0.22 0.63
margin
Contract DP
Downside protection index (DPI) 0.00 11.00
Other Variables
Pre-money valuation (000s) 910 493,000
Round number 1.00 5.00
Total round amount (000s) 50 110,000
Number of VCs in round 1.00 17.00
Company in California 0.00 1.00
High technology industry 0.00 1.00
Life science industry 0.00 1.00
Serial founder 0.00 1.00
Serial founder with IPO 0.00 1.00
Company age 0.00 10.00
VC in California 0.00 1.00
VC and company in same state 0.00 1.00
VC partnership 0.00 1.00
VC experience 1 797
VC age 0 47
VC IPO ratio 0.00 0.53
Notes: One observation is one contract between a venture-backed
company and its lead VC investor. Counsel General Expertise variables
are from the 2007 edition of American Lawyer 200. Each contract is
matched by company name and round date with an investment round
listed in Venture Economics. All VC variables are updated to match
the year of the contract. Table 2 details the coding of cash flow
contingencies that we aggregate to compute the downside protection
index (DPI). Lead VC is identified as the largest investor in the
round.
TABLE 2
Description of the Cash Flow Contingencies and their Coding
Cumulative Dividends: Dividends that the investor earns annually
until the company is sold or liquidated. Cumulative means that the
dividends are not paid out annually, but when the company is sold or
liquidated. Cumulative dividends are senior to common stock.
Above 8% = 2 8% or Below = 1 Not Included = 0
Number of 42 (5%) 170 (19%) 696 (77%)
observations
Liquidation Preferences: The multiple of the investors investment
that is paid back to the investor when the company is sold or
liquidated. Liquidation preference is senior to common stock.
Above 2X = 2 Above IX, Up to 2X = 1 IX = 0
Number of 7 (1%) 51 (6%) 850 (94%)
observations
Participation: With participation the investor receives both a
liquidation preference and a fraction of common stock when the
company is sold or liquidated. With "Capped" participation, the
investor only receives the liquidation preference if his/her
investment IRR is below a certain hurdle. With no participation, the
investor holds convertible preferred stock.
Not Capped = 2 Capped = 1 Not Included = 0
Number of 371 (41%) 237 (26%) 300 (33%)
observations
Antidilution-. The investor is issued additional shares if the
company raises a new financing round at a lower valuation than what
the investor paid (down round). "Full Ratchet" gives the investor
more additional shares than "Weighted Average," especially if the new
financing round is small.
Weighted
Full Ratchet = 2 Average = 1 Not Included =0
Number of 14 (2%) 832 (92%) 14 (2%)
observations
Redemption: The investor has the right to sell his/her shares back to
the company after a specified time period. A typical redemption right
provision gives the investor the right to sell back 1/3 of his/her
shares after 5 years, 1/3 after 6 years, and the remaining 1/3 after
7 years.
Included = 1 Not Included = 0
Number of observations 434 (48%) 474 (52%)
Pay-to-Play. Pay-to-Play provisions specify what contractual rights
the investor loses if he/she does not invest in a follow-up financing
round of the company. With "Convert to Preferred," the investor loses
some contractual rights (typically antidilution rights) that are
attached to his/her preferred stock. With "Convert to Common," the
investor loses all contractual rights that are attached to his/her
preferred stock.
Convert
Not Included = 2 Preferred = 1 Convert Common = 0
Number of 746 (82%) 36 (4%) 126 (14%)
observations
Notes: Each cash flow contingency contributes 0. 1. or 2 to the
downside protection index (DPI), where 2 is the most DP.
TABLE 3
DP and Legal Counsel Expertise, Univariate
Panel A: Downside Protection Index and Counsel VC Expertise,
Different Proxies
Less More
Expertise Expertise Difference Significance
Counsel VC # 4.86 4.39 0.47 0.00
deals
Counsel VC top 4.92 4.48 0.44 0.00
ranked
Counsel VC 5.11 4.58 0.53 0.00
practice area
Counsel VC office 4.82 4.48 0.35 0.00
in Silicon
Valley
All four counsel 5.17 4.36 0.81 0.00
proxies combined
Panel B: Separate Cash Flow Contingencies and Counsel VC Expertise
Less More
Expertise Expertise Difference Significance
Cumulative 0.40 0.15 0.25 0.00
dividends
Liquidation 0.08 0.07 0.01 0.86
preference
Participation 1.28 0.97 0.32 0.00
Antidilution 1.09 1.01 0.09 0.01
Redemption 0.49 0.39 0.11 0.07
Pay-to-play 1.83 1.75 0.08 0.33
Panel C: Downside Protection Index and Counsel General Expertise,
Different Proxies
Less More
Expertise Expertise Difference Significance
Counsel general 4.65 4.44 0.22 0.74
AmLaw top 10
Counsel general 4.65 4.61 0.05 0.98
AmLaw top 25
Counsel general 4.59 4.54 0.05 0.69
revenue
Counsel general 4.54 4.57 -0.04 0.88
lawyer
Counsel general 4.68 4.44 0.24 0.02
revenue per
lawyer
Counsel general 4.53 4.60 -0.07 0.50
gross profit
margin
Counsel general 4.50 4.57 -0.07 0.59
entry salary
Notes: Panel A presents the mean downside protection index (DPI) for
different sorts on Counsel VC Expertise. All four Counsel Proxies
Combined takes the value 1 if each proxy of Counsel VC Expertise
takes the value 1, and 0 if each proxy takes the value 0. Panel B
presents the mean for separate cash flow contingencies for Counsel VC
Expertise, based on all four proxies combined. See Table 2 for a
description of separate contract terms and their codings. Panel C
presents the mean (DPI) for different sorts on counsel general
expertise. Low (High) Expertise for nonbinary variables includes
variables below (above) the sample median. Rank test is a Wilcoxon
rank-sum test of difference of means.
TABLE 4
Downside Protection Index and Legal Counsel VC Expertise
Specification 1 2 3
Dependent variable
(log) Counsel VC# deals -0.155 ***
[0.034]
Counsel VC top ranked -0.290 ***
[0.104]
Counsel VC practice area -0.434 ***
[0.163]
Counsel VC office in SV
(log) Total round amount -0.137 *** -0.145 *** -0.150 ***
[0.048] [0.048] [0.048]
(log) VC Experience -0.229 *** -0.240 *** -0.248 ***
[0.055] [0.055] [0.055]
VC Partnership -0.404 *** -0.417 *** -0.405 ***
[0.109] [0.112] [0.111]
VC, Company same state -0.353 *** -0.362 *** -0.382 ***
[0.119] [0.117] [0.116]
(log) #VCs in round 0.349 *** 0.362 *** 0.382 ***
[0.115] [0.113] [0.112]
(log) Company age 0.303 *** 0.298 *** 0.306 ***
[0.085] [0.088] [0.089]
Serial founder -0.040 -0.037 -0.020
[0.166] [0.168] [0.169]
Serial founder with IPO -0.188 -0.184 -0.175
[0.211] [0.214] [0.215]
Serial founder with merger -0.020 -0.026 -0.057
[0.186] [0.186] [0.189]
Constant 8.291 *** 8.211 *** 8.499 ***
[0.767] [0.780] [0.788]
Observations 908 908 908
[R.sup.2] 0.12 0.11 0.11
VC location FE No No No
Company location FE No No No
Company industry FE No No No
Contract year FE No No No
Round number FE No No No
Specification 4 5 6
Dependent variable DPI
(log) Counsel VC# deals -0.163 ***
[0.032]
Counsel VC top ranked -0.333 ***
[0.100]
Counsel VC practice area
Counsel VC office in SV -0.210 *
[0.115]
(log) Total round amount -0.155 *** -0.063 -0.072
[0.050] [0.044] [0.044]
(log) VC Experience -0.246 *** -0.235 *** -0.243 ***
[0.054] [0.059] [0.059]
VC Partnership -0.404 *** -0.382 *** -0.389 ***
[0.111] [0.112] [0.113]
VC, Company same state -0.382 *** -0.132 *** -0.122 ***
[0.119] [0.118] [0.120]
(log) #VCs in round 0.366 *** 0.198 *** 0.208 ***
[0.115] [0.115] [0.117]
(log) Company age 0.293 *** 0.122 *** 0.122 ***
[0.092] [0.101] [0.103]
Serial founder -0.031 -0.112 -0.110
[0.168] [0.148] [0.149]
Serial founder with IPO -0.167 -0.093 -0.088
[0.218] [0.189] [0.190]
Serial founder with merger -0.037 0.024 0.014
[0.188] [0.204] [0.206]
Constant 8.318 *** 6.602 *** 6.518 ***
[0.782] [0.935] [0.914]
Observations 908 908 908
[R.sup.2] 0.10 0.24 0.23
VC location FE No Yes Yes
Company location FE No Yes Yes
Company industry FE No Yes Yes
Contract year FE No Yes Yes
Round number FE No Yes Yes
Specification 7 8
Dependent variable
(log) Counsel VC# deals
Counsel VC top ranked
Counsel VC practice area -0.469 ***
[0.162]
Counsel VC office in SV -0.239 **
[0.116]
(log) Total round amount -0.077 * -0.081 *
[0.044] [0.045]
(log) VC Experience -0.250 *** -0.246 ***
[0.058] [0.059]
VC Partnership -0.372 *** -0.368 ***
[0.113] [0.114]
VC, Company same state -0.144 *** -0.132 ***
[0.122] [0.121]
(log) #VCs in round 0.217 *** 0.211 ***
[0.117] [0.118]
(log) Company age 0.129 *** 0.130 ***
[0.105] [0.105]
Serial founder -0.096 -0.114
[0.149] [0.148]
Serial founder with IPO -0.082 -0.055
[0.195] [0.195]
Serial founder with merger -0.013 0.012
[0.208] [0.203]
Constant 6.692 *** 6.574 ***
[0.900] [0.907]
Observations 908 908
[R.sup.2] 0.23 0.22
VC location FE Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes
Notes: Table 2 details how we compute the Downside Protection
Index (DPI). A higher DP means that the contract includes more
investor- friendly cash flow rights. OLS regressions. Specifications
5-8 include fixed effects for VC firm location (California,
Massachussets, Texas, New York, and other), company location (state),
company industry (Venture Economics 10-group classification), round
year, and round number. Standard errors are clustered by counsel and
reported in brackets.
Significance at 10% level marked with *, 5% with **, and 1% with ***.
TABLE 5
Downside Protection Index and Legal Counsel VC and General Expertise
Specification 1 2 3
Dependent variable
(log)Counsel VC #deals -0.247 ***
[0.058]
Counsel VC top ranked -0.619 ***
[0.175]
Counsel VC practice area -0.760 ***
[0.188]
Counsel VC office in SV
(log)Counsel VC #deals 0.124 *
X Follow-up round [0.071]
Counsel VC top rank 0.405 *
X Follow-up round [0.212]
Counsel VC practice area 0.495 *
X Follow-up round [0.277]
Counsel VC office in SV
X Follow-up round
(log)counsel VC # deals
X Serial founder
Counsel VC top ranked
X Serial founder
Counsel VC practice area
X Serial founder
Counsel VC office in SV
X Serial founder
Counsel gen AmLaw top 25 -0.017 0.064 -0.005
[0.104] [0.115] [0.113]
Observations 908 908 908
[R.sup.2] 0.24 0.23 0.23
Full set of company, VC,
Round, founder controls Yes Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes Yes
Specification 4 5 6
Dependent variable DPI
(log)Counsel VC #deals -0.197 ***
[0.040]
Counsel VC top ranked -0.463 ***
[0.129]
Counsel VC practice area
Counsel VC office in SV -0.508 ***
[0.161]
(log)Counsel VC #deals
X Follow-up round
Counsel VC top rank
X Follow-up round
Counsel VC practice area
X Follow-up round
Counsel VC office in SV 0.391 **
X Follow-up round [0.189]
(log)counsel VC # deals 0.155 *
X Serial founder [0.086]
Counsel VC top ranked 0.502 *
X Serial founder [0.229]
Counsel VC practice area
X Serial founder
Counsel VC office in SV
X Serial founder
Counsel gen AmLaw top 25 0.001 -0.033 0.047
[0.118] [0.105] [0.118]
Observations 908 908 908
[R.sup.2] 0.23 0.24 0.23
Full set of company, VC,
Round, founder controls Yes Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes Yes
Specification 7 8
Dependent variable
(log)Counsel VC #deals
Counsel VC top ranked
Counsel VC practice area -0.619 ***
[0.169]
Counsel VC office in SV -0.281 *
[0.151]
(log)Counsel VC #deals
X Follow-up round
Counsel VC top rank
X Follow-up round
Counsel VC practice area
X Follow-up round
Counsel VC office in SV
X Follow-up round
(log)counsel VC # deals
X Serial founder
Counsel VC top ranked
X Serial founder
Counsel VC practice area 0.678 **
X Serial founder [0.340]]
Counsel VC office in SV 0.173
X Serial founder [0.241]
Counsel gen AmLaw top 25 -0.014 0.001
[0.113] [0.119]
Observations 908 908
[R.sup.2] 0.23 0.23
Full set of company, VC,
Round, founder controls Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes
Notes: Table 2 details how we compute the Downside Protection
Index (DPI). A higher DPI means that the contract includes more
investor-friendly cash flow rights. OLS regressions. All
specifications include fixed effects for VC firm location
(California, Massachussets, Texas, New York, and other), company
location (state), company industry (Venture Economics 10-group
classification), round year, and round number. All specifications
also include (log) Company Age, Serial Founder, Serial Founder with
IPO, Serial Founder with Merger, (log) Number of VCs in Round, (log)
Total Round Amount, VC and Company in Same State, (log) VC Experience
and VC Partnership dummy. Counsel General Expertise measured using
data from the 2007 issue of American Lawyer 200. Constant is
estimated, but not reported. Standard errors are clustered by counsel
and reported in brackets.
Significance at 10% level marked with *, 5% with **, and 1% with ***.
TABLE 6
Downside Protection Index, Interactions with Entrepreneur Experience
Specification 1 2 3
Dependent variable
(log) Counsel VC# deals -0.164 *** -0.163 *** -0.095 **
[0.032] [0.032] [0.039]
Counsel general AmLaw top 25 -0.076
[0.161]
Counsel general AmLaw top 10 -0.026
[0.104]
Counsel general (log) revenue -0.093
[0.062]
Counsel general (log) counsel
Counsel general (log) revenue
per counsel
Counsel general gross profit
margin
Counsel general entry salary
above median
Observations 908 908 694
[R.sup.2] 0.24 0.24 0.26
Full set of company, VC, round
Founder controls Yes Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes Yes
Specification 4 5
Dependent variable DPI
(log) Counsel VC# deals -0.087 ** -0.093 **
[0.038] [0.042]
Counsel general AmLaw top 25
Counsel general AmLaw top 10
Counsel general (log) revenue
Counsel general (log) counsel -0.076
[0.068]
Counsel general (log) revenue -0.138
per counsel [0 477]
Counsel general gross profit
margin
Counsel general entry salary
above median
Observations 701 653
[R.sup.2] 0.25 0.26
Full set of company, VC, round
Founder controls Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes
Specification 6 7
Dependent variable
(log) Counsel VC# deals -0.099 ** -0.159 ***
[0.039] [0.032]
Counsel general AmLaw top 25
Counsel general AmLaw top 10
Counsel general (log) revenue
Counsel general (log) counsel
Counsel general (log) revenue
per counsel
Counsel general gross profit -0.191
margin [0.644]
Counsel general entry salary -0.066
above median [0.068]
Observations 694 694
[R.sup.2] 0.26 0.24
Full set of company, VC, round
Founder controls Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes
Company location FE Yes Yes
Company industry FE Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes
Notes: Table 2 details how we compute the downside protection
index (DPI). A higher DPI means that the contract includes more
investor-friendly cash flow rights. OLS regressions. All
specifications include fixed effects for VC firm location
(California, Massachussets, Texas, New York, and other), company
location (state), company industry (Venture Economics 10-group
classification), round year, and round number. All specifications
also include (log) Company Age, Serial Founder, Serial Founder with
IPO, Serial Founder with Merger, (log) Number of VCs in Round, (log)
Total Round Amount, VC and Company in Same State, (log) VC Experience
and VC Partnership dummy. Counsel General Expertise measured using
data from the 2007 issue of American Lawyer 200. Constant is
estimated, but not reported. Standard errors are clustered by counsel
and reported in brackets.
Significance at 10% level marked with *, 5% with **, and 1% with ***.
TABLE 7
Legal Counsel VC Expertise and Matching Company Quality
Specification 1 2 3 4
Dependent variable (log) Counsel Counsel VC
VC # deals Top ranked
(log) Total round 0.131 *** 0.032 *
amount [0.048] [0.019]
(log) VC experience 0.175 **
[0.069]
VC IPO ratio 3.077 **
[1.025]
Observations 693 693 693 693
[R.sup.2] 0.22 0.23 0.24 0.14
Comp, age control Yes Yes Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Comp, industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Comp, location FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Specification 5 6 7 8
Dependent variable Counsel VC
Pract. area
(log) Total round 0.003
amount [0.013]
(log) VC experience 0.052 *** 0.021 *
[0.020] [0.012]
VC IPO ratio 0.791 ***
[0.293]
Observations 693 693 693 693
[R.sup.2] 0.14 0.14 0.21 0.22
Comp, age control Yes Yes Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Comp, industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Comp, location FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Specification 9 10 11 12
Dependent variable Counsel VC
Office
in Sil. Val.
(log) Total round 0.005
amount [0.022]
(log) VC experience 0.057 ***
[0.021]
VC IPO ratio 0.307 * 0.825 **
[0.159] [0.376]
Observations 693 693 693 693
[R.sup.2] 0.22 0.10 0.11 0.11
Comp, age control Yes Yes Yes Yes
VC location FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Comp, industry FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Comp, location FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Contract year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Round number FE Yes Yes Yes Yes
Notes: The specifications use different proxies for counsel VC
expertise (higher number means a more expert law firm).
Specifications 1-3 are OLS regressions. Specifications 4-12 are
probit regressions. All specifications include fixed effects for VC
firm location (California, Massachussets, Texas, New York, and
other), company location (state), company industry (Venture Economics
10-group classification), round year, and round number. Constant is
estimated, but not reported. Standard errors are clustered by counsel
and reported in brackets.
Significance at 10% level marked with *, 5% with **, and 1% with ***.
COPYRIGHT 2014 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2014 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.