Firm survival, uncertainty, and financial frictions: is there a financial uncertainty accelerator?
Byrne, Joseph P. ; Spaliara, Marina-eliza ; Tsoukas, Serafeim 等
Firm survival, uncertainty, and financial frictions: is there a financial uncertainty accelerator?
I. INTRODUCTION
The global financial crisis had dire economic consequences for a
host of public and private sector agents across advanced and emerging
economies. The crisis was a time of heightened uncertainty, financial
distress, and widespread firm closures. All firms continuing as going
concerns however, with lower investment after a rise in uncertainty, may
not be equivalent to some firms closing completely due to uncertainty.
(1) Reinforcing this effect, firms are more likely to experience
bankruptcy and to be more susceptible to macroeconomic and firm specific
uncertainty, in a situation in which they experience poor financial
health (see Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist 1996 and Ghosal and
Loungani 2000). Whether researchers fully model the impact of
uncertainty on economic activity depends upon, at least partly, whether
firms survive or close their operations completely. Surprisingly there
is limited empirical evidence regarding the effect of uncertainty on
firm closure, for example during the recent financial crisis.
In this paper, we consider the role of firm-level uncertainty in
firms' hazard of failure during economic downturns. More precisely,
we generate a measure of firm-specific uncertainty that stems from
firms' volatility in sales. Then we observe the most recent
financial crisis which provides an interesting set-up to explore the
role of uncertainty in firms' failure. Finally, we look at the
financial health of the firm, reflected in the quality of its balance
sheet. Our empirical work is based on an assessment of firm-specific
uncertainty on firms' chances of failure using an unbalanced panel
of 9,457 UK firms between 2000 and 2009. We employ annual firm-level
data from the Financial Analysis Made Easy (FAME) database. A discrete
proportional hazard model examines failure probability for firms with
different balance sheet characteristics and exposure in micro and macro
uncertainty. Then we take into account firms' reliance on bank debt
as well as their ownership structure (public or private).
In doing so, we contribute to the existing literature in three
important ways. First, we investigate the link between uncertainty and
firm survival, paying special attention to the most recent financial
crisis. While there is a large and growing literature on the effects of
uncertainty on firms' investment, capital structure, and
inventories (see Baum, Stephan, and Talavera 2009; Baum, Caglayan. and
Talavera 2010a, 2010b; Caglayan, Maioli, and Mateut 2012; Caglayan and
Rashid 2014), less attention has been given to the important dimension
of firm survival. Yet, the potential closure of a great number of
businesses was one of the most visible threats to economic performance
during the Great Recession. As far as we are aware, this study is the
first to provide a systematic analysis of the link between uncertainty
at the micro level, and corporate failures during the most recent global
financial crisis.
Second, this paper accounts for the important dimension of firm
heterogeneity, distinguishing between firms which are likely to be more
or less dependent on bank finance. This is particularly important
because UK banks interrupted their lines of credit during the crisis due
to liquidity problems (Bell and Young 2010). This phenomenon was also
evident in Europe as shown in the results of the EU bank lending survey
which points to a substantial reduction in loan supply and increased
lending standards that exposed bank dependent borrowers. Hence,
identifying those companies which rely heavily on bank finance will
allow us to provide a sharper test of the effect of uncertainty on firm
survival. We also distinguish between public and private firms, because
the latter are smaller and typically associated with the highest degree
of information asymmetry. (2)
Third, we employ a much broader sample of firms than other studies
in the literature. Our data-set is made up mainly by unlisted companies.
Unlike previous studies which typically rely on listed companies (see
for example Baum, Stephan, and Talavera 2009 and Baum, Caglayan, and
Talavera 2010a, 2010b), we use a large panel of financial data on UK
firms, over 98% of which are not quoted on the stock market. This
characteristic is vitally important because these firms are more likely
to suffer from information asymmetry problems and hence will be affected
the most during extreme economic events.
To preview our results, we find significant evidence of the impact
of uncertainty on firm survival in the UK using a broader sample of
firms than is typically used in the literature. Indeed, the impact of
uncertainty is more potent in the recent crisis period compared with the
great moderation. Furthermore our data-set is able to uncover important
heterogeneity in firm behavior. We identify that both more
bank-dependent and nonpublic firms are greatly impacted by uncertainty,
and this effect is magnified during the crisis. Overall, our evidence
provides a key contribution to the literature on firm survival,
uncertainty, and financial distress.
The rest of the article is set out as follows. In Section II, we
provide a short discussion of the related literature. Section III
presents the hypotheses and the empirical methods used. Section IV
describes our data and presents some summary statistics. Sections V and
VI illustrate our main empirical results and robustness tests. Section
VII concludes.
II. ECONOMIC BACKGROUND
The theoretical and empirical literature confirms that uncertainty
is associated with a decline in output, investment, and employment at
the aggregate and disaggregate level. Significant contributions in this
area include, for example, studies from Dixit and Pindyck (1994),
Caballero (1999), and Bond and Van Reenen (2007). There is less work,
however, on uncertainty and firm survival. Firms operating with less
investment may not be equivalent to some firms closing completely due to
uncertainty. That is to say, uncertainty may have different implications
for the economy depending upon whether firms close or not, and hence
different implications for longrun productive capacity of an economy.
Bloom (2007, 2009) highlights how temporary uncertainty may be
associated with a temporary downturn, but firms shall become active
again once uncertainty subsides. Clearly, if firms are more susceptible
to close down this will have implications for an economy's capacity
to return to trend growth. The irreversibility channel of uncertainty
therefore may be more potent when we consider the possibility that firms
may close.
Although there is less work looking at uncertainty and firm
survival, there is an established literature that examines uncertainty
and firmlevel investment and R&D: see Ghosal and Loungani (2000),
Ghosal (2003), Bo and Lensin (2005), Baum, Caglayan, and Talavera
(2010b), and Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajsek (2013). (3)
Bloom (2007) argues that uncertainty about future productivity and
demand conditions will generate fluctuations in investment, hiring, and
productivity. Higher uncertainty generates a temporary slowdown and
bounce back as firms postpone activity and wait for uncertainty to
subside. This effect is expected to be stronger during recessions. Dixit
(1989) emphasizes the implications of an uncertain environment on entry
and exit decisions of firms. In particular, Ghosal and Loungani (2000)
show that uncertainty has a negative effect on investment, which is
greater in small-firm-dominated industries. There is, however, limited
empirical evidence regarding the effect of uncertainty on the UK economy
particularly during the recent financial crisis, where uncertainty
remained at an elevated level for an extended period of time. Using
Granger causality tests, Haddow et al. (2013) argue that higher levels
of uncertainty have been a factor restraining the UK recovery and may
adversely affect growth. Denis and Kannan (2013) find in their vector
autoregression analysis that uncertainty shocks have a significant
impact on UK industrial production and gross domestic product and a
somewhat limited effect on employment.
Our paper is also innovative because it considers the interrelation
between firm survival, uncertainty, and financial shocks. It is
generally accepted that following an adverse shock firms with poorer
indicators of creditworthiness on their balance sheets will be more
constrained than those that are considered creditworthy. Bernanke,
Gertler, and Gilchrist (1996) present a theoretical channel whereby
financial structure impacts firm behavior. The "flight to
quality" by lenders, identified by Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist
(1996), underlies much of the dynamic adjustment observable in the
macro-economy due to the credit channel following an adverse shock.
Furthermore, the experience of UK corporates after the recent global
financial crisis suggests that the financial system can generate an
endogenous cycle (the accelerator) that propagates the initial shock
overtime, c.f. Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1996). Firms that
initially have lower credit ratings and are refused external finance on
this basis can find that their creditworthiness deteriorates further,
putting future external finance further out of reach. The implication is
that firms that are relatively constrained on the financial markets will
face higher agency costs of borrowing--a higher "external
premium"--for raising capital from financial markets compared with
the cost of internal finance funded from retained earnings (see also
Bernanke and Gertler 1995). The external finance premium is inversely
related to the firms' balance sheet, i.e., net worth, and to
macroeconomic conditions, creating a countercyclical movement in the
premium for external funds, which serves to amplify borrower's
spending and economic activity in the financial accelerator (see
Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist 1996, 1999).
Ghosal and Loungani (2000) suggest the investment uncertainty nexus
operates through capital market imperfections. Ghosal (2003) highlights
that uncertainty and sunk costs at the industry level have a large
negative impact on entry and exit probabilities of firms. (4)
The interrelationship between uncertainty, investment, and
financial variables is discussed by Baum, Stephan, and Talavera (2009)
and Baum, Caglayan, and Talavera (2010a, 2010b). The aforementioned
studies identify an important channel by which uncertainty reduces firm
access to credit, consequently leading to lower investment. Baum,
Stephan, and Talavera (2009) identify a strong negative relationship
between debt and macroeconomic uncertainty.
Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajsek (2013) also examine how macroeconomic
uncertainty influences investment through financial frictions. Using
macro and micro evidence, they establish that uncertainty impacts
investment largely through credit spreads. Specifically, increases in
uncertainty are associated with a widening of credit spreads and a
decline in output. By delineating an alternative transmission mechanism,
this calls into question the option value of waiting approach that
exists in the literature. As a consequence this research proposes a
specific channel by which uncertainty can impact upon firm survival.
Finally, Huynh, Petrunia, and Voia (2010) and Huynh and Petrunia
(2010) present empirical evidence on the determinants of firm survival
and growth, showing that firms' leverage matters for both
activities and has a nonlinear impact on survival. Indeed, it may be the
case that high leverage (or low profitability) does not have a
persistent effect on economic activity, but the consequences of leverage
for firm survival impinge upon recovery from recession. Such a view may
contribute to our understanding of business cycles (Hall 2010). In the
next section, we review specific research questions and discuss our
empirical methods.
III. HYPOTHESES AND METHODOLOGY
A. Research Questions
This paper seeks to consider a number of research questions. First,
we evaluate the direct effect of micro uncertainty on firms'
failures for UK firms, the vast majority of which are not quoted on the
stock market. After controlling for macro uncertainty and a number of
firm-specific and financial indicators we might expect that firm-level
uncertainty will lead to higher failure rates.
Second, we examine the impact of firm-specific uncertainty on the
hazard of failure in and out of the most recent financial crisis. This
can be tested through interactions between the measures of uncertainty
and a time-period dummy, which is aimed at capturing the 2007-2009
global financial crisis. One should expect that firms will be more
likely to fail during periods of economic uncertainty because firms have
to postpone their activities. This effect might be amplified during
economic downturns because firms find it extremely difficult to attract
external funding at a reasonable cost and therefore have to cut down
their activities.
Third, we test the probability of failure for different groups of
firms in and out of the crisis, taking into account the uncertainty
measures. Because of the nature of our data, we take into account firm
heterogeneity by looking at the extent to which firms rely upon bank
funding. As banks significantly restricted loans toward small-and
medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) during the financial crisis, it is
reasonable to suppose that bank-dependent firms are likely to have
suffered more than their less bank-dependent counterparts. This argument
is in line with Bell and Young (2010), who discuss statistics on loans
to SMEs and syndicated loan spreads in the UK. They note that while
investment-grade spreads peaked in 2008, they have fallen back after the
crisis. We should expect to find that more bank-dependent firms will be
more likely to fail when faced with higher levels of uncertainty
compared with their less bank-dependent counterparts. Moreover, this
link should be more important during the crisis. Finally, we intend to
corroborate our results using the distinction between public and
nonpublic firms. The latter group is more likely to be financially
constrained and hence may respond more strongly to uncertainty compared
with the former group of firms, especially during extreme economic
events.
B. Empirical Specifications
Baseline Model. To evaluate the effect of uncertainty on the
likelihood of firm failure, we use a complementary log-log model
(cloglog), a discrete time version of the Cox proportional hazard model.
This methodology is particularly indicated given that we are interested
in investigating the determinants of the timing of firms' chances
of failure. Considering this objective our analysis is related to the
passage of time before the event of failure occurs. The cloglog model
accounts for the incompletely observed lifespan of firms surviving past
the sample and allows us to capture the exact time of failure,
addressing in this way the potential right censoring bias. (5) The
assumption of the proportional hazard model is that the hazard ratio
depends only on time at risk, 0o(f) (the so-called baseline hazard) and
on explanatory variables affecting the hazard independently of time,
exp([beta]'K). The hazard ratio is then given by:
(1) [theta](i,K) = [[theta].sub.0](f)exp([beta]'/f)
The discrete-time hazard function, h(j,K), shows the interval
hazard for the period between the beginning and the end of the jth year
after the first appearance of the firm. This hazard rate, which is the
rate at which firms fail at time t given that they have survived in t -
1, takes the following form:
(2) h (j, K) = 1 - exp [- exp ([beta]'K + [[gamma].sub.j])]
where we are particularly interested in identifying the p
parameters, which show the effect of the explanatory variables
incorporated in vector K on the hazard rate. In the tables presented
below, we report coefficients rather than hazard ratios (exponential
coefficients). The interpretation of the coefficients is as follows. A
positive coefficient indicates that an increase in the associated
explanatory variable leads to an increase in the hazard of failure in
any given year. A negative coefficient estimate suggests that the
explanatory variable is negatively associated with the hazard and
therefore reduces the probability of failure. When interpreting our
results, it is useful to look at the exponentiated coefficients, which
have the interpretation of the ratio of the hazard for one unit change
in the explanatory variable. In our discussion of the findings, we will
present detailed examples of how we calculate the magnitude of the
coefficients. (6)
We set out a benchmark model to estimate how firms'
probability of failure is affected by uncertainty and their financial
conditions:
(3) h(j,X) = 1 - exp [-exp ([[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] Sigma +
[[beta].sub.2] X + [[beta].sub.3] Y + [[gamma].sub.j])]
where Sigma represents the uncertainty measured at the micro (firm)
level. The sign and significance of [[beta].sub.1] shows the importance
of uncertainty on the probability of firms' failure. Vectors X and
Y denote a set of control variables that have been found to be
influential in firm survival studies. We partition the control variables
into financial and other explicators.
Measuring Firm-Specific Uncertainty. There is an extensive
literature examining the impact of uncertainty in other contexts and we
seek to exploit that literature. Several studies use uncertainty on
forecast earnings or profits: von Kalckreuth (2000) and Lensink, Bo, and
Sterken (1999). Baum, Caglayan, and Talavera (2010b) use a capital asset
pricing model measure to identify the impact of firm uncertainty on
investment. To measure firm uncertainty Leahy and Whited (1996) and
Bloom, Bond, and Van Reenen (2001) use volatility of stock prices.
Ghosal and Loungani (2000) use profit forecasting to predict future
profit in order to assess the impact of uncertainty on investment. Sales
have been employed as a proxy for firm-specific uncertainty by Lensink,
Bo, and Sterken (1999) and Caglayan, Maioli, and Mateut (2012) who test
the effect of sales volatility on inventory investment and by
Garcia-Vega, Guariglia, and Spaliara (2012) who assess the effect of
uncertainty on exporting. (7)
The heterogeneity amongst firms in our data allows us to employ a
proxy of firm-specific uncertainty using firms' sales in line with
previous studies (Caglayan, Maioli, and Mateut 2012; Garcia-Vega,
Guariglia, and Spaliara 2012; Lensink, Bo, and Sterken 1999; Morgan,
Rime, and Strahan 2004). In particular, we construct our uncertainty
measure by estimating first an AR(1) model of sales augmented with time
and industry-specific dummies. (8) To take into account the panel data
nature of our data-set we employ a GMM system estimator (see Arellano
and Bover 1995; Blundell and Bond 1998). We verify that the diagnostics
do not indicate any problems regarding the choice and the relevance of
our instruments. Uncertainty is then computed as the standard deviation
of the firm's total real sales calculated over the 3 years
preceding and including year t. (9,10)
Other Influences. X is a vector of financial variables Leverage and
Profitability. Both variables capture different aspects of the financial
health of a firm. We control for firms' financial health motivated
by the theoretical model of Clementi and Hopenhayn (2006) (11) and
previous empirical studies (Bridges and Guariglia 2008; Bunn and Redwood
2003; Huynh, Petrunia, and Voia 2010). To begin with financial leverage
(Leverage), which is measured as the ratio of total current liabilities
over total assets, we note that high levels of existing debt are
associated with a worse balance sheet situation, which would increase
moral hazard and adverse selection problems, and lead to the inability
of firms to obtain external finance at a reasonable cost (see Levin,
Natalucci, and Zakrajsek 2004; Mizen and Tsoukas 2012). Zingales (1998)
and Bridges and Guariglia (2008) argue that higher leverage results in
higher failure probabilities. Accordingly, we expect a positive
relationship between leverage and the probability of survival.
Profitability (Profitability) is defined as the ratio of the
firm's profits before interests and tax to its total assets. We use
this indicator to measure a firm's efficiency. It is widely
accepted that internal funds can serve as a buffer to absorb unexpected
losses, reducing the probability of insolvency and, therefore, the
expected bankruptcy cost (see Bridges and Guariglia 2008; Bunn and
Redwood 2003). We therefore expect to find profitability to decrease the
probability of failure.
The covariates used in the vector Y are all chosen in view of other
work on firm survival. We add the firm size (Size) measured as the
logarithm of real total assets. According to Geroski (1995), a
firm's size plays an important role in determining firm failures.
The argument is that large firms experience higher survival
probabilities than their smaller counterparts because they have access
to alternative sources of external finance and they are less
informationally opaque. Thus large firms are less likely to fail than
small firms (Clementi and Hopenhayn 2006; Dunne, Roberts, and Samuelson
1998). In our analysis, we expect to find a positive relationship
between firm size and the probability of survival. We also include the
age of the firm (Age) which measures the number of years since the
firm's birth. Firms with an established track record are less
likely to fail than those that are younger because they are usually more
able to withstand past economic and financial downturns and therefore
face a smaller liquidation risk. This would be the case both for
domestic and multinational firms as noted by Gorg and Strobl (2002).
Consequently, we anticipate a negative relationship between age and the
probability of failure.
In addition, we account for whether a firm is part of a larger
corporation or a group (UK or foreign). Following the relevant
literature, we construct the dummy variable Group, which takes the value
one if a firm is part of a group, and zero otherwise. We expect to
observe a negative relationship between this variable and the hazard of
failure since group firms are likely to have better access to capital
markets and to respond more quickly to shocks than single firms, due to
better information processing (Bridges and Guariglia 2008). We also
control for foreign ownership by using a dummy variable, Ownership,
equal to one if the share of foreign ownership in a firm's equity
exceeds 24.99%, and zero otherwise. The evidence on the impact of
foreign-owned firms on survival chances is mixed. (12) Therefore, we
should expect ownership to have a significant effect on failure but its
sign will be determined by the data.
In vector Y we also control for the macroeconomic conditions by
adding the real exchange rate, which measures the exchange rate
environment. Baggs, Beaulieu, and Fung (2009) document a negative
association between survival and appreciation of the Canadian dollar. We
expect the exchange rate (Exchange) to be positively associated with the
firm's probability to fail. In addition, we control for aggregate
uncertainty by using a policy uncertainty measure. This economic policy
uncertainty measure for the UK is drawn from Baker, Bloom, and Davis
(2013). It is constructed with a 50% weight on a news-based component
from the Financial Times and The Times newspapers (i.e., the mention of
policy relevant terms) and 50% on Consensus Economics CPI and budget
deficit forecaster disagreement. We expect higher levels of aggregate
uncertainty to reduce firms' chances of survival. Finally, our
model includes a full set of time, industry, and regional dummies. To
obtain efficient estimators and unbiased standard errors we apply the
Huber-White sandwich or robust estimator.
The Effect of the Crisis. To examine whether the hazard of failure
differs in crisis years compared with tranquil periods, we augment
Equation (3) with a financial crisis dummy (Crisis), which takes value
one over the period 2007-2009, and zero otherwise. The financial crisis
might have both a direct and an indirect impact on exit by magnifying
the effect of uncertainty on firms' likelihood to fail.
(4) h(j,X) = 1 - exp [-exp ([[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1]Sigma *
Crisis + [[beta].sub.2]Sigma * (1 - Crisis) + [[beta].sub.3] Crisis +
[[beta].sub.4]X + [[beta].sub.5]T + [[gamma].sub.j])]
This test is motivated by the financial-accelerator-related
hypothesis, according to which a deterioration in economic conditions
negatively affects the health of firms' balance sheets. In these
circumstances, firms facing increased levels of uncertainty might face a
higher probability of failure during the crisis than outside. The sign
and significance of the interacted terms will reveal the extent to which
the impact of uncertainty on firm survival differs during tranquil and
turbulent periods. We expect the effects of changes in the uncertainty
on firms' chances of failure to be stronger during the crisis
(i.e., we expect to observe that [[beta].sub.1] > [[beta].sub.2]).
Finally, the crisis term is allowed to influence the probability of firm
failure directly, judged from the sign and significance of the
coefficient [[beta].sub.3].
Capturing Firm Heterogeneity. At the next stage we aim to assess
whether changes in the level of uncertainty of firms in and out of the
crisis will have a differential impact on their probability to fail,
taking into account firm heterogeneity. To test this hypothesis we
consider whether firms are more or less bank dependent. This test is
motivated by recent evidence, both in the UK and the United States,
which shows an increase in loan spreads during the crisis. In
particular, Santos (2011) and Bell and Young (2010) document that banks
interrupted their lines of credit due to liquidity problems, and thus we
should expect bank dependent firms to be more severely affected during
the financial crisis.
As in Kashyap, Stein, and Wilcox (1993) and Tsoukas (2011), we
define bank-dependent firms based on their ratio of short-term debt to
total debt (Mix). As short-term debt is predominantly made up of bank
finance, this ratio is a good proxy of bank dependency. (13) We modify
Equation (3) to contain interaction terms between the Mix ratio, the
Crisis dummy, and the uncertainty measure. This yields the following
empirical model:
(5) h(j,X) - 1 - exp [-exp ([[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1]Sigma *
Mix * Crisis + [[beta].sub.2] Sigma * Mix * (1 - Crisis) +
[[beta].sub.3]Mix + [[beta].sub.4]Crisis + [[beta].sub.5]X +
[[beta].sub.6]Y + [[gamma].sub.j])]
The sign and significance of the interacted terms will reveal
whether firms more (less) likely to be bank dependent are less (more)
likely to survive during the crisis compared with tranquil periods. We
also allow both Mix and the crisis dummy to influence firms'
chances of failure directly.
Finally, we run the above model distinguishing between public and
private companies. According to our hypothesis, private firms are more
likely to face financial constraints and hence may respond more strongly
to uncertainty compared with public firms, especially during the crisis
period. We expect, therefore, the behavior of private firms to match
that of firms with high dependence on banks. (14)
IV. DATA AND SUMMARY STATISTICS
A. Data Description
Our data set is drawn from the annual accounting reports taken from
the FAME database, published by Bureau Van Dijk Electronic Publishing
(BvDEP). We employ data for the period 2000-2009. (15) We use a rich
financial data-set that comprises mainly non-publicly traded UK
manufacturing firms. Our database includes a majority of firms that are
not traded on the stock market or quoted on alternative exchanges such
as the Alternative Investment Market (AIM) and the Off-Exchange (OFEX)
market. In fact, 98.2% of our sampled firms are private, while 1.8% are
public companies. This figure is comparable with recent studies that
employ the FAME database to analyze UK firms' behavior (see Brav
2009; Caglayan and Rashid 2014; Michaely and Roberts 2012). Moreover,
this is an appealing characteristic of the data as it allows our
measures of uncertainty and financial health to display a wide degree of
variation across observations in our sample. Having data on unquoted
firms is particularly valuable in our case, as the unlisted companies
are generally the smallest, youngest, and most-bank dependent firms.
They are, therefore, more likely to be associated with the highest
degree of information asymmetry and hence face an increased probability
of failure, especially during extreme economic conditions.
Looking at the quartile distribution of various size measures in
Table 1, we observe the variation over firms in terms of turnover, total
assets, and number of employees. The median UK firm in our sample has an
average of 85 employees, 4.7 million [pounds sterling] assets, and 9.5
million [pounds sterling] turnover which falls in the small and
medium-sized enterprise category. (16)
To accurately construct our dependent variable we also take into
account that some firms may exit due to mergers and acquisitions.
Following Gorg and Spaliara (2014), we employ Bureau Van Dijk's
ZEPHYR database which contains information on mergers and acquisitions.
Using ZEPHYR we are able to identify and drop those firms that are
mistakenly coded as "failed" in our data. This ensures that
our indicator variable has been accurately constructed to capture firms
that failed and did not exit due to mergers and acquisitions.
Following normal selection criteria used in the literature, we drop
firms that do not have complete records on our main regression. To
control for the potential influence of outliers, we exclude observations
in the .5% tails for each of our regression variables. Our final panel,
which is unbalanced, includes 9,457 firms corresponding to 51,101
observations.
B. Descriptive Analysis
As a way of preliminary analysis, we depict the evolution of micro
and macro uncertainty in Figures 1 and 2. In Figure 1 we plot average
values of the firm-specific uncertainty per annum. A period of
quiescence during the Great Moderation is followed by a considerable
increase in uncertainty associated with Lehman's collapse and the
Global Financial Crisis in 2008 and 2009. We observe that both measures
of uncertainty follow a similar trend over our sample period. (17)
We present summary statistics for the variables used in our
empirical analysis in Table 2. The figures are presented for all firms
(column 1), for failed and surviving firms (columns 2 and 3) and for
firms during and outside the crisis (columns 5 and 6) reporting means
and standard deviations. Further, the p values of a test for the
equality of means between failing and surviving firms as well as crisis
and noncrisis periods are presented in columns 4 and 7, respectively. We
can see that the average failure rate in our sample is 16.1% which is
much higher compared with previous UK studies (e.g., Bunn and Redwood
2003). The difference between our figures and theirs may probably be due
to the fact that their sample covers a much earlier time period (up to
2003). It is therefore possible that failure rates have increased
sharply over the most recent years. This is also consistent with
statistics reported in the Office for National Statistics (ONS Business
Demography Bulletins, 2007, 2008, and 2009).
When comparing failing and surviving firms, we note that the former
exhibit a substantially higher firm-specific uncertainty. We also
observe that surviving firms are less indebted and more profitable
compared with failing firms. These statistics confirm previous empirical
results (see Bridges and Guariglia 2008; Bunn and Redwood 2003; Zingales
1998) that firms which display healthier balance sheets are less likely
to fail. In addition, we find that survivors are larger and older which
is in line with previous empirical and theoretical research, which shows
that the probability of exit decreases with firm size and age (e.g.,
Jovanovic 1982; Clementi and Hopenhayn 2006). Furthermore, survivors are
more likely to be part of a UK group and foreign owned. These
differences between sub-samples are statistically significant in all
cases.
Moving to the comparison between crisis and out of crisis periods
(columns 5 and 6), we note that the average failure rate and the
firm-specific uncertainty are higher during the crisis. These
differences are statistically significant in both cases. In addition,
during the crisis firms display lower values of leverage and higher
profitability. This is consistent with the notion that firms took a
substantial amount of short-term debt in the precrisis period and
perhaps were unable to extend it further in the later years of our
sample. The latter statistic is in line with ONS data on profitability
for UK manufacturing firms. (18) p Values suggest that differences
between sub-samples are statistically significant in all but one case.
Taken together, these summary statistics suggest that there is a
significant correlation between firms' failure rates, firm-specific
uncertainty, and firms' financial health. This relationship is even
more important during the global financial crisis. It remains to be
seen, though, whether these preliminary findings continue to hold when
we control for a number of factors which are known to play a role in
determining firms' survival chances. In the sections that follow,
we test within a formal regression analysis framework whether the
sensitivity of survival to firm-specific uncertainty is significantly
higher during the financial crisis compared with tranquil periods.
V. MAIN RESULTS
A. Firm-Specific Uncertainty and the Financial Crisis
To assess the role of the firm-specific uncertainty in firms'
hazard of failure, we focus on the direct and indirect (through
interactions with the crisis dummy) impact on the probability of
survival. We specify a time-period dummy variable to indicate that firms
faced the 2007-2009 financial crisis, and this crisis dummy takes the
value of one during this period, and the value zero otherwise. Results
are reported in Table 3. In column 1, we include firm-specific
uncertainty along with time, industry, and regional dummies. In the
subsequent column, uncertainty is included along with a number of
firm-specific and other control variables to assess the consequences of
a ceteris paribus increase in uncertainty on the probability of
firms' failure. Column 3 explores whether in addition to having a
direct effect on firms' chances of survival, the financial crisis
may also have an asymmetric response through interactions with the
firm-specific uncertainty. (19)
To begin with, the coefficient on the firm-specific uncertainty
exerts a positive and highly significant effect on failure. This finding
is not only statistically but also economically important. The predicted
probability of exit, evaluated at the mean of the independent variables,
is 9%. The coefficient on the firm-specific uncertainty suggests that
the probability of failure is rising, which translates to an increase in
the predicted exit probability by around 12.5 percentage points. This is
calculated at the mean exit probability of 9%, using the exponentiated
coefficient: exp(.869) - 1 = 1.384, (1.384*9) = 12.46%. (20) Consistent
with our expectations, increases in the firm-specific uncertainty will
therefore negatively affect firms' survival prospects.
The point estimates on the control and financial variables behave
as conjectured. Specifically, the coefficient associated with the
aggregate uncertainty is positive and precisely determined, suggesting
that higher levels of macro uncertainty are likely to increase the
incidence of corporate failure. In addition, firms which are less
indebted and more profitable are less likely to fail. Larger and older
firms are also less at risk compared to smaller and younger companies
that lack track record reputation. These results are in line with a
number or previous studies (Zingales 1998; Bridges and Guariglia 2008;
Gorg and Spaliara 2014). Regarding the remaining control indicators,
being part of a group and being foreign owned improve the survival
prospects of firms (Bridges and Guariglia 2008). Lastly, as in Baggs,
Beaulieu, and Fung (2009), a stronger local currency raises the
probability of firm failure, while higher levels of aggregate
uncertainty will raise the probability of failure. This is consistent
with the existing evidence of negative impact of uncertainty on
investment at micro level, see for example Bloom, Bond, and Van Reenen
(2007) and Baum, Caglayan, and Talavera (2010b) for a panel of UK and US
firms respectively.
Moving to the interaction terms, as shown in column 3 of Table 3,
we gauge the differential role of microeconomic uncertainty in firm
survival. In particular, we find that uncertainty has a more potent role
during the crisis, because the coefficient on the interaction with the
crisis dummy is positive and highly significant. The difference in this
effect across the two time periods is economically important: a 1%
increase in the firm-specific uncertainty would raise the hazard of
failure by 19.45% over the crisis period 2007-2009, but only by 9.88%
during tranquil periods. The p value for the equality of the
coefficients indicates a statistically significant difference between
the two coefficients. In addition, we find that the crisis dummy attains
a positive and highly significant coefficient indicating that during the
crisis period the probability of firm failure is higher compared with
tranquil times.
B. The Role of Firm-Level Heterogeneity
Bank-Dependent Firms. Having identified a significant relationship
between firm-specific uncertainty, the financial crisis, and probability
of failure, we now explore whether this relationship differs when we
consider firms which are likely to be dependent on bank finance.
According to our hypothesis, bank-dependent firms have had their lines
of credit dramatically reduced during the recent crisis. Given their
inability to finance their activities from external sources (e.g.,
stocks or bond finance), they are likely to have suffered more than
their less bank-dependent counterparts. Consequently, we anticipate the
effect of firm-specific uncertainty to be stronger for firms exhibiting
a greater reliance on bank debt compared with their less-bank dependent
counterparts. Therefore, in Table 4 we explore the impact of
interactions between crisis and noncrisis periods and firm-specific
uncertainty for firms that are more or less likely to be categorized as
bank dependent.
Focusing on rows 1 and 2 of Table 4, we observe that as firms rely
more on bank debt, the measure of firm-specific uncertainty displays a
larger coefficient during the crisis than outside. A test for the
equality of the coefficients is reported at the foot of the table. It
shows that the differences in the coefficients on the interactions
during and outside the crisis are statistically significant. To put it
differently, the greater sensitivities of firm survival to changes in
the firm-specific uncertainty documented for more-bank firms during the
crisis than outside suggests that higher levels of uncertainty coupled
with limited access to credit may play a detrimental role in explaining
the high number of failures in the UK during the most recent financial
crisis.
With respect to the other control variables, it is worth noting
that the crisis dummy and the Mix ratio are both positive but
quantitatively unimportant. Lastly, the remaining firm-specific and
macroeconomic variables retain their significance, with the only
exception being the private dummy which enters with the expected
positive sign but it is not precisely determined.
Public Versus Private Firms. In a final exploration we investigate
whether the behavior of public firms is different from that of private
firms. Our rationale for the categorization of public versus nonpublic
firms stems from the fact that public companies are typically larger and
less informationaly opaque. Private companies, on the other hand, face a
higher degree of information asymmetry and tend to be more financially
constrained. As a consequence, for these firms lenders typically command
higher borrowing costs resulting to higher spreads (see Brav 2009;
Caglayan and Rashid 2014). We hypothesize, therefore, that private firms
are more likely to respond more strongly to uncertainty compared with
public firms, especially during the crisis period. Hence, we interact a
dummy variable representing the private firms (Private) with crisis and
noncrisis periods and our measure of firm-specific uncertainty.
The results are reported in Table 5. For private firms there is a
significant difference in response compared to public firms.
Firm-specific uncertainty is a highly significant determinant of firm
survival during the crisis compared to tranquil periods. The response of
public firms matches that of the less bank-dependent firms reported
above. When we consider public firms both in and out of the crisis, we
find that there is no significantly different response in crisis with
respect to uncertainty. We also note that the Mix ratio attains a
positive coefficient which is significant at the 1% level. This finding
shows that bank dependency affects the hazard rate directly since
greater levels of bank reliance are likely to increase the probability
of firm failure. We conclude that public and private firms may face
different credit supply conditions based on their specific
characteristics, and responded differently during the most recent
crisis.
VI. ROBUSTNESS TESTS
A. Re-Defining Firm-Specific Uncertainty
Thus far, we have used the 3-year moving standard deviation of the
unpredictable part of sales to generate our uncertainty measure. To
check the robustness of our results, we follow Caglayan, Maioli, and
Mateut (2012) and construct the firmspecific uncertainty measure using a
4-year moving standard deviation (Sigma2). (21)
The results are reported in Table 6. In agreement with our main
results, we show that the firm-specific uncertainty is more important in
predicting firm failures during the crisis compared with tranquil times.
In addition, we find that bank-dependent firms' survival chances
are affected significantly more by changes in uncertainty during the
crisis compared with more tranquil periods. In sum, we argue that our
main findings are robust to an alternative definition of firm-specific
uncertainty.
B. An Alternative Definition for Bank Dependency
To ensure the robustness of our findings, we re-define the variable
indicating firms' reliance on bank debt using the ratio of
short-term debt to total current liabilities (Mix2). The results are
reported in Table 7. Once again, we find that the crisis intensified the
effects of uncertainty and firms that were bank dependent faced
significantly higher chances of failure compared with less
bank-dependent firms. These results suggest that our main findings are
robust to using a different definition for the bank dependency.
VII. CONCLUSIONS
It is well established in the theoretical and empirical literature
that uncertainty has negative consequences for economic activity.
However, there is some debate about the exact mechanism by which
uncertainty affects the economy. The recent financial crisis has
highlighted that violations of Modigliani-Miller theorem may be more
transparent due to the specific banking nature of the Great Financial
Crisis. And while stock markets did suffer, the impact was much more
temporary. Financial markets were acting as an accelerator or amplifier
of economic shocks, including uncertainty.
One popular idea is financial conditions accelerate the uncertainty
impact on the economy. This paper sought to examine the uncertainty-firm
survival nexus, with particular reference to financial interactions.
Using a large firm-level data set we consider how financial conditions
may have altered during the recent financial crisis, over and above the
effects of firm-level uncertainty. We also explore whether
bank-dependent and private companies are impacted to a greater extent by
uncertainty. It may be reasonable to expect that firms exhibiting
greater reliance on bank debt and nonpublic firms shall be more
sensitive to uncertainty, for example due to an increase in the size of
their external finance premium or the extent of available credit.
Our results document a significant effect of uncertainty on firm
survival. This link is found to be more potent during the recent
financial crisis compared with tranquil periods. We also uncover
significant firm-level heterogeneity because the survival chances of
bank-dependent and nonpublic firms are most affected by changes in
uncertainty, especially during the recent global financial crisis. Our
findings are of interest to policy makers who should take into account
the response of firms to uncertainty when they contemplate policies that
will make finance to companies more readily available.
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12240
ABBREVIATIONS
AIM: Alternative Investment Market
FAME: Financial Analysis Made Easy
SMEs: Small- and Medium-Sized Enterprises
REFERENCES
Arellano, M., and O. Bover. "Another Look at the Instrumental
Variable Estimation of Error Components Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 68, 1995, 29-51.
Baggs, J., E. Beaulieu, and L. Fung. "Firm Survival,
Performance, and the Exchange Rate." Canadian Journal of Economics,
42, 2009, 393-421.
Baker, S., N. Bloom, and S. Davis. "Measuring Economic Policy
Uncertainty." Chicago Booth Working Paper No. 13-02. Accessed June
15, 2015. http://www .policyuncertainty.com, 2013.
Baum, C., A. Stephan, and O. Talavera. "The Effects of
Uncertainty on the Leverage of Non-Financial Firms." Economic
Inquiry, 47, 2009, 216-25.
Baum, C., M. Caglayan, and O. Talavera. "On the Investment
Sensitivity of Debt under Uncertainty." Economics Letters, 106,
2010a, 25-27.
--. "On the Sensitivity of Firms' Investment to Cash Flow
and Uncertainty." Oxford Economic Papers, 62, 2010b, 286-306.
Bell, V., and G. Young. "Understanding the Weakness of Bank
Lending." Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Q4,2010,311-20.
Bernanke, B., and M. Gertler. "Inside the Black Box: The
Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission." Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 9, 1995, 27-48.
Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. "The Financial
Accelerator and the Flight to Quality." Review of Economics and
Statistics, 78, 1996, 1-15.
--. "The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business
Cycle Framework," in Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1C, edited by
J. Taylor and M. Woodford. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier Science,
1999.
Bernard, A., and F. Sjoholm. "Foreign Owners and Plant
Survival." Working Paper 10039, NBER, 2003.
Blalock, G., P. J. Gertler, and D. Levine. "Financial
Constraints on Investment in an Emerging Crisis." Journal of
Monetary Economics, 55, 2008, 568-91.
Bloom, N. "Uncertainty and the Dynamics of R&D."
American Economic Review, 97, 2007, 250-55.
--. "The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks." Econometrica,
74,2009, 391-415.
Bloom, N., S. Bond, and J. Van Reenen. "The Dynamics of
Investment under Uncertainty." Working Paper 01/05, Institute for
Fiscal Studies, London, 2001.
--. "Uncertainty and Investment Dynamics." Review of
Economic Studies, 74, 2007, 391-415.
Blundell, R., and S. Bond. "Initial Conditions and Moment
Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 87, 1998, 115-43.
Bo, H., and R. Lensin. "Is the Investment Uncertainty
Relationship Nonlinear? An Empirical Analysis for the Netherlands."
Economica, 72, 2005, 307-31.
Bond, S., and J. Van Reenen. "Microeconometric Models of
Investment and Employment," in Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. 6,
edited by J. Heckman and E. Learner. Amsterdam, The Netherlands:
Elsevier Science, 2007.
Brav, O. "Access to Capital, Capital Structure, and the
Funding of the Firm." Journal of Finance, 64, 2009, 263-308.
Bridges, S., and A. Guariglia. "Financial Constraints, Global
Engagement, and Firm Survival in the UK: Evidence from Micro Data."
Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 55, 2008, 444-64.
Bunn, P, and V. Redwood. "Company Accounts Based Modelling of
Business Failures and the Implications for Financial Stability."
Working Paper 210, Bank of England, 2003.
Caballero, R. "Aggregate Investment," in Handbook of
Macroeconomics, Vol. IB, edited by J. Taylor and M. Woodford. Amsterdam,
The Netherlands: Elsevier Science, 1999.
Caglayan, M., and A. Rashid. "The Response of Firms'
Leverage to Risk: Evidence from UK Public Versus Nonpublic Manufacturing
Firms." Economic Inquiry, 52, 2014, 341-63.
Caglayan, M., S. Maioli, and S. Mateut. "Inventories, Sales
Uncertainty, and Financial Strength." Journal of Banking and
Finance, 36, 2012, 2512-21.
Carlsson, M. "Investment and Uncertainty: A Theory-Based
Empirical Approach." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,
69, 2007, 603-17.
Clementi, L., and H. Hopenhayn. "A Theory of Financing
Constraints and Firm Dynamics." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 54,
2006, 229-65.
Denis, S., and P. Kannan. "The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks on
the UK Economy." Working Paper 13/66, International Monetary Fund,
2013.
Desai, M., and K. Forbes. "Financial Constraints and Growth:
Multinational and Local Firm Responses to Currency Depreciations."
Review of Financial Studies, 21, 2008, 2857-88.
Dixit, A. "Entry and Exit Decisions under Uncertainty."
Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1989, 620-38.
Dixit, A., and R. Pindyck. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press, 1994.
Dunne, T, M. Roberts, and L. Samuelson. "Patterns of Firm
Entry and Exit in US Manufacturing Industries." Rand Journal of
Economics, 19, 1998,495-515.
Garcia-Vega, M., A. Guariglia, and M.-E. Spaliara.
"Volatility, Financial Constraints, and Trade." International
Review of Economics and Finance, 21, 2012, 57-76.
Geroski, P. "What Do We Know About Entry?" International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 1995, 421-40.
Ghosal, V. "Impact of Uncertainty and Sunk Costs on Firm
Survival and Industry Dynamics." Working Paper 12,
Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin (WZB), 2003.
Ghosal, V, and P. Loungani. "The Differential Impact of
Uncertainty on Investment in Small and Large Businesses." Review of
Economics and Statistics, 82, 2000, 338-43.
Gilchrist, S., J. Sim, and E. Zakrajsek. "Uncertainty,
Financial Frictions, and Investment Dynamics." Mimeo, Boston
University, 2013.
Gorg, H., and M.-E. Spaliara. "Financial Health, Exports, and
Firm Survival: Evidence from UK and French Firms." Economica, 81,
2014, 419-44.
Gorg, H., and E. Strobl. "Multinational Companies and
Indigenous Development: An Empirical Analysis." European Economic
Review, 46, 2002, 1305-22.
--. "Multinational Companies, Technology Spillovers and Plant
Survival." Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 105, 2003, 581-95.
Guiso, L., and G. Parigi. "Investment and Demand
Uncertainty." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 1999, 185-227.
Haddow, A., C. Hare, J. Hooley, and T. Shakir. "Macroeconomic
Uncertainty: What Is It, How Can We Measure It and Why Does It
Matter?" Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Q2, 2013, 100-09.
Hall, R. "Why Does the Economy Fall to Pieces after a
Financial Crisis?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24, 2010,
3-20.
Hopehayn, R. "Entry, Exit and Firm Dynamics in Long Run
Equilibrium." Econometrica, 60, 1992, 1127-55.
Huynh, K., and R. Petrunia. "Age Effects, Leverage and Firm
Growth." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34, 2010,
1003-13.
Huynh, K., R. Petrunia. and M. Voia. "The Impact of Initial
Financial State on Firm Duration across Entry Cohorts." Journal of
Industrial Economics, 58, 2010, 661-89.
Jenkins, S. "Survival Analysis." Mimeo, University of
Essex, 2005.
Jovanovic, B. "Selection and Evolution of Industry."
Econometrica, 50, 1982,3-37.
von Kalckreuth, U. "Exploring the Role of Uncertainty for
Corporate Investment Decisions in Germany." Swiss Journal of
Economics and Statistics, 139, 2000, 173-206.
Kashyap, A., J. Stein, and D. Wilcox. "Monetary Policy and
Credit Conditions: Evidence from the Composition of External
Finance." American Economic Review, 83, 1993,78-98.
Leahy, J., and T. Whited. "The Effect of Uncertainty on
Investment: Some Stylized Facts." Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 28, 1996, 64-83.
Lensink, R., H. Bo, and E. Sterken. "Does Uncertainty Affect
Economic Growth? An Empirical Analysis." Review of World Economics,
135, 1999, 379-96.
Levin, A., F. Natalucci, and E. Zakrajsek. "The Magnitude and
Cyclical Behaviour of Financial Market Frictions." Working Paper
2004-70, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2004.
Michaely, R., and M. Roberts. "Corporate Dividend Policies:
Lessons from Private Firms." Review of Financial Studies,
25,2012,711-46.
Mishkin, F. "Over the Cliff: From the Subprime to the Global
Financial Crisis." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25,
2011,49-70.
Mitchell, J., K. Mouratidis, and M. Weale. "Uncertainty in UK
Manufacturing: Evidence from Qualitative Survey Data." Economics
Letters, 94, 2007, 245-52.
Mizen, P., and S. Tsoukas. "The Response of the External
Finance Premium in Asian Corporate Bond Markets to Financial
Characteristics, Financial Constraints and Two Financial Crises."
Journal of Banking and Finance, 36, 2012, 3048-59.
Morgan, D., B. Rime, and P. Strahan. "Bank Integration and
State Business Cycles." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 2004,
1555-84.
Patillo, C. "Investment, Uncertainty and Irreversibility in
Ghana." IMF Staff Papers, 45, 1998, 522-53.
Santos, J. "Bank Corporate Loan Pricing Following the Subprime
Crisis." Review of Financial Studies, 24, 2011, 1916-43.
Tsoukas, S. "Firm Survival and Financial Development: Evidence
from a Panel of Emerging Asian
Economies." Journal of Banking and Finance, 35,2011, 1736-52.
Zingales, L. "Survival of the Fittest or the Fattest? Exit and
Financing in Trucking Industry." Journal of Finance,
53,1998,905-38.
(1.) It is a standard result in the theoretical literature that
uncertainty is associated with a decline in economic activity (see
Mishkin 2011). Dixit and Pindyck (1994) provide one appealing
explanation for why irreversible investment is reduced by uncertainty.
(2.) There is evidence showing that the leverage of private UK
manufacturing firms is more sensitive to firm-specific risk compared to
their public counterparts (Caglayan and Rashid 2014).
(3.) For an extensive survey of microeconomic studies of investment
and uncertainty see Bond and Van Reenen (2007). In particular, prominent
work in the literature on firm investment and uncertainty include Leahy
and Whited (1996), Guiso and Parigi (1999), and Bloom (2007).
(4.) In this context, firm size may be an important determinant.
(5.) To capture the particular nature of the data-set, given that
it is collected on a yearly basis, the cloglog model is more appropriate
than the standard Cox model (see Gorg and Spaliara 2014). Also, see
Jenkins (2005) for an excellent overview of complementary log-log and
proportional hazard models.
(6.) [[gamma].sub.j] is the log of the difference between the
integrated baseline hazard evaluated at the end and the beginning of the
interval. It, thus, captures duration dependence. We do not impose any
restrictions on these parameters, rather we estimate a full set of
[gamma.sub.j] time dummies.
(7.) Other authors use firm surveys of expectations (see Guiso and
Parigi 1999; Patillo 1998) or a theoretical measure of microeconomic
uncertainty (Carlsson 2007).
(8.) Alternative measures of firm level of uncertainty can in
principle be extracted from, for example, Confederation of British
Industry survey data (see Mitchell, Mouratidis, and Weale 2007).
However, the concordance of firms would present significant challenges
and coverage may be incomplete for our unlisted firms. Moreover
multivariate GARCH methods based upon the cross sectional data could be
adopted, but this would present significant computational challenges
given the short time dimension of the data.
(9.) We check the sensitivity of our results to using a different
measure of sales uncertainty computed over the 4 years preceding and
including year t (see Section VI).
(10.) It should be noted that given the way in which we calculate
uncertainty, this variable is not available for the years 2000 and 2001.
For this reason, all regressions which contain our main measure of
uncertainty are based on the sample 2002-2009.
(11.) Their model generates a role for capital structure in an
asymmetric information setup. The theoretical frameworks on survival
were first introduced by Hopehayn (1992) and Jovanovic (1982) without
considering a role for moral hazard.
(12.) Using data from Ireland and Indonesia, Gorg and Strobl (2003)
and Bernard and Sjoholm (2003), respectively, show that multinationals
are more likely to exit than domestic firms. On the other hand, Blalock,
Gertler, and Levine (2008), and Desai and Forbes (2008) find that global
engagement improves firms' performance, and hence reduces their
likelihood of failure.
(13.) To ensure that our results are robust, we carry out our
estimations using an alternative definition of bank dependency based on
short-term debt over current liabilities.
(14.) To ensure that bank dependence and the distinction between
private/public firms control for different firm aspects, we control for
firms' ownership structure when estimating models of bank
dependency and vice versa.
(15.) A maximum of 10 years of complete data history can be
downloaded at once. We have only selected firms that have unconsolidated
accounts: this ensures that the majority of the firms in our data-set
are relatively small. Moreover, it avoids the double counting of firms
belonging to groups, which would be included in the data-set if firms
with consolidated accounts were also part of it.
(16.) In the UK, sections 382 and 465 of the Companies Act 2006
define a small and medium-sized enterprise (SME) for the purpose of
accounting requirements. According to this, a small company is one that
has a turnover of not more than 6.5 million [pounds sterling], a balance
sheet total of not more than 3.26 million [pounds sterling], and not
more than 50 employees. A medium-sized company has a turnover of not
more than 25.9 million [pounds sterling], a balance sheet total of not
more than 12.9 million [pounds sterling], and not more than 250
employees.
(17.) Other indicators of economic uncertainty for the UK such as
the Confederation of British Industry firm survey on demand uncertainty
and the FTSE option-implied volatility paint a very similar picture.
(18.) See the ONS Statistical Bulletin for details on UK
firms' profitability.
(19.) Time dummies are included in all models, with the exception
of the crisis years 2007-2009 when the crisis term is included on its
own.
(20.) As already noted, the hazard ratio can be calculated as
exp(k) for the kth regressor. Hence, in column 1 the coefficient on
sigma is .869, which is equivalent to a hazard ratio of exp(.869) - 1 =
1.384.
(21.) We also experimented with measuring firm-specific uncertainty
using firms' real sales calculated over all years preceding and
including year t. Our results were robust to this modification.
JOSEPH P. BYRNE, MARINA-ELIZA SPALIARA and SERAFEIM TSOUKAS *
* We are grateful to two anonymous referees and Wesley W. Wilson
(editor) for very helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank
Mustafa Caglayan and Rebecca Riley and participants at the 2014 European
Meetings of the Econometric Society, Toulouse School of Economics for
comments on an earlier version of this paper. Any remaining errors are
our own.
Byrne: Economics, School of Management and Languages, Heriot-Watt
University, Edinburgh, Scotland EH14 4AS, UK. Phone +44 (0)131 451 3626,
Fax +44 (0) 131 451 3296, E-mailj.p.byme@hw.ac.uk
Spaliara: Economics, Adam Smith Business School, University of
Glasgow, Glasgow, Scotland G12 8QQ, UK. Phone +44 (0)141 330 7596, Fax
+44 (0) 141 330 4939, E-mail marina.spaliara@glasgow.ac.uk
Tsoukas: Economics, Adam Smith Business School, University of
Glasgow, Glasgow, Scotland G12 8QQ, UK. Phone +44 (0)141 330 6325, Fax
+44 (0) 141 330 4939, E-mail serafeim.tsoukas@glasgow.ac.uk
TABLE 1
Detailed Statistics of Size Variables
Employees Assets Turnover
(1) (2) (3)
25% 31 2,249 4.000
50% 85 4,748 9,586
75% 234 13.932 25,442
Observations 85,231 123,535 78.760
Notes: The table presents the median and the upper and
lower quartiles of three size measures. "Employees" denotes
the number of employees. "Assets" represents total assets.
"Turnover" is the sum of domestic and overseas turnover.
Assets and turnover are measured in thousands of UK sterling.
TABLE 2
Summary Statistics
All Firms Fail=1 Fail=0 Diff.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Fail .161 1.00 .00 --
(.37) (.00) (.00)
Sigma .159 .187 .157 .000
(.16) (.19) (.16)
Leverage .466 .527 .459 .000
(.27) (.31) (.27)
Profitability .076 .037 .081 .000
(.16) (.19) (.16)
Size 3.953 3.728 3.984 .000
(1.38) (1.29) (1.39)
Age 25.048 24.606 25.133 .000
(23.01) (23.47) (22.92)
Group .212 .099 .233 .000
(.41) (.29) (.42)
Ownership .174 .083 .190 .000
(.38) (.27) (.39)
Exchange 96.693 96.585 96.714 .130
(11.57) (5.01) (4.95)
Policy 97.539 97.899 97.470 .110
(37.59) (37.89) (37.53)
Observations 51,101 4,491 46,610
Crisis=1 Crisis=0 Diff.
(5) (6) (7)
Fail .165 .159 .014
(.37) (.36)
Sigma .164 .158 .000
(.16) (.17)
Leverage .440 .475 .000
(.28) (.27)
Profitability .088 .072 .000
(.17) (.16)
Size 4.040 3.922 .000
(1.32) (1.41)
Age 28.396 23.602 .000
(22.64) (23.02)
Group .210 .213 .325
(.41) (.41)
Ownership .173 .173 .795
(.37) (.38)
Exchange 84.229 102.081 .000
(9.20) (7.68)
Policy 140.106 79.141 .000
(38.49) (15.70)
Observations 16,854 34,247
Notes: The table presents sample means. Standard deviations are
reported in parentheses. Fail is a dummy that equals one if the
firm fails, and zero otherwise. Crisis is a dummy representing the
recent crisis and takes the value one in years 2007-2009, and zero
otherwise. Diff. is the p value of the test statistic for the
equality of means between failing and nonfalling firms (columns 1
and 2) as well as between crisis and noncrisis periods (columns 5
and 6). Sigma is a measure of firm-specific uncertainty. Leverage
is measured as the firm's total current liabilities to assets
ratio. Profitability is the ratio of the firm's profits before
interest and tax to its total assets. Size is denoted by the log of
real assets. Age is defined as the difference between the present
year and the firm's date of incorporation. Group is a dummy
variable equal to one if the firm is part of a group UK or foreign,
and zero otherwise. Ownership is a dummy equal to one if the share
of foreign ownership in a firm's equity exceeds 25%, and zero
otherwise. Exchange is the real effective exchange rate. Policy is
a measure of aggregate uncertainty. Firm-specific variables are
measured in thousands of UK sterling.
TABLE 3
Firm Survival and Uncertainty
(1) (2) (3)
Sigma .869 *** .782 ***
Sigma*Crisis (13.96) (11.38)
1.152 ***
Sigma*(1-Crisis) (5.74)
.741 ***
(10.21)
Crisis .245 ***
(3.78)
Leverage .009 * .009 *
(1.86) (1.85)
Profit -.024 * -.024 *
(-1.89) (-1.87)
Size -.182 *** -.182 ***
(-15.47) (-15.47)
Age -.002 *** 1 b o FO
(-2.47) (-2.47)
Group -.990 *** -.990 ***
(-19.33) (-19.35)
Ownership -.620 *** -.620 ***
(-12.59) (-12.59)
Exchange 6.469 *** 6.478 ***
(3.76) (3.76)
Policy 1.499 *** 1.501 ***
(3.71) (3.71)
Observations 51,762 51,101 51.101
Log-likelihood -14,101 -13,031 -13,029
Test of equality (p value)
Sigma .053
Notes: Proportional hazard model results are reported.
The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm
fails, and 0 otherwise. Robust z-statistics are presented in
parentheses. The F test of equality for Sigma refers to
the test of equality between Sigma*Crisis and Sigma*(1-
Crisis). Time, industry, and regional dummies are included in
all models.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant
at 1%.
TABLE 4
Uncertainty, Bank Dependency, and the Crisis
Sigma*Mix*Crisis 1.583 ***
(6.73)
Sigma*Mix*(1 -Crisis) .845 ***
(8.23)
Crisis .242
(.77)
Mix .063
(1.29)
Private .061
(.65)
Leverage .007
(1.61)
Profit -.025 *
(-1.93)
Size -.180 ***
(-15.37)
Age -.002 ***
(-2.75)
Group -.993 ***
(-19.38)
Ownership -.619 ***
(-12.54)
Exchange 6.438 ***
(3.75)
Policy 1.491 ***
(3.70)
Observations 51.101
Log likelihood -12,983
Test of equality (p value)
Sigma*Mix .003
Notes: Proportional hazard model results are reported.
The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm
fails, and 0 otherwise. Robust z-statistics are presented in
parentheses. Sigma *Mix refers to the test of equality between
Sigma*Mix*Crisis and Sigma*Mix*(l-Crisis). Time,
industry, and regional dummies are included in all models.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; ** significant
at 1%.
TABLE 5
Uncertainty, Ownership Structure, and the Crisis
Sigma*Private*Crisis 1.105 ***
(5.36)
Sigma*Private*(1-Crisis) .715 ***
(9.67)
Sigma*(1-Private)*Crisis .653 ***
(3.91)
Sigma*(1-Private)*(1-Crisis) 1.056 ***
(2.96)
Crisis .245
(.78)
Mix .237 ***
(5.22)
Private .31
(1.15)
Leverage .008
(1.63)
Profit -.024 *
(-1.87)
Size -.179 ***
(-15.36)
Age -.002 **
(-2.44)
Group -.992 ***
(-19.38)
Ownership -.617 ***
(-12.53)
Exchange 6.475 ***
(3.76)
Policy 1.500 ***
(3.71)
Observations 51.101
Log likelihood -12,956
Test of equality (p value)
Sigma*Private .074
Sigma*(1-Private) .309
Sigma*Crisis .070
Sigma*(l-Crisis) .347
Notes: Proportional hazard model results are reported.
The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the
firm fails, and 0 otherwise. Robust z-statistics are
presented in parentheses. Sigma*Private refers to the test
of equality between Sigma*Private*Crisis and Sigma*
Private*(l-Crisis). Sigma*Private) refers to the test of
equality between Sigma*Private)*Crisis and Sigma*
(1-Private)*(1-Crisis). Sigma*Crisis refers to the test
of equality between Sigma*Private*Crisis and Sigma*
(1-Private)*Crisis. Finally, Sigma*(1-Crisis) refers to the test
of equality between Sigma*Private*(1-Crisis) and Sigma*(1-
Private)*(l-Crisis). Time, industry, and regional dummies
are included in all models.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant
at 1%.
TABLE 6
Robustness: Alternative Definition of
Uncertainty
(1) (2)
Sigma2*Crisis .717 ***
(6.07)
Sigma2*(l-Crisis) .419 ***
(4.64)
Crisis .279 *** .227
(3.69) (.69)
Sigma2*Mix *Crisis .890 ***
(5.96)
Sigma2*Mix *(l-Crisis) .520 ***
(6.26)
Mix .104 *
(1.92)
Leverage .017 *** .015 **
(3.26) (2.90)
Profit -.018 -.019
(-1.32) (-1.18)
Size -.206 *** -.204 ***
(-15.48) (-15.31)
Age -.002 * -.002 **
(-1.89) (-2.16)
Group -.950 *** -.946 ***
(-16.42) (-16.37)
Ownership -.550 *** -.555 ***
(-10.16) (-10.15)
Exchange 6.019 *** 6.005 ***
(3.67) (3.67)
Policy 1.393 *** 1.391 ***
(3.62) (3.61)
Private .065
(.61)
Observations 44,559 44,559
Log likelihood -10.472 -10,473
Test of equality (p value)
Sigma2 .055
Sigma2*Mix .027
Notes: Proportional hazard model results are reported.
The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the
firm fails, and 0 otherwise. Robust z-statistics are presented
in parentheses. Sigma2*Mix refers to the test of
equality between Sigma2*Mix*Crisis and Sigma2*Mix *(1-
Crisis). Time, industry, and regional dummies are included in
all models.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant
at 1%.
TABLE 7
Robustness: Alternative Definition of Bank
Dependency
Sigma*Mix2*Crisis 1.670 ***
(5.47)
Sigma*Mix2*(1-Crisis) 1.007 ***
(8.21)
Crisis .243
(.76)
Mix2 -.071
(-1.10)
Private .056
(.60)
Leverage .007
(1.60)
Profit -.024 *
(-1.89)
Size -.185 ***
(-16.65)
Age -.002 ***
(-2.82)
Group -.991 ***
(-19.36)
Ownership -.623 ***
(-12.64)
Exchange 6.438 ***
(3.74)
Policy 1.492 ***
(3.69)
Observations 51.101
Log likelihood -13.044
Test of equality (p value)
Sigma*Mix2 .037
Notes: Proportional hazard model results are reported.
The dependent variable is a dummy equal to 1 if the
firm fails, and 0 otherwise. Robust z-statistics are
presented in parentheses. Sigma*Mix2 refers to the test of
equality between Sigma*Mix2*Crisis and Sigma *Mix2 *(1-
Crisis). Time, industry, and regional dummies are included in
all models.
* Significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant
at 1%.
COPYRIGHT 2016 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2016 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.