首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月08日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:PROSPECTS FOR THE UK ECONOMY.
  • 作者:Kara, Amit ; Hantzsche, Arno ; Lennard, Jason
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2018
  • 期号:August
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 摘要:Section 1. Overview and policy recommendations

    It is particularly difficult to be confident about any forecast of the UK economy at the moment in view of the significant uncertainty around important policy decisions. Despite this the economy is growing in line with potential but it is reaching a crunch point soon.

    As before, Brexit remains the most important source of uncertainty facing the United Kingdom (Carreras et al., 2016, and Piggott, 2016) and there is evidence to suggest that the economy has been weakened by elevated uncertainty. The UK is just eight months away from the March 2019 EU exit date and the range of outcomes remains as wide as ever. We are by no means sure that there will be a deal that can be struck by then and even if there is a deal, it is not clear how policymakers, businesses and households will respond to the new arrangement and all along, the chance of a second referendum is rising.

    There are other policy driven uncertainties. Among the most significant, at the global level, is the risk of a trade war between the US and other economies. The size of the tariffs imposed so far is relatively contained, but there is a risk that the tariff wars spread to other goods and services and also involve more countries. In Box A of the World Economy chapter we show that the impact on GDP and inflation of the tariffs imposed so far is relatively modest but the impact would be more significant if the US government imposed new tariffs and others responded with tit-for-tat measures. See Carney (2018) for a further example of a recent NiGEM simulation on the impact of tariffs on global GDP.

PROSPECTS FOR THE UK ECONOMY.


Kara, Amit ; Hantzsche, Arno ; Lennard, Jason 等


PROSPECTS FOR THE UK ECONOMY.

Section 1. Overview and policy recommendations

It is particularly difficult to be confident about any forecast of the UK economy at the moment in view of the significant uncertainty around important policy decisions. Despite this the economy is growing in line with potential but it is reaching a crunch point soon.

As before, Brexit remains the most important source of uncertainty facing the United Kingdom (Carreras et al., 2016, and Piggott, 2016) and there is evidence to suggest that the economy has been weakened by elevated uncertainty. The UK is just eight months away from the March 2019 EU exit date and the range of outcomes remains as wide as ever. We are by no means sure that there will be a deal that can be struck by then and even if there is a deal, it is not clear how policymakers, businesses and households will respond to the new arrangement and all along, the chance of a second referendum is rising.

There are other policy driven uncertainties. Among the most significant, at the global level, is the risk of a trade war between the US and other economies. The size of the tariffs imposed so far is relatively contained, but there is a risk that the tariff wars spread to other goods and services and also involve more countries. In Box A of the World Economy chapter we show that the impact on GDP and inflation of the tariffs imposed so far is relatively modest but the impact would be more significant if the US government imposed new tariffs and others responded with tit-for-tat measures. See Carney (2018) for a further example of a recent NiGEM simulation on the impact of tariffs on global GDP.

As before, our central case assumes an exit from the EU where the UK maintains a high level of market access for goods and services to the EU and where financial markets are not subject to dislocation, the so-called 'soft Brexit'. We also assume that the trade dispute between the US and other countries remains contained with negligible implications for global trade and UK GDP growth. Under those circumstances, GDP growth is set to grow at close to its potential at 1.7 per cent next year after growth of 1.4 per cent this year (figure 1), which was affected by severe weather in the first quarter: this path is consistent with the short-term growth forecast from our new monthly GDP Tracker and also broadly similar to our previous forecast. The risks to our GDP growth forecast are tilted to the downside.

It is against this backdrop that HM Treasury and the Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) will set fiscal and monetary policy. We have argued previously that austerity fatigue has set in and the government's focus must shift away from repairing public finances to repairing public services (Hantszche and Young, 2018). At the least, this requires the government to maintain the current level of spending (as a proportion of GDP) and look to fund that additional spending either through borrowing or tax increases. Should the economy evolve in line with our forecast, there is a case for the MPC to remain on a gentle path of interest rate normalisation and emphasise to the public that there is not a pre-determined path for the policy rate. In particular, we would expect the MPC to communicate its willingness to stand ready to act quickly and aggressively in either direction should alternative circumstances materialise.

Brexit White Paper

In a major development since our last forecast, the UK government published a White Paper on 12 July with an outline of its preferred relationship with the EU after Brexit. Although this is the most detailed plan published by the UK government to date, many questions remain open. Moreover, the White Paper has failed to unite the Cabinet, the governing Conservative Party or Parliament and, as a result, the entire spectrum of possibilities, ranging from a second referendum to a no-deal Brexit, remains as likely as before (Hix, 2018).

Although a large part of the draft withdrawal agreement has been settled between the two sides, important areas related to the future trading relationship and the status of a customs border in and around Ireland remain outstanding. Both sides are looking to reach an agreement by October 2018 to allow the European Parliament to approve the withdrawal agreement and ensure that a deal is in place ahead of Brexit on 29 March 2019.

In the White Paper the government has prioritised trade in goods over services and aims to limit the free movement of people. The core of the proposal is a free trade area for goods with a 'common rulebook' with the EU and a new type of customs arrangement (Facilitated Customs Arrangement) that will replace the single market and the existing customs union and at the same time ensure that there is no hard border between Ireland and Northern Ireland. For services, the government is no longer seeking a mutual recognition arrangement and has instead asked for enhanced equivalence. Mutual recognition offers market access even with regulatory divergence whereas under an equivalence regime both sides need to be satisfied that the regulations achieve the same outcome.

In Box A we compare the White Paper proposals against other EU free trade arrangements and conclude that the trade proposals in the White Paper are similar in scope to the EU-Switzerland arrangement. It is likely, therefore, that if the UK insists on this level of engagement the EU will insist on concessions on the movement of people, the role of the Court of Justice of the European Union and a budgetary contribution.

Assuming that the government's White Paper proposals are adopted in full, we estimate a GDP loss of around 2.5 per cent relative to our soft-Brexit central forecast over the next 10 years, but this does not include the possible impact of a loss in productivity which could be material (Hantzsche and Kara, 2018). In that case inflation will be higher by 1.4 percentage points on impact, mainly because we assume that the currency will depreciate, and in our view any fiscal gains from a lower financial contribution to the EU will be more than offset by a loss to GDP.

Productivity

Alongside policy-related uncertainty, there is also uncertainty about future productivity growth and the overall speed limit of the economy. UK productivity has been particularly weak and disappointing since the financial crisis, so much so that the productivity gap relative to a pre-crisis trend is twice as big in the UK as for the G7 (ex UK) average.

Recently tentative signs of a recovery in labour productivity in the second half of last year were snuffed out in the first quarter (see Supply Conditions). As before, we have treated this putative recovery with caution for this forecast round and held our lower medium-term productivity forecast unchanged, but there are some reasons to be optimistic. Higher minimum wages and the very rapid increase in the living wage, together with lower levels of net migration that create labour scarcity, may well trigger increases in business investment that can help raise labour productivity which, in turn, is likely to help lift real wage growth (see Box B in the May 2018 Review and Riley and Rosazza Bondibene, 2017).

Fiscal assumptions

As in our May forecast, we have assumed that the government will struggle to maintain its self-imposed fiscal rule. The government's target to lower the total managed expenditure-to-GDP ratio to a level below its long-run average is unsustainable in our view. As a result, our forecast assumes additional government spending such that the ratio remains constant at its current level (see Public Finance section below). As it happens, some of that additional spending has already been pledged with the decision to spend an additional 20.5 billion [pounds sterling] per year (around 1 per cent of GDP) by 2023-4 on the National Health Service. In addition, pay increases for public sector workers will add to funding pressures. The pay rises will help narrow, but not eliminate, the wage gap between the private and public sector that started to emerge after the government imposed a pay restraint on public sector wages. Additional pay rises will be necessary, in our view, to further narrow that gap.
Box A. UK government Brexit White Paper

The UK government published a White Paper (The future relationship
between the United Kingdom and the European Union) on 12 July
outlining its preferences for a future relationship with the EU.
(1) In this box we compare the proposals outlined in the White
Paper against other EU free trade agreements (FTA) and also
estimate the impact on the UK relative to our central forecast
which assumes a soft Brexit.

Benchmarking the White Paper proposals

The World Bank database of preferential trade agreements provides a
detailed measure of the depth of all the agreements worldwide that
were signed after 1957. We update that database with the White
Paper proposals, building on earlier work that was published in the
February Review (see Box C 'The Great British trade-off).

Our results suggest that the trade intensity of the White Paper
proposals is comparable to Switzerland or Canada and is less
comprehensive than a Norway-style EEA arrangement. The score
essentially reflects a comprehensive FTA for goods and the
shortfall is explained by the proposals for services.

Non-EU countries that have secured deep and broad trading
arrangements with the EU have had to concede ground on the free
movement of labour, the jurisdiction of the CJEU and/or make a
budgetary contribution to various programmes run by the EU. Figure
AI is a visual representation of the extent of the depth and
breadth of EU engagement We have selected three key dimensions to
define the relationship between the EU and non-EU countries and the
vertices of the triangle correspond to each of these: full market
access, complete freedom of movement of people and size of the
financial contribution (as a percentage of Gross National Income).
One could add other dimensions to the analysis such as the role of
the CJEU, security, defence, fiscal harmonisation, but we have, for
the sake of simplicity, restricted our analysis to the what we
believe are the three most important areas of negotiation between
the UK and the EU.

Briefly, the largest triangle represents the UK current level of
engagement as a member state of the EU: the UK has full access to
the EU market in goods and services, allows EU citizens to move
freely in and out of the UK, and contributes about 0.5 per cent of
GNI to the EU budget, net of what it receives. Norway opted to join
the European Economic Area (EEA) to have close to full access to
the single market, both in goods and services. The dashed red
triangle shows that, to be accepted as a member of the EEA, Norway
had to agree to significant financial contributions ('Norway
Grants', amounting to 0.14 per cent of GNI) and freedom of movement
of persons. Switzerland's bilateral agreements with the EU means
that it allows freedom of movement of persons, makes a very small
net budgetary contribution, but its market access is significantly
reduced in the service sector. Finally, the trade deal with Canada
(CETA) is less extensive than Switzerland and is essentially
restricted to just goods. Canada does not make a budgetary
contribution.

The UK White Paper proposals are represented in the dotted black
line. Market access for the White Paper, based on our scoring,
stands at 90, which is close to Switzerland (89) and Canada (79)
and the movement of labour provisions fall well short of
Switzerland and only marginally higher than Canada. We have assumed
that the UK budgetary contribution to the EU will be small. Legal
technicalities aside, our benchmarking exercise suggests that the
EU is likely to insist on more generous provisions for the free
movement of labour and is also likely to insist on a budgetary
contribution.

Impact on the economy

To simulate the effects of a deal as implied by this White Paper,
in contrast to the soft Brexit assumed in our forecast, we have
made the following assumptions, which come into effect in the first
quarter of 2021, after the transition period ends:

* UK exports: In our soft Brexit central case the UK maintains a
close but not complete trading relationship with the EU.
Immediately after the end of the transition period, some services
e.g. financial services that require passporting rights will no
longer be exported to the EU. Over time, trade in services between
the UK and the EU will continue to decline as businesses develop
new trading relationships. In this alternative scenario we assume
that trade between the UK and the EU is reduced by about 40% in the
long run, based on estimates by Ebell (2016).

* Business investment: Compared to our soft Brexit scenario, the
reduction in trade and increase in uncertainty will likely weigh on
investment spending by UK firms and also foreign direct investment
We consider a reduction in FDI of around 12 per cent which is
approximately half the shock implied by HM Treasury (2016) and
Dhingra et al. (2017) in the case of a no-deal WTO variant

* Migration: To account for reduced movement of labour within the
EU as well as the UK potentially becoming a less attractive
destination for migrants, we consider a reduction in net migration
of around 50,000 per year compared to the ONS' principal population
projection, which is not based on any Brexit specific assumptions.
This figure is halfway between the ONS' principal and low migration
population projections.

* Fiscal: According to the UK government, applying the methodology
set out in the Phase I agreement implies a financial settlement
with the EU of 35 [pounds sterling]-39 billion [pounds sterling].
The schedule of payments is yet to be decided although the Phase I
agreement makes clear that the UK will not be required to make any
payments earlier than if the UK had remained a Member State. After
the budgetary framework ends in 2020, the UK continues to service
its existing commitments and makes a negligible ongoing
contribution. Overall, we assume that annual net contributions to
the EU reduce by approximately 25 per cent

Figure A2 plots the growth rate of real GDP in this scenario,
relative to our baseline soft Brexit forecast. We expect output
growth to stall due to an immediate reduction in services exports
to the EU. This would be moderated somewhat by a depreciation of
sterling, which cheapens goods and services exported to the EU and
the rest of the world but raises the price of imports. We expect
this rise in import prices to feed into consumer prices, adding
almost 1.4 percentage points to inflation in 2021 (figure A3),
dampening domestic demand. Over time the growth rate of real GDP
would settle at a lower rate than assumed in our soft Brexit
forecast as net migration falls and productive capacity grows at a
slower rate. This accumulates to a loss of around 500 [pounds
sterling] per person per year compared to the soft Brexit scenario
and to a loss of around 800 [pounds sterling] under the
counterfactual WTO rules.

NOTE

(1) 'The future relationship between the United Kingdom and the
European Union' available at:
https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/file/725288/
The_future_relationship_between_the_United_Kingdom_
and_the_European_Union.pdf/.

REFERENCES

Dhingra, S., Ottaviano, G.,Sampson, T. and van Reenen, J. (2017),
'The impact of Brexit on foreign direct investment in the UK', CEP
Brexit Analysis, 3.

Ebell, M. (2016), 'Assessing the impact of trade agreements on
trade', National Institute Economic Review, 238, R31-42.

HM Treasury (2016), HM Treasury Analysis: the long-term economic
impact of EU membership and the alternatives, CM92S0.

Hofmann, C., Osnago, A. and Ruta, M. (2017), 'Horizontal depth: a
new database on the content of preferential trade agreements',
Policy Research working paper, no. WPS 7981, Washington, D.C.:
World Bank Group,
https://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/deep-trade-agreements.

This box was prepared by Arno Hantzsche, Amit Kara, Cyrille Lenoel
and Rebecca Piggott.


Inflation and GDP forecasts

All in all, we judge the risk to our GDP growth forecast to be skewed to the downside and the risk to the inflation forecast to the upside. Figures 2 and 3 are generated from our structural model, NiGEM, which allows the forecaster to apply an expert judgement and convey a complete narrative. The skew is primarily driven by our judgement on the impact of a no-deal Brexit. See Barrell et al. (2000) and McCarthy (1972) for details of how the fan charts are constructed.

CPI inflation is set to continue falling from an average of 2.7 per cent in 2017 to 2.3 per cent this year, before settling close to the target rate of 2 per cent in 2019 and beyond. This drop is in spite of the recent depreciation of sterling. As discussed above, there are countervailing risks to that central forecast from Brexit and continued weak productivity growth. Taking both together, we judge the overall risk to inflation to be skewed to the upside.

These forecasts can be benchmarked against those we are publishing by the Warwick Business School (WBS) Forecasting System, which combines state-of-the-art statistical models weighted solely by the forecasting performance of each model (Box B). On their forecasts, real GDP growth for the final quarter of 2018 is most likely to be somewhere between 1-2 per cent (NIESR = 1.6 per cent) but their forecast is skewed to the upside, while ours points to a downside risk. The purely statistical models will tend to generate a return to long-run trends and cannot automatically condition on new events such as exit from the European Union, which is something that we can do using other models and judgement to inform the whole density. The WBS growth forecast for the final quarter of 2019 is expected to be between 2-3 per cent compared with the NIESR forecast of 1.7 per cent.

Similarly, the WBSFS model points to CPI inflation between 2-3 per cent as the most likely outcome for both the final quarters of 2018 and 2019.

An alternative benchmark for the central forecast is provided by an analysis of recent trends in the monetary aggregates. As noted in Box C, broad money growth has slowed significantly since 2016 and may be pointing to a somewhat weaker inflation outlook than in our central forecast.

Monetary policy

As before, we maintain our view that the Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) should take a further step on the path towards the removal of some monetary policy accommodation with a 25 basis point increase in Bank Rate to 0.75 per cent at its August meeting. Beyond that, and subject to the economy evolving broadly as in our central forecast, we recommend that Bank Rate rises by 25 basis points every six months so that it reaches 2 per cent by early 2021.

The news on the economy is mixed. On one side, economic growth has recovered in the UK and elsewhere after a weak first quarter. According to some metrics there is now little spare capacity in the economy, consistent with the employment rate being at an all-time high and the unemployment rate at a post-1975 low. The current pace of growth is probably in line with potential. It is not easy to gauge spare capacity in an economy as it is, among other factors, also a function of current plans for investment and developments in the labour market but, if anything, we think that the decision to leave the European Union will constrain supply-side capacity in the short and medium run.

Even though growth is close to potential and employment is at record levels, we see very little sign of wage or price pressure. Regular pay rose by just 2.5 per cent in nominal terms in the three months to May and CPI inflation has been trending downwards since December with the most recent outturn for the second quarter surprisingly low.

There are a number of explanations for low wage growth in the UK and elsewhere (see the Supply Side section below). One possibility is that real wage growth is a consequence of low productivity (Kara et al., 2018). In itself that would imply a monetary policy stance that is close to neutral because unit labour costs are growing at a rate that is consistent with the inflation target. There is also the possibility that wages are low because we are underestimating the amount of supply capacity in the labour market (Bell and Blanchflower, in this Review). Under that view there is no need to remove monetary accommodation.

Our recommendation for a rate increase places weight on both explanations but, in our view, with the policy rate still at levels that are close to historic lows, a gradual increase will do little more than withdraw some of the stimulus in the economy. Monetary policy will remain accommodative even after the rate increase in our central view of how the economy will develop.

The MPC also has to take account of the uncertainty related to the outcome of the Brexit negotiations when setting policy. Not only is the outcome of the negotiations unknown, the response of the economy to a given outcome is also unclear ex ante. Under a soft Brexit scenario, such as the one that underpins our central forecast, the MPC should raise the policy rate gradually. Under an alternative hard Brexit scenario the policy response may not be as clear. An exchange rate shock together with an adverse supply shock to productivity would drive both short-term and longer-term inflation higher, but the overall impact on inflation will also depend on the response of aggregate demand. The appropriate monetary policy response in that case is not so clear.
Box B. Forecasting with a benchmark: the Warwick Business School
forecasting system

We provide benchmark forecasts to help understand and contextualise
the forecasts presented in this Review. The box presents density
forecasts for UK GDP annual growth and inflation, and reports the
probabilities of a range of output and inflation events occurring,
as calculated using the Warwick Business School Forecasting System
(WBSFS).

To reflect the uncertainties inherent in economic forecasting, and
following the practice of NIESR and other forecasters such as the
Bank of England and OBR, the WBSFS provides probabilistic
forecasts. The WBSFS forecasts are produced by explicitly combining
density forecasts from a set of twenty four, statistically
motivated, univariate and multivariate econometric models commonly
used in the academic literature. The use of combination forecasts
or model averaging reflects the view, supported by research (e.g.,
see Bates and Granger, 1969; Wallis, 2011; Geweke and Amisano,
2012; Rossi, 2013), that because any single model may be
mis-specified there may be gains from the use of combination
forecasts.

Comparison of the Institute's forecasts with the probabilistic
forecasts from the WBSFS may be interpreted as providing an
approximate indicator of the importance of expert judgement, which
may include views on the underlying structure of the macroeconomy.
This is because the WBSFS forecasts are computed by exploiting
regularities in past data with the aid of automated time-series
models; they do not take an explicit, structural or theoretical
view about how the macroeconomy works; and they do not rely on
(subjective) expert judgement to the same degree as those presented
by the Institute. The forecasts from the WBSFS are not altered once
produced; they are deemed 'simply' to represent the data's view of
what will happen to the macroeconomy in the future.

Figure B1 presents WBSFS's latest (as of 11 July 2018)
probabilistic forecasts for real GDP growth and inflation--defined
as year-on-year growth rates for 2018q4 and 2019q4--as histograms.
The information set used to produce these forecasts includes
information on GDP growth up to 2018q1 and data on CPI inflation up
to May 2018.

Table B1 extracts from these histogram forecasts the probabilities
of specific output growth and inflation events. The events
considered are the probability of output growth being less than 0
per cent, 1 per cent and 2 per cent, and of inflation lying outside
the 1-3 per cent target range (i.e., the probability of the Bank
of England's Governor having to write a letter explaining how and
why inflation has breached its target range). Also reported are the
individual probabilities of inflation being less than I per cent
and greater than 3 per cent, to indicate which side of the target
range is most likely to be breached.

Inspection of the forecasts for output growth for 2018Q4 in table
BI suggests that, compared with our forecasts made one quarter ago,
lower output growth is more likely. The most likely range for the
forecast remains for economic growth between I per cent and 2 per
cent in 2018Q4, but the probability of growth less than 2 per cent
has increased from 58 per cent in April to 71 per cent in July.
Looking out further to 2019Q4, the change in the probability
forecast from April to July is less pronounced, with higher growth
between 2 and 3 per cent now marginally less likely. As table Bl
shows, the difference between the forecasts made in April and July,
for 2019q4, is small--with a small upward revision to the risk of
'low' growth (growth less than I per cent)--the probability of this
event has risen from 20 to 25 per cent.

For inflation, our probabilistic forecasts for 2018Q4 have changed
between April and July, such that the probability of inflation
being outside the 1-3 per cent range, thereby triggering an
explanatory letter from the Governor of the Bank of England, has
decreased from 41 to 28 per cent. This change is largely
attributable to the probability of inflation exceeding 3 per cent
falling from 35 per cent to 24 per cent. An inflation rate between
2 and 3 per cent remains the most likely outcome in the year ending
2018Q4, with a 44 per cent probability (up by 6 percentage points
from the previous estimate of 38 per cent). But the WBSFS predicts
that inflationary pressures for 2019Q4 remain approximately as we
forecast in April, with a probability of around 27 per cent of
inflation falling in the 1-2 per cent range and 32 per cent in the
2-3 per cent range. In comparison with our previous forecasts, the
probability of inflation rising above 3 per cent in 2019Q4 remains
essentially the same, having fallen from 30 per cent to 29 per
cent.

NOTE

WBSFS forecasts for UK output growth and inflation have been
released every quarter since November 2014. Details of the releases
are available at
https://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/subjects/emf/forecasting/
and a description of the models in the system and of the indicators
employed is available at
https://wvvw2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/subjects/emf/forecasting/summary
of_wbs_forecastng_system.pdf.

REFERENCES

Bates, J.M. and Granger, C.W. (1969), The combination of
forecasts', Operational Research Quarterly, 20, pp. 451-68.

Geweke, J. and Amisano, G. (2012), 'Predictions with misspecified
models', American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 102, pp.
482-6.

Rossi, B. (2013), 'Advances in forecasting under model instability'
in Elliott, G. and Timmermann, A. (eds), Handbook of Economic
Forecasting, Volume 2B, Elsevier Publications, pp. 1203-324.

Wallis, K.F. (201 I), 'Combining forecasts--forty years later',
Applied Financial Economics, 21, pp. 33-41.

This Box was prepared by Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James
Mitchell.

Box C. Monetary trends giving cautionary signal

This box provides a different perspective on UK economic prospects
based on an assessment of recent developments in the monetary
aggregates. UK monetary growth rates have fallen significantly
since 2016 and are below post-crisis averages, suggesting weak
prospects for economic activity and domestically-generated
inflation.

The discussion below focuses on 'non-financial' broad (M4) and
narrow (Ml) monetary aggregates, comprising money holdings of
households and private non-financial businesses. The Bank of
England's M4ex broad aggregate additionally includes money held by
non-bank financial corporations, excluding intermediaries, but such
holdings are volatile and appear unrelated to future spending on
goods and services.

Figure C1 compares annual rates of change of nominal GDP and the
non-financial money measures. Swings in monetary momentum have
generally preceded swings in nominal GDP momentum over the period
shown, although the lead time has been variable. Non-financial MI
has given clearer directional signals than non-financial M4.

The annual growth rates of the aggregates were well above their
post-crisis averages in mid-2016, suggesting that economic
expansion would continue in 2016-17 despite the negative shock of
the EU referendum result. The growth rates, however, peaked in
September 2016, more than halving over the subsequent 18 months
before recovering slightly in April/May 2018. This downswing was
reflected in a slowdown in nominal GDP, annual growth of which
peaked in the fourth quarter of 2016 and fell steadily through the
first quarter of 2018.

The monetary slowdown occurred despite the August 2016 rate cut, a
further round of quantitative easing between August 2016 and March
2017 and additional monetary base expansion until February 2018
resulting from Bank of England lending to banks under the term
funding scheme. This suggests that the slowdown was demand-driven:
the referendum shock may have weakened economic confidence and
spending intentions, leading to a reduction in desired money
holdings.

According to the credit counterparts analysis of non-financial M4,
the fall in annual growth between September 2016 and May 2018 was
attributable (in an accounting sense) to a combination of slowdowns
in bank lending to the public sector and to households/
non-financial firms and a drag from other sterling counterparts
(i.e. net overseas deposits and non-deposit funding).

Figure C2 compares, over a longer period, the two-quarter rate of
change of constant-price GDP and the six-month change in
non-financial MI deflated by consumer prices. The fall in real
non-financial M I momentum since 2016 ranks as the fourth largest
since the mid-1980s. The three larger declines in 1986-88, 1989-90
and 2007-8, and a smaller reduction in 2010-11, were followed by a
significant loss of economic momentum.

A sectoral split is available between the household sector and
private non-financial corporations. Six-month growth of real
household MI is currently below that of real corporate MI but the
latter has also slowed significantly since 2016, suggesting weak
prospects for both consumer spending and business investment.

The current pace of broad money growth may be inconsistent with
achievement of the 2 per cent inflation target over the medium
term. The velocity of non-financial M4--i.e. the ratio of nominal
GDP to the aggregate--has fallen at an average rate of 0.7 per cent
per annum since end-2009, compared with a reduction of 3.0 per cent
per annum over the prior decade. Assuming a continued decline of
0.7 per cent per annum, current annual growth of non-financial M4
of 3.3 per cent in May, if sustained, would result in a 2.6 per
cent per annum rate of increase of nominal GDP. This would imply an
inflation undershoot unless potential economic expansion is below I
per cent per annum.

Monetary Policy Committee member Michael Saunders has suggested
that broad money trends have been affected by a portfolio shift by
households into mutual funds, sales of which rose strongly in 2017
after weakness in 2016. This shift cannot fully explain the
slowdown in non-financial M4: annual growth of an expanded
liquidity measure including mutual funds, National Savings
instruments and foreign currency deposits has also fallen, reaching
a six-year low in April/May. Mutual funds and other longer-term
savings products, moreover, are not money: a portfolio shift into
such funds may indicate a reduced likelihood of near-term spending.

This box was prepared by Simon Ward of NS Partners and Janus
Henderson Investors


When setting policy the MPC will need to consider the consequences of 'getting it wrong'. It is possible that circumstances next year will require much looser monetary policy and the MPC will then regret a decision to raise Bank Rate in August. But would the damage to the economy and the Bank of England's reputation from a premature rate increase outweigh the costs of a delayed rise? Decision-making under uncertainty requires an assessment of outcomes in all possible eventualities that balances the risks. The committee can mitigate the consequences of a policy error by departing from current practice and emphasising the uncertainty (rather than the certainty) of its future policy stance. The communication should also make clear that it stands ready to adjust Bank Rate quickly and aggressively in either direction should circumstances turn out to be different from what currently appears most likely.

Financial markets are pricing in a rate increase in August. Further out, expectations of Bank Rate have eased slightly since our previous forecast in May (figure 4). The difference between our central forecast and the implied market path is likely to be due to the markets placing weight on downside risks that are not contained in our central forecast. Our central forecast, and our recommendation for further Bank Rate increases beyond August, is conditioned on two very uncertain assumptions about future monetary and fiscal policy.

First, the market view of rates is based on a probability-weighted average of that entire spectrum, whereas our central forecast is based on a soft Brexit.

Second, we have decisively assumed that government spending will overshoot the OBR's latest fiscal forecast published in March. Crucially, from the perspective of monetary policy, some of that additional spending is due to higher public sector wages which will raise the government consumption deflator with some spillover into the private sector (see Public Finance section below).

The MPC has long stated that it will continue to reinvest the proceeds from maturing bonds bought under its Asset Purchase Facility until the policy rate reaches the threshold of 2 per cent. That guidance changed in June and the MPC has decided to lower that threshold by 50 basis points to 1.5 per cent (Bank of England, 2018). We would therefore expect the Bank's balance sheet to start to shrink from mid-2020 as bonds mature, given that on our central forecast the threshold is reached at that point. We assume that the Bank will not actively sell bonds back to the market or reinvest the proceeds of maturing bonds.

At its June meeting, the Financial Policy Committee (FPC) held the countercyclical capital buffer rate unchanged at 1 per cent. Brexit remains a key risk for the FPC and in its judgement the UK banking system has the resilience to continue supporting the economy even through a disorderly Brexit. The FPC however, believes that the risks from a disorderly Brexit are material, especially to derivative contracts.

Public finances

While most recent developments in the public finances have been favourable, substantial risks to the fiscal position are building up in the years ahead. According to the latest ONS outturn estimate from June, public sector net borrowing in 2017-18 was 1.9 per cent of GDP, 0.3 percentage points below the estimate provided by the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) in March this year, as a result of both higher receipts and lower spending. Between April and June of the current fiscal year, the government borrowed 5.4 billion [pounds sterling] less than over the same period one year ago.

Spending pressures

Nevertheless, the government faces rising pressures to increase spending in a number of areas, to accommodate the needs of an ageing population and maintain the quality of public services, as we highlighted in detail in our last Review (Hantzsche and Young, 2018). In its Fiscal Sustainability Report from July 2018, the OBR corroborates our findings and stresses that, absent major policy changes, public finances will come under significant pressure over the next fifty years.

As in our previous forecast, we therefore deviate from official spending plans, which project that total managed expenditure will fall from 38.4 per cent of GDP currently to 37.6 per cent in 2022-3, as laid out in the OBR's March 2018 forecast. Instead we assume that the share of spending in GDP will remain stable over the forecast horizon. In fact, since the Spring Statement the government has announced a substantial increase in NHS spending of 20.5 billion [pounds sterling] per year by 2023-4, or 0.9 per cent of GDP, as well as 1.25 billion [pounds sterling] in the next two years to alleviate pension pressures. While the government has stated that this additional spending will be financed by spending cuts in other areas and higher taxes (as well as lower EU budgetary contributions), details remain to be provided.

Our assumption of public expenditure remaining stable at just under 39 per cent of GDP would allow the government space to finance the increase in spending on the NHS and allocate additional spending of up to 20 billion [pounds sterling] per year to other areas, for instance to finance the end of public sector pay restraint. While NHS employees saw the cap on pay growth lifted in April this year, overall earnings in the public sector have remained stagnant. As a result, our estimate of the gap between public sector wages and their long-run trend was around 3 per cent in May (Dolton et al., 2018) (figure 5). In July, a pay rise was announced for public sector employees in a number of additional areas, like education and defence, to be financed within their existing budgets. This pay rise will align public sector wage growth better with that in comparable private sectors. Nevertheless, additional adjustments to pay may be necessary for some time to close the gap between public sector pay and its long-run sustainable level in order to prevent recruitment difficulties from building up, which will require additional funding of around 5 billion [pounds sterling] per year.

For our central forecast, the assumption of additional spending implies that, absent any adjustments to tax rates, public sector net borrowing will continue to be around 2 per cent of GDP per annum over the forecast horizon. As a result, we project public sector net debt to settle at around 80 per cent of GDP in the medium term. Given that the risks to our forecast are to the downside, this suggests that it is unlikely that the government will reach its target of a balanced budget by the middle of the 2020s without further policy action.

Fiscal risks

In its Managing Fiscal Risks report, HM Treasury outlines how it aims to address several potential risks to public finances. While fiscal risks can also arise from underspending (Chadha, 2018a), the largest risks to the sustainability of public finances arise from economic downturns and financial crises. In Box A, we assess the economic impact of two Brexit scenarios. One corresponds to the recent White Paper proposal by the government and the other scenario models the potential failure of negotiations and a no-deal Brexit as of the second quarter of 2019.

Figures 6 and 7 illustrate the fiscal consequences of both scenarios for public sector net borrowing and net debt. Figure 6 shows that even if the government's current plans of a free trade agreement in goods and adherence to a common rulebook were implemented, we would still expect the positive fiscal effect of lower contributions to the EU budget to be more than offset by the fiscal implications of an economic slowdown that would result from the reduction in services trade. In this White Paper scenario, the public deficit as a share of GDP is estimated to increase by up to 0.6 percentage points relative to our central forecast which is based on soft Brexit assumptions, leaving no room for a 'Brexit dividend'. Under a no-deal Brexit scenario, the deficit widens even further, preventing the level of government debt from declining.

Section 2: Forecast in detail

Financial markets developments

Stronger oil price, exchange rate depreciation and flattening of the yield curve

The FTSE All-Share Index is close to its level of 4,200 from the beginning of the year, after having gone through a trough of 3,811 on 26 March 2018. This probably reflects several forces balancing out each other: on the one hand the surge in oil prices benefitted the oil and gas sector and on the other hand fears about trade tensions, political instability and Brexit weighed down on the outlook for future earnings. Looking at the sectoral performance of the FTSE All-Share Index, we find that the best performers were Health Care and Oil and Gas with 10 per cent returns year-to-date until 19 July, and the laggards were Telecoms and Technology with respective negative returns of 17 and 18 per cent year-to-date. Oil and Gas stocks represent a large share (14 percent) of the FTSE All-Share Index and were boosted by the higher oil price. On the other hand, the large fall in the performance of the Telecoms and Technology sectors only had a muted impact on the FTSE All-Share Index because taken together, these sectors account for less than 4 per cent of the share of the index.

The trade-weighted exchange rate has depreciated by 2.8 per cent since our May forecast (figure 8). The Chequers statement on 6 July and the publication of the White Paper on 12 July detailing the government's Brexit strategy were received with scepticism in the foreign exchange market. Sterling depreciated versus the euro from 1.131 [euro] on 6 July to 1.118 [euro] on 19 July. That drop may well have been driven by political instability in the UK and the prospect of difficult negotiations. Two senior members of the Cabinet, Boris Johnson, the Foreign Secretary and David Davis, the Brexit Secretary, resigned to mark their disapproval of the new strategy. The initial response by the European Commission was lukewarm; it asked member states to prepare for a no-deal exit. Our forecast assumes that the sterling effective exchange rate will weaken by a further 1 per cent in the third quarter of 2018 and then stay at the same level into the medium term. Our assumption is based on uncovered interest parity, meaning that changes in the exchange rates are driven by relative changes in interest rates.

In the bond market, the gilt yield curve flattened in the 3 months from May to July with yields decreasing mainly at the long end of the curve. The 10-year to 2-year spread reached 0.46 percentage points on 19 July (figure 9), the lowest since August 2016 just after the EU referendum, when there were fears that the economy could go into recession. Lower long-term yields may help to stimulate the economy, but an inverted yield curve is often seen as an advance signal of a looming recession, as discussed in the case of the US in Lenoel (2018).

In the commodities sector, Brent oil, which is the benchmark for crude oil in Europe, has traded at a higher price recently. Converted into sterling, the price per barrel increased from an average of 48 [pounds sterling] in the first quarter to 57 [pounds sterling] at the time of writing. Regarding other commodities, the price of coal traded at ICE increased from 62.4 [pounds sterling] per ton in the first quarter to 77 [pounds sterling] at the time of writing but the price of natural gas decreased in the Nymex market from 2.14 [pounds sterling] to 2.08 [pounds sterling] per million British thermal units over the same period.

Output and the components of demand

The ONS nudged higher its estimate of first quarter GDP growth from 0.1 per cent to 0.2 per cent in line with our monthly GDP estimate. Growth nevertheless slowed in the first quarter and the precise reason for the weakness is unclear. Temporary factors such as adverse weather conditions have, in all likelihood, played a part but that does not appear to be the whole story.

To start with, other economies such as the Euro Area, US and Japan also slowed and, furthermore, an examination of the national accounts data across a number of countries, including the UK, for this period suggests that much of the weakness reflects a slowdown in trade volumes, pointing therefore to a common international trigger, but again there is no clear explanation.

Monthly GDP Tracker

Looking ahead into the second quarter and beyond, our judgement is that economic growth will recover and that the slowdown in the first quarter was a temporary soft patch rather than the start of a prolonged period of weakness. Our short-term UK GDP growth forecast is informed by our new monthly GDP Tracker (see figure 10). Accordingly, UK growth is forecast to rise to 0.4 per cent in the second quarter and 0.5 per cent in the third.

From July 2018, the ONS started publishing an official monthly GDP series and its main sub-components with a two month lag, so we now have the estimate for May. Building on this new initiative by the ONS, our monthly GDP Tracker is a bottom-up model that forecasts ten sectors on the output side of the national accounts. It takes account of recent trends in the ONS data, consumer and business surveys, and judgement based on a variety of other available information and intelligence. We published our forecast for June and also for Q2 and Q3 on the same day as the ONS.

Trade

On the expenditure, net trade is set to make a positive contribution again in 2018 in spite of weak first quarter export volume growth, following a strong positive contribution to real GDP growth in 2017 (figure 11).

Survey indicators such as those from Markit PMI/CIPS and BCC have been pointing to robust export growth recently (figure 12). Export volume growth is supported by the competitive exchange rate in the near term, but going forward, even with a soft Brexit, we judge that UK exports will face headwinds as the uncertainty of future relationships offsets the benefits of the currency depreciation.

Household consumption

Turning to the other expenditure components, we expect consumption growth of just below 1.5 per cent in 2018. Household consumption depends largely on real disposable income, in turn determined by real wages and employment. Real disposable income was weak at the end of last year, but should recover in 2018 as wage growth picks up, inflation declines and employment continues to rise.

Household consumption is also affected by tangible wealth such as housing. Annual house price inflation slowed recently from 4.8 per cent in the third quarter of 2017 to 3.0 per cent in May 2018, according to HM Land Registry, on the back of stamp duty increases, less generous tax allowance for buy-to-let properties and the squeeze in real incomes. This was the lowest annual growth since August 2013 when it was also 3.0 per cent and is in line with our earlier predictions of a cooling down of the housing market. The number of transactions on residential properties declined by 0.5 per cent in May compared to a year ago and the number of mortgage approvals decreased by 2.1 per cent over the same period according to the Bank of England. However the housing market is not cooling off in all UK regions: house prices in the East Midlands grew at an annual rate of 6.3 per cent in May compared with a decline of 0.4 per cent in London. According to Chadha (2018b), the dispersion of regional house prices growth can partly be explained by the productivity of workers in different regions. Analysis by Dhingra et al. (2017) on the local economic effects of Brexit suggests that the South of England and urban areas--in particular London--would be hardest hit by Brexit. The negative productivity shock from Brexit could therefore explain why the London housing market is cooling off more than in the rest of the country.

Considering short-run factors, the GFK Consumer confidence survey, which has been on a downward trend since the Brexit referendum, seems to have stabilised since the turn of the year. Unusually warm weather as well as morale-boosting events such as the royal wedding and World Cup may have supported a recovery in retail sales in the second quarter. Retail sales volume growth rebounded from -0.4 per cent in the first quarter to 2 per cent in the second. In reflection of that, retail sales surveys, such as the British Retail Consortium, have been strong since they dipped in spring, possibly mirroring the adverse weather conditions.

Government spending

As in the May Review, we have replaced our practice of adopting the OBR's forecast of government spending, and assume a higher path for government consumption relative to the OBR. As a result, government spending should add 0.2 points to real GDP growth this year and 0.3 the next.

Business investment

Business investment has also shown signs of moderation since the turn of the year, similar to the trend in the other major economies. Survey indicators paint a somewhat different picture, having shown a pick-up in investment intentions since the start of the year (figure 13). Looking ahead, a number of opposing factors, taken together, point to business investment growth of around 2-3 per cent in 2018. On the one hand, linked to the increase in exports and a substitution away from imports, investment should pick up to sustain the process of transition towards domestic production (Bank of England Inflation Report, May 2018). On the other hand, there is clear evidence from business surveys that Brexit-related uncertainty is weighing down on medium-term investment plans. In the most recent Decision Maker Panel survey, 37 per cent of panel members thought that Brexit was currently in the top three sources of uncertainty. That is slightly lower compared to one year earlier, yet overall it shows that the shadow of Brexit-related uncertainty on businesses persists (Agents' summary of business conditions, 2018 Q2).

Supply conditions

Migration

The latest ONS data show that net migration to the UK rose slightly to 282,000 in the year ending in the fourth quarter of 2017, however it remains around 50,000 lower per year than the level that prevailed prior to the 2016 referendum (figure 14). This can be largely attributed to a reduction in net migration from the EU (Rolfe, 2018), which reached its lowest level since 2013, with net migration from A8 countries in particular showing a sharp decline. This has more than offset the rise in net migration from outside the EU over the same period. Whilst some of this reduction can undoubtedly be attributed to uncertainty surrounding potential migrants' access to the labour market once the UK leaves the EU, stronger economic growth in the A8 countries relative to the UK reduces the incentives for migration. Additionally, the depreciation of sterling, which has fallen by around 19 per cent relative to the Euro since its peak in the third quarter of 2015, means that any savings or remittances from wages earned in the UK are worth less in a migrant's home currency and reduces the attractiveness of the UK as a destination compared to Germany for example. The effect of leaving the EU on net migration of EU nationals will depend largely on the outcome of negotiations between the EU and the UK regarding movement of labour. The assumption underlying our forecast is that the UK population evolves according to ONS principal projections, which are based on a gradual reduction in net migration in the near and medium term. Thus net migration falling more sharply following the UK's exit from the EU presents a downside risk to our forecast for output capacity. Hantzsche and Kara (2018) simulate the effects of a reduction in net migration of 100,000 per year compared to the ONS principal projection and find that this reduces the level of real GDP by around 1.7 per cent after ten years.

Employment

The unemployment rate remained at a 42-year low of 4.2 per cent in the three months to May, while the employment rate rose to a record high of 75.7 per cent. Despite this apparent labour market tightness, wage growth has remained weak (figure 15). Real average weekly earnings grew by 0.2 per cent including bonuses and 0.4 per cent excluding bonuses in the three months to May compared to the same period one year earlier. Bell and Blanchflower (2018) contend that part of the explanation for this sluggish wage growth, despite the very low unemployment rate, is that the underemployment rate, which rose during the Great Recession, has not yet returned to pre-recession levels. Thus by looking at the unemployment rate alone, we are underestimating the amount of slack in the labour market. They also conclude that the natural rate of unemployment has shifted down as workers' bargaining power has been reduced due to increased migration, the public sector pay freeze, and heightened fear in the wake of the Great Recession. We expect unemployment to remain low in the near term, averaging 4.2 per cent in 2018 and 2019, before stabilising at around 4% per cent in the medium term.

Productivity

A further explanation for the underperformance of real wages is the weak labour productivity growth since the recession. Kara et al. (2018) estimate a wage equation for the G7 economies and find that productivity is by far the most important contributor to low wage growth in the UK and the other G7 economies. Strong growth in output per hour in the second half of 2017 has continued into 2018, rising by 0.9 per cent in the first quarter compared to the same quarter in 2017. However much of this boost was due to a reduction in average hours worked, which is a volatile measure often subject to revisions. Output per worker, a more stable measure of labour productivity, declined slightly in the first quarter of 2018, compared to the same quarter in 2017. Both output per worker and output per hour declined by 0.4 per cent in the first quarter of 2018 compared to the previous quarter.

On the basis of our soft-Brexit assumption, we expect business investment to pick up modestly next year and for this to be sustained over the medium term. The resulting increase in the growth rate of capital stock should support labour productivity growth. We continue to expect modest growth in output per hour this year and a slight acceleration into the medium term.

Prices

Having climbed above 3 per cent in 2017, consumer price inflation has been unchanged at 2.4 per cent in each month between March and June 2018.

Developments

Recent developments in the value of sterling and oil prices suggest that there may be some upward pressure in the pipeline on CPI inflation that has not yet materialised. On a trade weighted basis, sterling depreciated by roughly 2 per cent between the ends of March and June. And the sterling price of Brent Crude has risen from an average price of 47 [pounds sterling] a barrel in March to 56 [pounds sterling] in June.

But there are reasons to be cautious about the effect of these specific changes on inflation. Empirical estimates of the degree of pass-through from exchange rate movements suggest that only large changes (in excess of 5 per cent) have significant effects on consumer prices (Lewis, 2016), as firms absorb the impact of small changes into their markups (Nakamura and Zerom, 2010). And while oil prices are higher, beneath the surface of the consumer price index are a number of goods and services experiencing disinflation. Our measure of trimmed mean inflation, which is the arithmetic mean of all price changes once 5 per cent of the highest and lowest price changes have been excluded, has fallen by 1.5 percentage points since October 2017 to 1.2 per cent in June (see box D).

It has been suggested that CPI inflation was temporarily depressed in June because stores were bringing forward their summer sales (Financial Times, 2018). There is little evidence of this. Figure 16 shows the fraction of prices that remain fixed each month, the fraction of prices that change due to sales and the fraction of prices that change due to other reasons. While sales have become more common over time, 5 per cent of the goods and services that make up the CPI were at sale prices in June, precisely the same as in each of the previous five Junes.

Expectations of future inflation remain broadly consistent with the inflation target. As there is an array of measures of inflation expectations (Kapetanios et al., 2016), we construct a new composite measure. Using various household surveys, firm surveys and financial market measures, we use principal component analysis to summarise this information at various horizons. This composite measure implies that expected inflation fell from 2.5 per cent to 2.3 per cent at the 1-year horizon and from 2.3 per cent to 2.2 per cent at the 5-10-year horizon between February and May, but remained flat at 2.3 per cent at the 2-3 year horizon.

Outlook

Our forecast incorporates both the short-run temporary impact of higher oil prices and the long-run disinflationary trend. We expect CPI inflation to fall from 2.3 per cent at the end of this year to around the Bank of England's target of 2 per cent thereafter. A hard Brexit is the biggest risk to our forecast. Another large depreciation could push inflation over and above our estimate (see Box A).

Sectoral balance

Table A9 shows the financial position of the private and public sectors of the economy and the resulting balance with the rest of the world. The private sector is further split into a household and a corporate sector. If investment is greater than saving for a sector, then this sector is a net borrower. The aggregation of these three sectors is the current account balance, which, if in deficit, implies that borrowing from the rest of the world is required in order to fund domestic investment plans.
Box D. The price of everything

The consumer price index is a fundamental economic statistic for
households, firms and policymakers. This number summarises the
prices of hundreds of thousands of goods and services across the
country. Yet the behaviour of individual prices is erratic, some
rise and fall by an order of magnitude from one month to the next,
others rarely change. These idiosyncrasies are central to
understanding aggregate price dynamics (Gagnon, 2009; Nakamura et
al., forthcoming).

What is the rate of inflation when the most volatile prices are
excluded? This box answers this question by constructing a measure
of trimmed mean inflation, which excludes a fraction of the highest
and lowest price changes each month, calculating the arithmetic
mean across the remaining observations. (1) We find that current
trimmed mean inflation is a powerful predictor of future consumer
price index inflation. Although trimmed mean inflation has fallen
in recent months, it remains in line with the Bank of England's
target.

We begin by collecting micro data on the prices of the individual
items that underlie the all items consumer price index (CPI) for
the United Kingdom. This data set contains the prices of up to
135,000 goods and services each month, which adds up to
approximately 30 million price quotes since the 1990s. (2) This
data will also allow us to monitor the variance, skewness, kurtosis
and frequency of price changes at a regional and national
resolution.

In order to calculate the trimmed mean, the first step is to
calculate month-on-month inflation rates for items i = 1,2 ..., N
at time t: [DELTA][p.sub.i,t] = [[p.sub.i,t]/[p.sub.i,t-1]] - 1. The
second step is to calculate the j = 0,1, ..., 50 per cent trimmed
mean for each month, [[PI].sup.m.sub.j,t]. The final step is to
calculate the jth per cent annualised trimmed mean for each month:
[[product].sup.y.sub.j,t] = ((I + [[product].sup.m.sub.j,t]) x (1 +
[[product].sup.m.sub.j,t-1]) x ... x (1 +
[[product].sup.y.sub.j,t-11]) - 1).

It is possible to discard anything from 0 per cent of the most
extreme price changes, which is simply the mean of the full
distribution, to 50 per cent, which is equivalent to the median. (3)
In order to select the optimal trimming percentage, we run a simple
horserace, where we assess how well the jth per cent trimmed mean
forecasts future CPI inflation. In this race, we also include CPI
inflation and CPI excluding energy, food, alcoholic beverages and
tobacco inflation (CPI-ex) as benchmarks. Specifically, we
calculate the root mean square error (RMSE) from the following
equation:

[[pi].sub.t+12] = [alpha] + [beta][x.sub.t] + [e.sub.t] (1)

which regresses year ahead CPI inflation, [[pi].sub.t+12], on a
constant, [alpha], and a measure of inflation (either the jth
trimmed mean, CPI or CPI-ex), [x.sub.t].

The results are shown in figure Dl. The results indicate that the 5
per cent trimmed mean is optimal. In addition, the 5 per cent
trimmed mean yields better forecasts of future inflation than the
CPI and CPI-ex not only at the 12-month horizon but also at the
24-and 36-month horizons.

Figure D2 plots the 5 per cent trimmed mean, CPI and CPI-ex
inflation rates. The three measures are highly correlated, with a
correlation coefficient of 0.90 between trimmed mean and CPI
inflation and 0.74 between trimmed mean and CPI-ex inflation. The
level of CPI-trim inflation is lower on average but more volatile
than CPI inflation. These differences are due to how the largest
price changes are treated and to how the prices are weighted, as
trimmed mean inflation is an unweighted average of a truncated
distribution, while CPI inflation is a weighted average of the full
distribution.

An important result is how trimmed mean inflation has recently
fallen. After the depreciation of sterling in 2016, both trimmed
mean inflation and CPI inflation rose sharply following a spell of
disinflation. Since October 2017, however, trimmed mean inflation
has fallen by 1.5 percentage points, suggesting that the
pass-through effects are fading. Based on the latest outturn of
trimmed mean inflation, equation (I) suggests that CPI inflation
will be 2.2 per cent in a year's time.

NOTES

(1) See Dolmas (2005) and Bryan and Cecchetti (1994) for overviews
of trimmed mean inflation measures. Trimmed mean inflation is based
on the arithmetic mean, while the CPI typically uses the geometric
mean.

(2) Quotes are linked by the item ID, shop code, shop type and
region to form a panel. Items that could not be uniquely linked
between months were excluded, as were items where the price is
zero.

(3) Asymmetric trimmed means can also be calculated, where a
different percentage is trimmed from each tail. While we only focus
on integers, there are still 2450 possible combinations. For
computational reasons, we focus on the 50 possible integers for
symmetric trimmed means.

REFERENCES

Bryan, M.F. and Cecchetti, S.G. (1994), 'Measuring core inflation',
in Mankiw, N.G. (ed.), Monetary Policy, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.

Dolmas, J. (2005), Trimmed mean PCE inflation', Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas Research Department Working Paper, No. 0506.

Gagnon, E. (2009), 'Price setting during low and high inflation:
evidence from Mexico', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 3, pp.
1221-63.

Nakamura, E., Steinsson, J., Sun, P. and Villar, D. (forthcoming),
'The elusive costs of inflation: price dispersion during the U.S.
great inflation', Quarterly Journal of Economics.

This box was prepared by Jason Lennard.


It is not possible to infer the optimality of the levels of capital from the current account but rather just the immediate financing needs of the economy. In 2017, all three domestic sectors of the economy--households, companies and government--were in deficit for the first time since at least 1987 (figure 18), and we forecast this pattern to carry on into the medium term.

Household

The ONS has revised lower its estimate of wages and salaries and as a result, the household saving estimate for 2017 was revised downwards. According to the latest vintage of data, household saving was just 3 per cent of GDP in 2017, which is the lowest on record.

In the first quarter of 2018, household saving as a fraction of GDP remained at about the same level as in 2017. We expect households to continue to favour consuming over saving in 2018 and 2019. Over the medium term however, we see saving as a proportion of GDP rise as real personal disposable income recovers. An important driver of the increase in saving will be the ongoing auto-enrolment into workplace pensions.

Household investment rose steadily from a trough of 3.2 per cent of GDP in 2009 to 4.3 per cent of GDP in 2017, which is similar to the pre-crisis high of 4.5 per cent in 2006-7. With demand for housing still growing strongly, we project household investment to increase in each subsequent year and to reach 5 per cent of GDP in 2022. The saving and investment positions of the household sector imply that in 2017 households required 1.3 per cent of GDP in funding from the rest of the economy. This represents the first time since at least 1987 that the household sector was a net borrower. With both household saving and investment growing slowly, we expect households to return to a near-balanced net position in the medium term.
Box E. The Brexit assumptions underpinning our forecasts

In this box we outline the Brexit-related assumptions embedded in
our central forecast. The UK government published its preferred
blueprint for a future relationship between the UK and EU in a
White Paper on 12 July. We discuss the White Paper proposals in Box
B. Suffice to say that the White Paper has done little to lift the
fog of uncertainty about the future relationship and as a result
our central forecast continues to assume a soft Brexit. We define
'soft' Brexit as: the UK and the EU maintain a very high level of
access to each other's market for both goods and services, fully
functioning financial markets, free movement of labour, a budgetary
contribution that is broadly unchanged and a 21-month transition
period after the UK exits the EU in March 2019 during which the
country remains bound by regulations of the single market and
customs union. Our central forecast continues to assume a soft
Brexit.

The specific assumptions in our central forecast are as follows:

* UK trade: As before, we assume the UK maintains a close but not
frictionless trading relationship with the EU. This also reflects
the Prime Minister's expectation that "people need to face up to
some hard facts" and "life is going to be different". That less
comprehensive relationship is reflected by negative residuals to
the export volume equation.

* Productivity: The smaller degree of competition due to lower
trade volumes, less investment and a potential reduction in skilled
migration could drive productivity lower in the long run. Effects
on labour productivity are likely to materialise only with a long
lag and may be ambiguous in the short run if employment reduces as
a result of Brexit We have not explicitly introduced a
Brexit-related productivity shock into our forecast, which
therefore constitutes a key downside risk to our forecast.

* Fiscal contributions: Regarding the UK's financial contributions
to the EU budget, a payments schedule is yet to be decided. The
British government has already announced that it would seek
associate membership in EU agencies, which would require financial
contributions to be made, in addition to payments towards the
'divorce bill'. We have assumed that the UK continues to make
contributions beyond 2020 as if it were a member of the EU.

The risk of a more pessimistic scenario remains high. In our
February 2018 Review we reported estimates for a case in which
negotiations fail and the UK moves to a WTO-style trading
relationship on exit. (1) Our results show that this would cause a
mild recession within one year and real GDP per head would be some
2,000 [pounds sterling] lower relative to our 'soft' Brexit case
after a decade. In the May 2018 Review, Erken et at. (2018)
provided a more pessimistic view: their headline result for a
'hard' Brexit is that cumulative GDP growth could be 18 percentage
points lower by 2030 compared to a scenario in which the UK remains
in the EU. (2) In this Review (Box B) we provide an analysis of a
scenario that is broadly in line with the proposals outlined in the
July White Paper.

NOTES

(1) See also Hantzsche, A. and Kara, A. (2018), 'Deal, or no deal?
The 2,000 [pounds sterling] question', NIESR blog, 16 February
2018.

(2) Erken, H., Hayat, R., Prins, C., Heijmerikx, M. and de Vreede
I. (2018), 'Measuring the permanent costs of Brexit', National
Institute Economic Review, 244, pp. 46-55.

This box was prepared by Arno Hantzsche and Amit Kara.


Corporate

On the corporate side, saving rebounded strongly in 2017, rising to 9Vi per cent of GDP from 7Vi per cent in 2016. This was driven by an increase in corporate profits both in manufacturing and in the oil and natural gas exploration and extraction sector. We forecast corporate saving to GDP to remain close to 9 per cent in the medium term as the headwinds from Brexit are balanced by stronger international growth. The corporate investment ratio was steady at around 10Vi per cent of GDP in 2017. Conditional on a soft Brexit assumption, we forecast corporate investment to remain at about 10 per cent of GDP in the medium term, and therefore the corporate sector still to require about 1 Vi to 2 per cent of GDP of net financing from the rest of the economy over the same time horizon.

Government

Government sector dis-saving, which reached a peak in 2009 of around 5Vi per cent of GDP, has vanished in 2016 as a result of the ongoing fiscal consolidation. We now expect saving to be steady at 1-1V2 per cent of GDP from 2018 to 2022. This represents a deviation from the OBR forecast and reflects our belief that the government will slow the pace of fiscal consolidation from 2019 onwards. Government investment stayed stable in 2017 at 2 Vi per cent of GDP and we have maintained our estimate of 2Vi per cent of GDP over the forecast horizon. As a result of reduced saving and constant investment, we now expect the government to remain in a net borrowing position of 1-1 1/2 per cent of GDP until 2022, after having borrowed 1.4 per cent in 2017.

External

To finance the triple deficit of the household, corporate and government sectors, the domestic economy had to borrow 3.9 per cent of GDP in 2017 from the rest of the world, the lowest ratio since 2012. The current account balance is forecast to stabilise at around 3 1/2 per cent of GDP in 2022.

NOTES

(1) 'The future relationship between the United Kingdom and the European Union' available at: https://assets.publishing.service. gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/ file/725288/The_future_relationship_between_the_United_ Kingdom_and_the_European_Union.pdf

(2) 'Brexit Preparations and Negotiations Debate on 23 July 2018' House of Lords Library Briefings available at: http:// researchbriefings.files.parliament.uk/documents/LLN-20180085/LLN-2018-0085.pdf

(3) Government statement following Cabinet away day at Chequers https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/government-statement-following-cabinet-away-day-at-chequers

(4) The future relationship between the United Kingdom and the European Union https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/ the-future-relationship-between-the-united-kingdom-and-the-european-union

(5) Preparing for the withdrawal of the United Kingdom from the European Union on 30 March 2019, https://ec.europa.eu/info/ publications/preparing-withdrawal-united-kingdom-europeanunion-30-march-2019_en.

REFERENCES

Bank of England (2018), 'Monetary policy summary and minutes of the Monetary Policy Committee meeting ending on 20 June 2018'.

Barrell, R., Dury, K.and Hurst, I. (2003), 'International monetary policy coordination: an evaluation of cooperative strategies using a large econometric model', Economic Modelling, 20(3), pp. 507-27.

Bell, D.N.F. and Blanchflower, D.G. (2018), 'The lack of wage growth and the falling NAIRU', National Institute Economic Review, 245, p. 40-55.

Carney, M. (2018), 'From Protectionism to Prosperity', speech given at the Northern Powerhouse Business Summit--Great Exhibition of the North, July.

Carreras, O., Ebell, M., Kirby, S., Meaning, J., Piggott, R. and Warren, J. (2018), The long and the short of it: what price UK exit from the EU?', NIESR Blog, 12 May 2016.

Chadha, J.S. (2018a),'Friday Flyer: Fiscal space--this time is different', NIESR Blog, 5 June.

--(2018b), 'Commentary: The housing market and the macroeconomy', National Institute Economic Review, 243, F4-9.

Cunliffe, J. (2018), 'A little bit of stodginess?', speech given at the Cumbria Chamber of Commerce, Kendal, July.

Dhingra, S., Machin, S. and Overman, H. (2017), 'Local economic effects of Brexit', National Institute Economic Review, 242, pp. R24-36.

Dolton, P., Hantzsche, A. and Kara, A. (2018), 'Follow the leader? The interaction between public and private sector wage growth in the UK', NIESR mimeo (presented at Royal Economic Society Annual Conference, March 2018).

Ebell, M. (2016),'Assessing the impact of trade agreements on trade', National Institute Economic Review, 238, R31-42.

Erken, H., Hayat, R., Prins, C., Heijmerikx, M. and deVreede, I. (2018), 'Measuring the permanent costs of Brexit', National Institute Economic Review, 244, pp. R46-55.

Hantzsche, A. (2017), 'Box B: Lifting the cap? The importance of interactions between public and private sector wage growth in the UK', National Institute Economic Review, 242, pp. F18.

Hantzsche, A. and Kara, A. (2018), 'Deal, or no deal? The 2,000 [pounds sterling] question', NIESR blog, 16 February.

Hantzsche, A. and Young, G. (2018),'Commentary: Light at the end of the fiscal tunnel?', National Institute Economic Review, 244, F4-10.

HM Treasury (2016), 'HM Treasury Analysis: the long-term economic impact of EU membership and the alternatives', CM9250.

Hix, S. (2018), 'Two years after the vote there is little certainty where the UK-EU relationship is heading', LSE Blog, 16 July.

Hofmann, C., Osnago, A. and Ruta, M. (2017), 'Horizontal depth: a new database on the content of preferential trade agreements', Policy Research working paper, WPS 7981, Washington, D.C.: World Bank Group.

Kapetanios, G., Maule, B. and Young, G. (2016), 'A new summary measure of inflation expectations', Economics Letters, 149(C), pp. 83-5.

Kara, A., Lopresto, M. and Piggott, R. (2018), 'Box B: Decomposing wages: the productivity gap persists', National Institute Economic Review, 244, pp. F14.

Lenoel, C. (2018), 'Predicting recessions in the United States with the yield curve', National Institute Economic Review, 244, pp. F42.

Lewis, J. (2016), 'What can Big Data tell us about the pass through of big exchange rate changes?', Bank of England Staff Working Paper No. 579.

McCarthy, M. (1972), 'Some notes on the generation of pseudo-structural errors for use in stochastic simulation studies', in Hickman, B.G. (ed.), Econometric Models of Cyclical Behaviour, New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 185-91.

Nakamura, E. and Zerom, D. (2010), 'Accounting for incomplete pass-through', Review of Economic Studies, 77(3), pp. 1192-230.

Piggott, R. (2016), 'Post referendum developments in uncertainty measures: an update', National Institute Economic Review, 238, pp. F78-80.

Riley, R. and Rosazza Bondibene, C. (2017), 'Raising the standard: minimum wages and firm productivity', Labour Economics, 44, pp. 27-50.

Rolfe, H. (2018), 'Government's message over free movement is deterring migrants in key sectors', NIESR Blog, 16 June.

Appendix--Forecast details
Table A1. Exchange rates and interest rates

                            UK exchange rates
                                                     FTSE
                     Effective    Dollar   Euro    All-share
                     2011 = 100                      index

2012                   104.1       1.6      1.2     2617.7
2013                   102.6       1.6      1.2     3006.2
2014                   110.2       1.7      1.2     3136.6
2015                   116.3       1.5      1.4     3150.1
2016                   104.8       1.4      1.2     3102.0
2017                    99.3       1.3      1.1     3542.4
2018                   101.7       1.4      1.1     3640.6
2019                   101.3       1.3      1.1     3661.5
2020                   101.5       1.4      1.1     3678.5
2021                   101.6       1.4      1.1     3749.4
2022                   101.7       1.4      1.1     3852.9

2017 Q1                 98.9       1.2      1.2     3467.5
2017 Q2                100.0       1.3      1.2     3549.2
2017 Q3                 98.3       1.3      1.1     3548.3
2017 Q4                100.1       1.3      1.1     3604.5

2018 Q1                102.1       1.4      1.1     3552.5
2018 Q2                102.2       1.4      1.1     3643.8
2018 Q3                101.2       1.3      1.1     3673.0
2018 Q4                101.2       1.3      1.1     3693.3

2019 Q1                101.2       1.3      1.1     3683.5
2019 Q2                101.2       1.3      1.1     3666.4
2019 Q3                101.3       1.3      1.1     3647.2
2019 Q4                101.3       1.3      1.1     3649.1

Percentage changes
2012/2011               4.2        -1.1     7.0       1.2
2013/2012               -1.5       -1.3    -4.5      14.8
2014/2013               7.4        5.3      5.4       4.3
2015/2014               5.6        -7.2    11.1       0.4
2016/2015               -9.9      -11.4    -11.2     -1.5
2017/2016               -5.2       -4.9    -6.7      14.2
2018/2017               2.4        4.6     -0.7       2.8
2019/2018               -0.4       -1.5    -0.6       0.6
2020/2019               0.2        1.6     -1.0       0.5
2021/2020               0.2        1.6     -1.0       1.9
2022/2021               0.1        1.4     -1.0       2.8

2017Q4/2016Q4           2.0        6.9     -2.1       9.2
2018Q4/2017Q4           1.1        -0.5     0.3       2.5
2019Q4/2018Q4           0.2        1.2     -0.8      -1.2

                                 Interest rates

                     3-month   10-year   World (a)     Bank
                      rates     gilts                Rate (b)

2012                   0.8       1.8        1.2        0.5
2013                   0.5       2.4        0.9        0.5
2014                   0.5       2.5        0.9        0.5
2015                   0.6       1.8        0.9        0.5
2016                   0.5       1.3        0.9        0.3
2017                   0.4       1.2        1.2        0.4
2018                   0.7       1.4        1.8        0.8
2019                   1.3       2.0        2.2        1.3
2020                   1.7       2.6        2.5        1.7
2021                   2.1       3.1        2.6        2.1
2022                   2.5       3.5        2.8        2.5

2017 Q1                0.4       1.3        1.0        0.3
2017 Q2                0.3       1.0        1.1        0.3
2017 Q3                0.3       1.2        1.2        0.3
2017 Q4                0.5       1.3        1.3        0.4

2018 Q1                0.6       1.5        1.4        0.5
2018 Q2                0.7       1.4        1.6        0.5
2018 Q3                0.7       1.3        2.0        0.7
2018 Q4                0.9       1.5        2.1        0.8

2019 Q1                1.1       1.8        2.1        0.9
2019 Q2                1.2       2.0        2.2        1.0
2019 Q3                1.3       2.1        2.2        1.2
2019 Q4                1.4       2.3        2.4        1.3

Percentage changes
2012/2011
2013/2012
2014/2013
2015/2014
2016/2015
2017/2016
2018/2017
2019/2018
2020/2019
2021/2020
2022/2021

2017Q4/2016Q4
2018Q4/2017Q4
2019Q4/2018Q4

Notes: We assume that bilateral exchange rates
for the second quarter of this year are the average
of information available to 12 July 2018. We then assume
that bilateral rates remain constant for the following two
quarters before moving in line with the path implied by the
backward-looking uncovered interest rate parity condition
based on interest rate differentials relative to the US.
(a) Weighted average of central bank intervention rates
in OECD economies, (b) End of period.

Table A2. Price indices

2016=100

                       Unit    Imports    Exports      World
                      labour   deflator   deflator   oil price
                      costs                           ($) (a)

2012                   96.2     104.8       99.0       112.5
2013                   98.0     105.6      101.2       109.1
2014                   97.3     101.8       98.7        99.6
2015                   98.1      95.4       94.2        52.8
2016                  100.0     100.0      100.0        43.4
2017                  102.4     105.9      106.4        53.5
2018                  105.0     109.0      106.1        72.1
2019                  106.8     11l.1      105.9        74.7
2020                  108.7     112.8      106.1        75.6
2021                  110.6     115.0      107.0        77.1
2022                  112.8     117.6      108.3        78.7

Annual Growth Rates
2012/2011               1.0      -0.9       -0.9         1.8
2013/2012               1.9       0.7        2.2        -3.0
2014/2013              -0.7      -3.6       -2.4        -8.7
2015/2014               0.8      -6.3       -4.6       -47.0
2016/2015               1.9       4.8        6.1       -17.7
2017/2016               2.4       5.9        6.4        23.3
2018/2017               2.5       2.9       -0.3        34.7
2019/2018               1.8       1.9       -0.2         3.5
2020/2019               1.8       1.5        0.2         1.3
2021/2020               1.8       2.0        0.8         2.0
2022/2021               1.9       2.2        1.2         2.0

                                   GDP
                      Consump-   deflator   Retail   Consumer
                        tion     (market    price     prices
                      deflator   prices)    index     index

2012                    94.0       94.2      92.3      95.5
2013                    96.2       95.9      95.1      97.9
2014                    98.1       97.6      97.3      99.3
2015                    98.6       98.0      98.3      99.4
2016                   100.0      100.0     100.0     100.0
2017                   102.1      101.9     103.6     102.7
2018                   104.6      103.5     107.1     105.0
2019                   106.6      105.3     111.2     107.0
2020                   108.7      107.4     115.1     109.1
2021                   110.9      109.5     119.2     111.3
2022                   113.1      111.6     123.3     113.5

Annual Growth Rates
2012/2011                2.1        1.6       3.2       2.9
2013/2012                2.3        1.9       3.0       2.6
2014/2013                1.9        1.7       2.4       1.4
2015/2014                0.5        0.4       1.0       0.1
2016/2015                1.4        2.1       1.7       0.7
2017/2016                2.1        1.9       3.6       2.7
2018/2017                2.5        1.6       3.4       2.3
2019/2018                1.9        1.7       3.8       1.9
2020/2019                2.0        2.0       3.5       2.0
2021/2020                2.0        2.0       3.6       2.0
2022/2021                2.0        2.0       3.4       2.0

Notes: (a) Per barrel, average of Dubai and Brent spot prices.

Table A3. Gross domestic product and components of expenditure

billion [pounds sterling], 2016 prices

               Final consumption         Gross capital
                  expenditure              formation

            Households    General     Gross       Changes in
            & NPISH (a)    govt.    fixed in-   inventories (b)
                                    vestment

2012          1176.0       353.0      282.8          -0.3
2013          1197.7       352.4      292.4           7.9
2014          1222.1       360.1      313.5          14.4
2015          1253.4       365.2      324.0          10.8
2016          1292.6       368.0      331.4           8.4
2017          1316.0       367.5      342.8          -0.3
2018          1333.0       372.0      345.0          -2.2
2019          1354.4       377.5      354.2          -2.2
2020          1370.5       386.1      366.1          -2.2
2021          1387.2       396.6      374.8          -2.2
2022          1404.8       407.9      381.4          -2.2

Percentage changes
2012/2011        1.5         1.2        2.1
2013/2012        1.8        -0.2        3.4
2014/2013        2.0         2.2        7.2
2015/2014        2.6         1.4        3.4
2016/2015        3.1         0.8        2.3
2017/2016        1.8        -0.1        3.4
2018/2017        1.3         1.2        0.6
2019/2018        1.6         1.5        2.6
2020/2019        1.2         2.3        3.4
2021/2020        1.2         2.7        2.4
2022/2021        1.3         2.9        1.8

Decomposition of growth in GDP
2012             1.0         0.2        0.3           0.2
2013             1.2         0.0        0.5           0.5
2014             1.3         0.4        1.1           0.4
2015             1.7         0.3        0.6          -0.2
2016             2.0         0.1        0.4          -0.1
2017             1.2         0.0        0.6          -0.4
2018             0.8         0.2        0.1          -0.1
2019             1.1         0.3        0.4           0.0
2020             0.8         0.4        0.6           0.0
2021             0.8         0.5        0.4           0.0
2022             0.8         0.5        0.3           0.0

            Domestic    Total      Total
             demand    exports    final
                         (c)      expenditure

2012         1793.7     508.3      2302.1
2013         1839.4     516.0      2355.3
2014         1902.0     527.8      2429.5
2015         1953.2     551.2      2504.2
2016         2000.4     557.0      2557.4
2017         2026.0     586.9      2613.0
2018         2047.8     600.4      2648.1
2019         2083.8     617.8      2701.6
2020         2120.5     638.1      2758.6
2021         2156.3     658.2      2814.6
2022         2191.9     677.6      2869.5

Percentage changes
2012/2011       1.9       1.4         1.8
2013/2012       2.5       1.5         2.3
2014/2013       3.4       2.3         3.1
2015/2014       2.7       4.4         3.1
2016/2015       2.4       1.0         2.1
2017/2016       1.3       5.4         2.2
2018/2017       1.1       2.3         1.3
2019/2018       1.8       2.9         2.0
2020/2019       1.8       3.3         2.1
2021/2020       1.7       3.1         2.0
2022/2021       1.6       2.9         2.0

Decomposition of growth in GDP
2012           1.9        0.4         2.3
2013           2.5        0.4         3.0
2014           3.4        0.9         4.0
2015           2.7        1.1         3.9
2016           2.4        0.4         2.8
2017           1.3        1.4         2.8
2018           1.1        0.7         1.8
2019           1.8        0.9         2.6
2020           1.8        1.0         2.8
2021           1.7        1.0         2.7
2022           1.7        0.9         2.6

               Total       Net     GDP
            imports (c)   trade     at
                                  market
                                  prices
                                   (d)

2012           503.9        4.5   1799.5
2013           519.8       -3.7   1836.4
2014           539.5      -11.7   1890.5
2015           569.1      -17.9   1934.9
2016           587.8      -30.9   1969.5
2017           606.9      -20.0   2002.1
2018           612.9      -12.6   2030.1
2019           631.0      -13.2   2065.5
2020           652.2      -14.1   2101.3
2021           672.0      -13.8   2137.4
2022           689.2      -11.6   2/75.2

Percentage changes
2012/2011       3.0                  1.4
2013/2012       3.2                  2.0
2014/2013       3.8                  2.9
2015/2014       5.5                  2.3
2016/2015       3.3                  1.8
2017/2016       3.2                  1.7
2018/2017       1.0                  1.4
2019/2018       2.9                  1.7
2020/2019       3.4                  1.7
2021/2020       3.0                  1.7
2022/2021       2.5                  1.8

Decomposition of growth in GDP
2012           -0.8        -0.4      1.4
2013           -0.8        -0.5      2.0
2014           -1.3        -0.4      2.9
2015           -1.5        -0.3      2.3
2016           -1.1        -0.7      1.8
2017           -0.8         0.6      1.7
2018           -0.3         0.4      1.4
2019           -0.9         0.0      1.7
2020           -1.0         0.0      1.7
2021           -0.9         0.0      1.7
2022           -0.8         0.1      1.8

Notes: (a) Non-profit institutions serving households,
(b) Including acquisitions less disposals of valuables
and quarterly alignment adjustment (c) Includes Missing
Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (d) Components may not add
up to total GDP growth due to rounding and the statistical
discrepancy included in GDP.

Table A4. External sector

            Exports of   Imports of      Net
            goods (a)    goods (a)    trade in
                                      goods (a)

                 billion [pounds sterling],
                       2016 prices (b)

2012          279.3        373.2        -93.9
2013          277.0        384.6       -107.6
2014          284.1        398.3       -114.3
2015          303.0        415.9       -112.9
2016          299.1        431.7       -132.7
2017          319.2        449.3       -130.2
2018          331.9        452.6       -120.7
2019          346.4        470.4       -124.1
2020          360.3        489.5       -129.2
2021          373.1        506.7       -133.6
2022          384.8        521.0       -136.2

Percentage changes
2012/2011      -0.7          2.5
2013/2012      -0.8          3.0
2014/2013       2.6          3.6
2015/2014       6.7          4.4
2016/2015      -1.3          3.8
2017/2016       6.7          4.1
2018/2017       4.0          0.7
2019/2018       4.4          3.9
2020/2019       4.0          4.1
2021/2020       3.5          3.5
2022/2021       3.1          2.8

            Exports    Imports      Net
               of         of      trade in
            services   services   services

              billion [pounds sterling],
                   2016 prices (b)

2012         228.4      130.2       98.2
2013         239.8      134.8      104.9
2014         244.3      140.9      103.5
2015         248.2      153.3       94.8
2016         257.9      156.1      101.8
2017         267.8      157.6      110.2
2018         268.4      160.3      108.1
2019         271.4      160.5      110.8
2020         277.8      162.7      115.1
2021         285.2      165.4      119.8
2022         292.9      168.2      124.7

Percentage changes
2012/2011      4.6        4.3
2013/2012      4.9        3.5
2014/2013      1.9        4.5
2015/2014      1.6        8.9
2016/2015      3.9        1.8
2017/2016      3.8        0.9
2018/2017      0.3        1.8
2019/2018      1.1        0.1
2020/2019      2.4        1.4
2021/2020      2.7        1.6
2022/2021      2.7        1.7

              Export        World     Terms of    Current
               price      trade (d)   trade (d)   balance
            competitive
             ness (c)

                          2016=100                % of GDP

2012           98.8          85.2        94.5        -3.8
2013           99.0          87.7        95.9        -5.1
2014          102.7          91.6        97.0        -4.9
2015          103.0          96.7        98.8        -4.9
2016          100.0         100.0       100.0        -5.2
2017           97.3         103.3       100.5        -3.9
2018           95.8         106.4        97.4        -3.3
2019           92.6         111.1        95.4        -3.5
2020           90.4         116.6        94.1        -3.8
2021           88.6         121.1        93.0        -3.6
2022           87.4         125.2        92.1        -3.4

Percentage changes
2012/2011       0.6           1.3         0.0
2013/2012       0.2           2.9         1.5
2014/2013       3.8           4.5         1.2
2015/2014       0.3           5.6         1.8
2016/2015      -2.9           3.4         1.2
2017/2016      -2.7           3.3         0.5
2018/2017      -1.6           3.0        -3.1
2019/2018      -3.3           4.4        -2.0
2020/2019      -2.4           5.0        -1.3
2021/2020      -1.9           3.8        -1.2
2022/2021      -1.4           3.4        -1.0

Notes: (a) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud,
(b) Balance of payments basis, (c) A rise denotes a loss in
UK competitiveness, (d) Weighted by import shares in UK export
markets, (e) Ratio of average value of exports to imports.

Table A5. Household sector

             Average (a)    Compen-     Total       Gross
              earnings     sation of   personal   disposable
                           employees    income      income

              2016=100        billion [pounds sterling],
                                    current prices

2012             93.3        847.2      1480.9      1163.5
2013             95.9        880.7      1532.7      1206.0
2014             96.3        900.0      1577.7      1242.8
2015             97.3        928.5      1665.4      1314.0
2016            100.0        963.4      1701.4      1332.5
2017            102.9       1002.9      1741.8      1352.5
2018            105.5       1042.4      1805.6      1398.3
2019            108.9       1079.3      1868.5      1445.8
2020            112.5       1117.3      1940.8      1500.4
2021            116.2       1156.8      2019.4      1559.5
2022            120.0       1200.0      2103.0      1623.0

Percentage changes
2012/2011         2.1          2.5         3.9         5.0
2013/2012         2.7          3.9         3.5         3.7
2014/2013         0.4          2.2         2.9         3.0
2015/2014         1.0          3.2         5.6         5.7
2016/2015         2.8          3.8         2.2         1.4
2017/2016         2.9          4.1         2.4         1.5
2018/2017         2.6          3.9         3.7         3.4
2019/2018         3.1          3.5         3.5         3.4
2020/2019         3.3          3.5         3.9         3.8
2021/2020         3.3          3.5         4.0         3.9
2022/2021         3.3          3.7         4.1         4.1

                Real         Final       Saving
             disposable   consumption   ratio (c)
             income (b)   expenditure

                 billion [pounds        per cent
             sterling], 2016 prices

2012           1237.2       1176.0         87.6
2013           1253.5       1197.7         89.9
2014           1267.1       1222.1         97.1
2015           1333.1       1253.4        102.9
2016           1332.6       1292.6        110.1
2017           1324.7       1316.0        115.1
2018           1336.2       1333.0        119.6
2019           1356.3       1354.4        123.0
2020           1380.3       1370.5        124.4
2021           1406.4       1387.2        125.0
2022           1434.6       1404.8        125.1

Percentage changes
2012/2011         2.8          1.5
2013/2012         1.3          1.8
2014/2013         1.1          2.0
2015/2014         5.2          2.6
2016/2015         0.0          3.1
2017/2016        -0.6          1.8
2018/2017         0.9          1.3
2019/2018         1.5          1.6
2020/2019         1.8          1.2
2021/2020         1.9          1.2
2022/2021         2.0          1.3

               House         Net
             prices (d)   worth to
                           income
                          ratio (e)

2012             6.2         6.3
2013             6.3         6.2
2014             6.5         6.7
2015             6.8         6.8
2016             7.2         7.4
2017             7.4         7.5
2018             7.5         7.5
2019             7.5         7.4
2020             7.3         7.3
2021             7.2         7.2
2022             7.1         7.0

Percentage changes
2012/2011        0.7
2013/2012        1.1
2014/2013        4.0
2015/2014        3.7
2016/2015        7.0
2017/2016        2.7
2018/2017        0.7
2019/2018       -0.2
2020/2019       -1.7
2021/2020       -1.7
2022/2021       -1.8

Notes: (a) Average earnings equals total labour compensation
divided by the number of employees, (b) Deflated by consumers'
expenditure deflator, (c) Includes adjustment for change in net
equity of households in pension funds, (d) Office for National
Statistics, mix-adjusted, (e) Net worth is defined as
housing wealth plus net financial assets.

Table A6. Fixed investment and capital

billion [pounds sterling], 2016 prices

                          Gross fixed investment

             Business      Private      General     Total
            investment   housing (a)   government

2012          166.9          58.1         57.9      282.8
2013          171.7          65.2         55.7      292.4
2014          180.6          71.7         61.1      313.5
2015          187.4          76.0         60.6      324.0
2016          187.0          83.2         61.2      331.4
2017          190.1          90.5         62.3      342.8
2018          192.1          95.5         57.5      345.0
2019          196.3          98.6         59.3      354.2
2020          200.9         102.2         63.0      366.1
2021          205.3         105.9         63.6      374.8
2022          207.5         109.8         64.2      381.4

Percentage changes
2012/2011       7.2          -1.5         -7.7        2.1
2013/2012       2.9          12.2         -3.8        3.4
2014/2013       5.2          10.0          9.7        7.2
2015/2014       3.7           6.0         -0.8        3.4
2016/2015      -0.2           9.4          1.0        2.3
2017/2016       1.6           8.8          1.7        3.4
2018/2017       1.1           5.5         -7.7        0.6
2019/2018       2.2           3.3          3.2        2.6
2020/2019       2.4           3.6          6.2        3.4
2021/2020       2.2           3.7          1.0        2.4
2022/2021       1.1           3.6          0.8        1.8

               User       Corporate      Capital stock
               cost        profit
                of        share of    Private   Public (b)
            capital (%)    GDP (%)

2012           13.0         24.6      3267.3      1020.8
2013           11.9         24.6      3217.2      1027.6
2014           11.9         25.6      3256.7      1070.8
2015           10.7         24.9      3292.5      1086.1
2016           10.5         25.0      3346.1      1098.7
2017           11.1         24.8      3407.8      1128.7
2018           11.2         24.4      3472.3      1158.4
2019           11.6         24.8      3539.8      1188.6
2020           11.8         25.4      3611.0      1221.7
2021           12.0         25.8      3685.6      1256.5
2022           12.2         26.0      3761.3      1292.7

Percentage changes
2012/2011      -2.9         -1.4         0.7         0.4
2013/2012      -8.1          0.0        -1.5         0.7
2014/2013      -0.2          3.8         1.2         4.2
2015/2014      -9.7         -2.8         1.1         1.4
2016/2015      -2.1          0.6         1.6         1.2
2017/2016       5.5         -0.7         1.8         2.7
2018/2017       1.3         -1.9         1.9         2.6
2019/2018       3.4          1.9         1.9         2.6
2020/2019       1.2          2.1         2.0         2.8
2021/2020       2.2          1.6         2.1         2.8
2022/2021       1.4          1.2         2.1         2.9

Notes: (a) Includes private sector transfer costs of non-produced
assets, (b) Including public sector non-financial corporations.

Table A7. Productivity and the labour market

                   Employment
                                         ILO
             Employees    Total (a)   unemploy-    Labour
                                        ment      force (b)

2012           25213        29697       2572        32269
2013           25515        30045       2474        32519
2014           25962        30755       2026        32781
2015           26505        31284       1781        33064
2016           26760        31727       1633        33360
2017           27068        32057       1480        33537
2018           27433        32348       1406        33754
2019           27539        32472       1422        33894
2020           27594        32537       1524        34061
2021           27659        32614       1614        34228
2022           27782        32759       1635        34394

Percentage changes
2012/2011        0.4          1.1       -0.8          0.9
2013/2012        1.2          1.2       -3.8          0.8
2014/2013        1.7          2.4      -18.1          0.8
2015/2014        2.1          1.7      -12.1          0.9
2016/2015        1.0          1.4       -8.3          0.9
2017/2016        1.2          1.0       -9.4          0.5
2018/2017        1.4          0.9       -5.0          0.6
2019/2018        0.4          0.4        1.2          0.4
2020/2019        0.2          0.2        7.2          0.5
2021/2020        0.2          0.2        5.9          0.5
2022/2021        0.4          0.4        1.3          0.5

                               Productivity
             Population         (2015=100)               ILO
             of working                              unemployment
              age (c)     Per hour   Manufacturing       rate

2012           40507        98.3         100.3           8.0
2013           40552        97.9         100.0           7.6
2014           40683        98.5         100.8           6.2
2015           40873        99.5         100.0           5.4
2016           41031       100.0         100.0           4.9
2017           41156       100.7         101.5           4.4
2018           41272       101.6         105.0           4.2
2019           41396       103.0         113.0           4.2
2020           41517       104.5         119.3           4.5
2021           41638       106.1         124.7           4.7
2022           41760       107.5         129.4           4.8

Percentage changes
2012/2011       -0.1        -0.7          -2.1
2013/2012        0.1        -0.4          -0.4
2014/2013        0.3         0.6           0.9
2015/2014        0.5         1.0          -0.9
2016/2015        0.4         0.5           0.0
2017/2016        0.3         0.7           1.5
2018/2017        0.3         0.9           3.4
2019/2018        0.3         1.3           7.7
2020/2019        0.3         1.5           5.5
2021/2020        0.3         1.5           4.5
2022/2021        0.3         1.3           3.8

Notes: (a) Includes self-employed, government-supported
trainees and unpaid family members, (b) Employment plus
ILO unemployment (c) Population projections are based on
annual rates of growth from 2014-based population
projections by the ONS.

Table A8. Public sector financial balance and borrowing requirement

billion [pounds sterling], fiscal years

                                              2014-15    2015-16

Current           Taxes on income               386.0      401.4
receipts:         Taxes on expenditure          233.1      243.2
                  Other current receipts         40.9       39.7
                  Total                         660.0      684.3
                  (as a % of GDP)                35.6       35.8

Current           Goods and services            357.6      362.6
expenditure:      Net social benefits paid      229.9      232.8
                  Debt interest                  37.4       38.0
                  Other current expenditure      49.9       49.2
                  Total                         674.8      682.6
                  (as a % of GDP)                36.4       35.7

Depreciation                                     39.0       40.1
Surplus on public sector                        -53.9      -38.4
current budget (a)                               -2.9       -2.0
(as a % of GDP)

Gross investment                                 75.6       74.2
Net investment                                   36.6       34.1
(as a % of GDP)                                   2.0        1.8

Total managed expenditure                       750.4      756.8
(as a % of GDP)                                  40.5       39.6

Public sector net borrowing                      90.5       72.5
(as a % of GDP)                                   4.9        3.8

Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b)            83.2       82.5

GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100)         97.6       98.4
Money GDP                                      1855.0     1912.5

Financial balance under                          -5.3       -4.2
  Maastricht (% of GDP) (c)
Gross debt under Maastricht                      86.5       87.3
  (% of GDP) (c)

                                              2016-17    2017-18

Current           Taxes on income               434.2      452.1
receipts:         Taxes on expenditure          252.2      258.5
                  Other current receipts         39.9       39.4
                  Total                         726.3      750.0
                  (as a % of GDP)                36.5       36.5

Current           Goods and services            369.4      374.5
expenditure:      Net social benefits paid      233.7      236.9
                  Debt interest                  40.2       44.5
                  Other current expenditure      49.6       51.9
                  Total                         692.7      707.8
                  (as a % of GDP)                34.8       34.4

Depreciation                                     40.8       41.0
Surplus on public sector                         -7.2        1.2
current budget (a)                               -0.4        0.1
(as a % of GDP)

Gross investment                                 79.3       81.7
Net investment                                   38.5       40.7
(as a % of GDP)                                   1.9        2.0

Total managed expenditure                       772.0      789.5
(as a % of GDP)                                  38.8       38.4

Public sector net borrowing                      45.7       39.5
(as a % of GDP)                                   2.3        1.9

Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b)            86.0       85.6

GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100)        100.6      102.3
Money GDP                                      1989.2     2056.2

Financial balance under                          -2.9       -1.8
  Maastricht (% of GDP) (c)
Gross debt under Maastricht                      87.3       87.0
  (% of GDP) (c)

                                              2018-19    2019-20

Current           Taxes on income               472.7      489.9
receipts:         Taxes on expenditure          272.0      283.4
                  Other current receipts         32.8       32.3
                  Total                         777.5      805.6
                  (as a % of GDP)                36.9       36.9

Current           Goods and services            386.4      400.9
expenditure:      Net social benefits paid      235.8      240.0
                  Debt interest                  42.9       45.1
                  Other current expenditure      60.6       62.6
                  Total                         725.8      748.6
                  (as a % of GDP)                34.4       34.3

Depreciation                                     40.9       42.2
Surplus on public sector                         10.8       14.7
current budget (a)                                0.5        0.7
(as a % of GDP)

Gross investment                                 89.3       93.4
Net investment                                   48.4       51.2
(as a % of GDP)                                   2.3        2.3

Total managed expenditure                       815.1      842.0
(as a % of GDP)                                  38.7       38.5

Public sector net borrowing                      37.6       36.5
(as a % of GDP)                                   1.8        1.7

Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b)            85.0       83.6

GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100)        103.9      105.8
Money GDP                                      2108.6     2185.6

Financial balance under                          -1.9       -1.7
  Maastricht (% of GDP) (c)
Gross debt under Maastricht                      85.5       84.2
  (% of GDP) (c)

                                              2020-21    2021-22

Current           Taxes on income               509.1      531.8
receipts:         Taxes on expenditure          293.6      304.4
                  Other current receipts         33.5       34.7
                  Total                         836.2      870.9
                  (as a % of GDP)                36.9       37.0

Current           Goods and services            418.8      439.1
expenditure:      Net social benefits paid      248.7      258.3
                  Debt interest                  47.3       50.0
                  Other current expenditure      64.7       66.8
                  Total                         779.5      814.2
                  (as a % of GDP)                34.4       34.6

Depreciation                                     43.5       44.9
Surplus on public sector                         13.2       11.8
current budget (a)                                0.6        0.5
(as a % of GDP)

Gross investment                                 98.9      101.4
Net investment                                   55.4       56.5
(as a % of GDP)                                   2.4        2.4

Total managed expenditure                       878.4      915.5
(as a % of GDP)                                  38.7       38.9

Public sector net borrowing                      42.2       44.7
(as a % of GDP)                                   1.9        1.9

Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b)            80.9       78.6

GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100)        107.9      110.0
Money GDP                                      2267.0     2351.0

Financial balance under                          -1.8       -1.9
  Maastricht (% of GDP) (c)
Gross debt under Maastricht                      82.8       81.6
  (% of GDP) (c)

Notes: These data are constructed from non-seasonally adjusted
Public Sector Finance data and all fiscal aggregates exclude
public sector banks, (a) Public sector current budget surplus
is total current receipts less total current expenditure and
depreciation, (b) Data for QI. Seasonal adjustment applied
in NiGEM results in differences in between the figures here
and official unadjusted PSF data, (c) Calendar year.

Table A9. Saving and investment

As a percentage of GDP

          Households             Companies

       Saving   Investment   Saving   Investment

2012    6.6        3.3        9.8         9.9
2013    6.1        3.7        7.7        10.3
2014    6.1        3.8        8.6        10.8
2015    6.8        3.9        6.7        10.7
2016    4.8        4.1        7.3        10.7
2017    3.0        4.3        9.4        10.5
2018    2.8        4.4        9.6        10.0
2019    2.8        4.5        9.3        10.0
2020    3.2        4.6        8.9        10.1
2021    3.7        4.7        8.9        10.1
2022    4.1        4.9        8.7        10.1

        General government      Whole economy

       Saving   Investment   Saving   Investment

2012    -4.3       2.6        12.1       15.8
2013    -2.4       2.5        11.4       16.5
2014    -2.3       2.6        12.3       17.3
2015    -1.1       2.6        12.3       17.2
2016     0.0       2.5        12.0       17.3
2017     1.1       2.5        13.5       17.4
2018     1.0       2.4        13.5       16.8
2019     1.3       2.4        13.4       16.9
2020     1.3       2.5        13.4       17.2
2021     1.2       2.5        13.8       17.4
2022     1.2       2.5        14.0       17.4

         Finance from
          abroad (a)
                              Net
       Total   Net factor   national
                 income      saving

2012    3.8       1.0        -0.2
2013    5.1       2.0        -0.9
2014    4.9       2.0         0.1
2015    4.9       2.2         0.1
2016    5.2       2.4        -0.2
2017    3.9       1.5         1.3
2018    3.3       0.7         1.2
2019    3.5       0.3         1.1
2020    3.8       0.1         1.1
2021    3.6      -0.4         1.4
2022    3.4      -0.9         1.7

Notes: Saving and investment data are gross of depreciation
unless otherwise stated, (a) Negative sign indicates a
surplus for the UK.

Table A10. Medium and long-term projections

All figures percentage change unless otherwise stated

                                     2014     2015     2016

GDP (market prices)                   2.9      2.3      1.8
Average earnings                      0.4      1.0      2.8
GDP deflator (market prices)          1.7      0.4      2.1
Consumer Prices Index                 1.4      0.1      0.7
Per capita GDP                        2.2      1.5      1.0
Whole economy productivity (a)        0.6      1.0      0.5
Labour input (b)                      2.8      1.5      1.4
ILO Unemployment rate (%)             6.2      5.4      4.9
Current account (% of GDP)           -4.9     -4.9     -5.2
Total managed expenditure
  (% of GDP)                         40.5     39.8     39.0
Public sector net borrowing
  (% of GDP)                          5.2      4.0      2.8
Public sector net debt (% of GDP)    81.9     83.5     83.3
Effective exchange rate
  (2011 = 100)                      110.2    116.3    104.8
Bank Rate (%)                         0.5      0.5      0.4
3 month interest rates (%)            0.5      0.6      0.5
10 year interest rates (%)            2.5      1.8      1.3

                                    2017     2018     2019

GDP (market prices)                  1.7      1.4      1.7
Average earnings                     2.9      2.6      3.1
GDP deflator (market prices)         1.9      1.6      1.7
Consumer Prices Index                2.7      2.3      1.9
Per capita GDP                       1.0      0.8      1.1
Whole economy productivity (a)       0.7      0.9      1.3
Labour input (b)                     1.2      0.5      0.4
ILO Unemployment rate (%)            4.4      4.2      4.2
Current account (% of GDP)          -3.9     -3.3     -3.5
Total managed expenditure
  (% of GDP)                        38.5     38.4     38.3
Public sector net borrowing
  (% of GDP)                         1.8      1.8      1.6
Public sector net debt (% of GDP)   86.1     85.8     84.9
Effective exchange rate
  (2011 = 100)                      99.3    101.7    101.3
Bank Rate (%)                        0.3      0.6      1.1
3 month interest rates (%)           0.4      0.7      1.3
10 year interest rates (%)           1.2      1.4      2.0

                                     2020     2021     2022    2023-27

GDP (market prices)                   1.7      1.7      1.8        1.8
Average earnings                      3.3      3.3      3.3        3.3
GDP deflator (market prices)          2.0      2.0      2.0        2.1
Consumer Prices Index                 2.0      2.0      2.0        2.0
Per capita GDP                        1.1      1.2      1.2        1.3
Whole economy productivity (a)        1.5      1.5      1.3        1.4
Labour input (b)                      0.2      0.2      0.4        0.4
ILO Unemployment rate (%)             4.5      4.7      4.8        4.9
Current account (% of GDP)           -3.8     -3.6     -3.4       -3.2
Total managed expenditure
  (% of GDP)                         38.5     38.7     38.9       39.0
Public sector net borrowing
  (% of GDP)                          1.8      1.9      1.9        1.7
Public sector net debt (% of GDP)    83.3     80.5     78.6       76.0
Effective exchange rate
  (2011 = 100)                      101.5    101.6    101.7      101.5
Bank Rate (%)                         1.5      1.9      2.3        3.4
3 month interest rates (%)            1.7      2.1      2.5        3.6
10 year interest rates (%)            2.6      3.1      3.5        4.0

Notes: (a) Per hour, (b) Total hours worked.


Amit Kara, with Arno Hantzsche, Jason Lennard, Cyrille Lenoel, Marta Lopresto, Rebecca Piggott and Garry Young *

* NIESR. E-mail: a.kara@niesr.ac.uk.Thanks to Jagjit Chadha, lana Liadze, Barry Naisbitt and Yanitsa Kazalova for helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank Yanitsa Kazalova for compiling the database. Unless otherwise stated, the source of all data reported in the figures and tables is the NiGEM database and forecast baseline. The UK forecast was completed on 25 July 2018.

Caption: Figure 1. Real GDP growth (per cent per quarter)

Caption: Figure A1. The EU engagement triangle

Caption: Figure A2. Baseline real GDP growth, White Paper variant and no-deal Brexit

Caption: Figure A3. Baseline rate of inflation, White Paper variant and no-deal Brexit

Caption: Figure 2. GDP growth fan chart (per cent per annum)

Caption: Figure 3. Inflation fan chart (per cent per annum)

Caption: Figure B1. WBSFS forecast probabilities for real GDP growth and inflation, year-on-year

Caption: Figure C1. UK nominal GDP and narrow/broad money (% 12-month change)

Caption: Figure C2. UK GDP and real non-financial MI (% six-month change)

Caption: Figure 4. Market-implied paths for short-term interest rates and NIESR forecast

Caption: Figure 5. Gap between current level of public sector wages and their long-run trend

Caption: Figure 6. Public sector net borrowing and Brexit variants

Caption: Figure 7. Public sector net debt and Brexit variants

Caption: Figure 8. Sterling exchange rate

Caption: Figure 9.Yield spread between 10-year and 2-year UK government bonds

Caption: Figure 10. NIESR monthly GDP Tracker

Caption: Figure 11. Expenditure components: contribution to GDP growth (percentage points)

Caption: Figure 12. Exports expectations and export growth outturn

Caption: Figure 13. Investment intentions (net balance) and business investment (annual percentage change)

Caption: Figure 14. Net migration to the UK

Caption: Figure 15. Unemployment and average weekly earnings, January 2007-May 2018

Caption: Figure 16. Decomposing price changes (per cent)

Caption: Figure 17.The term structure of CPI inflation expectations (per cent)

Caption: Figure 18. Sectoral balances

Caption: Figure D1. Forecasting inflation: RMSE (percentage points)

Caption: Figure D2. Measures of inflation (per cent)
Table 1. Summary of the forecast

Percentage change unless otherwise stated

                                2014    2015    2016

GDP                              2.9     2.3     1.8
Per capita GDP                   2.2     1.5     1.0

CPI Inflation                    1.4     0.1     0.7
RPI Inflation                    2.4     1.0     1.7

RPDI                             1.1     5.2     0.0
Unemployment, %                  6.2     5.4     4.9
Bank Rate, %                     0.5     0.5     0.4
Long Rate, %                     2.5     1.8     1.3
Effective exchange rate          7.4     5.6    -9.9

Current account as % of GDP     -4.9    -4.9    -5.2

Net borrowing as % of GDP (a)    4.9     3.8     2.3
Net debt as % of GDP (a)        83.7    83.3    86.2

                                2017    2018    2019

GDP                              1.7     1.4     1.7
Per capita GDP                   1.0     0.8     1.1

CPI Inflation                    2.7     2.3     1.9
RPI Inflation                    3.6     3.4     3.8

RPDI                            -0.6     0.9     1.5
Unemployment, %                  4.4     4.2     4.2
Bank Rate, %                     0.3     0.6     1.1
Long Rate, %                     1.2     1.4     2.0
Effective exchange rate         -5.2     2.4    -0.4

Current account as % of GDP     -3.9    -3.3    -3.5

Net borrowing as % of GDP (a)    1.9     1.8     1.7
Net debt as % of GDP (a)        86.2    85.2    84.3

                                2020    2021    2022

GDP                              1.7     1.7     1.8
Per capita GDP                   1.1     1.2     1.2

CPI Inflation                    2.0     2.0     2.0
RPI Inflation                    3.5     3.6     3.4

RPDI                             1.8     1.9     2.0
Unemployment, %                  4.5     4.7     4.8
Bank Rate, %                     1.5     1.9     2.3
Long Rate, %                     2.6     3.1     3.5
Effective exchange rate          0.2     0.2     0.1

Current account as % of GDP     -3.8    -3.6    -3.4

Net borrowing as % of GDP (a)    1.9     1.9     1.9
Net debt as % of GDP (a)        81.7    78.5    78.8

Notes: RPDI is real personal disposable income.
PSNB is public sector net borrowing. PSND is public
sector net debt, (a) Fiscal year, excludes the impact
of financial sector interventions, but includes the flows
from the Asset Purchase Facility of the Bank of England.
Annual averages unless stated otherwise.

Table B1. Probability event forecasts for 2018Q4 and
2019Q4 annualised % real GDP growth and CPI inflation
(extracted from theWBSFS forecast histograms)

                       Real GDP growth (%, p.a.)

Year      Prob(growth<0%)   Prob(growth<1%)   Prob(growth<2%)

Updated Forecasts (July 2018)

2018Q4          6%                31%               71%
2019Q4          9%                25%               53%

Previous Forecasts (April 2018)

2018Q4          7%                26%               58%
2019Q4          8%                20%               49%

                   CPI inflation (%, p.a.)

Year      Prob(letter)   Prob(CPI<1%)   Prob(CPI>3%)

Updated Forecasts (July 2018)

2018Q4        28%             4%            24%
2019Q4        41%            12%            29%

Previous Forecasts (April 2018)

2018Q4        41%             6%            35%
2019Q4        43%            13%            30%
COPYRIGHT 2018 National Institute of Economic and Social Research
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有