A MODEL-BASED ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF INCREASED PUBLIC INVESTMENT.
Pain, Nigel ; Rusticelli, Elena ; Salins, Veronique 等
A MODEL-BASED ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECT OF INCREASED PUBLIC INVESTMENT.
There is a strong case for boosting public investment in many
countries based on identified country-specific structural weaknesses and
the relatively low levels of such investment. This paper analyses the
potential macroeconomic benefits of increased public investment using
simulations on NiGEM. The results suggest that the supply-side benefits
from raising potential output are likely to lead to more favourable
macroeconomic outcomes than those from using many other standard fiscal
instruments, although it takes many years for the full effect on
potential output to accumulate. Variant model simulations also suggest
that a fiscal stimulus will be more effective in the short term the less
it is offset by monetary policy, making well-targeted policy initiatives
especially effective when policy interest rates are at the zero lower
bound. Globalisation implies that spillover effects from collective
action are larger than in the past, boosting multipliers relative to the
case where countries take individual action, particularly in the first
two years after the policy change. Such spillovers are likely to be
particularly important in small open European economies, especially
those strongly integrated in European value chains.
Keywords: public investment, fiscal multiplier, spillovers,
macroeconomic model.
JEL codes: C5, E6.
1. Introduction
Enhancing the capacity and regulation of public infrastructure is
judged to be among the highest priorities in eleven of the 36 OECD
countries and eight out of the twelve non-OECD countries surveyed in the
OECD's latest annual Going for Growth assessment of structural
policies (OECD, 2018).The case for an increase in public investment is
further supported by the observation that levels of such expenditure are
below pre-crisis levels in around half of the OECD countries shown in
figure 1. Shortfalls are particularly apparent in public investment in
infrastructure, both in terms of maintenance of existing infrastructure
and in responding to changing demands (ASCE, 2017). In Europe, the
decline in government investment accounts for about three-quarters of
the entire fall in infrastructure investment activities since 2009 (EIB,
2017).
Previous OECD work on a range of models has examined the case for
raising public investment (Mourougane et al., 2016). This paper focuses
on a single model, NiGEM, (1) providing an opportunity to highlight the
sensitivity of results to different assumptions about policy, to
consider more closely cross-country differences and dynamic responses,
and to consider in more detail the potential gains from collective
action by a number of countries.
The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. The next
section compares the effects of a shock to public investment and public
consumption, highlighting the different supply-side response from the
two shocks. In Section 3, the sensitivity of the results from the public
investment shock to alternative monetary and fiscal policy assumptions
is examined. In Section 4, cross-country differences are considered as
well as the possible gains from collective action. Some concluding
remarks are made in Section 5.
2. Public investment compared to public consumption
The short-run multiplier effects of a shock to public expenditure
will depend on a variety of country-specific factors, in particular the
degree of openness, and the setting of monetary and fiscal policies. To
contrast the effect of an increase in public investment and public
consumption the focus here is on a single country example--the United
States--with both policy shocks undertaken using the same policy rules
(monetary policy is set to maintain a nominal GDP target and direct
taxes are set so as to maintain an unchanged budget). The simulation
exercises are all based on a permanent increase in public investment by
the equivalent of 1/2 per cent of GDP per annum. In practice, achieving
a large immediate increase in public investment may be challenging as,
for the typical OECD country, it represents an increase in the volume of
government investment by about 15 per cent. All shocks are undertaken
using NiGEM in forward mode.
An increase in public investment or public consumption, equivalent
to about 1/2 per cent of GDP, both generate an increase in GDP of about
0.4 per cent in the first year when monetary policy is endogenous, so
implying a multiplier of about 0.8. Both multipliers decline in the
second and third year, particularly as monetary policy tightens in
response to increased inflation (figure 2). It is only from the third
year that there is a discernible difference between the two shocks, with
the public investment multiplier plateauing and then gradually
increasing, whereas the public consumption multiplier continues to
decline and becomes mildly negative over time. This illustrates the
beneficial effect that an increase in public investment has on
supply-side potential by increasing the productive capital stock and
hence potential output. A sustained increase in public investment of 0.5
per cent of GDP implies a large adjustment to the public capital stock,
of between 10-20 per cent in the very long term in the typical G7
economy.
In the long run (here after the maximum feasible simulation period
of eighteen years) potential output has increased by 0.9 per cent
following the public investment shock, but is close to zero in the case
of the public consumption shock. While the simulation also demonstrates
that it takes several years before the differential supply-side effects
materialise, the long-run increase in potential output from an increase
in public investment is more than twice as high as the first-year
effects on GDP.
We show potential output rather than actual output after eighteen
years, as adjustment to the long run is not yet complete. Some
simulation exercises that point to stronger or faster output gains from
public investment do not fully account for the length of time it takes
for the eventual steady-state capital stock to accumulate. This accounts
for part of the differences in the impact of public investment in the
three models used in Mourougane et al. (2016). In the particular example
shown here for the United States, the productive public capital stock is
over 9 per cent higher than baseline after eighteen years. However, this
is less than three-quarters of the eventual steady-state capital stock
change, as investment continues to accumulate, implying that potential
and actual output would rise further, all else equal, if the simulation
horizon were to be extended.
The simulation assumes that the projects undertaken are
economically worthwhile. More specifically, the implicit assumption
embedded within the aggregate production functions used in NiGEM is that
the marginal return on public capital is the same as on private capital.
This could understate the return to well-targeted increases in public
investment, particularly if the increase were to lead to spillover
effects that boost economic efficiency. A recent meta-analysis suggests
that such spillovers are larger for public capital installed by
local/regional governments and for 'core public' capital such
as roads, railways and utilities (Bom and Lighart, 2014).
3. The public investment stimulus with alternative macroeconomic
policy settings
The size and persistence of the multiplier effects from a shock to
public expenditure depend in part on the setting of monetary and fiscal
policy. In the default scenario set out above, additional spending on
public investment, or public consumption, is offset by a higher
effective tax rate on households so as to maintain budget neutrality,
and monetary policy in each economy reacts according to the default
two-pillar rule in NiGEM. This section focuses on two specific changes
to these policy assumptions: using a debt-financed stimulus rather than
a budget-neutral stimulus, and allowing monetary policy to be less
restrictive than otherwise because of the positive supply shock.
Changes in the monetary policy rule
The fiscal expansion pushes up inflation in the near term, as
demand rises more rapidly than supply, prompting a rise in policy
interest rates. Over time, this reaction fades, as potential output
begins to build up. If monetary policymakers allow for the long-term
improvement in supply from the higher capital stock, and the extent to
which this will reduce medium-term inflationary pressures relative to
the baseline, the initial rise in policy interest rates, and so real
long-term interest rates, will be smaller (figure 3). Technically, this
is implemented in NiGEM by raising the nominal GDP target by 1 per cent
in the US monetary policy rule. While this makes little difference to
the very long-run outcome, it raises the near-term fiscal multiplier
effects by around one-sixth in the first year of the shock, and by more
in the second year (figure 4). In turn, this helps to foster additional
private spending, and marginally raises the positive spillover benefits
for other economies.
Moving to a debt-financed expansion
Financing the fiscal stimulus by debt rather than by taxes makes
relatively little difference to the near-term multiplier effects, but
significantly lowers the longer-term supply-side benefits. Technically,
this is implemented in NiGEM by changing the target budget balance in
the fiscal rule, making it more negative by 0.5 per cent of GDP
throughout the period of the shock. The additional government debt
results in a rise of 7 percentage points in the US government
debt-to-GDP ratio over the course of the simulation. In turn, this
raises the term premia on US debt by around 8 basis points and results
in a permanent increase in the real long-term interest rate and the user
cost of capital (figure 3). This crowds out part of the private
investment that would otherwise be catalysed by the expansion in the
public capital stock. By the end of the simulation period considered,
the business capital stock is only 0.2 per cent above baseline, compared
with a rise of around 0.8 per cent in the original scenario (with the
default rules). Given the importance of the United States in the global
economy and in financial markets (Rey, 2016), the permanently higher
level of US real interest rates in this scenario is also reflected in
real interest rates and investment in other economies.
4. Cross-country differences and spillovers from collective action
Collective rather than country-specific action also has a
significant influence on both domestic multipliers and spillovers to
other economies. The simulation exercises shown here are again all based
on a permanent increase in public investment by the equivalent of 1/2
per cent of GDP, and compare the effects of single country shocks to
collective action in each of the G7 economies. Spillover effects,
reflecting essentially the response of each country to the initial
demand shock in other countries, decrease over time but can be sizable
over the short run. Their magnitude varies widely across countries
according to country-specific factors, such as overall trade openness or
trade linkages with the G7 economies. The results also highlight the
importance of monetary policy as a transmission channel.
* For a single country shock, the first year multipliers are
greater for countries where trade is a smaller share of GDP; so
multipliers are higher in the United States and Japan, at around 0.8,
compared with the major European countries (figure 5, panel A). A
corollary of this is that fiscal multipliers in individual economies may
have declined somewhat over time as economies have become more open, all
else equal.
* With globalisation bringing tighter links between countries,
collective actions have become more powerful than taking individual
actions. If all G7 economies implement the stimulus simultaneously, the
first year GDP impact rises on average by nearly 0.1 percentage point,
and by more in the countries which are more open to trade (figure 5,
panel A).
* Policy interest rates rise by around 30 basis points in the
United States, Japan, the United Kingdom and Canada and by around 20
basis points in the Euro Area economies in the first 2-3 years of the
collective simulation, reflecting the near-term stimulus to demand,
before fading thereafter. This contributes to the gradual crowding out
of the short-term demand effects of the stimulus.
* The stimulus to demand in the G7 economies provides a boost to
growth in other economies, the magnitude of which depends on
country-specific factors. Small, open European economies, such as
Belgium, Netherlands, Slovak Republic or Hungary, benefit significantly
from the G7 fiscal stimulus due to their strong integration in the
European value chain with Germany as a central player (figure 6, panels
A and B; De Backer and Miroudot, 2014). In some cases, such as the
Slovak Republic or Hungary, the first-year multiplier is higher than in
Germany, Italy or France. By the second year, these gains have generally
faded. In part, this fading reflects the monetary policy responses in
many of the smaller economies. Policy interest rates generally rise by
between 10-20 basis points, and by more for those economies who are
members of the Euro Area, reflecting the spillovers into demand from
stimulus elsewhere.
The policy rules being used in the G7 economies have an important
bearing on the size and persistence of spillovers to other countries. A
more relaxed monetary policy in the G7 economies, with the nominal GDP
target being raised by 1 per cent in all economies, lowers long-term
real interest rates and boosts their final demand (see section 3). This
raises the first-year multipliers from the collective shock in the G7
economies but also outside, especially in the Euro Area countries (with
monetary policy being set for the Euro Area as a whole), and allows the
demand benefits from the shock to persist for longer (figures 5 and 6).
Financing the fiscal stimulus by debt, on the other hand, leads to
higher long-term rates than in the default scenario, so reducing the
spillover benefits of the stimulus. Outside the G7 economies, the
differences are particularly sizeable in the other countries of the Euro
Area, as their interest rates are impacted directly (figure 6, panels A
and B). With integrated global financial markets, this persistent
increase in long-term interest rates is reflected in other economies as
well.
5. Concluding remarks
While the case for increased public investment will partly depend
on the need to address structural weaknesses and so on country-specific
circumstances and the specific projects being considered, model
simulations described here suggest that the supply-side benefits from
raising potential output are likely to lead to more favourable
macroeconomic outcomes than from using many other standard fiscal
instruments. At the same time, the simulations also demonstrate that it
takes many years for the full effect on the public capital stock, and so
potential output, to accumulate.
Variant model simulations also suggest that a fiscal stimulus will
be more effective in the short term the less it is offset by monetary
policy, making well-targeted policy initiatives especially effective
when policy interest rates are at the zero lower bound. And, as OECD
research has shown, choices about the mix of spending and tax policies,
including over the ways in which a fiscal expansion is financed, will
have longer-term implications for growth and the extent to which
improvements in living standards are widely shared (Cournede et al.,
2013; Fournier and Johansson, 2016).
Globalisation implies that the spillovers effects from collective
action are larger than in the past, boosting multipliers relative to the
case where countries take individual action, particularly in the first
two years after the policy change. Such spillovers are likely to be
particularly important in small open European economies, especially
those strongly integrated in European value chains.
NOTES
(1) The OECD uses NiGEM for simulation analysis to evaluate
alternative policy scenarios around its central macroeconomic
projections which are published twice-yearly in the OECD Economic
Outlook. OECD forecasts are not, however, generated using NiGEM or any
other global model, but instead rely heavily on the judgement of country
experts which is informed by inputs from various models (for further
discussion, see Turner, 2016). The version of NiGEM used to carry out
the analysis presented in this paper was released in October 2017.
REFERENCES
ASCE (2017), 201 7 Infrastructure Report Card, American Society of
Civil Engineers.
Bom, P. and Lighart, J. (2014), 'What have we learned from
three decades of research on the productivity of public capital',
Journal of Economic Surveys, 28, Ch. 5.
Cournede, B., Goujard, A. and Pina, A., (2013), 'Reconciling
fiscal consolidation with growth and equity', OECD Journal:
Economic Studies, Vol. 2013/1.
De Backer, K. and Miroudot, S. (2014), 'Mapping global value
chains', ECB working paper, No. 1677.
EIB (2017), Investment Report 201 7118, European Investment Bank.
Fournier, J.M. and Johansson, A. (2016), 'The effect of the
size and the mix of public spending on growth and inequality', OECD
Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1344, Paris: OECD Publishing.
Mourougane, A., Botev, J., Fournieri, J.-M., Pain, N. and
Rusticelli, E. (2016), 'Can an increase in public investment
sustainably lift economic growth?', OECD Economics Department
Working Papers, No. 1352, Paris: OECD Publishing.
OECD (2018), Going for Growth Interim Report, Paris: OECD
Publishing.
Rey, H. (2016), 'International channels of transmission of
monetary policy and the Mundellian Trilemma', IMF Economic Review,
64, I, pp.6-35.
Turner, D. (2016), 'The use of models in producing OECD
macroeconomic forecasts', OECD Economics Department Working Papers,
No. 1336, Paris: OECD Publishing.
Nigel Pain, Elena Rusticelli, Veronique Salins and David Turner *
* OECD Economics department. Corresponding author:
David.TURNER@oecd.org. The views in this paper should not be reported as
representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries.
The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the authors.
Caption: Figure 1. Government investment in 2016 relative to 2000-7
average (nominal shares, percentage points of GDP)
Caption: Figure 2. Comparing public consumption and public
investment shocks (percentage change in GDP from baseline)
Caption: Figure 3. Reaction of real long-term interest rates with
different macro rules (% points difference from baseline)
Caption: Figure 4. Sensitivity of GDP to changes in the underlying
macroeconomic rules (% points difference in level of GDP from the
default scenario)
Caption: Figure 5. The first-year impact of a collective public
investment shock in the G7 economies (change in GDP level from baseline,
%)
Caption: Figure 6. Spillovers from a collective public investment
stimulus in the G7 economies (change in GDP level from baseline, %)
COPYRIGHT 2018 National Institute of Economic and Social Research
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.