Taxpayer willingness to pay for health insurance reform: a contingent valuation analysis.
Lavetti, Kurt ; Simon, Kosali ; White, William D. 等
Taxpayer willingness to pay for health insurance reform: a contingent valuation analysis.
A key criterion for evaluating policies to expand health insurance
coverage is weighing the costs of such policies against the willingness
of the public to pay for coverage expansions. We use new panel survey
data from New York State to estimate residents' willingness to pay
(WTP) to expand public insurance coverage. Using a nonparametric
double-bounded contingent valuation (CV) approach, we specifically ask
residents about their WTP to reduce the rate of uninsurance in the
state. Our results imply an aggregate lower-bound WTP of over $2,800 per
year to cover one person. We also analyze heterogeneity in WTP by
sub-group and changes in individual WTP over time between 2008 and 2010.
We find that a large majority of residents are willing to pay additional
taxes to reduce the number of uninsured in the state, and that average
WTP remained remarkably stable despite the economic downturn and the
politically polarized discussions surrounding the Affordable Care Act.
Decomposing the changes in individual WTP, we find that economic factors
related to the recession, including changes in income and employment
status, cannot explain changes in individual WTP, whereas individual
changes in political opinions about health insurance reform between 2008
and 2010 are strongly correlated with changes in WTP. (JEL H20, H42,
H51, H75,113)
I. INTRODUCTION
Public expansion of health insurance coverage has been a subject of
intense debate in the United States at both national and state levels,
especially in recent years (Epstein et al. 2009; Gruber 2008). The 2010
Affordable Care Act (ACA) puts
into motion substantial further increases in public health
insurance, most of which take effect in 2014. One reason for the
controversy surrounding the issue is that the costs of reform are
substantial and salient, (1) while the benefits are difficult to
estimate, and may include direct components from improving access as
well as indirect benefits associated with insurance against future risk
and altruistic concerns about fairness and equity.
The high costs of reform make it important to assess not only
whether people support reforms in principal, through polling or election
results, but also to estimate their willingness to pay (WTP) higher
taxes to finance reforms. That is, as Kessler and Brady (2009) put it,
it is important to examine the willingness of the public to "put
their money where their mouth is." In addition, there has been
recent interest among policymakers and academics in examining how
economic recessions affect support for tax-funded social safety nets
(Russell Sage Foundation 2011), which can be crucial for the long-run
viability of such policies. Finally, we also test whether public policy
debates prior to the passage of the ACA may have changed WTP directly by
affecting opinions about public insurance expansions.
Despite these concerns, there has been relatively little systematic
analysis of WTP for health reform. A handful of opinion polls have asked
whether respondents support increasing taxes to fund health insurance
reform, although none have been longitudinal studies of the same
individuals. Apart from one poll by Kessler and Brady (2009), these
polls do not specify the size of tax increases and do not elicit WTP
specifically. (2)
In their analyses, Kessler and Brady (2009) use a contingent
valuation (CV) approach and national survey data to measure support for
selected reforms. Specifically, they examine expansions of coverage that
would be financed through proportional increases in individual income
tax payments. Using individual-specific estimates of required tax
increases based on reported income, each respondent is asked whether
they would support a coverage expansion. Each respondent is only asked a
single "yes/no" question about their proposed tax increase.
However, the survey is repeated for three selected reforms--a subsidy
for private insurance, an expansion of Medicaid, or coverage of
individuals with chronic illness. In each case, some individuals are
asked if they would be willing to pay amounts that would cover 50% of
the estimated cost of reforms, while others are asked about amounts that
would cover 100% or 150%. Using this approach, Kessler and Brady compute
the percentage of respondents answering "yes" for each
reform/payment option. They do not, however, attempt to use their data
to make any dollar estimates of WTP either per respondent or per covered
beneficiary.
On the basis of their analysis of the percentages of respondents
supporting reforms, Kessler and Brady (2009) conclude that the lower the
estimated cost of reforms, the higher the percentage of respondents
willing to pay for reforms, but that except for coverage of the
chronically ill, only a minority of individuals are willing to pay the
increases in their taxes Kessler and Brady estimate will be required to
fund the programs. They also find that the percentage of respondents
willing to support reforms is lower at higher incomes. However, the
implication of this finding for the relationship between income and
absolute WTP is difficult to evaluate because the amounts asked in
Kessler and Brady's WTP questions are dependent on both income and
the progressivity of average federal income tax rates at the time
(higher income individuals are asked about their WTP larger amounts) and
the authors do not report any dollar estimates of WTP.
No study to date has estimated individual WTP by administering a
set of double-bounded questions. Nor has any study looked directly at
relationships between income and WTP holding constant the amounts asked,
or estimated how other demographic factors may affect heterogeneity in
individual WTPs. There also has been no attempt to validate concordance
between WTPs and stated opinions regarding health reform.
The passage of the ACA in 2010 shifted attention towards national
reforms, whereas during the prior two decades states had been very
active in health policy. However, attention has recently shifted back
towards the states, which, since the U.S. Supreme Court ruling in 2012
regarding Medicaid expansions, face decisions about the willingness of
voters to support state-specific public insurance expansions (KFF
2013a). New York State in particular is of interest because it is a
large, wealthy state and has taken a leadership role in establishing a
state insurance exchange as well as in expanding Medicaid coverage (KFF
2013b).
In this paper, we use a CV approach to estimate willingness of New
York State residents to pay higher taxes to fund public policies to
reduce uninsurance in the state. Specifically, we consider three
questions. First, what is the WTP higher general taxes for hypothetical
reforms to reduce the rate of uninsurance in the state, both overall and
specifically for low-income individuals? Second, how does WTP vary with
individual sociodemographic characteristics and with views on specific
types of health reform proposals? Third, how does WTP change
longitudinally, and what factors, including changes in economic
conditions and opinions about reform, may be correlated with those
changes?
In exploring these questions, we seek to contribute to the
literature on WTP for reforms in several ways. First, we use a
double-bounded CV approach to provide lower-bound estimates of aggregate
WTP for public health insurance expansion. Second, in addition to
looking at relationships between WTP and sociodemographic
characteristics, we consider how WTP corresponds with individuals'
self-reported views on reform. Third, we use standardized longitudinal
data to consider changes in WTP for reforms and their correlates. To our
knowledge, all three aspects of this research are new to the literature.
We find that there is broad-based WTP to reduce uninsurance among
New York State residents. The lower-bound WTP amounts are substantial
when judged against several possible cost estimates of covering the
uninsured. For example, in 2008, for both our overall and low-income
proposals, more than 70% of respondents indicated a WTP at least $25 in
higher taxes annually to reduce uninsurance in the state by a quarter.
Our lower-bound estimates of the average WTP higher taxes are about $95
and $90 annually per resident for the low-income and overall referenda,
respectively. Taking into account the number of residents and the number
of individuals who are uninsured in New York State, these estimates
imply average lower-bound WTPs of about $2,881 (3) and $3,465, (4)
respectively, to insure one additional person for one year. (5)
There are several different cost benchmarks that one could compare
with these estimated benefits. One approach is to compare our estimates
of WTP against Medicaid costs. Medicaid costs are relevant not only
because they provide a general indicator of the possible costs of
expanding coverage, but because state decisions about implementing
Medicaid expansions has emerged as a major policy issue under the ACA.
(6) The national average cost of Medicaid coverage in 2009 was $2,900
for an adult and $2,305 for a child, and the New York State average
costs were $4,277 and $2,505, respectively. (7) Another possible
benchmark is the marginal cost of Medicaid expansion under the ACA,
rather than the average cost per beneficiary prior to expansion.
Estimates based on analyses by the Urban Institute (2012) suggest that
marginal costs of expanding Medicaid in New York State would be about
$1,080 per beneficiary coverage-year. (8) An alternative benchmark is
the cost of obtaining coverage through a state exchange. Under approved
rates for individual coverage effective 2014 for the New York State
Benefits Exchange, the cost of the most affordable standardized
"Bronze" plan will be $3,029 per year. (9) Thus, our 2008
lower-bound WTP estimates of $2,881-$3,465 suggest that New York State
residents would be willing to pay amounts to expand coverage that are
comparable to the cost of either traditional Medicaid expansions or
expansions through private insurance purchased on the state exchange.
The national average premium for private group coverage was higher
however, at $4,669 in 2009, as reported in the Medical Expenditure Panel
Survey (AHRQ 2009).
In addition, we find WTP (measured in absolute dollars) is higher
when indicators of socioeconomic status (SES) are higher and that
individual WTP is correlated in expected ways with opinions about
support for health insurance reform policies, consistent with
individuals being willing to "put their money where their mouths
are." As noted, we also find that average WTP remained remarkably
stable between 2008 and 2010, despite both the onset of a major
recession in late 2008 that peaked in 2010, and an intense debate over
the ACA in 2009 through early 2010 that could have shifted attention
towards national reforms. There is, however, considerable variation
within individuals in their WTP over time. Interestingly, this
individual variation is not explained by changes in economic factors,
such as employment and health insurance coverage, and is more strongly
correlated with changes in individual opinions about specific health
insurance reform mechanisms.
We briefly describe our conceptual framework for analyzing WTP in
Section II. Section III describes the data, while Section IV describes
our estimation methods and findings. Section V discusses study
limitations, and Section VI concludes. II.
II. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK
The primary assumption in this research is that an
individual's reported WTP for the proposed policy captures
information about their underlying preferences for the policy that would
not necessarily be captured by measures of the direct impact of
policies, for example by estimates of the impact of an expansion in
health insurance coverage on recipient health outcomes. A person's
preferences for expanding coverage may be influenced not only by direct
self-interest, but also by altruism. Thus, individuals may be motivated
by "warm-glow" or altruistic benefits related to their beliefs
about the appropriate roles of government, fairness and equity, and this
may be reflected in their WTPs. In addition, of course, preferences may
reflect individuals' own self-interest and their current and
anticipated future coverage. Individuals who are currently uninsured may
have a direct interest in expanding coverage. For example, Krueger and
Kuziemko (2013) use a similar survey elicitation strategy to estimate
the willingness of the uninsured to pay for their own coverage and find
that over 60% of the uninsured would be willing to pay $2,000 per year
to purchase insurance if that option were available to them immediately.
Likewise, individuals who currently have private coverage may have a
preference for expanding coverage as insurance against the risk of
becoming uninsured in the future. In the case of individuals with public
coverage, it is possible they may support expanding coverage as they
have already benefited from such coverage, but it is also possible that
they could oppose it if they believe that an expansion could be
accompanied by cutbacks in existing benefits.
In order to gain a deeper understanding of preferences, and to
verify that responses plausibly capture preferences, we also estimate
how WTPs vary with sociodemographic characteristics such as age, gender,
race, and educational attainment, as well as with general political
opinions and specific opinions about several health insurance reform
proposals.
A natural starting point is to question how WTP changes with
income. Our discussion of preferences for reforms to expand coverage
suggests two possible hypotheses. The first is that WTP may increase
with income for altruistic reasons. Consistent with this is research on
the relationship between altruism and income such as Andreoni (1990) and
Feldstein and Taylor (1976), which finds that among high-income groups,
donations to public goods increase with income. However, offsetting this
effect, WTP for self-interested reasons may decrease with income if
higher income individuals are less likely to be uninsured or are less
likely to anticipate potentially benefiting from expanded public
coverage; although we cannot disentangle the two types of effects, we
can estimate their net impact. In addition to income, we also examine
how other components of SES (including insurance coverage) relate to
WTP, conditional on income.
In the face of concerns that CV analysis elicits respondents'
true preferences, responses to opinion questions about individuals'
political convictions and support for particular types of reforms
provide possible indicators of their concordance. Although these opinion
measures are often highly correlated with income, education, and other
SES measures, opinion and political ideology polls are widely believed
to track closely with actual behavior in voting, which is the
relationship we are interested in validating. In general, we expect that
self-identified liberals will be more likely to support a publicly
funded expansion of coverage than conservatives (KFF). Following Bundorf
and Fuchs (2008), we hypothesize that those with more favorable views of
government intervention may be more likely to support universal
coverage, suggesting that WTP will be higher among individuals who
support reform options such as universal Medicare or universal mandates.
(10)
Over time, WTP may be affected by changes in respondents'
economic status and insurance coverage and by changes in their opinions
about reform. We collected data from our respondents in two periods: the
first quarter of 2008 just prior to the onset of the 2008 recession, and
the first quarter of 2010, just prior to the passage of the ACA, a
period of intense policy debate about reform. We hypothesize that
economic factors may impact WTP directly through effects on employment,
income, and insurance coverage. If personal resource availability falls,
this may reduce support for expanding coverage for altruistic reasons,
but support may increase for self-interested reasons to the extent
individuals become or expect to become uninsured so that the predicted
net impact is ambiguous.
At the macro level, the economic downturn may have the increased
perceived need for reform, but also raised concerns about the ability to
pay for it. Concurrently, the policy debate about the ACA may have
increased awareness of issues surrounding health reform, increasing
intensity of opinions pro and con, while shifting attention away from
state-level reforms towards national reforms. While we lack a way to
disentangle these various effects, we can test the extent to which WTP
is associated with changes in employment, income, insurance status, and
opinions about reforms at the individual level.
When attempting to generalize results from one state, it is
important to keep in mind that WTP estimates may be affected by factors
specific to New York State. For example, the state has a highly
regulated insurance market, which may cause respondents to believe that
high WTP is needed to afford policies in that state. It is also possible
that respondents rarely interact with the individual health insurance
market and are not aware of specific costs of coverage. New York is also
an outlier state in tax policy, and this could lead to either lower or
higher WTP for coverage reforms, relative to other states. These factors
should
all be kept in mind when considering the results of a single state
study. However, New York State's high level of policy activity also
makes it important to investigate in light of the ACA implementation
process.
III. DATA
Our analyses use data from three surveys of New York State
residents. The first two are state-representative cross-sectional
surveys, each with 800 respondents, conducted in the first quarters of
2008 and 2010 as parts of the Cornell University Empire State Polls
(ESPs). (11) The sampling frames were split equally between upstate and
downstate residents to allow comparisons between these geographic
sub-regions, and sample weights allow us to produce estimates that are
representative of the state as a whole. Within the sample frames, phone
numbers were randomly selected, giving each household an equal chance of
being included. Within each household, the surveyor asked to speak to
the adult resident whose birth date was closest to a randomly selected
date, giving each adult within the household an equal chance of being
selected, thus making it an individual-level survey. (12) In addition to
the 2008 and 2010 cross-sectional surveys, we commissioned a special
follow-up survey in the first quarter of 2010 in which the 2008 ESP
sample was resurveyed, creating a longitudinal sample of 411 of the
original 800 respondents.
The survey was targeted at individuals, rather than at households.
As a result there was a large proportion of individuals who were
randomly selected to participate in the survey, but whom we were unable
to successfully contact to request their participation. Of those whom we
successfully contacted, 69.3% completed the survey in 2008. (13)
Similarly, for the 2010 ESP and 2010 follow-up survey, 72.9% and 96%,
respectively, of those who were contacted completed the survey. The
higher completion rate of the 2010 follow-up sample is likely due to the
fact that they had already completed the 2008 survey. The vast majority
of nonresponses to each survey was due to bad or disconnected telephone
numbers, or because after at least six attempts there was no successful
contact. Including potential respondents that we were never able to
contact to request participation as nonresponders, the response rates
were 23.3%, 34.6%, and 51%, respectively.
The first round of the survey was conducted during the first
quarter of 2008, just after the peak of the business cycle in December
2007, when the unemployment rate was under 5% in New York State and the
share of nonelderly state residents without health insurance at some
point during the year was 13.8%. The second round was conducted during
the first quarter of 2010, just before the ACA was signed into law. By
this time the state unemployment rate was at a peak of 8.9%, while the
share of nonelderly state residents without health insurance had risen
to 16.7% (BLS 2012; U.S. Census 2012).
As our main outcome measure, respondents to the ESP were asked a
set of double-bounded questions about their WTP for a hypothetical
policy that would reduce the rate of uninsurance in the state by
one-quarter. In order to isolate support only for an increase in the
prevalence of health insurance, our WTP survey question intentionally
avoided discussion of the specific reform policy that might be used to
potentially achieve such results. Two slightly different variants of
this WTP question were asked. In 2008, half the respondents were asked
if they would support a referendum to reduce the overall rate of
uninsurance in the state by one-quarter ("overall
referendum"). The other half were asked if they would support a
referendum to reduce the rate of uninsurance by one-quarter among those
in the state who earn less than 300% of the FPL. We refer to this as a
targeted "low-income referendum" in the rest of the text. In
2010, to minimize respondent burden, and upon seeing data from 2008
suggesting that the difference in the wording of the question appeared
to have very little effect on responses, respondents to the 2010
cross-sectional survey were only asked about the "overall
referendum." However, the 411 followup respondents in 2010 were
asked the same version of the question that they answered in 2008. (14)
Our surveys also include questions about demographics, education,
employment, income, health insurance coverage, and political philosophy
(liberal, middle of the road, or conservative). Respondents were also
asked a series of questions eliciting opinions regarding health reform,
based on a similar survey conducted in New Jersey by Cantor et al.
(2007) and modified for New York State by Simon and White (2008).
Opinion questions that we use in our analyses include: how important it
was for state government leaders to work to reduce the costs of health
insurance ("cost important") and the number of uninsured
("# uninsured important"); whether respondents support
mandates requiring large employers to provide health insurance to their
employees ("large employer mandate"); whether they support a
universal health insurance mandate ("universal mandate"); and,
in 2008 only, we asked whether they support allowing high-deductible
plans to be offered in New York State. (15) Some opinion questions, such
as "cost important" and questions about particular proposals,
use a 4-point Likert scale. In these cases responses are coded as 1 if
respondents indicated that an issue was "extremely important"
or "very important" or they "strongly favor" or
"somewhat favor" a proposal and are coded as 0 if respondents
indicated that the issue was "somewhat important" or "not
important" or "somewhat oppose" or "strongly
oppose" a proposal. (16)
IV. METHODS AND FINDINGS
We use these survey data to answer three questions: First, in each
survey, how much are respondents willing to pay to reduce uninsurance?
Second, using cross-sectional data, what determines an individual's
WTP? Third, utilizing longitudinal data, what factors are associated
with changes in an individual's WTP over time?
A. CV Method
We assess WTP for health insurance reform by using CV, an approach
developed to estimate the value of goods for which no markets exist, a
common feature of most public goods. CV has been used extensively since
its validation during litigation surrounding the Exxon Valdez oil spill
in 1989, for example in Donaldson (1990), Philips et al. (1997), and
Cawley (2008). The CV method provides an estimate of the Hicksian
compensating variation in monetary welfare associated with the
referendum in question. In the context of health insurance expansion,
compensating variation measures how much a respondent would pay and
remain indifferent between the current state and the state in which
taxes are higher and public health insurance is expanded.
During the initial work in 1989 that validated the use of CV in
economics, the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration appointed
a panel of expert economists, including Kenneth Arrow, Robert Solow,
Paul Portney, Edward Learner, Roy Radner, and Howard Schuman, to study
whether CV methods can be used reliably to estimate the values of
nonmarket, passively used goods. The panel issued a report including
recommended practices for CV estimation, which proposed the following
guidelines: (1) use probability sampling; (2) use survey approaches that
allow high response rates; (3) conduct interviews personally or over the
telephone, as opposed to eliciting values through the mail or in
today's terms, the Internet; (4) pretest the survey; (5) report
sample statistics and WTP by respondent characteristics; (6) format the
question as one of WTP for a referendum, since this is a more
conservative design; (7) provide respondents with the option of
abstaining from voting, in addition to the "yes" and
"no" voting options; (8) remind respondents that their WTP for
a referendum would reduce their remaining budget for other goods (Arrow
et al. 1993). A recent review of the literature on CV analysis by Kling,
Phaneuf, and Zhao (2012) and work by Carson (2012) suggests that this
consensus on best practices for CV analysis continues to hold; we follow
all of these eight recommendations. Specifically, our surveys adhered to
recommendations (1)--(4) and (6)-(8), and the analysis we report in the
paper follows recommendation (5). Further, while a common criticism of
CV methods is that they are used to value things that are difficult to
conceptualize, our analysis focuses on a policy change that provides a
good that is relatively easy to conceptualize and value (Kling, Phaneuf,
and Zhao 2012). (17)
In all three surveys (2008 ESP, 2010 ESP, and 2010 follow-up), for
the overall referendum version of our WTP question, we began by asking
respondents the question below. The low-income referendum added the
italicized text in brackets.
"Suppose there is a new voter referendum in the state. The
referendum is a proposal to fund policies that will reduce uninsurance
in the state by a quarter [among families earning less than three times
the poverty level, which is about $60,000 for a family of 4 (low-income
version)]. Set aside for now how it will reduce uninsurance, but assume
it will do so with certainty. If the referendum passes, you and everyone
else will have to pay $50 more in taxes every year. Given your current
budget, would you vote for or against this referendum?"
Possible responses of the hypothetical taxpayers were to vote, for
the referendum, vote against it, not vote, or choose a "don't
know" option. To more narrowly estimate each respondent's WTP,
respondents were then asked up to two additional dichotomous choice
questions that depended on responses to the initial question. If
respondents indicated that they would vote for such a referendum, they
were then asked if they would be willing to pay $100, and then $250 if
they responded affirmatively to the $100 question. If respondents were
unwilling to vote for the referendum at a cost of $50, they were asked
if they would be willing to pay $25, and then $5. These amounts are the
same for all respondents, and do not vary by the income of the
respondent.
An important methodological issue is how best to estimate WTP from
responses to these types of questions. The concern in particular is that
there are infinitely many continuous distributions of underlying
preferences that are consistent with the sets of discrete responses
observed in the data, and different distributions can imply different
mean values of the WTP. Our approach is to estimate a lower bound on
respondents' WTP based on responses to these questions in the most
conservative way possible, and without imposing distributional
assumptions. Specifically, we assign to each respondent a WTP equal to
the highest cost at which they respond "yes" to the referendum
question. For example, if a respondent says "yes" to $50 and
"no" to $100, the lower-bound estimate is $50. Individuals who
respond "no" to all questions are given WTP equal to zero.
This estimation approach is known commonly as the Turnbull
distribution-free estimator (e.g., see Haab and McConnell 2003). Using
this approach, mean and median estimates of WTP do not require any
information other than that contained in survey responses. (18)
B. Descriptive Statistics
Table 1 presents summary statistics for responses to questions
about health reform, sociodemographic characteristics, and political
preferences in each of the three sub-samples described in the data
section. The columns on the right of Table 1 indicate significant
differences in mean values between pairs of surveys. The vast
The average characteristics of the two crosssectional samples are
fairly similar. As expected, the share of the sample that was employed
dropped from 65% to 60%, consistent with the macroeconomic downturn. The
panel respondents also look fairly similar to the full 2008 sample, with
the exceptions that the follow-up respondents are slightly more likely
to be married and white. Comparing the responses of the panel sample in
2008 and 2010 (Columns B and C) for time-varying questions shows that
fewer respondents thought that healthcare costs and the number of
uninsured in the state should be top priorities for lawmakers, and that
support for the universal mandate declined, consistent with the
cross-sectional patterns.
C. The Distribution of WTP
Figure 1 shows the distribution of lower bounds on
respondents' WTP for each of the samples. In the full 2008
cross-sectional surveys, out of 800 respondents, 432 were asked whether
they would support a referendum to reduce the overall rate of
uninsurance by one-quarter (overall referendum) and 368 were asked
whether they would support a referendum to reduce by one-quarter the
rate of uninsurance among those who earn less than 300% of the FPL
(low-income referendum). About 86.4% of overall referendum respondents
and 88.3% of low-income referendum respondents indicated willingness to
support such a referendum at a cost of at least $5 per respondent. These
percentages are both substantially higher than the fractions of
respondents who reported being willing to pay higher taxes to expand
health insurance in earlier polls in which the size of tax increases was
not specified. Moreover, the share of respondents who would vote in
support of the referenda remains substantial at higher levels of tax
increases. 76.37% and 80.91% of the overall and low-income respondents
indicated they were willing to support paying a cost of at least $25,
while 64.3% and 62.8% indicated, respectively, a willingness to support
paying at least $50. In the 2010 survey we did not ask the low-income
referendum question, but results were similar for the overall
referendum. Out of 800 respondents in 2010, 88% indicated a WTP at least
$5, 76.20% indicated a WTP at least $25, and 60% a WTP at least $50. In
both cross-sectional surveys the modal lower-bound WTP was $250, and the
second most prevalent range of WTPs was $100 to $250 for all of the 2010
survey groups, as shown in Figure 1. WTP was also noticeably more
polarized in 2010 than it was in 2008, as the percentage of respondents
with WTP below $5 jumped from 13.3% in the 2008 full sample to 17.5% in
the 2010 full sample. (19)
Tables 2 and 3 show the mean lower-bound estimates of WTP, which
are relatively stable across the two referenda questions and over time.
The mean lower-bound WTP based on the full 2008 cross-sectional sample
was $95.09 per resident-year for the overall referendum, and $90.35 for
the low-income referendum. (20) In 2010, respondents indicated a similar
mean lower-bound WTP of $93.33 for the overall referendum.
The primary purpose of our WTP analyses is to provide information
that could be of use in cost-benefit analyses of public policies that
expand insurance coverage. An intuitive way to express our WTP estimates
is to normalize them to a beneficiary-year level and compare them to
typical costs for health insurance. For illustration, in 2008 there were
about 19.4 million people in New York State. Using our mean lower-bound
WTP estimates from 2008, and assuming our samples are representative of
state residents, yields a lower-bound estimate of total WTP of about
$1.84 billion for the overall proposal, and $1.75 billion for the
low-income proposal. At the same time there were 2.56 million (21)
uninsured residents in New York, about 2.02 million (22) of whom earned
less than 300% of the FPL. This implies an average WTP per beneficiary
coverage-year of at least $2,881 for the overall proposal, and at least
$3,465 for the low-income proposal, about 20% more per beneficiary
coverage-year.
The difference in WTP per beneficiary between the overall and
low-income proposals arises because, even though the WTP per resident is
fairly similar for both proposals, implying a similar total aggregate
WTP, including nonlowincome uninsured substantially increases the total
population that would need to be covered. One possible explanation for
the similarity is that respondents generally believed that most of the
uninsured were in the low-income category (<300% FPL), even when they
were asked about the uninsured in general. That is, respondents may have
been unaware that responding with a similar WTP for the overall and the
low-income referenda implies a lower level of funding per beneficiary
per year for the overall referendum, since there are substantially more
uninsured residents than there are residents who are both uninsured and
low-income. A second possible explanation is that respondents were
unwilling to support as high a level of funding per beneficiary when
both high-income and low-income people were covered. We cannot
distinguish between these two cases in our data.
The cost-benefit analysis of interest to policymakers is to compare
these measures of benefits to the actual costs of public insurance
expansions. As previously discussed, there are several different types
of health insurance packages that could be used to increase coverage,
but our lower-bound estimates of the benefits of coverage expansion for
low-income residents are higher than estimated costs of expansion
through either Medicaid or private insurance based on approved rates for
individual coverage that will become available in the state exchange in
2014, suggesting that the costs and benefits justify low-income
expansions, and possibly even income-neutral expansions.
We also estimated alternative parametric models using these data,
but such models require additional structural assumptions. (23) Our
estimates are highly sensitive to these distributional assumptions on
the upper tail because a large share of the respondents to our survey
fell into the highest WTP category, so we prefer to avoid distributional
assumptions. Although the large share in the highest WTP category is a
drawback to estimating an upper bound WTP and to using parametric
estimates, this does not affect the main conclusion of our work as the
conservative lower-bound estimates of WTP are in the vicinity of actual
costs for Medicaid expansions. We discuss this point further in Section
VI.
D. Validation of Cross-Sectional CV Estimates
An important component of CV analyses is validating that estimates
could plausibly reflect respondents' preferences by carefully
examining whether variation in WTP reflects expected patterns. We test
hypotheses from our conceptual framework by first reporting how WTP
changes with income. We next estimate correlations between a full set of
respondent characteristics, including demographics and opinions, and
support for the proposed referenda using a probit model.
Tables 2 and 3 report the average lower-bound WTP estimates by
household income for each survey sample. As shown, there is broad
support for paying higher taxes to fund the referenda at all income
levels. For the full sample in 2008, among respondents with household
incomes above $200,000 per year, WTP was $133.52, compared to $59.99 for
respondents in households with incomes below $30,000 per year. In the
full 2010 sample the respective mean WTPs were $136.51 and $81.97.
Figure 2 shows the full distributions of WTP within each income group
for the general referendum sample in 2008. A notable feature of this
figure is that the share supporting successively higher proposed tax
amounts drops at a much slower rate among individuals from higher income
households, relative to those from lower-income households. For
households with income below $30,000, the share supporting the overall
referendum drops from over 85% at a cost of $5 to under 10% at a cost of
$250, while for households earning over $200,000 it only falls from 80%
to 45%.
The income results in Tables 2 and 3 and in Figure 2 are in the
direction consistent with altruism being a normal good, but the income
gradients are not as high as one might expect, perhaps because of the
countervailing effect exerted by the decreased need for public coverage
as income increases. While these findings may seem at odds with Kessler
and Brady's (2009) finding that support is higher at lower-income
levels, they reflect quite different methods and are not necessarily
contradictory.
As noted earlier, in our survey the amounts in the WTP questions
are uniform, whereas WTP questions in Kessler and Brady change according
to income, with reference amounts being substantially higher at higher
incomes. This would mean, for example, that someone with an income of
$125,000 may be asked a dollar amount many times the amount asked of
someone with an income of $30,000, so that even if a high-income
individual says "no" to large estimated tax increase, their
maximum WTP could still exceed that of a low-income individual who says
"yes" to a small increase. Consequently, although Kessler and
Brady do not express their results in the form of dollar estimates of
WTP, it is possible that their data could imply comparable aggregate WTP
estimates. At the same time, it is still possible that because our WTP
lower bounds for the highest income group (>$200,000) is about the
same as that for the next highest group (>80,000 to <200,000), we
too might find that WTP may not increase as rapidly with income as it
would need to if progressive or even proportional taxation were used to
finance the expansion.
To further examine the correlates of referendum support, we turn to
multivariate results from a probit regression model. Since the data
include dichotomous choice questions with follow-up questions, there are
multiple responses per individual. The latent model is expressed as:
[[??].sub.i] = [x.sub.i][beta] + [[epsilon].sub.i]
where [[??].sub.i] is a 5 x 1 vector of continuous values
indicating support for the referendum in question at each possible cost
($5, $25, $50, $100, and $250), [x.sub.i], is a 5 XK matrix that
includes demographic characteristics and opinions about health insurance
reform and referendum costs, and [[epsilon].sub.i] N(0,
[[SIGMA].sub.i]), allowing for within-person correlation. We observe:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
This model is estimated separately for the 2008 and 2010 rounds of
the survey, and for each version of the referendum question.
Table 4 reports the probit estimates of support based on data from
the two proposed referenda questions in the 2008 sample, and the general
referendum question in the 2010 sample. Reported marginal effects
suggest support for all referenda decreases with the cost of the reform,
as expected. A $ 100 per respondent increase in taxes decreases support
for the referenda by about 30 percentage points.
We find that responses to the opinion questions about health care
reform are also highly correlated with willingness to support the
referenda. Respondents who indicated support for a universal mandate
were willing to pay higher taxes to support the referenda, and were
between 9 and 25 percentage points more likely to support the referenda.
Respondents who thought that the number of uninsured people in the state
was an important issue to address were not necessarily more likely to
support the referenda raising taxes in 2008, but by 2010 they were 16
percentage points more likely to support it. Respondents to the
low-income referendum question in 2008 and to the overall referendum
question in 2010 who indicated support for a universal Medicare-style
program were 18 and 24 percentage points, respectively, more likely to
support the referenda. These findings suggest that when it comes to
paying for reforms, New Yorkers broadly are prepared to put their
"money where their mouth is," although amounts may not
necessarily be proportional to the costs of reforms.
Turning to sociodemographic variables, respondents with less than
high school educations were less likely to support the referenda,
suggesting that this demographic group responds more to the burden
aspect of the tax than to the fact that they themselves are
statistically more likely to benefit from the reforms. Self-identified
liberals were slightly more likely than people who classified themselves
as "middle of the road" to support the referenda, while
conservatives were slightly less likely to support the overall
referendum, consistent with findings in Bundorf and Fuchs (2008) that
those with more favorable views of government intervention were more
likely to support universal coverage. Although the marginal effect of
income in the model is negligible, income is strongly correlated with
other included covariates, such as employment and education. The
positive income and WTP correlation is presumably absorbed by these two
sets of variables, which tend in the same direction as the bivariate
income comparison. (24) In the Appendix, we present results from
additional specifications that test whether WTP results are affected by
the inclusion of detailed measures of an individual's current
source of coverage; we find little evidence that source of coverage
affects WTP. Table 4 also indicates that those who live in upstate New
York have lower WTP, which may reflect the realization that upstate
residents would cross-subsidize downstate residents, where the cost of
care is higher, and/or that upstate residents have relatively less to
gain from a coverage expansion since the rate of uninsurance is higher
in the downstate area.
E. Changes in WTP During the Great Recession
The second part of the analysis focuses on factors that lead
individuals to change their stated WTP over time. Panel data analysis of
CV is relatively novel to the literature, and the only other paper we
know of that uses this method is Gartoulla, Liabsuetrakul, and Pradhan
(2010), who estimate changes in the WTP for obstetric care in Nepal.
Both within-person intertemporal variation in WTP and the repeated
cross-sectional variation provide valuable information about the
stability of preferences over time. The specific time period of
February-March 2008 to February-March 2010 is of particular interest for
this analysis because of the deep recession that took place in between
the two dates. Specifically, we are interested in whether people prefer
governments to increase the size and generosity of health insurance
social safety nets during economic downturns or whether they more
strongly prefer the government to reduce the tax burden on households,
and how these changes in preferences depend upon changing circumstances.
At the same time, as noted, the latter part of our study period was
marked by intense debate over the ACA which may have influenced opinions
about reform as well. As discussed, while we cannot fully disentangle
the combined effects of the recession and the ACA debates, we can
examine the extent to which individuals' WTPs have been associated
with changes in their economic circumstances and in their opinions about
reform.
Of the 411 respondents who were surveyed in 2008 and again in 2010,
192 were asked both times about an overall referendum and 219 were asked
both times about the low-income referendum. As reported in Tables 2 and
3, average WTP remained remarkably stable during the study period. The
mean lower-bound WTP for the overall referendum fell slightly from
$99.87 to $85.14 in 2010, and rose slightly from $91.60 to $93.35 for
the low-income referendum. However, despite the stability of mean WTPs,
over time there were substantial within-person changes.
Figure 3 shows the lower-bound WTP estimates in 2010 by each
respondent's 2008 WTP, focusing on low-income referendum
respondents. Although not shown, the figure looks very similar for the
overall referendum. Only 37% of respondents reported no change in WTP
between 2008 and 2010. Further, people whose WTPs were in the tails of
the distribution in 2008 were the most likely to report the same WTP in
2010. Conversely, those who were in the middle in 2008 were the most
likely to report a different WTP in 2010. Since the mean lower-bound WTP
changed very little between 2008 and 2010, by implication the 63% of
respondents who changed their WTP reported changes that largely
counteracted each other.
Using the panel sample, we estimate how changes in individual
economic conditions, such as employment status, income, and insurance
status, and changes in opinions about health reform, affect changes in
WTP. The empirical model is:
[DELTA] WT[P.sub.i] = [DELTA][x.sub.i], [beta] + [[epsilon].sub.i]
where the independent variables that change over time include
income, employment status, insurance status, and opinions about health
insurance reform questions. (25) Each covariate except for income is
included asymmetrically to test, for example, whether gaining a job has
a different effect than losing a job.
Table 5 presents the estimates from this model. Results based on
the overall referendum question suggest that losing one's own
insurance tends to reduce WTP significantly, by about $208. Consistent
with the cross-sectional findings, this suggests that those who are most
likely to gain insurance personally are less willing to pay for the
referenda.
In the low-income sample, those who became employed between 2008
and 2010 were less willing to pay for reform, with a mean decrease of
$74. This could be due to the fact that being employed is positively
correlated with having health insurance, so gaining employment reduces
demand for insurance, and the demand for reform that provides insurance.
However, in the cross-sectional probit model this effect was positive,
suggesting that those who have been employed continuously are more
willing to pay than those who are newly employed, all else equal. The
results also highlight the importance of changing political opinions.
Those who changed their minds between 2008 and 2010 and became
supporters of a universal Medicare system increased their WTP on average
by about $59, while a change in opinion in the opposite direction was
associated with a reduction in WTP of about $30. Those who became
supporters of a large employer mandate decreased their WTP taxes to
support alternative government-led reform described in the referendum
proposals by about $51. These findings are informative in two ways. The
correlations between changes in opinions and changes in WTP further
validate that the WTP measure is correlated with preferences in each
period. Second, while the opinion questions have no causal
interpretation, and simply reflect preferences that are not captured by
economic variables alone, they are informative in clarifying that
changes in WTP were driven heavily by factors other than changes in
personal economic outcomes during the recession.
A concise and informative way to convey how economic changes and
opinion changes affected WTP is to decompose the aggregate change into
components due to each type of variable. To do this we estimate an
Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition model (26):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The first term in this decomposition tells us how changes in
observable characteristics between 2008 and 2010 led to changes in WTP
holding constant the effects of characteristics at their 2008 levels.
The second component tells us how changes in the effects of
characteristics on WTP contributed to the overall change. To put these
components in context, one question we are interested in investigating
is whether and how WTP changes with individual conditions, such as
unemployment, the prevalence of which rose in New York State from 4.9%
in the first quarter of 2008 to 8.9% in the first quarter of 2010 (BLS
2012). The model decomposes changes in reported WTP into a component due
to changes in the employment status of respondents, and a separate
component due to changes in the effect on WTP of being employed in 2010
versus being employed in 2008.
The results of this decomposition are shown in Table 6. There are
two sets of variables included in the decomposition: those related to
changes in opinion, and those related to changes in socioeconomic
wellbeing. The socioeconomic changes include changes in income,
employment status, and health insurance coverage (either gaining or
losing insurance). Regarding the overall referendum, the change in the
mean lower-bound WTP predicted by the change in the explanatory
variables is a decrease of $12.66. This decrease is composed of an $8.65
decrease attributable in a mechanical sense to observed changes in SES
and opinions about insurance reform, and a $4.03 decrease due to a
change in the effect that these variables have on WTP. (27) The second
row of the table shows estimates from a model that includes only
socioeconomic characteristics as explanatory variables, and the
explanatory power of changes in these characteristics is nearly zero.
Estimates in the third row are from a model that only includes opinion
variables. Results show that changes in opinions alone explain nearly
the entire decrease in lower-bound WTP estimated in the full model. This
implies that changes in individual economic outcomes explain a very
small share of the total change in WTP, while other factors that are
correlated with opinions about health care reform had much larger
effects.
One possible interpretation of these findings is that the debates
leading to the passage of the ACA increased the level of information
about health insurance reform, or changed opinions in other ways that
directly affected preferences over WTP for reforms. However, changes in
opinions themselves are not causal mechanisms, and could instead pick up
changes in other characteristics that are also correlated with our
measure of WTP, including changes in economic conditions at both
individual and macroeconomic levels. In any case, these findings suggest
two broad take-a-ways. First, regardless of the interpretation of the
impacts of changes in opinion, consistent with our cross-section
findings, views on reform are strongly correlated with WTP for it.
Second and perhaps more strikingly, changes in individual economic
conditions appear to have had very little direct effect on WTP despite
the magnitude of the economic downturn during the study period.
Table 6 also shows there is less total change in WTP for the
low-income referendum question, so the decomposition is somewhat less
informative. The mean change in WTP was positive $6.69, but the
components had opposite signs. Changes in characteristics explain a
$3.22 decrease in WTP, which was more than offset by a $7.29 increase in
WTP caused by changes in coefficients and a positive interaction term.
Again, when we include only economic variables the included variables
explain almost none of the mean change in WTP, whereas when we include
only changes in opinions the results closely match those of the full
model.
In summary, we use a double-bounded CV approach to estimate the
nonparametric lower-bound WTP in order to answer the three questions
relevant to health policy towards the uninsured, finding that (1) there
is a high prevalence of positive individual WTP, where the estimated
aggregate WTP is at least as high as $2,800 to cover one uninsured
person per year, which is close to the actual average cost nationally
for Medicaid; (2) correlates of WTP are largely as expected, for
example, WTP increases with income; (3) average WTP stayed remarkably
stable over time, despite the economic and political changes between
2008 and 2010. In addition, at the individual level, we find that
changes in political opinions about health insurance reform are strongly
correlated with changes in WTP, while economic factors related to the
recession, such as changes in income and employment, are not. These
findings move the literature forward in several dimensions. Prior polls,
apart from one, have not elicited specific responses about WTP, and no
prior study has used a set of double-bounded questions or examined how
demographics affect WTP. Nor has any prior study examined whether there
is concordance between WTPs and stated opinions regarding health reform.
We next discuss limitations of our work, before concluding with the
lessons to be drawn for public policy.
V. CAVEATS
There are several important limitations to the analyses in this
paper. One limitation, as with all CV analyses, is that hypothetical
answers are not necessarily representative of actual behavior, or how
voters in other states or other periods of time would respond to the
same hypothetical questions (e.g., the WTP of New York State residents
may be different from the national WTP). Arrow et al. (1993) recommend
using independently drawn samples at different points to assess the
reliability of responses to CV questions, which we do in this paper. A
second limitation is that responses to the ESP poll are affected by the
numerical prompts in the question, potentially causing psychometric
anchoring bias (Green et al. 1998). Anchoring has been found to be
problematic in other polls, but without variation in numerical prompts
across respondents, this is not testable using our data. A third
limitation is that a large proportion of our sample (more than 20%)
falls into the highest WTP category of supporting a $250 tax increase.
Although this is not problematic per se, it suggests that our
lower-bound estimate may substantially understate the true mean WTP as
many individuals may have been willing to pay substantially more than
$250. Given our lower-bound estimates show that aggregate WTP is
comparable to the actual costs of covering the uninsured under public
health insurance currently, for the purposes of the present analysis a
smaller lower-bound is not especially problematic. However, future
estimates of WTP could estimate mean WTP ranges more accurately using a
larger set of double-bounded questions.
Other possible problems are that our longitudinal analysis only
considers an economic downturn. Results from a downturn may not
necessarily be symmetric for a period of macroeconomic growth. Future
survey data could build upon our results to address this issue. In
addition, as discussed, debate surrounding the ACA may have influenced
responses to state-specific questions over time. Finally, as highlighted
earlier, survey results may, of course, be sensitive to the particular
framing of questions, and the choice of the sample population (New York
State). Our survey results indicate substantially broader support for
insurance reform than is suggested by other polls cited earlier in this
paper. Potential explanations include differences in the way questions
are framed, the use of a CV approach and targeting of different
geographic populations (e.g., a national sample or other states).
However, questions about generalizability remain.
VI. DISCUSSION
Despite the fact that uninsurance is a highly policy-relevant and
timely problem, cost-benefit analyses of reforms have been conspicuously
absent from discussions because of a lack of estimates of the benefits
of such reforms. In part this is due to the complicated nature of
calculating the benefits of providing public health insurance, which
could include direct short-term benefits, insurance against future risk
of becoming uninsured, and altruism. However, there is a history in
economics of using methods to elicit and measure benefits associated
with goods for which there are no observable markets. We use one such
method, CV, to estimate the WTP higher taxes to fund a policy that would
reduce the rate of uninsurance.
Combining CV methods with more carefully phrased questions that
directly specify cost yields estimates of the share of respondents
willing to pay any increased taxes to support increased coverage that
are substantially greater than previously reported estimates for
national and state-specific samples. Moreover, estimates of WTP indicate
broad-based and deep support that remained remarkably stable between
2008 and 2010, despite a major economic downturn and passage of national
reforms, which may have diluted support for state-specific reforms. We
find that in both 2008 and 2010 more than 80% of respondents were
prepared to pay some additional taxes to reduce the rate of uninsurance,
and the average nonparametric lower-bound estimate of WTP by New York
State residents exceeded $90 per respondent in both years. This implies
a lower-bound WTP of about $2,880 per beneficiary-year for an expansion
of coverage that is independent of income, and $3,465 for a policy that
targets low-income residents, which as discussed, is comparable to
potential costs associated with a Medicaid expansion or offering
coverage through a state exchange. Moreover, as discussed above, there
is reason to believe that our lower-bound estimates substantially
understate the average WTP.
One of the innovations in this paper is the use of panel data
covering 2008-2010 to conduct longitudinal CV analyses to address these
key questions about how respondents' views of the role of
government change when they face changing circumstances during
recessionary times. Our results reveal that despite the large economic
downturn, on balance the majority of people were still willing to pay
higher taxes for health insurance reform that would expand social safety
nets. This finding has important policy implications in gauging the
extent to which economic downturns could affect the long-run viability
of health insurance reform. Despite the fact that many respondents
changed their WTP over time, on net the changes balanced out. Moreover,
an Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition shows that these changes in WTP were not
driven by changes in individual economic outcomes, such as changes in
income and employment status. Instead we find that, conditional on
economic outcomes, changes in opinions about specific health insurance
reform proposals explain nearly all of the variation. Possible
explanations are that noneconomic variables correlated with opinions
were the primary drivers of changes in WTPs, or that changes in opinions
themselves, perhaps due to debates prior to the passage of the ACA,
causally affected WTP. In any case, our analysis finds a strong relation
between support for reforms and WTP for them.
ABBREVIATIONS
AAPOR: American Association for Public Opinion Research
ACA: Affordable Care Act
CATI: Computer-Assisted Telephone Interviewing
CV: Contingent Valuation
ESP: Empire State Poll
FPL: Federal Poverty Line
HSAs: Health Savings Accounts
SES: Socioeconomic Status
SRI: Survey Research Institute
WTP: Willingness to Pay
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12083
REFERENCES
Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality. "Center for
Financing, Access and Cost Trends." Medical Expenditure Panel,
Table I.C., 2009. Accessed March 12, 2014.
http://meps.ahrq.gov/mepsweb/data_stats/
summ_tables/insr/national/series_l/2009/ticl.pdf.
Andreoni, J. "Impure Altruism and Donation to Public Goods: A
Theory of Warm-Glow Giving." The Economic Journal 100(401),
1990,464-77.
Arrow, K., R. Solow, P. Portney, E. Learner, R. Radner, and H.
Schuman. "Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation."
Federal Register, 58(10), 1993, 4601-14.
Blinder, A. S. "Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and
Structural Variables." Journal of Human Resources, 8, 1973,436-55.
Bundorf, M. K., and V. R. Fuchs. "Public Support for National
Health Insurance: the Roles of Attitudes and Beliefs." Forum for
Health Economics and Policy, Frontiers in Health Policy Research, 10(1),
2008, 1-33.
Bureau of Labor Statistics. "Local Area Unemployment
Statistics, New York State (Series Id: LASST360000000000003)."
2012. Accessed March 12,2014.
http://data.bls.gOv/timeseries/LASST360000000000003.
Cantor, J., S. Brownlee, C. Zukin, and M. Roller. "New Jersey
Health Care Opinion Poll: Public Concerns and Support for Reform,"
2007. Accessed March 12, 2014.
http://www.cshp.rutgers.edu/Downloads/7530.pdf.
Carson, R. "Contingent Valuation: A Practical Alternative When
Prices Aren't Available." Journal of Economic Perspectives,
26(4), 2012, 27-42.
Cawley, J. "Contingent Valuation Analysis of Willingness to
Pay to Reduce Childhood Obesity." Economics and Human Biology, 6,
2008, 281-92.
Congressional Budget Office. "Updated Estimates for the
Insurance Coverage Provisions of the Affordable Care Act." March
2012. Accessed March 12, 2014. http://cbo.gov/sites/default/files/
cbofiles/attachments/03-13-Coverage%20Estimates.pdf (Tables 1 and 2).
Donaldson, C. "Willingness to Pay for Publicly-Provided Goods:
A Possible Measure of Benefit?" Journal of Health Economics, 9(1),
1990, 103-18.
Epstein, A., H. Aaron, K. Baicker, J. Hacker, and M. Pauly.
"Perspective Roundtable: Health Care Reform in Perspective."
New England Journal of Medicine, October 15, 2009. Accessed March 12,
2014. http://www.nejm.org/ doi/full/10.1056/NEJMp0909384#t=article.
Feldstein. M., and A. Taylor. "The Income Tax and Charitable
Contributions." Econometrica, 44(6), 1976, 1201-22.
Gartoulla, P. T. Liabsuetrakul, and N. Pradhan. "Change in
Willingness to Pay for Normal and Caesarean Section During Pregnancy and
After Delivery in Kathmandu." Tropical Medicine and International
Health, 15(10), 2010, 1227-34.
Green, D., K. Jacowitz. D. Kahneman, and D. McFadden.
"Referendum Contingent Valuation, Anchoring, and Willingness to Pay
for Public Goods." Resource and Energy Economics, 20(2). 1998.
85-116.
Gruber, J. "Covering the Uninsured in the United States."
Journal of Economic Literature, 46(3), 2008, 571-606.
Haab, T. C., and K. E. McConnell. Valuing Environmental and Natural
Resources: The Econometrics of Non-Market Valuation. Northampton, MA:
Edward Elgar Publishing. 2003.
Howard, Paul. "Building a Market-Based Health-Insurance
Exchange in New York." Manhattan Institute Report, 2011. Accessed
February 18, 2014. http://www. manhattan-institute.org/html/mpr_13.htm.
Jost, T. S., and M. Hall. "The Role of State Regulation in
Consumer-Driven Health Care." American Journal of Law and Medicine,
31, 2005, 395-418.
Kaiser Family Foundation (KFF). "Kaiser Health Tracking Poll:
Public Opinion on Health Care Issues." June 2009. Publication
#7925. Accessed February 18, 2014.
http://www.kff.org/kaiserpolls/upload/7925.pdf.
--. "Kaiser Public Opinion, Data Note: A Snapshot of Public
Opinion on the Individual Mandate." March 2012. Publication #8296.
Accessed February 18, 2014.
http://kaiserfamilyfoundation.files.wordpress.com/2013 /01/8296.pdf.
--. "State Decisions on Health Insurance Exchanges and the
Medicaid Expansion, as of June 20 2013." 2013a. Accessed July 11,
2013. http://kff.org/healthreform/state-indicator/state-decisions-for-creating- health-insurance-exchanges-and-expanding-medicaid/.
--. "State Exchange Profiles: New York." January 28,
2013. 2013b. Accessed July 10, 2013. http://kff.org/
health-reform/state-profile/state-exchange-profilesnew-york/.
Kessler, D., and D. W. Brady. "DataWatch: Putting the
Public's Money Where Its Mouth Is." Health Affairs, 28(5),
2009, w917-25, online issue.
Kling, C., D. Phaneuf, and J. Zhao. "From Exxon to BP: Has
Some Number Become Better Than No Number?" Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 26(4), 2012, 3-26.
Krueger, A. B., and I. Kuziemko. "The Demand for Health
Insurance Among Uninsured Americans: Results of a Survey Experiment and
Implications for Policy." Journal of Health Economics, 32(5), 2013,
780-93.
Musumeci, Mary Beth. "Implementing the ACA's Medicaid
Related Health Reform Provisions After the Supreme Court's
Decision." Focus on Health Reform: Report, August 2012, The Henry
J. Kaiser Family Foundation, 2012. Accessed July 15, 2013. http://
kaiserfamilyfoundation.files.wordpress.com/2013/01/ 8348.pdf.
New York Times. "Support for a Public Health Plan." 2009.
Accessed March 12, 2014. http://www.nytimes.com/ imagepages/2009/06/21
/health/policy/21 poli_graphic_ ready.html.
Oaxaca, R. "Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban Labor
Markets." International Economic Review, 14(October), 1973,
693-709.
Parente, S., and T. Bragdon. "Healthier Choice: An Examination
of Market-Based Reforms for New York's Uninsured." 2009.
Accessed March 12, 2014. http://www.
manhattan-institute.org/html/mpr_10.htm.
Phillips, K. A., R. K. Homan, H. S. Luft, P. H. Hiatt, K. R. Olson,
T. E. Kearney, and S. E. Heard. "Willingness to Pay for Poison
Control Centers." Journal of Health Economics, 16(3), 1997, 343-57.
Russell Sage Foundation. "Special Initiative on the Social and
Economic Effects of the Great Recession," 2011. Accessed March 12,
2014. http://www. russellsage.org/research/social-effects-great-recessiondescription.
Simon, K., and W. White. "Informing Health Care Reform Options
for New York State." Cornell University report written for New York
State Health Foundation, 2008. Accessed March 12,
2014.http://nyshealthfoundation.
org/resources-and-reports/resource/informing-healthcare-reform-options-for-new-york-state.
Supreme Court. National Federation of Independent Business et al.
v. Sebelius, Secretary of Health and Human Services, et al., 132 Supreme
Court of the United States 2566. 2012. Accessed February 18,
2014.http://www. supremecourt.gov/opinions/11pdf/11-393c3a2.pdf.
Survey Research Center. "Empire State Poll Introduction and
Method, Cornell University." 2008. Accessed February 18,
2014.http://www.sri.cornell.edu/sri/files/esp/
2008/Report_1_2008-Intro_Method.pdf.
--. "Empire State Poll Introduction and Method, Cornell
University," 2010.http://sri.cornell.edu/sri/files/esp
/2010/Report%201 %20-%202010%20-%20Introduction%20and%20Methodology.pdf.
Urban Institute. "The Cost and Coverage Implications of the
ACA Medicaid Expansion: National and Stateby-State Analysis," 2012.
Accessed July 2013. http://
www.urban.org/UploadedPDF/412707-The-Costand-Coverage-Implications-of-the-ACA-Medicaid- Expansion.pdf.
U.S. Census Bureau. "Small Area Health Insurance
Estimates," 2012. Accessed March 12, 2104. http://www.
census.gov/did/www/sahie/data/interactive/.
SUPPORTING INFORMATION
Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online
version of this article:
Appendix 1: Alternative Specifications of Probit Model of
Referendum Support Including Detailed Insurance Coverage*
(1.) For example, at the federal level, it has been estimated that
under the ACA, the total gross cost of expanding coverage to 30 million
uninsured Americans over the years 2012-2021 will be $1,496 billion (CBO
2012).
(2.) The 2008 and 2009 Kaiser Family Foundation (KFF 2008,2009)
Health Tracking Polls and a 2009 New York Times and CBS News poll (New
York Times, 2009) found the shares of respondents willing to pay higher
taxes to increase health insurance coverage ranged from 34% and 41% in
Kaiser polls to 57% in the New York Times/CBS poll. Kessler and Brady
(2009) found that 51.3% of respondents were willing to support a 5%
increase in federal income taxes to expand Medicaid to cover half the
uninsured and Cantor et al. (2007) found that 47.9% of certain New
Jersey residents were willing to pay more than $500 per year in taxes so
that "everyone in New Jersey has health insurance they can't
lose, no matter what," and another 9.2% were willing to accept a
"more modest tax hike."
(3.) $2,881 equals $95.09 WTP per person, times 19.38 million
residents (source: http://quickfacts.census. gov/qfd/states/36000.html),
divided by 25% of 2.56 million uninsured residents (source:
http://www.statehealthfacts.
org/profileind.jsp?sub=40&rgn=34&cat=3).
(4.) $3,465 equals $90.35 WTP per person, times 19.38 million
residents, divided by 25% of 2.02 million uninsured residents below 300%
of the federal poverty line (FPL) (source: http://www.
nyhealthcarecommission.org/docs/uninsured_in_new_york. pdf).
(5.) Further, in response to a repeated question about willingness
to pay for an overall expansion of coverage in 2010, the average WTP
remained remarkably stable despite both the onset of a major recession
in late 2008 that peaked in 2010, and an intense debate over the ACA in
2009 through early 2010 that could have shifted attention towards
national reforms.
(6.) Participation in Medicaid expansions specifically became
optional following a ruling by the U.S. Supreme Court in 2012.
Participation for selected eligible groups is initially at no cost to
states, and state cost shares increase to 10% by 2020 and remain fixed
thereafter (Musumeci 2012). An interesting question is how individual
taxpayers may view the costs of expanding state Medicaid coverage. While
the costs at the state level are modest, taxpayers may also consider the
possible implications for their federal taxes.
(7.) The cost of a child Medicaid beneficiary in 2009 was $2,305
for the United States on average and $2,505 for New York. See
http://www.statehealthfacts.org/comparetable.jsp? ind=183&cat=4
(last accessed December 2012).
(8.) In Table 8 (Urban Institute 2012), the authors estimate that
over 10 years the total cost (federal and state) of the Medicaid
expansion will be $3,456 billion, and that 320,000 new people will be
eligible in the state (Table 9). Combining these estimates leads to an
estimate of $ 1,080 per beneficiary coverage-year for marginal Medicaid
enrollees (non-parents in the 100%--133% of FPL range).
(9.) See http://www.govemor.ny.gov/assets/documents/
Approved2014HeaIthInsuranceRates.pdf
(10.) Asking both opinion and WTP questions in the same survey
raises a question of whether the responses are independent of each
other. If respondents feel the need to justify their answers to initial
questions, this may affect subsequent responses. In particular, this
seems an important concern if opinion questions are asked before WTP
questions, but in our survey, WTP questions come first. However, it is
still possible that responses to WTP questions may affect
respondents' answers to subsequent qualitative questions about
their opinions about reforms, and lead to answers that look more similar
to each other than would otherwise be the case.
(11.) The ESP is a random telephone survey of New York State
residents aged 18 and over conducted annually in the first quarter
(February and March) by the Cornell Survey Research Institute (SRI)
since 2003. Responses are collected through a computer-assisted
telephone interviewing (CATI) system. ESP data have been used in prior
CV research studies, such as Cawley (2008) who studies WTP to reduce
childhood obesity through taxes.
(12.) If the resident was unavailable, the interview was terminated
and the Cornell SRI attempted to follow up later. If these attempts were
unsuccessful (called unsuccessfully 5+ times) or the respondent refused,
additional households were added to the sample and this process
continued until a total of 800 respondents was obtained. The survey
design thus ensured that subjects who are selected are not more likely
to be those out of the labor force simply by virtue of being more likely
to answer the phone. It is expected that chance variation in the sample
should not cause results in either the 2008 or the 2010 ESP to vary by
more than 3.5 percentage points in no more than 1 in 20 cases from the
answers that would have been obtained if all New York State residents
were interviewed. More details of the survey can be found at the ESP
website at http://www.sri.cornell.edu/sri/esp.introduction.cfm and from
SRI (2008, 2010).
(13.) These rate calculations follow American Association for
Public Opinion Research (AAPOR) definitions: the response rate is
computed by dividing the number of completed surveys by the total
eligible sample, while the cooperation rate is computed by dividing the
number of completed surveys by the number of potential interviews (which
includes all instances where the properly selected individual was
reached but refused to complete the survey, but not due to language or
physical limitations). SRI notes that these rates compare favorably with
telephone surveys conducted by other research organizations such as the
Pew Research Center (SRI, 2008, 2010). We note that these rates compare
favor ably to other health-related telephone polls too. For example, the
cooperation rate of the Political Typology Survey conducted by The Pew
Research Center used in Bundorf and Fuchs (2008) is 45% (p. 3).
(14.) Because the regular ESP does not re-sample individuals
included in previous ESPs, there is no overlap between the 2010
follow-up survey of 2008 ESP respondents and the 2010 ESP cross-section
sample of new respondents.
(15.) The high-deductible plan question was only asked in the 2008
ESP. High-deductible plans were not allowed in the individual market in
New York State by law at the time of the 2008 survey (Jost and Hall
2005; Parente and Bragdon 2009). Although Health Savings Accounts (HSAs)
remained unavailable in the individual market in New York State (Howard
2011), HSA compatible high-deductible plans have been available on a
limited basis under the state-subsidized Healthy New York program
available to low-income working families from 2007 onwards (11 NYCRR
362. available at http://www.dfs.ny.gov/insurance/r_misc/rhlthny
171a3.htm).
(16.) "Favor" is coded as 1 and "oppose" as 0
where only these two responses were offered. In all cases, responses of
"don't know" or "refused" are treated as
missing in our analysis of these and other questions.
(17.) We would like to thank an anonymous referee for this point.
(18.) The only potential constraint that the lower bound model can
impose is monotonicity, but responses in our data are monotonic without
imposing any constraints, so our estimates are free of distributional
assumptions. See Haab and McConnell (2003) for more on distributional
assumptions. majority of respondents felt that it was important to
reduce the number of uninsured residents, although the share decreases
over time from 88% to 81% in the cross-sectional samples, and by a
similar amount in the panel sample. In 2008 only 39% favored increasing
coverage by imposing a large employer mandate; this share dropped
slightly to 36% in 2010. Support for a universal insurance mandate also
fell from 76% in 2008 to 71% in 2010. Similarly, the share supporting
universal Medicare fell from 70% in 2008 to 63% in 2010.
(19.) A way to improve the accuracy of hypothetical WTP responses
suggested by Arrow et al. (1993) in their report to the NOAA on CV is to
offer respondents the option to say that they would not vote for the
referendum. This option was offered for all questions, and these
responses were conservatively coded as a lack of support for the
referendum. On average, 2.8% of responses to all questions were
"Would not Vote," with a range for specific questions from
0.8% to 5.7%.
(20.) We report findings on a per respondent basis, but it is
possible respondents in households with multiple earners who file
jointly may misinterpret the question to refer to total tax payments by
the household.
(21.) See http://www.statehealthfacts.org/profileind.
jsp?sub=40&rgn=34&cat=3
(22.) See http://www.nyhealthcarecoimnission.org/docs/
uninsured_in_new_york.pdf
(23.) To explore the sensitivity of our estimates, we also
considered several alternative specifications for 2008 results in which
we made structural assumptions. Among the specifications tested, the
best-fitting parametric model was a loglinear WTP model, which suggested
a mean WTP of $449.99 per household for referendum version 1 in 2008 and
$286.03 for version 2. The bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals of the
mean estimator were ($291.76, $860.25) and ($201.28, $423.69),
respectively.
(24.) In alternative model specification that include only opinion
variables, income, age, gender, and children, the coefficient on income
is significantly positive in every sample, but small in magnitude,
consistent with the bivariate pattern. For example, in the 2008 overall
referendum sample, the coefficient on income suggests that a $100,000
increase in annual income increases the conditional probability of
supporting the referendum by about 8.9 percentage points.
(25.) We also ran a separate model to test whether changes in WTP
could have been predicted by characteristics in 2008. We found that none
of the 2008 characteristics had significant explanatory power in
predicting subsequent changes in WTP.
(26.) See Oaxaca (1973) and Blinder (1973).
(27.) These decreases do not add exactly to $ 12.66 because they
are partially offset by small increases in WTP from the simultaneous
interaction effect of the two changes.
KURT LAVETTI, KOSALI SIMON and WILLIAM D. WHITE*
* This research was supported in part by Cornell University
Agricultural Experiment Station federal formula funds, Project No.
NYC-3247412 received from the National Institutes for Food and
Agriculture (NIFA) U.S. Department of Agriculture, and by funding from
the New York State Health Foundation, Grant No 2007-2055189. Any
opinions, findings, conclusions, or recommendations expressed in this
publication are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect
the view of the U.S. Department of Agriculture or the New York State
Health Foundation. We are grateful to Anna Hill for excellent research
assistance and to Asako Moriya, two anonymous referees, and participants
at ASHEcon and APPAM annual research conferences for helpful comments.
Lavetti: Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Ohio State
University, Columbus, OH 43210. Phone 1-301-752-0895, Fax
1-614-292-3906. E-mail lavetti. 1 @osu.edu
Simon: Professor, School of Public and Environmental Affairs,
Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405. Phone 1-812-856-3850, Fax
1-812-855-7802, E-mail simonkos@ indiana.edu
White: Professor, Department of Policy Analysis and Management,
Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853. Phone 1-607-254-6476, Fax
1-607-255-4071, E-mail wdw8@Cornell.edu
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics, 2008-2010
Mean Comparisons
B
A 2008 Panel
Full 2008 Respondents
Sample in 2008
Reform opinion questions
Cost important 0.92 0.91
#Uninsured important 0.88 0.87
Large employer mandate 0.39 0.40
Universal mandate 0.76 0.71
Support high deductible 0.68 0.67
Universal medicare 0.70 0.66
Sociodemographic questions
Age 48.51 51.99
Male 0.50 0.51
Married 0.53 0.60
Children (in household) 0.41 0.36
<High school 0.09 0.06
High school diploma 0.22 0.19
Some college 0.28 0.27
White (non-Hispanic) 0.66 0.75
Black (non-Hispanic) 0.15 0.13
Hispanic 0.13 0.08
Insured 0.92 0.94
Employed 0.65 0.62
Income 80,483 84,027
Liberal 0.34 0.36
Conservative 0.30 0.31
Upstate 0.50 0.53
N 800 411
Mean Comparisons
C D
2008 Panel New
Respondents Respondents
in 2010 in 2010
Reform opinion questions
Cost important 0.85 0.85
#Uninsured important 0.80 0.81
Large employer mandate 0.38 0.36
Universal mandate 0.63 0.71
Support high deductible 0.65
Universal medicare 0.61 0.63
Sociodemographic questions
Age -- 51.21
Male -- 0.49
Married -- 0.53
Children (in household) -- 0.39
<High school -- 0.06
High school diploma -- 0.24
Some college -- 0.25
White (non-Hispanic) -- 0.66
Black (non-Hispanic) -- 0.21
Hispanic -- 0.11
Insured 0.93 0.92
Employed 0.58 0.60
Income 81,040 80,206
Liberal -- 0.33
Conservative -- 0.32
Upstate -- 0.50
N 411 800
Tests of Differences in Means
A vs. D A vs. B B vs. C C vs. D
Reform opinion questions
Cost important *** **
#Uninsured important *** ***
Large employer mandate
Universal mandate ** ** ***
Support high deductible
Universal medicare ***
Sociodemographic questions
Age *** ***
Male
Married **
Children (in household) *
<High school ** *
High school diploma
Some college
White (non-Hispanic) ***
Black (non-Hispanic) ***
Hispanic ***
Insured
Employed *
Income
Liberal
Conservative
Upstate
N
Notes: The values in this table show the fraction of the relevant
sample that reported "yes" to the specific health reform questions
in the first panel, and who have the relevant demographic
characteristics indicated in the second panel. Column A corresponds
to the 800 respondents in the 2008 ESP, column B corresponds to the
2008 answers of the subset of the 2008 ESP who also responded in
2010, column C corresponds to the 2010 answers of the subset of the
2008 ESP who also responded in 2010, and column D corresponds to
the 2010 ESP (new) sample. The second set of columns test whether
the indicated columns represent values that are statistically
different from each other in a two tailed f-test. See Appendix for
wording of survey questions. "--" indicates question was not asked
in survey round.
* Significant difference at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level;
*** significant at 1% level.
TABLE 2
Lower-Bound WTP Estimates for Overall
Referendum
2008 2008 2010 2010
Full Panel Panel New
Sample Sample Sample Sample
Mean lower $95.09 $99.87 $85.14 $93.33
bound WTP (7.63) (10.51) (10.80) (5.20)
[368] [192] [192] [800]
WTP, income $133.52 $113.09 $135.34 $136.51
$200,000+ (26.39) (33.76) (38.62) (15.28)
[26] [15] [11] [85]
WTP, income $130.01 $144.29 $127.86 $115.98
$80,000 to (13.28) (16.75) (17.66) (10.31)
$199,999 [103] [59] [58] [184]
WTP, income $90.64 $85.16 $77.47 $80.81
$30,000 to (13.11) (18.21) (18.41) (8.00)
$79,999 [126] [67] [68] [352]
WTP, income $59.99 $66.05 $48.76 $81.97
below $30,000 (17.96) (26.25) (24.30) (13.21)
[75] [35] [43] [144]
WTP, missing $60.14 $62.92 $7.60 $54.18
income data (25.75) (38.71) (14.02) (22.91)
[38] [16] [12] [35]
Notes: Mean lower bound estimates of WTP reported overall and by
income group for each survey sample. Standard errors in
parentheses, and number of observations in brackets. "Overall
Referendum" refers to the first version of the survey question in
which respondents are asked their WTP to reduce uninsurance by one
quarter.
TABLE 3
Lower-Bound WTP Estimates for Low-Income
Referendum
Low-Income Referendum
2008 2008 2010
Full Panel Panel
Sample Sample Sample
Mean lower $90.35 $91.60 $93.35
bound WTP (7.08) (9.90) (9.93)
[432] [219] [219]
WTP, income $135.35 $89.98 $68.58
$200,000+ (24.10) (35.15) (41.37)
[31] [18] [13]
WTP, income $94.00 $96.55 $112.56
$80,000 to (14.51) (19.90) (19.52)
$199,999 [101] [53] [52]
WTP, income $95.39 $97.96 $103.00
$30,000 to (11.26) (15.41) (13.97)
$79,999 [166] [88] [105]
WTP, income $59.35 $50.91 $50.46
below $30,000 (16.27) (30.32) (28.01)
[78] [27] [32]
WTP, missing $86.27 $103.83 $85.58
income data (20.02) (25.49) (37.26)
[56] [33] [17]
Notes: Mean lower bound estimates of WTP reported overall and by
income group for each survey sample. Standard errors in parentheses,
and number of observations in brackets. "Low-Income Referendum" refers
to the second version of the survey question in which respondents are
asked their WTP to reduce uninsurance by one quarter among those who
earn less than 300% of the FPL.
TABLE 4
Probit Model of Referendum Support
Dependent Variable: Support for Referendum
2008 2010
Low-
Overall Income Overall
Referendum cost -0.003 *** -0.003 *** -0.003 ***
Think cost is 0.063 0.014 -0.008
important
Think # uninsured is -0.044 #REF! 0.163 ***
important
Support large 0.055 0.135 *** 0.002
employer mandate
Support universal 0.189 *** 0.090 ** 0.251 ***
mandate
Support 0.049 0.100 *
high-deductible
plans
Support universal 0.066 0.182 *** 0.236 ***
medicare
Age 0.000 0.001 0.002 *
Male 0.030 0.165 *** 0.031
Married 0.083 -0.037 0.042
Children -0.031 0.079 0.068 *
<High school -0.172 * -0.344 *** -0.038
HS diploma -0.116 -0.106 -0.154 ***
Some college -0.029 -0.139 ** -0.087 *
White (Non-Hispanic) 0.026 -0.002 -0.095
Black (Non-Hispanic) -0.202 * -0.025 -0.249 **
Hispanic -0.097 -0.092 -0.190 *
Uninsured -0.092 0.012 -0.008
Employed 0.036 -0.003 0.141 ***
Income ($ 10,000s) 0.000 0.004 0.004
Liberal 0.070 0.118 * 0.028 ***
Conservative -0.114 * -0.012 -0.084 *
Upstate -0.125 ** 0.006 -0.032
Introduction -0.049 0.001
N obs. 1405 1540 3200
N clusters 281 308 640
[R.sup.2] 0.230 0.279 0.274
Notes: Dependent variable equals 1 if respondent indicated that they
would vote for the referendum at the specified price. Data are from
full samples in respective years. Reported coefficients are marginal
effects. Income is in tens of thousands of dollars.
* Coefficient is significant at 10% level based on standard errors
clustered by individual; ** significant at 5% level; *** significant
at 1% level.
TABLE 5
Change in WTP vs. Change in Characteristics and Opinions, Panel
Sample
Overall Referendum Coefficient (SE)
Gained insurance -15.89 (50.29)
Lost insurance -207.75 (68.12) ***
Became employed 17.56 (26.64)
Became unemployed -6.46 (37.52)
Change in income -0.63 (2.18)
Changed opinion up: cost important 128.34 (61.92) **
Changed opinion down: cost important -7.53 (24.53)
Changed opinion up: # uninsured important -67.04 (47.11)
Changed opinion down: # uninsured important -42.90 (27.46)
Changed opinion up: large employer mandate -22.20 (21.31)
Changed opinion down: large employer mandate -33.27 (24.39)
Changed opinion up: universal mandate -12.74 (27.39)
Changed opinion down: universal mandate 3.79 (23.53)
Changed opinion up: high deductible 3.21 (27.82)
Changed opinion down: high deductible -12.56 (20.98)
Changed opinion up: universal medicare 15.54 (28.13)
Changed opinion down: universal medicare -36.75 (23.22)
N 126
[R.sup.2] 0.07
Overall Referendum Coefficient (SE)
Gained insurance -1582.4835
Lost insurance -87.73 (8.62) ***
Became employed -21.22 (27.72)
Became unemployed -21.01 (33.95)
Change in income 0.22 (1.72)
Changed opinion up: cost important
Changed opinion down: cost important
Changed opinion up: # uninsured important
Changed opinion down: # uninsured important
Changed opinion up: large employer mandate
Changed opinion down: large employer mandate
Changed opinion up: universal mandate
Changed opinion down: universal mandate
Changed opinion up: high deductible
Changed opinion down: high deductible
Changed opinion up: universal medicare
Changed opinion down: universal medicare
N 159
[R.sup.2] 0.02
Overall Referendum Coefficient (SE)
Gained insurance
Lost insurance
Became employed
Became unemployed
Change in income
Changed opinion up: cost important 66.12 (46.99)
Changed opinion down: cost important -8.50 (22.62)
Changed opinion up: # uninsured important -50.72 (47.80)
Changed opinion down: # uninsured important -44.47 (27.13)
Changed opinion up: large employer mandate -25.60 (20.09)
Changed opinion down: large employer mandate -26.73 (22.46)
Changed opinion up: universal mandate 10.06 (22.10)
Changed opinion down: universal mandate 3.18 (22.84)
Changed opinion up: high deductible 4.73 (24.53)
Changed opinion down: high deductible -6.96 (20.26)
Changed opinion up: universal medicare 11.57 (26.80)
Changed opinion down: universal medicare -36.12 (21.24) *
N 146
[R.sup.2] 0.04
Low-Income Referendum Coefficient (SE)
Gained insurance -28.54 (46.11)
Lost insurance 74.17 (46.05)
Became employed -74.02 (30.94) **
Became unemployed -45.59 (37.48)
Change in income -1.03 (0.99)
Changed opinion up: cost important -39.77 (88.53)
Changed opinion down: cost important -46.15 (45.98)
Changed opinion up: # uninsured important 18.21 (41.70)
Changed opinion down: # uninsured important -4.67 (17.04)
Changed opinion up: large employer mandate -51.15 (19.49) ***
Changed opinion down: large employer mandate -22.07 (26.51)
Changed opinion up: universal mandate -46.09 (37.83)
Changed opinion down: universal mandate 6.15 (23.00)
Changed opinion up: high deductible 13.85 (21.70)
Changed opinion down: high deductible 8.88 (21.85)
Changed opinion up: universal medicare 59.34 (23.63) **
Changed opinion down: universal medicare -30.15 (16.27) *
N 132
[R.sup.2] 0.20
Low-Income Referendum Coefficient (SE)
Gained insurance -41.02 (42.61)
Lost insurance 80.58 (46.47) *
Became employed -74.37 (27.58) ***
Became unemployed -9.98 (32.96)
Change in income -1.29 (1.18)
Changed opinion up: cost important
Changed opinion down: cost important
Changed opinion up: # uninsured important
Changed opinion down: # uninsured important
Changed opinion up: large employer mandate
Changed opinion down: large employer mandate
Changed opinion up: universal mandate
Changed opinion down: universal mandate
Changed opinion up: high deductible
Changed opinion down: high deductible
Changed opinion up: universal medicare
Changed opinion down: universal medicare
N 179
[R.sup.2] 0.07
Low-Income Referendum Coefficient (SE)
Gained insurance
Lost insurance
Became employed
Became unemployed
Change in income
Changed opinion up: cost important -20.23 (48.75)
Changed opinion down: cost important -8.77 (28.80)
Changed opinion up: # uninsured important 18.82 (38.81)
Changed opinion down: # uninsured important -12.53 (17.95)
Changed opinion up: large employer mandate -50.13 (16.49) ***
Changed opinion down: large employer mandate -29.88 (23.76)
Changed opinion up: universal mandate -33.60 (29.97)
Changed opinion down: universal mandate 4.16 (19.26)
Changed opinion up: high deductible 5.74 (23.01)
Changed opinion down: high deductible -2.14 (18.31)
Changed opinion up: universal medicare 58.12 (21.29) ***
Changed opinion down: universal medicare -41.46 (17.55) **
N 155
[R.sup.2] 0.08
Notes: Changed opinion up indicates that the respondent disagreed
with the reform proposal in 2008 and agreed with the proposal in
2010. Changed opinion down indicates that the respondent changed
their opinion in the opposite direction. Change in income is measured
in tens of thousands of dollars.
* Coefficient is significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5%
level; *** significant at 1% level.
TABLE 6 Change in WTP vs. Changes in Characteristics: Oaxaca-Blinder
Decomposition
Explanatory Variables
Insurance
Change N Income Employment Coverage
Overall referendum
-12.66 310 X X X
-13.20 355 X X X
-10.23 329
Low-income referendum
6.69 332 X X X
4.80 388 X X X
3.87 367
Decomposition
Opinions Due to Change in Due to
About Explanatory Change in
Change Reform Variables Coefficients
Overall referendum
-12.66 X -8.65 * -4.03
-13.20 -0.58 -12.91
-10.23 X -8.73 ** -4.17
Low-income referendum
6.69 X -3.22 7.29
4.80 -1.06 4.49
3.87 X -3.85 6.66
Notes: Changes in opinions about reform includes changes in "cost
important," "# uninsured important," "large employer mandate,"
"universal mandate," "high deductible," and "universal medicare." The
column labeled "change" is the predicted change based on the included
explanatory variables, marked with "X." The "decomposition" columns
show the contributions of changes in explanatory variables and
changes in estimated coefficients to the total change. Data are from
the panel sample. The interaction term of the decomposition is not
shown.
* Decomposition component is significantly different from zero at 10%
level; ** significant at 5% level; *** significant at 1% level.
COPYRIGHT 2014 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2014 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.