Oligarchies and development in a global economy: a tale of two elites.
Akerman, Anders ; Naghavi, Alireza ; Seim, Anna 等
Oligarchies and development in a global economy: a tale of two elites.
I. INTRODUCTION
Data from the post-World War II era of globalization reveal a
striking variation in the growth performance of nondemocratic countries:
they tend to either excel or fall behind. At the lower end of the
spectrum are some of the world's poorest performing economies, and
at the upper end the miraculous East Asian Tiger Economies, who have
doubled their income in a decade or less since the beginning of the
1960s. Openness to trade appears to have been conducive to growth in
some nondemocracies, but not in others. How can we explain these
differences in performance?
This research highlights an empirical feature that has been
somewhat overlooked in the literature: the fact that the endowments of
the political elites differ across countries. We build a specific-factor
trade model of an oligarchy, where the nature of the ruling political
elites and the comparative advantage determine the economy's
long-term performance. (1) The paper argues that the interaction of the
trade regime with industrial policies and with international capital
mobility is crucial for growth and development. If the political elites
are landowners in a capital-scarce economy, openness to trade creates an
environment of institutional neglect and stagnation. However, if the
political elites are instead capitalists, they gradually shift the
comparative advantage toward manufacturing by promoting sound industrial
policies, which eventually provides an incentive to open up to trade and
allow for foreign capital inflows. We also add to the existing
literature by stressing that the complementarity of policies on trade
and capital mobility is crucial for the economic success of oligarchies
and show that such complementarities arise if the ruling elites are
capitalists. (2)
A growing strand of literature emphasizes how political and
economic institutions shape long-run performance and helps us understand
some of the reasons nondemocracies differ, see for instance Acemoglu,
Johnson, and Robinson (2005a) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) for
overviews. (3) The relationship between openness and institutions has
become subject to intensive research only in recent years and the
empirical results are mixed. Free trade can either lead to stronger
institutions as in Ades and Di Telia (1999), Acemoglu, Johnson, and
Robinson (2005b), Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi (2004), and Rigobon
and Rodrik (2005), or to institutional deterioration as in Treisman
(2000) and Tavares (2007). As argued by Stefanadis (2010), the empirical
literature has been ahead of theory in this area and more theoretical
work is needed to deepen our understanding of the interaction between
globalization and the quality of institutions.
While proponents of trade argue that economic integration is
conducive to stronger institutions, a series of recent papers point out
that this is not always the case. Johnson, Ostry, and Subramanian (2007)
suggest that if returns from trade fall into the hands of a small elite,
the concentration of power that may follow can worsen institutions.
Bardhan (2010) confirms that the trade expansion in
natural-resource-intensive products has strengthened the political power
of large exporters who subsequently have raised barriers to entry and
promoted elite institutions. Levchenko (2013) adds that trade improves
the institutional quality if it reduces the rents from dysfunctional
institutions, but brings institutional deterioration in the opposite
case. Galiani and Torrens (2014) introduce trade policy as a political
cleavage between different types of elites. In the presence of
intra-elite conflict, elite groups bargain to control the economy and
confront popular revolt by shifting power to the group whose preferred
trade policy is in line with workers' demands. Other theoretical
papers have demonstrated the negative effect of autocracies opening to
trade on domestic economic institutions such as investment in schooling
(Falkinger and Grossman 2005), the investment climate (Do and Levchenko
2009), property rights (Stefanadis 2010), and technology adoption
(Cervellati, Naghavi, and Toubal 2013).
We contribute to the aforementioned literature by building a theory
showing that the effects of trade on economic institutions are
contingent on the nature of the political elites. We model an oligarchy,
consisting of an agricultural sector and a manufacturing sector. The
political elites hold either land or capital and we shall henceforth
refer to these economies as land and capital oligarchies, respectively.
Capital accumulation derives from capitalists leaving bequests to their
children, and the price of bequests crucially determines the saving
environment of the economy. (4) The economic institution that we focus
on is an industrial policy that encourages growth in the manufacturing
sector. We also introduce capital market liberalization as an additional
policy instrument that interacts with the trade regime in determining
economic performance. The rulers' policy space thus comprises the
following elements: (1) allowing for international trade in goods, (2)
strengthening economic institutions that promote manufacturing total
factor productivity (TFP), and (3) allowing for the inflow of foreign
capital.
The construct allows us to model strategies of import substitution
industrialization (ISI): by prohibiting trade, the oligarchs can
encourage the domestic industrial sector and protect it against foreign
competition. We consider a setting where each economy is characterized
by an initial comparative disadvantage in manufacturing, and study the
optimal regimes chosen in three types of oligarchies: a benchmark
capital oligarchy with inexpensive bequests, a land oligarchy, and a
capital oligarchy with expensive bequests. We show that the different
types of oligarchs choose trade regime based on the comparative
(dis)advantage of the factor that they hold and subsequently choose
different industrial policies. In addition, the endowments of the
political elites govern whether openness to trade and foreign capital
inflows are complementary policies.
The results suggest that the benchmark capitalist oligarchy
initially shelters the economy from global markets while promoting
industrial policies that encourage the development of the manufacturing
sector. By creating an environment conducive to capital accumulation and
growth, a comparative advantage in manufacturing is eventually achieved
and the oligarchs open up to trade once the domestic economy has grown
sufficiently strong. The strong industrial policies further succeed in
attracting productive, foreign capital, which further spurs growth. The
benefits of allowing for foreign capital inflows are realized only once
the economy is open to trade so that openness to trade and foreign
capital imports are complementary policies. This finding is consistent
with Rodrik (1994), who stresses that an important factor behind the
outstanding performances of South Korea and Taiwan was indeed
governments' abilities to raise the returns to private investments,
thereby increasing the demand for imported capital goods. Moreover, the
entrepreneurial elites in these miracle economies promoted large-scale
capital inflows only after opening up to trade in the 1970s. (5)
Landed oligarchs prefer to open up to trade at an early stage of
development, which impedes growth by creating an environment where
economic institutions are neglected. The weak institutions render the
economy unattractive to foreign investors and the landed elites opt
against the inflow of foreign capital. The landed oligarchy is thus
bound for stagnation. The complementarity between openness to trade and
the inflow of foreign capital that works as a catalyst for growth in the
capital oligarchy fails to materialize in the land oligarchy. The
predictions for this economy are broadly consistent with the development
of Argentina in the nineteenth century, when the political power lay in
the hands of landowners and the country primarily traded large volumes
of agrarian products.
Finally, we consider a capital autocracy where the saving
environment is less beneficial than in the benchmark. Allowing the price
of bequests to exceed that of current consumption changes the trade-off
between consumption and bequests faced by capitalists and creates weaker
incentives to invest. This capital autocracy still chooses to pursue an
1SI strategy by prohibiting trade and promoting industrial policies, but
capital accumulation is now hampered. The moderate growth of the
domestic capital stock delays the comparative-advantage reversal and the
economy opens up to trade later than in the benchmark capital oligarchy.
In terms of growth, this economy outperforms the land oligarchy, but
falls short of its counterpart with inexpensive bequests. This
experiment shows that being ruled by capitalists is no guarantee for
growth--institutions conducive to capital accumulation must also be in
place. The predictions for this example economy are largely consistent
with developments in Argentina in the postwar period when politicians,
catering to the preferences of industrial elites and workers,
implemented ISI policies that were unsuccessful in fostering growth. In
the case of Argentina, this led to the coup of 1976 in which the
military government backed by the agricultural elite seized power
(Brambilla, Galiani, and Porto 2015).
In sum, our model thus suggests the following: (1) starting out
with a comparative advantage in agriculture, capitalist oligarchs will
choose an ISI strategy and stay closed to trade while land oligarchs
will open immediately, (2) capitalist oligarchs strengthen economic
institutions in an open economy while landed oligarchs neglect them, (3)
trade in goods and capital imports are complementary policies in a
capital oligarchy but not in a land oligarchy, and (4) being ruled by
industrialists is no panacea for miracle growth--institutions conducive
to capital accumulation must also be in place.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II presents
the model. Section III discusses the equilibrium under different trade
regimes. Section IV introduces international capital mobility. Section V
presents the political-economy layer of the model and derives analytical
results on optimal policies. The results from a numerical simulation of
the model are presented in Section VI. A discussion based on historical
anecdotal evidence is presented in Section VII. Section VIII concludes.
II. THE MODEL
Consider a small, potentially open economy. The economy consists of
two sectors denoted j = A, M for agriculture and manufacturing. Each
sector produces a sector-specific good that is tradable in the world
market. There are three groups of households that differ in their
initial endowments and supply either land, capital, or labor to firms.
We assume that each time period, denoted t, is one generation so that
households and policymakers have one-period lives. Owners of the factors
of production have warm-glow preferences and leave bequests. (6)
We vary the assumption on the nature of the ruling oligarchs and
assume that they are either landowners or capitalists. (7) The oligarchs
govern economic institutions and make decisions on whether or not to
allow for international trade in goods and the inflow of foreign
capital.
We first treat regimes as exogenously given and focus on solving
the economic model in Sections II-IV. As we are ultimately interested in
how the ruling elites choose policies, we put particular emphasis on the
real returns to capital and land under different regimes in these
sections. The preferences and optimal choices of the oligarchs are then
analyzed in Section V.
A. Production
The agricultural and manufacturing sectors differ in terms of
technology and the factors employed in production. Labor is the only
input used in both technologies and is perfectly mobile across the two
sectors so that the labor supply is infinitely elastic.
The agricultural sector uses land (X) and labor (L) to produce the
agricultural good. Letting [Y.sub.A] denote the output of the
agricultural good:
(1) [Y.sub.At] = [X.sup.[alpha].sub.t] [L.sup.1-[alpha].sub.At],
where [alpha] [member of] (0, 1) and [L.sub.At] denotes the labor
employed in the sector.
The manufacturing sector uses capital (K) and labor to produce the
manufacturing good:
(2) [Y.sub.Mt] =
[A.sub.Mt][K.sup.[alpha].sub.t][L.sup.1-[alpha].sub.Mt],
where [A.sub.Mt] denotes total factor productivity in the
manufacturing sector and [L.sub.Mt] refers to the labor employed in the
sector. (8) [K.sub.t] = [A.sub.Kt][K.sub.Dt] + [K.sub.Ft] is the total
effective capital stock in the economy and comprises domestic and
foreign capital, [K.sub.Dt] and [K.sub.Ft], respectively. We treat
[A.sub.Kt] as a parameter for now to derive equilibrium expressions that
hold for [K.sub.Ft] [greater than or equal to] 0, and will return to
this issue in Section IV. (9)
While total factor productivity is assumed to be constant and
normalized to 1 in the agricultural sector, TLP in the manufacturing
sector grows at some exogenous rate [[gamma].sub.t] > 0. However, the
evolution of manufacturing TLP is also governed by industrial policy.
Specifically, [A.sub.Mt] evolves according to:
(3) [A.sub.Mt] = (1 + [[pi].sub.Mt][[gamma].sub.t]) [A.sub.Mt-1]
where [[pi].sub.Mt] [member of] 0, 1] is a policy variable. The
construct allows us to think of [[pi].sub.Mt] as a broad measure of the
quality of economic institutions, capturing the extent to which
policymakers seek to promote technological progress. In an environment
with strong economic institutions, that is, where industrial policy is
conducive to technology adoption, [[pi].sub.Mt] = 1, so that
manufacturing TLP grows at its full potential.
B. Endowments, Preferences, and Income
The population consists of capitalists, indexed K, landowners,
indexed X, and workers, indexed L. Letting [N.sub.K], [N.sub.X] and L
denote the measure of each group, the total population at time t is
[N.sub.t] = [N.sub.Kt] + [N.sub.Xt] + [L.sub.t]. We assume a stationary
Population normalized to 1, as population growth is of no importance for
the dynamics of interest in our setting. Landowners hold one unit of
land that they rent to firms in the agricultural sector, while
capitalists rent their capital to firms in the manufacturing sector.
(10)
Owners of the factors of production derive utility from consumption
and from leaving bequests to the next generation, depending on the
nature of their endowment. As our focus is on a regime where equilibrium
outcomes are driven by the preferences of the political elites, we
assume for simplicity that workers do not hold any resources, leave no
bequests, and hence consume their entire income. The utility function of
the elites takes the following form:
U ([C.sub.t], [B.sub.ht]) = [C.sup.[mu].sub.t]
[B.sup.1-[mu].sub.ht]
for h = K, X where [C.sub.t] = [C.sup.[sigma].sub.At]
[C.sup.1-[sigma].sub.Mt] is aggregate consumption, [B.sub.ht] denotes
bequests, and the maximization is subject to constraints that are
household-specific. Land and capital differ in that land does not
depreciate while capital depreciates fully from one generation to
another. This means that landowners simply leave their land endowments
to their successor, while capitalists bequeath a share of their income
in terms of an investment good. This makes bequests solely a part of the
budget constraint of capital owners, that is, [mu] = 1 for landowners.
(11)
Let [P.sub.At], [P.sub.Mt], and [P.sub.Bt] denote the prices of
agricultural, manufacturing, and bequest goods respectively. For
simplicity, we assume that savings are made in terms of manufacturing
goods, which implies [P.sub.Bt] = [xi][P.sub.Mt]. The parameter [xi]
[greater than or equal to] 1 indicates how costly bequests are relative
to current consumption and allows us to study the effects of different
saving environments. We treat the manufacturing sector as the numeraire
sector and set [P.sub.Mt] to unity. [P.sub.At] therefore denotes the
relative price of agricultural goods in terms of manufacturing goods.
Define the general price level as the nominal income needed to buy one
unit of the optimal basket of consumption and savings, so that the price
index facing each group is [P.sub.ht] = [[xi].sup.(1-[mu])]
[P.sup.[mu][sigma].sub.At].
Under these assumptions, the indirect utility functions of the
elite households are:
(4) [V.sub.ht] = [[lambda].sub.h]
[[[i.sub.ht][x.sub.ht]]/[[xi].sup.(1-[mu])] [P.sup.[mu][sigma].sub.At],
where [i.sub.ht] denotes returns to each sector-specific factor of
production, [x.sub.ht] = [h.sub.Dt]/[N.sub.ht] is the factor endowment
of each elite individual, and [[lambda].sub.h] [equivalent to]
[([mu][sigma]).sup.[mu][sigma]] ([mu][(1 - [sigma])).sup.[mu](1 -
[sigma])][(1 - [mu]).sup.(1 - [mu])] with [mu] = 1 for landowners.
III. EQUILIBRIUM UNDER DIFFERENT TRADE REGIMES
This section solves for the equilibrium prices of goods, factor
allocations, returns, and output levels in the two sectors under
different trade regimes. We start by discussing general equilibrium
conditions in Section III.A, and proceed by discussing the equilibria in
closed and open economies in Sections III.B and III.C, respectively.
A. General
From the profit-maximization problems of firms, it follows that
returns to capital, land, and labor are given by:
(5) [i.sub.Kt] = [[partial derivative][Y.sub.Mt]/[partial
derivative][K.sub.t]] = [alpha] (1 + [[pi].sub.Mt][[gamma].sub.t])
[A.sub.Mt-1][K.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t] [L.sup.1- [alpha].sub.Mt],
(6) [i.sub.Xt] = [P.sub.At] [[partial
derivative][Y.sub.At]/[partial derivative][X.sub.t]] = [P.sub.At][alpha]
[X.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t] [L.sup.1-[alpha].sub.At],
(7) [w.sub.Mt] = [[partial derivative][Y.sub.Mt]/[partial
derivative][L.sub.Mt]] = (1 - [alpha])(1 +
[[pi].sub.Mt][[gamma].sub.t])[A.sub.Mt-1][K.sup.[alpha].sub.t] [L.sup.-
[alpha].sub.Mt],
(8) [w.sub.At] = [P.sub.At] [[partial
derivative][Y.sub.At]/[partial derivative][L.sub.At]] = [P.sub.At] (1 -
[alpha]) [X.sup.[alpha].sub.t] [L.sup.-[alpha].sub.At].
Equation (5) defines returns to effective capital [K.sub.t]. As
domestic and foreign capital differ in productivity, returns to each
type of capital will differ accordingly. The manufacturing firms'
optimal choices of each type of capital input imply that the returns to
domestic and foreign capital, respectively, are given by:
(9) [i.sub.Dt] = [[partial derivative][Y.sub.Mt]/[partial
derivative][K.sub.Dt]] = [A.sub.Kt][i.sub.Kt],
(10) [i.sub.Ft] = [[partial derivative][Y.sub.Mt]/[partial
derivative][K.sub.Ft]] = [i.sub.Kt],
where [i.sub.Kt] is given by Equation (5).
Regardless of the trade regime, under full employment and inelastic
labor supply, employment in the two sectors adds up to the total labor
supply:
(11) [L.sub.t] = [L.sub.At] + [L.sub.Mt].
Labor can move freely between the two sectors, equalizing the wage
across sector so that [w.sub.t] = [w.sub.At] = [w.sub.Mt]. Equations (7)
and (8) imply:
(12) [P.sub.At] = (1 + [[pi].sub.Mt][y.sub.t])[A.sub.Mt-1]
[([[K.sub.t]/[X.sub.t]] [[L.sub.At]/[L.sub.Mt]]).sup.[alpha]].
B. Closed Economy
In autarky, prices are endogenously determined in the domestic
market. Aggregating the demand functions over the population yields
aggregate demand for agricultural goods:
(13) [Y.sub.At] = [[sigma]/[P.sup.C.sub.At] ([w.sub.t][L.sub.t] +
[r.sub.Xt][X.sub.t] + [mu][r.sub.Kt][K.sub.t]).
The corresponding expression in the manufacturing sector is:
(14) [Y.sub.Mt] = (1 - [sigma]) ([w.sub.t][L.sub.t] +
[r.sub.Xt][X.sub.t] + [mu][r.sub.Kt][K.sub.t]) + [[1 - [mu]]/[xi]]
[r.sub.Kt][K.sub.t],
where the second term on the right-hand side comes from the demand
for manufacturing goods left as bequests and is decreasing in the price
of bequests.
In a closed economy, the relative price of agricultural goods is
directly implied by the condition for wage equality (Equation (12)). The
expression shows that the relative price of agricultural goods is
proportional to manufacturing TFP, which increases with sound industrial
policy. Agricultural goods are also more expensive if land is scarce
relative to capital and if there is a high share of labor employed in
agriculture.
Combining Equations (5), (12), (13), and (14) the relative labor
allocation is given by:
(15) [[L.sub.At]/[L.sub.Mt]] = [[sigma]/[1 = [sigma]]] (1 - [alpha]
([[1 - [mu]]/[xi])).
As is standard in specific-factor models, the relative labor
allocation across sectors is independent of factor endowments in
autarky. This obtains since prices adjust in proportion to the labor
share in the two sectors. The term [alpha]/l - [sigma] captures the
relative demand for agricultural goods and is positively related to the
share of labor in agriculture. A lower [sigma] indicates lower marginal
returns to capital, and hence less resources devoted to bequests. As
bequests come from savings in terms of manufacturing goods, the demand
for it decreases, as does [L.sub.Mt]. The same mechanism is at work if
bequests are more costly, that is, if [xi] is large. Alternatively,
stronger preferences toward leaving bequests captured by a larger (1 -
[mu]) reflects more savings and therefore a higher demand for
manufacturing goods and labor. (12)
Equation (15) allows us to rewrite the price equation (12) as:
(16) [P.sub.At] = (1 + [[pi].sub.Mt][[gamma].sub.t]) [A.sub.Mt-1] x
[([[sigma]/[1 - [sigma]] (1 - [alpha] ([1 - [mu]]/[xi]))
[[K.sub.t]/[X.sub.t]]).sup.[alpha]].
By using the price indices derived in Section II.B, we may define
the real returns to domestic capital and land, respectively, as
[r.sub.Dt] [equivalent to] [A.sub.Kt][i.sub.Kt]/
([P.sup.[mu][sigma].sub.At]) and [r.sub.Xt] [equivalent to]
[i.sub.Xt]/[P.sup.[sigma].sub.At]. By using Equations (5), (6), (11),
and (16), we may derive the real returns to the domestic factors of
production in Table 1.
The linear relationship between the real returns and the indirect
utility of each type of elite immediately suggests that better economic
institutions, that is, higher [[pi].sub.Mt], is beneficial for both
landed and capitalist oligarchs, but through different channels.
Industrial policies that spur manufacturing TFP raise the returns to
capital by affecting capital's marginal productivity. Land returns
also increase with growth-promoting industrial policies, but through a
lower relative price of manufacturing. A higher price of bequests
directly reduces returns to capital through [xi] and additionally
decreases (increases) the marginal productivity of capital (land) by
drawing workers into the agricultural sector. Moreover, relative
abundance of capital with respect to land increases (decreases) returns
to land (capital), while a larger labor stock increases the returns to
both factors in their specific sectors.
C. Open Economy
In an open economy, the relative price of agricultural goods is
exogenously given by the world relative price, [P.sup.*.sub.At].
Imposing this condition on Equation (12) implies that relative labor
allocation across sectors is given by:
(17) [[L.sub.At]/[L.sub.Mt]] = [([(1 +
[[pi].sub.Mt][[gamma].sub.t]) [A.sub.Mt-
1]]/[P.sup.*.sub.At]).sup.-1/[alpha]] [[X.sub.t]/[K.sub.t]].
Under free trade in goods, the allocation of labor between the two
sectors is influenced by factor endowments as the prices are fixed and
cannot counterbalance them as they do in autarky. The relative
allocation of labor is higher in manufacturing with better economic
institutions, larger effective capital stock, and higher world relative
price of manufacturing goods.
In analogy to the closed economy, real returns in the open economy
are defined as [r.sub.Dt] [equivalent to]
[A.sub.Kt][i.sub.Kt]/([[xi].sup.1-[mu]] [P.sup.*[mu][sigma].sub.At]) and
[r.sub.Xt] [equivalent to] [i.sub.Xt]/[P.sup.*[sigma].sub.At]. Using
Equations (5), (6), (11), and (17), real returns to capital and land in
the open economy are displayed in Table 1 and provide insights on the
effects of industrial policy under free trade, in relation to the
sectoral allocation of labor. Capitalists benefit from strong economic
institutions as this is conducive to technological progress and raises
the marginal productivity of capital. More expensive bequests, however,
disfavor capitalists and create a disincentive to save. By contrast,
improved economic institutions hurt landowners by drawing labor out of
agriculture, thereby decreasing the marginal productivity of land. In an
open economy, landowners can satisfy their demand for manufacturing
goods through imports, and internal prices are no longer relevant.
Clearly, a higher world price of agricultural goods benefits landowners
and translate into a loss for capitalists.
IV. INTRODUCING INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MOBILITY
We next introduce the possibility that the oligarchs can allow
foreign, more productive, capital to flow into the country. We assume
that returns generated from foreign capital, [K.sub.Ft], are measured in
terms of domestic goods and transferred back to the country of origin.
The real returns to foreign capital are therefore [r.sub.Ft] [equivalent
to] [i.sub.Ft]/([[xi].sup.1-[mu]] [P.sup.*[mu][sigma].sub.At]) where
[i.sub.Ft] is given by Equation (10) and [P.sub.At] is given by Equation
(12) in a closed economy but equal to [P.sup.*.sub.At] in an open
economy. We further let [r.sup.*.sub.t] denote the real rate of return
that can be obtained on international capital markets. Finally, we
assume that [A.sub.Kt] is a measure of the degree of spillovers
generated by foreign capital inflows so that [A.sub.Kt] =
[A.sub.Kt]([K.sub.Ft]), where [A'.sub.Kt] ([K.sub.Ft]) > 0. We
start by discussing the equilibrium implications for the closed economy
in Section IV.A and proceed with the open economy in Section IV.B.
A. Closed Economy
The stock of foreign capital, [K.sub.Ft], is governed by the
potential returns it will generate in the country. The real returns to
foreign capital in autarky are presented in the bottom row of Table 1,
and calculated using Equation (10) and [r.sub.Dt] in a closed economy
from the same table. As [A'.sub.Kt] ([K.sub.Ft]) > 0, it follows
directly that [partial derivative][r.sub.Ft]/[partial
derivative][K.sub.Ft] < 0. The opportunity cost for foreign investors
is given by the returns to capital that prevail on the international
market, [r.sup.*.sub.t]. Foreign capital enters the country only if
returns are at least as high as [r.sup.*.sub.t] until there are no
arbitrage opportunities from investing in a particular country in
equilibrium. As [partial derivative][r.sub.Ft]/[partial
derivative][K.sub.Ft] < 0, it is sufficient to examine whether the
latent return to the first unit of foreign capital entering the country,
[[??].sub.Ft] [equivalent to] [r.sub.Ft] | [K.sub.Ft] = 0, satisfies
this condition. Using [r.sub.Ft] in a closed economy from Table 1, we
can formulate the following lemma:
LEMMA 1. In a closed economy, given that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
foreign capital will flow into the country until [r.sub.Ft] =
[r.sup.*.sub.t].
Proof. The lemma follows directly from the closed-economy
[r.sub.Ft] in Table 1, setting [K.sub.Ft] = 0. Capital flows into the
country until the equilibrium level of foreign capital is reached at
[r.sub.Ft] = [r.sup.*.sub.t]:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
In the expression for latent returns, [A.sub.Kt](0) is the
lower-bound productivity of domestic capital that obtains in the absence
of foreign capital. As we assume that domestic capital is less
productive than foreign capital, we let [A.sub.Kt](0) be less than
unity.
The lemma suggests that countries promoting technological progress
by maintaining strong economic institutions attract more capital, as the
rate of return is higher in these countries. Countries with a large
relative endowment of effective domestic capital [A.sub.Kt][K.sub.Dt],
however, are characterized by lower returns to capital and are therefore
less attractive to foreign investors. Likewise, circumstances that
result in costly bequests deter foreign capital due to less demand for
manufacturing goods and thus a nonprogressing industrial sector.
Finally, abundance in land attracts foreign capital in a closed economy
through an increase in the relative price of manufacturing goods.
B. Open Economy
Real returns to foreign capital in an open economy are also
presented in Table 1 and found analogously using Equation (10),
[r.sub.Dt] in an open economy from the same table and [P.sub.At] =
[P.sup.*.sub.At]. The expression confirms that real returns to foreign
capital are decreasing in the stock of foreign capital also in an open
economy so that [partial derivative][r.sub.Ft]/[partial
derivative][K.sub.Ft] < 0. As before, we may derive a latent return
to the first unit of capital entering the economy and prove the
following lemma.
LEMMA 2. In an open economy where the following condition holds:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
foreign capital will flow into the country until
[r.sub.Ft] = [r.sup.*.sub.t].
Proof. The lemma follows directly from the open-economy [r.sub.Ft]
in Table 1, setting [K.sub.Ft] = 0. Capital flows into the country until
the equilibrium level of foreign capital is reached at [r.sub.Ft] =
[r.sup.*.sub.t]:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The result suggests that appropriate industrial policies increase
the likelihood of a positive inflow of capital in an open economy.
Although better economic institutions increase the demand for labor in
the economy, they also increase returns to manufacturing and the latter
effect always dominates. Costly bequests could work as an opposing force
that hampers the positive effect of productivity-enhancing industrial
policies and blocks the inflow of foreign capital. A smaller stock of
effective domestic capital attracts foreign investors also in an open
economy. In an open economy, the effect of more land is the opposite to
that under autarky: instead of lowering prices, an increase in land
lowers the marginal returns to capital by drawing workers out of
manufacturing.
V. POLITICAL ECONOMY
Having identified the equilibrium of the model for given economic
institutions and trade and capital regimes, we now add a political layer
and endogenize the oligarchs' policy choices. We consider two
economies that differ only with respect to the endowments of the
oligarchs, who may hold either land or capital. We refer to the regime
as a land (capital) oligarchy if the elites are endowed with land
(capital). As discussed in the introduction, imperfect political
institutions have been modeled inter alia as rent seeking and
expropriation in the previous literature. Here we assume that rents from
the sector that is of no interest to the elites cannot be expropriated
by the oligarchs. This is plausible if the rulers need to maintain order
in the society in order to avoid a revolution and stay in power. In the
same vein, Galiani and Torrens (2014) provide a rich model where
different types of elites reallocate political power within their clique
to avoid popular revolts.
The rulers have three policy instruments at their disposal. The
oligarchs can prohibit trade, impose barriers to technology adoption by
letting [[pi].sub.Mt] < 1 according to Equation (3), or block foreign
capital inflows. For convenience, we define the following policy
variables:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The rulers thus choose a policy vector, [[pi].sub.t] =
([[pi].sub.Ot], [[pi].sub.Ft], [[pi].sub.Mt]), to maximize their
indirect utility. The optimal policy mix therefore satisfies:
[[pi].sub.ht] = arg max [V.sub.ht] ([[pi].sub.ht])
where [V.sub.ht] is given by Equation (4) for h = K, X. As the
oligarchs' individual endowments, [x.sub.t], are given in each
period, what matters to them is merely the real returns to the factors
of production displayed in Table 1.
We next examine the optimal choices of the two types of oligarchs.
As the simultaneous evaluation of all three policies is analytically
intractable, we first analyze how trade interacts with economic
institutions (Section V.A) and second, how trade interacts with foreign
capital inflows (Section V.B) for each type of oligarchy. Numerical
results on the simultaneous interplay between all three policies are
then presented in Section VI.
A. Trade and Economic Institutions
We start by looking at the decision of the ruling oligarchs whether
or not to open the economy to international trade, given the policies on
economic institutions and capital mobility. A capitalist oligarch
prefers free trade if [V.sub.Kt](1, [[pi].sub.Ft], [[pi].sub.Mt]) >
[V.sub.Kt](0, [[pi].sub.Ft], [[pi].sub.Mt]). Using real returns to
domestic capital under a closed and an open economy in Table 1, this
inequality is satisfied when:
(18) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Stronger economic institutions, in terms of the industrial policy
[[pi].sub.Mt] that favors technological progress, increases the
willingness of a capitalist oligarch to engage in trade by making
manufacturing firms more competitive. In addition, more effective
capital in the form of domestic capital growth, the inflow of foreign
capital, or an increase in the productivity of capital makes a
capitalist oligarch more positive toward free trade. More expensive
bequests that retard capital accumulation can erode the impact of
industrial policy and thus delay the capitalists' decision to open
up to trade (see Section VI). Positive changes in the world relative
price of manufacturing goods, inversely measured by
[P.sup.*1/[alpha].sub.At], also increases the willingness of a
capitalist oligarch to engage in trade.
For a landed oligarch, the condition is instead [V.sub.Xt](1,
[[pi].sub.Ft], [[pi].sub.Mt]) > [V.sub.Xt](0, [[pi].sub.Ft],
[[pi].sub.Mt]). Real returns to land in a closed and an open economy in
Table 1 imply that this obtains when:
(19) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The condition suggests that a landed oligarch is more inclined to
trade when the absence of industrial policy entails weak economic
institutions, the economy is relatively well-endowed with land (for
reasons of comparative advantage) and when the world relative price of
agricultural goods is high. We may formulate the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 1. Given sufficiently weak economic institutions, an
economy with a comparative disadvantage in manufacturing, that is, with
[K.sub.t]/[X.sub.t] low enough to generate [P.sub.At] <
[P.sup.*.sub.At], is opened up to trade if ruled by landed oligarchs,
but remains closed under capitalist oligarchs.
Proof. Condition (18) does not hold for a sufficiently low level of
[K.sub.t] as [K.sub.t] enters additively in the denominator and with a
smaller exponent than in the numerator. A low level of [K.sub.t] is
tantamount to a comparative disadvantage in manufacturing. By contrast,
condition (19) does hold for a sufficiently low [K.sub.t] as [K.sub.t]
appears only in the denominator.
Having established how oligarchs choose the trade regime for a
given level of [[pi].sub.Mt] we next investigate how they set industrial
policy for a given trade regime [[pi].sub.Ot]. Equation (4) and real
returns to domestic capital from Table 1 reveal that, regardless of the
trade regime, it is optimal for a capitalist oligarch to promote
industrial policy, as
[[partial derivative][V.sub.Kt] (0, [[pi].sub.Ft],
[[pi].sub.Mt])/[partial derivative][[pi].sub.Mt]] > 0, [[partial
derivative][V.sub.Kt] (1, [[pi].sub.Ft], [[pi].sub.Mt])/[partial
derivative][[pi].sub.Mt] > 0.
Intuitively, industrial policies that are conducive to
technological progress in the manufacturing sector raise the marginal
productivity of capital and therefore always increase current returns to
domestic capitalists. The extent of the impact of such policy on
economic growth, however, depends on the cost of bequests.
Turning to the choice of a landed oligarch, Equation (4) and the
real returns to domestic capital from Table 1 imply:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
A landed oligarch thus prefers strong economic institutions in
autarky, but weak economic institutions when the economy is open to
trade. Intuitively, industrial policies that promote manufacturing TFP
reduce the relative price of manufacturing goods in a closed economy,
which benefits the landed elites by raising returns to land. In an open
economy, no such price effect can arise as the relative price is
determined in the world market. In a globalized setting, weaker economic
institutions reduce manufacturing TFP growth and therefore the marginal
productivity of labor employed in that sector. This leaves more workers
in agriculture, which spurs returns to land and benefits landowners.
Interestingly, this suggests that globalization changes the incentives
of the landed oligarchs in a way that is detrimental for industrial
growth.
PROPOSITION 2. A capitalist oligarch always seeks to strengthen
economic institutions regardless of whether the country is closed or
open to trade. A landed oligarch supports industrial policy conducive to
technology adoption in autarky but blocks improvements in economic
institutions in an open economy.
Proof. The proposition follows directly from the differentiation of
real returns to land and domestic capital in Table 1 with respect to
[[pi].sub.Mt].
B. Trade and Foreign Capital Inflows
We now turn to the ruling oligarchs' decision of whether or
not to allow for the inflow of foreign capital under different trade
regimes. On the entry of foreign capital, what matters is not only how
the oligarchs set [[pi].sub.Ft] but also whether returns are such that
the country is able to attract foreign capital. This implies that
[[pi].sub.Ft] and [[pi].sub.Mt] interact in important ways. In this
section, we consider the choice of [[pi].sub.Ft] for a given trade
regime and for a given industrial policy.
Starting with the optimal policies of a capitalist oligarch, the
results in Table 1 show that the effect of foreign capital on the
returns to domestic capital is ambiguous in a closed economy. Foreign
capital enters the denominator of domestic returns to capital due to
diminishing marginal returns. However, foreign capital also enters the
numerator through its technological spillovers on domestic capital,
captured by [A.sub.Kt]([K.sub.Ft]). A capital oligarchy thus only favors
capital inflows if the gains from the productivity spillovers dominate
the losses from the direct reduction in the marginal productivity of
capital, that is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Differentiating Equation (4) with respect to [K.sub.Ft], using real
returns to capital under each trade regime in Table 1. we find that
[V.sub.Kt](0, 1, [[pi].sub.Mt]) > [V.sub.Kt](0, 0, [[pi].sub.Mt])
when
(20) [d[V.sub.Kt] (0, [[pi].sub.Ft], [[pi].sub.Mt])/d[K.sub.Ft]]
> 0, for [[psi].sub.t] > (1 - [alpha] (1 - [mu][sigma]))
[equivalent to] [[psi].sup.c.sub.t],
where [[psi].sub.t] [equivalent to] [K.sub.Dt][A'.sub.Kt] (0)
/ (1+ [K.sub.Dt][A'.sub.Kt] (0)) [member of] [0, 1] is an index of
potential spillovers from foreign capital at the point where no foreign
investment has yet taken place in the country. In the open economy,
condition [V.sub.Kt](1, 1, [[pi].sub.Mt]) > [V.sub.Kt](1, 0,
[[pi].sub.Mt]) is instead satisfied when
(21) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
from which we can deduce the following lemma.
LEMMA 3. The threshold level of spillovers above which the
capitalist oligarchs choose to allow the inflow of foreign capital are
higher in a closed economy than in an open economy, that is
[[psi].sup.c.sub.t] > [[psi].sup.o.sub.t].
Proof In Equation (21), it is easy to see that [[psi].sup.o.sub.t]
< 1 - [alpha], and as 1 - [alpha] < (1 - [alpha](1 -
[mu][sigma])), Equations (20) and (21) together imply
[[psi].sup.c.sub.t] > [[psi].sup.o.sub.t]
Lemma 3 suggests that all else equal, a capitalist oligarch is more
in favor of foreign capital inflows in an open economy than in a closed
economy. Thus, as long as spillovers are sufficiently large to satisfy
Equation (21), the oligarchs choose to allow for capital mobility when
open to trade but not in autarky. We can therefore conclude from the
results that trade and capital mobility are complementary policies in a
capital oligarchy.
The choice of the landed oligarch is more straightforward. Real
returns to land for each trade regime in Table 1 imply that a landowner
is in favor of the entry of foreign capital in a closed economy, but
against it in an open economy (13):
(22) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
A landed oligarch is thus more in favor of foreign capital inflows
in a closed economy than in an open economy. Trade and capital mobility
are thus substitute policies in a land oligarchy. (14) The findings can
be summarized in the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 3. Free trade and capital mobility are complementary
policies in a capital oligarchy but substitute policies in a land
oligarchy.
Proof. The result for a capital oligarchy follows from Equations
(20) and (21) and in turn from Lemma 3. The result for a land oligarchy
is obtained by differentiating Equation (4) with respect to [K.sub.Ft]
using the returns to land in Table 1.
The mechanism that causes policies on trade and capital inflows to
be substitutes in a land oligarchy is closely linked to the result in
Proposition 2. In a closed economy, a larger capital stock (and more
efficient domestic capital) raises the relative price of agricultural
goods and hence the real income of a landowner. Under free trade,
however, a larger capital stock will affect the sectoral allocation of
workers to the disadvantage of landowners. For a capital oligarchy, the
problem is very different. The inflow of foreign capital potentially has
three effects on domestic capitalists and these effects go in opposite
directions as far as the real returns to capital are concerned. The
positive effect of foreign capital is that it causes technological
spillovers that raise the productivity of domestic capital. The two
negative effects are, first, that, for a given allocation of labor, more
capital implies more capital per worker in the manufacturing sector and
this lowers the marginal productivity of all capital. Second, the
foreign capital increases the supply and lowers the relative price of
manufacturing goods. In autarky, all three effects are present. Under
free trade, however, the third effect disappears as relative prices are
fixed. Therefore, a capitalist oligarch is more likely to favor capital
inflows under free trade than under autarky.
VI. THE EVOLUTION OF THE ECONOMY
To illustrate the simultaneous interaction between industrial
policy, goods trade, and the inflow of foreign capital, we next display
numerical solutions to the model. We solve for the optimal policies in
each period and simulate the economy over time. We start out in a state
where the economy holds a comparative disadvantage in manufacturing and
study the decision in each oligarchy to open up to trade and allow for
foreign capital inflows. When possible, we try to match key statistics
for the South Korean economy in parameterizing the model and therefore
think of the capital oligarchy as a crude representation of this
economy. For the same parameterization, we then conduct two
counterfactual experiments and study (1) how South Korea would have
evolved had its elite been landowners rather than capitalists and (2)
how South Korea would have evolved if the price of bequests had exceeded
that of manufacturing goods, thus creating an environment less conducive
to capital accumulation.
A. Parameters
In parameterizing the model, we set the capital share in
manufacturing, and thus the land share in agriculture, to match the
average labor share of 0.703 reported for the South Korean economy over
the period 1966-1990 by Young (1995), and let [alpha] =.297. In choosing
the consumption share of income, [mu], we note that bequests correspond
to domestic investments in our setting. We thus set p to match the 0.081
investment share of gross domestic product (GDP) in South Korea in 1960,
obtained from the Penn World Tables 7.1, and let [mu] =.919. We have no
prior on how to set the agricultural share of consumption but let
[sigma] =.10 in the benchmark simulation. In modeling the growth process
of manufacturing TFP, we follow Hansen and Prescott (2002) in choosing
an average annual growth rate of 1.4%. As one model period spans one
generation, we convert these annual rates to 30-year equivalents and let
[gamma] =s.518. (15)
We also need estimates of the population shares. To the best of our
knowledge, direct estimates of the share of landowners and capitalists
in South Korea are not available, but as these households represent the
potential elites, they are bound to be a small number. In the benchmark,
we want to make the two groups of elites equally influential in their
respective economies and therefore set [N.sub.X] = [N.sub.K] =.05. As
the population is normalized to one, this implies L =.90. As stated in
the theoretical section, each landowner holds one unit of land, which
implies that the total land endowment in the economy is [X.sub.t] =
[N.sub.x] =. 05.
We have no prior on how to set the international relative price of
agricultural goods but as we want to mimic South Korea's transition
from a closed to an open economy, we make sure that the economy starts
out with a comparative disadvantage in manufacturing by ensuring that
[P.sup.*.sub.A] < [P.sub.A0], and let [P.sup.*.sub.A] = 1. The final
set of parameters are related to the inflow of foreign capital. We
choose a simple, linear relation between [K.sub.F] and [A.sub.K] and
assume:
[A.sub.K] = [[kappa].sub.1] + [[kappa].sub.2][K.sub.Ft],
where [[kappa].sub.1] [member of] (0,1) and [[kappa].sub.2] > 0.
As we want domestic capital to be less productive than foreign capital
when [K.sub.Ft] = 0 and spillovers from foreign capital to be positive,
we let [[kappa].sub.1] = .80 and [[kappa].sub.2] = 2. We set the
international real interest rate such that foreign investors would like
to invest in the capital oligarchy, given the opportunity to do so, and
let [r.sup.*] = 6.
B. Results
Table 2 displays the optimal policies from the benchmark experiment
in the three types of oligarchies: our benchmark capital oligarchy, a
land oligarchy, and a capital oligarchy with the price of bequests being
five times that of manufacturing. To understand how these policies
affect the comparative advantage of the economies, it is useful to
simultaneously study the impact of these policies on the evolution of
the relative price of agricultural goods, displayed in Figure 1. The
benchmark capitalist oligarchy starts out with a comparative
disadvantage in manufacturing, so that the relative price of
agricultural goods in this economy is lower than the world market price
[P.sup.*.sub.A]. Consequently, the capitalist oligarchs initially
maintain a closed economy. As shown in Table 2, the oligarchs continue
to strengthen economic institutions and set [[pi].sub.M] to 1. The
strong industrial policy promotes technological progress and spurs
manufacturing TFP growth, which gradually shifts the comparative
advantage of this economy from agriculture to manufacturing. Figure 1
suggests that in period 3, the relative price of agricultural goods has
become higher than the world market price of these goods in the capital
oligarchy. This implies that the relative price of manufacturing goods
now has become lower than the world market price on these goods, that
is, the economy has developed a comparative advantage in manufacturing.
This makes the capitalist oligarchs favor trade openness and set
[[pi].sub.O] = 1 from period 3 onwards. Figure 2A displays the evolution
of domestic capital, the inflow of foreign capital, the implied relative
productivity of domestic capital, and the total effective capital stock
in this economy. The graphs suggest that the strong economic
institutions promote domestic capital accumulation by generating high
returns to this factor. Turning to the decision whether or not to allow
the inflow of foreign capital, the results in Table 2 suggest that the
oligarchs allow for such inflows from period 9 onwards. The reason is
that the potential spillovers from such capital, as captured by
[[psi].sub.t] in Equation (21), is increasing in domestic capital. Once
the oligarchs decide to set [[pi].sub.F] = 1, the strong industrial
policy and high returns to capital have made the economy attractive to
investors and foreign capital will flow into the country. As shown in
Figure 2, the inflow of foreign capital boosts the total effective
capital stock through two channels: in addition to having a direct
effect on K, it increases the relative productivity of domestic capital.
(16) Moreover, the increase in the productivity of domestic capital will
dampen some of the fall in returns generated by a growing capital stock.
This feature of the model is consistent with Hsieh (2002), who shows how
technological spillovers from the inflow of foreign capital can prevent
a fall in the returns to capital and trigger further investment in the
economy. Figure 3 reports the evolution of GDP over time. The graph
shows that the capital oligarchy grows at a steady but moderate pace for
the first eight periods. Once foreign capital is allowed into the
country in period 9, however, the growth rate increases dramatically and
boosts GDP. (17)
We next consider the evolution of the same economy, but under the
rule of landed oligarchs. As the economy starts out with a comparative
advantage in agriculture, the landed oligarchs open up to trade
immediately as the relative price of agriculture is lower than the
relative world market price of these goods. The results in Table 2
indicate that the landed oligarchs set [[pi].sub.O] = 1 from period 1
onwards and Figure 1 corroborates that [P.sub.A] < [P.sup.*.sub.A] in
this economy. Consistent with Proposition 2, the results in Table 2 show
that in this open environment, the land oligarchy neglects economic
institutions and sets [[pi].sub.M] to zero. The barriers to
technological progress that ensue cause manufacturing TFP to stagnate.
The graph in Figure 1 reveals that the lack of growth in manufacturing
productivity implies that the relative price of agriculture that would
prevail in autarky decreases slightly over time and that the comparative
advantage is never overturned. (18) Figure 2B shows that the weak
industrial policy that is sustained in this open economy is detrimental
to capital formation. The absence of growth in manufacturing TFP
generates low returns to capital and deters capital accumulation.
Consistent with it is never optimal for the landed oligarchs to allow
for foreign investment. The graph of GDP in Figure 3 confirms that the
weak industrial policy, constant manufacturing TFP, and failure to
encourage capital accumulation constitute a path toward stagnation.
Finally, we consider the effect of a higher price of bequests on
capital accumulation in an oligarchy run by capitalists. Letting [xi] =
5, the price of bequests becomes five times that of manufacturing goods,
creating an environment detrimental to saving. The graph in Figure 1
confirms that the moderate capital growth delays the shift in
comparative advantage toward manufacturing so that it will be optimal
for the oligarchs to open up to trade only at a later stage of
development. The results in Table 1 confirm that this alternative
capital oligarchy opens up to trade only in period 4. Trade
liberalization is thus delayed by an entire generation. Figure 2C
illustrates the weak performance of this economy in terms of capital
accumulation. Domestic capital grows at a very moderate pace and it is
never optimal for the oligarchs to allow for foreign investment within
the time frame of the simulation, that is, ten generations. The growth
acceleration that occurs in the benchmark capital oligarchy therefore
fails to manifest in this counterfactual economy. The results are
corroborated by the GDP plot in Figure 3. The capital oligarchy with
expensive bequests represents a middle ground between the benchmark
capital oligarchy that is conducive to saving and the economy ruled by
land oligarchs.
Additional results, available on request, show that a higher price
of bequests delays the process even more: when [xi]= 100 the oligarchs
open up to trade in period 6 and when [xi] = 500 trade liberalization
does not occur until period 7. In the extreme case when the price of
bequests tends to infinity ([xi]=100 000), the capitalist oligarchy
remains closed to trade throughout the time frame of the experiment. The
results suggest that being ruled by capitalist oligarchs is no panacea
for a successful ISI process: an environment conducive to saving must
also be in place for a comparative-advantage reversal to occur.
VII. DISCUSSION
Historical accounts suggest that the politically influential group
of any country tends to be in possession of the economy's natural
resources. In industrialized economies with a developed business sector,
the elites tend to be capitalists who derive profits from manufactures.
South Korea is an example of an economy where the powerful industrial
families of the Jaebols constituted a politically influential group from
the 1950s onwards, see for instance Kim (1976). The strong influence of
capitalists and bankers in Shanghai under the Kuomintang regime in the
late 1920s is also well documented (Coble 1979). In traditionally
agrarian economies, such as Argentina in the nineteenth century, the
political power of landowners is undisputed, see for instance Taylor
(1997). However, the emergence of the industrial elite after the
interwar period changed the balance of power which then came to
oscillate between the two elites (Galiani and Torrens 2014).
As discussed above, it is often believed that the autocratic
governments in South Korea and Taiwan were heavily influenced by
industrialists and the financial industry. Rodrik (1994) emphasizes that
the governments in these economies prioritized industrial development
and sought to affect their comparative advantage by various policy
measures. The GDP per capita levels in these two countries were in 1960
on par with those in many sub-Saharan countries and well below those of
several large Latin American countries such as Brazil. Argentina, or
Mexico. During the following three decades, however, the average growth
rates of GDP per capita have averaged almost 7%. The cases of Taiwan and
South Korea closely follow our predictions. In the 1960s, domestic
levels of investment rose sharply and many have argued that this rise in
investment was strongly connected to government policy. Rodrik (1994)
writes:
... in the early 1960s and thereafter the Korean and
Taiwanese governments managed to engineer a significant
increase in the private return to capital. They
did so not only by removing a number of impediments
to investment and establishing a sound investment
climate, but more importantly by alleviating
a coordination failure which had blocked economic
take-off. (p. 2)
Importantly, however, export-to-GDP ratios remained low throughout
the 1960s but rose sharply, in fact almost doubled, during the early
1970s. The 1970s and the 1980s were also the decades when Taiwan started
to receive large inflows of foreign direct investment. (19) These two
countries thus remained closed well into the 1960s, while the capital
stock and competitiveness grew. In time, however, the rulers in these
countries found it favorable to enter world markets and started to allow
for foreign capital inflows. This sequence of events: (1) low levels of
trade and FDI but high levels of investment and TFP growth before the
1970s, (2) opening up to trade in the early 1970s, and (3) substantial
capital inflows during the later 1970s and 1980s, follows our
model's predictions very closely.
The model's predictions for the land oligarchy are broadly
consistent with the evolution of the landed Latin American economies of
the nineteenth century. These economies opened up to trade at an early
stage of development, focusing on exports of primary goods. As the
elites were predominantly landowners in these economies, the model
provides a rationale for why they favored globalization early on. The
model is also consistent with the weak economic institutions that were a
feature of the Latin American landscape at the time and can help explain
why the region failed to attract foreign investors. (20)
Furthermore, the example of the capital oligarchy with expensive
bequests helps shed light on some of the mechanisms affecting the
likelihood of successful ISI. By varying the price of bequests, we may
compare the unparalleled East Asian experience to postwar Argentina
prior to the coup of 1976. In Argentina, the Peronists brought about a
conflict of interest concerning trade policy and put an end to the
country's history of liberal trade policies. Industrial elites,
supported by industrial workers, opted for protectionist policies that
would prove unsuccessful in generating sustainable growth. Consistent
with the model's predictions, the economy remained on the brink of
autarky until the military government, backed by the rural elite, took
over in 1976 and opened up to trade. (21)
In sum, the most common views on the development of South Korea,
Taiwan, and Argentina are largely consistent with our model. Building a
model that is in line with the consensus view of the factor endowments
of the political elites in these countries, we demonstrate how the
interaction between industrial policy and trade in goods and capital is
capable of generating sequences of events in accordance with actual
developments in these economies. By varying the price of bequests, the
model is able to endogenously explain why ISI policies have been
successful in some countries but not in others: in addition to
implementing industrial policies that promote technological progress in
the manufacturing sector, institutions must be such that bequests are
inexpensive and hence conducive to capital accumulation.
VIII. CONCLUDING REMARKS
In this paper, we present a specific-factor model of an economy
where the ruling oligarchs may or may not strengthen
technology-promoting institutions, open up to trade and allow for
foreign capital inflows. We argue that the endowments of the ruling
oligarchs can have far-reaching effects on the economy's long-run
development. The framework shows that economic institutions in terms of
industrial policy and openness to trade in goods and capital interact in
ways that may help explain the heterogeneous performance of economies
with imperfect political institutions.
We illustrate the workings of the model by simulating an economy
that starts out with a comparative disadvantage in manufacturing and
vary the assumption about the nature of the political elites. We find
that if the oligarchs are endowed with capital, they are likely to
maintain a closed economy while strengthening economic institutions. The
continuous promotion of sound industrial policy will lead to capital
accumulation and a gradual shift toward a comparative advantage in
manufacturing that eventually will make the oligarchs favor
international trade. The strong economic institutions will make the
economy attractive to foreign investors and productive capital will flow
into the country and spur the accumulation of effective capital. In a
capital oligarchy, trade in goods and capital are thus complementary
policies that will lead to rapid growth and long-term development. We
argue that our results for the capital oligarchy are consistent with
actual developments in the Tiger Economies of South Korea and Taiwan
during the postwar period.
If the oligarchs are instead endowed with land, they are likely to
embrace globalization at an early stage. Opening up to trade, however,
creates an adverse incentive not to improve economic institutions or
allow for foreign capital inflows, which discourages capital
accumulation. In such a land-oriented oligarchy, allowing for trade and
foreign capital inflows are substitute policies and, due to the weak
industrial policy that ensues, the economy is bound to stagnate over
time. We argue that the results for the land oligarchy are broadly
consistent with the developments in Argentina during the pre-Peronist
era and during the military rule of the 1980s. (22)
Finally, we show that implementing ISI policies favoring the
manufacturing sector is no guarantee for successful growth. ISI policies
may fail if investments are too costly and thus discourage capital
accumulation. Under such circumstances, capitalist oligarchies
liberalize trade at a later stage and are less likely to be attractive
to foreign investors.
We have chosen to model an oligarchy rather than a democracy as
this simplifies the political-economy layer of the model. However, our
results would obtain also in a democracy where the political elites
could form a political lobby and exert pressure on the democratic
leader. The results could thus be derived from a more general framework
with imperfect political institutions. (23) The model can be extended in
several interesting dimensions. It would be interesting to study the
foundations of institutions in greater detail and to add
microfoundations for firms' incentives to invest in new technology.
Another possibility would be to introduce a number of explicit trade
policies and let the ruling oligarchs set tariffs.
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12284
ABBREVIATIONS
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
ISI: Import Substitution Industrialization
TFP: Total Factor Productivity
APPENDIX UTILITY MAXIMIZATION
Denote the bequests given in terms of capital and land by
[B.sub.Kt] and [B.sub.Xt], respectively. The problem facing the
capitalist household is then:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to
[P.sub.At][C.sub.At] + [P.sub.Mt] [C.sub.Mt] + [P.sub.Bt]
[B.sub.Kt] [less than or equal to] [I.sub.Kt]
The optimal choices of the capitalist household are:
[C.sub.At] = [mu][sigma] [I.sub.Kt]/[P.sub.At], [C.sub.Mt] = [mu](1
- [sigma])[I.sub.Kt], [B.sub.Kt] = (1 - [mu]) [I.sub.Kt]/[xi],
The problem facing the landed household is:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to
[P.sub.At] [C.sub.At] + [P.sub.Mt] [C.sub.Mt] [less than or equal
to] [I.sub.Xt], [B.sub.Xt] [less than or equal to] [x.sub.t] = 1
where [x.sub.t] [equivalent to] [X.sub.t]/[N.sub.Xt], denotes land
holdings per landowner. Given [mu] = 1, the optimal choices of the
landed household becomes:
[C.sub.At] = [sigma] [[I.sub.Xt]/[P.sub.At]], [C.sub.Mt] = (1 -
[sigma]) [I.sub.Xt], [B.sub.Xt] = 1.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D., and J. A. Robinson. Economic Origins of Dictatorship
and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006.
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. "Institutions as a
Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth," in Handbook of Economic
Growth, Vol. 1A, edited by P. Aghion and S. N. Durlauf. Amsterdam:
Elsevier, 2005a, 385-472.
--. "The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change,
and Economic Growth." American Economic Review, 95(3), 2005b,
546-79.
Adamopoulos, T. "Land Inequality and the Transition to Modern
Growth." Review of Economic Dynamics, 11, 2008, 257-82.
Ades, A., and R. Di Tella. "Rents, Competition and
Corruption." American Economic Review, 89, 1999, 982-993.
Albornoz, F., S. Galiani, and D. Heymann. "Foreign Investment
and Expropriation under Oligarchy and Democracy." Economics &
Politics, 24, 2012, 24-46.
Bardhan, P. "Reflections on Some Under-researched Issues in
Trade and Development." Keynote lecture given to IGC Trade Group at
Columbia University, 2010.
Brambilla, I., S. Galiani, and G. Porto. Forthcoming.
"Argentine Trade Policies in the XX Century: 60 Years of
Solitude," in Argentine Exceptionalism, edited by R. Di Tella, E.
Glaeser, and L. Llach. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2015.
Cervellati, M., A. Naghavi, and F. Toubal. "Trade
Liberalization, Democratization, and Technology Adoption." IZA
Discussion Paper No. 7132, 2013.
Coble, P. M. "The Kuomintang Regime and the Shanghai
Capitalists." The China Quarterly, 77, 1979, 1-24.
Do, Q.-T., and A. A. Levchenko. "Trade, Inequality, and the
Political Economy of Institutions." Journal of Economic Theory,
144, 2009, 1489-520.
Engerman, S. L., and K. L. Sokoloff. "Institutions, Factor
Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World." Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 2000, 217-32.
Falkinger, J., and V. Grossman. "Institutions and Development:
The Interaction between Trade Regime and Political System." Journal
of Economic Growth, 10, 2005, 231-72.
--. "Oligarchic Land Ownership, Entrepreneurship, and Economic
Development." Journal of Development Economics, 101, 2013, 206-15.
Galiani, S., D. Heymann, C. Dabus, and F. Tohme. "On the
Emergence of Public Education in Land-rich Economies." Journal of
Development Economics, 86, 2008, 434-46.
Galiani, S., and G. Torrens. "Autocracy, Democracy and Trade
Policy." Journal of International Economics, 93, 2014, 173-93.
Galor, O., O. Moav, and D. Vollrath. "Inequality in
Landownership, the Emergence of Human-Capital Promoting Institutions,
and the Great Divergence." Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 2009,
143-79.
Hansen, G. D., and E. C. Prescott. "Malthus to Solow."
American Economic Review, 92(4), 2002, 1205-17.
Hsieh, C. T. "What Explains the Industrial Revolution in East
Asia? Evidence from the Factor Markets." American Economic Review,
92(3), 2002, 502-26.
Johnson, S., Ostry, J., and Subramanian, A. "The Prospects for
Sustained Growth in Africa: Benchmarking the Constraints." IMF
Working Paper 07/52, 2007.
Jones, R. W. "A Three-Factor Model in Theory, Trade and
History," in Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth, edited by J.
Bhagwati, R. W. Jones, R. A. Mundell, and J. Vanek. Amsterdam:
North-Holland Publishing Company, 1971.
--. "Co-movements in Relative Commodity Prices and
International Capital Flows: A Simple Model." Economic Inquiry,
27(1), 1989, 131-41.
Jones, R. W., and J. P. Neary. "The Positive Theory of
International Trade," in Handbook of International Economics, Vol.
1, edited by R. W. Jones and P. B. Kenen. Amsterdam: North-Holland,
1984.
Kim, K.-D. "Political Factors in the Formation of the
Entrepreneurial Elite in South Korea." Asian Survey, 16(5), 1976,
465-77.
Levchenko, A. A. "International Trade and Institutional
Change." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 29(5), 2013,
1145-81.
Markusen, J. R. "Factor Movements and Commodity Trade as
Complements." Journal of International Economics, 19, 1983, 341-56.
Markusen, J. R., and L. E. O. Svensson. "Trade in Goods and
Factors with International Differences in Technology."
International Economic Review, 26, 1985, 175-92.
Matsuyama, K. "Agricultural Productivity, Comparative
Advantage, and Economic Growth." Journal of Economic Theory, 58(2),
1992, 317-34.
Mussa, M. "Tariffs and the Distribution of Income: The
Importance of Factor Specificity, Substitutability and Intensity in the
Short and Long Run." Journal of Political Economy, 82, 1974,
1191--203.
Neary, J. P. "Short-run Capital Specificity and the Pure
Theory of International Trade." Economic Journal, 88, 1978,
458-510.
--. "Factor Mobility and International Trade." Canadian
Journal of Economics, 28, 1995, 4-23.
Paltseva, E. Autocracy, Devolution and Growth. Mimeo, University of
Copenhagen, 2008.
Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. "Is Inequality Harmful for
Growth?" American Economic Review, 84(3), 1994, 600-21.
Rigobon, R., and D. Rodrik. "Rule of Law, Democracy, Openness,
and Income: Estimating the Interrelationships." Economics of
Transition, 13, 2005, 533-64.
Rodrik, D. "Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and
Taiwan Grew Rich." NBER Working Paper No. 4964, 1994.
Rodrik, D., A. Subramanian, and F. Trebbi. "Institutions Rule:
The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic
Development." Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 2004, 131-65.
Samuelson, P. A. "Ohlin Was Right." Swedish Journal of
Economics, 73, 1971, 365-84.
Segura-Cayuela, R. "Inefficient Policies, Inefficient
Institutions and Trade." Documentos de Trabajo, No. 0633, Banco de
Espana, 2006.
Seim, A. L., and S. L. Parente. "Democracy as a Middle Ground:
A Unified Theory of Development and Political Regimes." European
Economic Review, 64, 2013, 35-56.
Shen, L. "When Will a Dictator Be Good?" Economic Theory,
31(2), 2007, 343-66.
Stefanadis, C. "Appropriation, Property Rights Institutions
and International Trade." American Economic Journal: Economic
Policy, 2, 2010, 148-72.
Tavares, S. C. "Do Rapid Political and Trade Liberalizations
Increase Corruption?" European Journal of Political Economy, 23(4),
2007, 1053-76.
Taylor, A. M. "Latifundia as Malefactor in Economic
Development? Scale, Tenancy, and Agriculture on the Pampas,
1880-1914." Research in Economic History, 17, 1997, 261-300.
Treisman, D. "The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National
Study." Journal of Public Economics, 76(3), 2000, 399-457.
Wong, K. "Are International Trade and Factor Mobility
Substitutes?" Journal of International Economics, 21, 1986, 25-44.
Young. A. "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical
Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience." Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 100(3), 1995, 641-80.
(1.) For seminal contributions to the class of specific-factor
models, see Jones (1971), Samuelson (1971), Mussa (1974), and Neary
(1978).
(2.) The notion that trade in goods and capital movements interact
with each other, and can be either complements or substitutes, is the
subject of a large literature comprising Markusen (1983), Jones and
Neary (1984), Markusen and Svensson (1985), Wong (1986), Jones (1989),
and Neary (1995).
(3.) Within this literature, more specific forms of imperfect
political institutions include expropriation (Segura-Cayuela 2006;
Stefanadis 2010; Albornoz, Galiani, and Heymann 2012) and inequality in
land ownership (Galor, Moav, and Vollrath 2009; Falkinger and Grossman
2013).
(4.) We thank a referee for suggesting that bequest costs may vary
across countries. Bequests could, for example, be more costly in an
unstable political environment due to the risk of future expropriation.
(5.) Source: Statistics on Approved Overseas Chinese and Foreign
Investment by Area, the Investment Commission, Ministry of Economic
Affairs, Taiwan.
(6.) Spacing the warm-glow preference structure enables us to
characterize the equilibrium in each period. The bequests ensure that
there is a dynamic link between periods and that the capital stock is
growing over time.
(7.) The possibility that autocrats may be heterogeneous and have
different objectives is also present in Shen (2007), Paltseva (2008),
and Seim and Parente (2013). However, these papers do not take into
account that the endowments of the political elites may be country
specific.
(8.) We assume labor intensity, 1 - [alpha], to be the same in both
sectors. The assumption is made for simplicity and is of minor
importance: sectoral differences in terms of labor's share in
production are not related to the dynamics of interest in our model.
(9.) A key feature of the model is an assumption that domestic
capital is less productive than foreign capital and we let the parameter
[A.sub.Kt] denote the relative productivity of domestic capital. At a
later stage, we will model [A.sub.Kt] as a function of [K.sub.Ft],
thereby assuming that the presence of foreign, more productive capital
will have positive spillover effects on domestic capital. In
equilibrium, the presence of such capital will hinge on domestic returns
to capital being sufficiently high as well as the ruling oligarchs
allowing for such capital inflows.
(10.) An alternative would be to assume that landed oligarchs own
agricultural firms and capitalist oligarchs own manufacturing firms so
that they are residual claimants. The main results would obtain also in
such a framework.
(11.) See Appendix for details of the households' maximization
problems.
(12.) The allocation of labor would be a function of the relative
preferences for agricultural versus manufacturing goods as in the
standard model in the absence of bequests, that is, [mu] = 1.
(13.) Note that very high levels of [[psi].sub.t], at which the
landed autocrat would favor capital inflows also in autarky, are not
relevant for our analysis. In such cases, excessive spillovers
discourage foreign investors, as can be seen from [A.sub.Kt] appearing
in the denominator of the latent returns to foreign capital and entering
negatively in the equilibrium level of foreign capital in the proofs of
Lemmas 1 and 2.
(14.) Moreover, as we know from Proposition 1 that the landed
oligarchs maintain weak economic institutions when open to trade,
foreign investors would be less likely to invest in the country, even if
they were allowed to do so.
(15.) This is a conservative estimate. An alternative would be to
set the annual TFP growth rate to match the average annual growth rates
of 3% over the period 1966-1990, as reported in Table VII in Young
(1995). However, since we think of the starting date for our experiment
as pre-1960, we opt for a more modest growth rate. Moreover, we wish to
study how policy choices affect the evolution of the two types of
autocracies and thus seek to minimize the exogenous influence on the
economies.
(16.) The sharp increase in [A.sub.Kt] in period 9 gives
substantial leverage to the [A.sub.Kt][K.sub.Dt] term toward the end of
the simulation, causing sustained growth in [K.sub.t] despite the modest
increase in [K.sub.Dt].
(17.) Additional results, available on request, reveal that in the
absence of positive spillovers from foreign capital, GDP in the capital
oligarchy continues to grow steadily but without the distinct
acceleration displayed in Figure 3.
(18.) To allow for some TFP-growth also in the land oligarchy, we
could set km at some lower bound, slightly greater than zero, so that
the elites cannot block all technological progress in manufacturing.
However, whether we set [[pi].sub.M] to zero or to some arbitrarily
small number does not matter for the main results or for comparisons
across regimes.
(19.) See footnote 5.
(20.) Several studies addressing the stagnation of Latin America
identify the concentration of land ownership as a possible culprit, see
for instance Persson and Tabellini (1994), Engerman and Sokoloff (2000).
and Adamopoulos (2008). Galor, Moav, and Vollrath (2009) show that
inequality in land ownership may be detrimental to the emergence of
institutions promoting human capital and may therefore delay
industrialization. On a similar note, Galiani et al. (2008) study
investments in public education in economies governed by landlords who
do not engage in the production of manufacturing goods. They argue that
such economies fail to sustain strong educational institutions as the
elites do not benefit from more educated workers.
(21.) The model falls short of explaining, however, why industrial
policies conducive to growth in the manufacturing sector were not
implemented during this era. It may well be that our simplifying
assumption that industrial policies are costless plays a key role in
this regard. Introducing a trade-off between the benefits of industrial
policies and the costs that they incur could plausibly explain why the
Peron administration did not strengthen institutions as predicted by the
model. An interesting way of generating predictions consistent with
actual developments in Peronist Argentina would be to directly link the
higher price of bequests to a higher cost of industrial policies and
therefore weaker economic institutions.
(22.) Our results are in line with Matsuyama (1992), who also
considers growth in the agricultural sector. He shows that in a closed
economy, there is a positive link between agricultural productivity and
economic growth, whereas for a small open economy the relationship is
negative. Having growth in agriculture would thus amplify our results
that a land autocracy that opens up to trade at an early stage of
development is bound for stagnation, while a closed capital autocracy
investing in sound industrial policy is bound to prosper.
(23.) See for instance Levchenko (2013) for a framework with
political lobbying or Galiani and Torrens (2014) for a model of conflict
between the elites.
ANDERS AKERMAN, ALIREZA NAGHAVI and ANNA SEIM *
* We are indebted to Marianna Belloc, Matteo Cervellati, I-Hui
Cheng, Rikard Forslid, Volker Grossman, Nils-Petter Lagerlof, Helene
Lundqvist, David Mayer-Foulkes, and Peter Neary for very helpful
comments. We would also like to thank seminar participants at Uppsala
University, conference participants at the 26th annual congress of the
European Economic Association in Oslo 2011, the Annual Meeting of
Swedish Economists 2011, XVI conference on Dynamics, Economic Growth and
International Trade in St. Petersburg 2011, the Italian Trade Study
Group in Rome 2012, and the Public Economic Theory annual conference in
Taipei 2012. Any remaining errors are our own. Financial support from
the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Research Foundation and the Swedish
Research Council, Stiftelsen Soderstroms Donationsfond (Project number
FOA09H-355), and from MIUR, through the PRIN project "Institutions,
Social Dynamics, and Economic Development," is gratefully
acknowledged by Anders Akerman, Anna Seim, and Alireza Naghavi,
respectively.
Akerman: Postdoctoral Researcher, Department of Economics,
Stockholm University, Stockholm SE-106 91, Sweden. Phone +46-816-21-63,
Fax +46-815-94-82, E-mail anders.akerman@ne.su.se
Naghavi: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University
of Bologna, Bologna 40126, Italy. Phone +39-051-209-8873, Fax
+39-051-209-4080, E-mail alireza.naghavi@unibo.it
Seim: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Stockholm
University, Stockholm SE-106 91, Sweden. Phone +46-816-38-65, Fax
+46-815-94-82, E-mail anna.seim@ne.su.se
TABLE 1
Real Returns to the Factors of Production Under
Each Trade Regime
Closed Open
[r.sub.Dt] [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[r.sub.Xt] [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[r.sub.Ft] [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Note: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
TABLE 2
Optimal Policies in the Three Different
Oligarchies
t 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Capital [[pi].sub.Ot] 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
oligarchy, [[pi].sub.Ft] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1
[xi] = 1 [[pi].sub.Mt] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
Land oligarchy [[pi].sub.Ot] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
[[pi].sub.Ft] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
[[pi].sub.Mt] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Capital [[pi].sub.Ot] 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
oligarchy, [[pi].sub.Ft] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
[xi] = 5 [[pi].sub.Mt] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
COPYRIGHT 2016 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2016 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.