PROSPECTS FOR THE UK ECONOMY.
Kara, Amit ; Hantzsche, Arno ; Lennard, Jason 等
Box A. UK government Brexit White Paper The UK government published a White Paper (The future relationship between the United Kingdom and the European Union) on 12 July outlining its preferences for a future relationship with the EU. (1) In this box we compare the proposals outlined in the White Paper against other EU free trade agreements (FTA) and also estimate the impact on the UK relative to our central forecast which assumes a soft Brexit. Benchmarking the White Paper proposals The World Bank database of preferential trade agreements provides a detailed measure of the depth of all the agreements worldwide that were signed after 1957. We update that database with the White Paper proposals, building on earlier work that was published in the February Review (see Box C 'The Great British trade-off). Our results suggest that the trade intensity of the White Paper proposals is comparable to Switzerland or Canada and is less comprehensive than a Norway-style EEA arrangement. The score essentially reflects a comprehensive FTA for goods and the shortfall is explained by the proposals for services. Non-EU countries that have secured deep and broad trading arrangements with the EU have had to concede ground on the free movement of labour, the jurisdiction of the CJEU and/or make a budgetary contribution to various programmes run by the EU. Figure AI is a visual representation of the extent of the depth and breadth of EU engagement We have selected three key dimensions to define the relationship between the EU and non-EU countries and the vertices of the triangle correspond to each of these: full market access, complete freedom of movement of people and size of the financial contribution (as a percentage of Gross National Income). One could add other dimensions to the analysis such as the role of the CJEU, security, defence, fiscal harmonisation, but we have, for the sake of simplicity, restricted our analysis to the what we believe are the three most important areas of negotiation between the UK and the EU. Briefly, the largest triangle represents the UK current level of engagement as a member state of the EU: the UK has full access to the EU market in goods and services, allows EU citizens to move freely in and out of the UK, and contributes about 0.5 per cent of GNI to the EU budget, net of what it receives. Norway opted to join the European Economic Area (EEA) to have close to full access to the single market, both in goods and services. The dashed red triangle shows that, to be accepted as a member of the EEA, Norway had to agree to significant financial contributions ('Norway Grants', amounting to 0.14 per cent of GNI) and freedom of movement of persons. Switzerland's bilateral agreements with the EU means that it allows freedom of movement of persons, makes a very small net budgetary contribution, but its market access is significantly reduced in the service sector. Finally, the trade deal with Canada (CETA) is less extensive than Switzerland and is essentially restricted to just goods. Canada does not make a budgetary contribution. The UK White Paper proposals are represented in the dotted black line. Market access for the White Paper, based on our scoring, stands at 90, which is close to Switzerland (89) and Canada (79) and the movement of labour provisions fall well short of Switzerland and only marginally higher than Canada. We have assumed that the UK budgetary contribution to the EU will be small. Legal technicalities aside, our benchmarking exercise suggests that the EU is likely to insist on more generous provisions for the free movement of labour and is also likely to insist on a budgetary contribution. Impact on the economy To simulate the effects of a deal as implied by this White Paper, in contrast to the soft Brexit assumed in our forecast, we have made the following assumptions, which come into effect in the first quarter of 2021, after the transition period ends: * UK exports: In our soft Brexit central case the UK maintains a close but not complete trading relationship with the EU. Immediately after the end of the transition period, some services e.g. financial services that require passporting rights will no longer be exported to the EU. Over time, trade in services between the UK and the EU will continue to decline as businesses develop new trading relationships. In this alternative scenario we assume that trade between the UK and the EU is reduced by about 40% in the long run, based on estimates by Ebell (2016). * Business investment: Compared to our soft Brexit scenario, the reduction in trade and increase in uncertainty will likely weigh on investment spending by UK firms and also foreign direct investment We consider a reduction in FDI of around 12 per cent which is approximately half the shock implied by HM Treasury (2016) and Dhingra et al. (2017) in the case of a no-deal WTO variant * Migration: To account for reduced movement of labour within the EU as well as the UK potentially becoming a less attractive destination for migrants, we consider a reduction in net migration of around 50,000 per year compared to the ONS' principal population projection, which is not based on any Brexit specific assumptions. This figure is halfway between the ONS' principal and low migration population projections. * Fiscal: According to the UK government, applying the methodology set out in the Phase I agreement implies a financial settlement with the EU of 35 [pounds sterling]-39 billion [pounds sterling]. The schedule of payments is yet to be decided although the Phase I agreement makes clear that the UK will not be required to make any payments earlier than if the UK had remained a Member State. After the budgetary framework ends in 2020, the UK continues to service its existing commitments and makes a negligible ongoing contribution. Overall, we assume that annual net contributions to the EU reduce by approximately 25 per cent Figure A2 plots the growth rate of real GDP in this scenario, relative to our baseline soft Brexit forecast. We expect output growth to stall due to an immediate reduction in services exports to the EU. This would be moderated somewhat by a depreciation of sterling, which cheapens goods and services exported to the EU and the rest of the world but raises the price of imports. We expect this rise in import prices to feed into consumer prices, adding almost 1.4 percentage points to inflation in 2021 (figure A3), dampening domestic demand. Over time the growth rate of real GDP would settle at a lower rate than assumed in our soft Brexit forecast as net migration falls and productive capacity grows at a slower rate. This accumulates to a loss of around 500 [pounds sterling] per person per year compared to the soft Brexit scenario and to a loss of around 800 [pounds sterling] under the counterfactual WTO rules. NOTE (1) 'The future relationship between the United Kingdom and the European Union' available at: https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/ uploads/attachment_data/file/725288/ The_future_relationship_between_the_United_Kingdom_ and_the_European_Union.pdf/. REFERENCES Dhingra, S., Ottaviano, G.,Sampson, T. and van Reenen, J. (2017), 'The impact of Brexit on foreign direct investment in the UK', CEP Brexit Analysis, 3. Ebell, M. (2016), 'Assessing the impact of trade agreements on trade', National Institute Economic Review, 238, R31-42. HM Treasury (2016), HM Treasury Analysis: the long-term economic impact of EU membership and the alternatives, CM92S0. Hofmann, C., Osnago, A. and Ruta, M. (2017), 'Horizontal depth: a new database on the content of preferential trade agreements', Policy Research working paper, no. WPS 7981, Washington, D.C.: World Bank Group, https://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/deep-trade-agreements. This box was prepared by Arno Hantzsche, Amit Kara, Cyrille Lenoel and Rebecca Piggott.
Box B. Forecasting with a benchmark: the Warwick Business School forecasting system We provide benchmark forecasts to help understand and contextualise the forecasts presented in this Review. The box presents density forecasts for UK GDP annual growth and inflation, and reports the probabilities of a range of output and inflation events occurring, as calculated using the Warwick Business School Forecasting System (WBSFS). To reflect the uncertainties inherent in economic forecasting, and following the practice of NIESR and other forecasters such as the Bank of England and OBR, the WBSFS provides probabilistic forecasts. The WBSFS forecasts are produced by explicitly combining density forecasts from a set of twenty four, statistically motivated, univariate and multivariate econometric models commonly used in the academic literature. The use of combination forecasts or model averaging reflects the view, supported by research (e.g., see Bates and Granger, 1969; Wallis, 2011; Geweke and Amisano, 2012; Rossi, 2013), that because any single model may be mis-specified there may be gains from the use of combination forecasts. Comparison of the Institute's forecasts with the probabilistic forecasts from the WBSFS may be interpreted as providing an approximate indicator of the importance of expert judgement, which may include views on the underlying structure of the macroeconomy. This is because the WBSFS forecasts are computed by exploiting regularities in past data with the aid of automated time-series models; they do not take an explicit, structural or theoretical view about how the macroeconomy works; and they do not rely on (subjective) expert judgement to the same degree as those presented by the Institute. The forecasts from the WBSFS are not altered once produced; they are deemed 'simply' to represent the data's view of what will happen to the macroeconomy in the future. Figure B1 presents WBSFS's latest (as of 11 July 2018) probabilistic forecasts for real GDP growth and inflation--defined as year-on-year growth rates for 2018q4 and 2019q4--as histograms. The information set used to produce these forecasts includes information on GDP growth up to 2018q1 and data on CPI inflation up to May 2018. Table B1 extracts from these histogram forecasts the probabilities of specific output growth and inflation events. The events considered are the probability of output growth being less than 0 per cent, 1 per cent and 2 per cent, and of inflation lying outside the 1-3 per cent target range (i.e., the probability of the Bank of England's Governor having to write a letter explaining how and why inflation has breached its target range). Also reported are the individual probabilities of inflation being less than I per cent and greater than 3 per cent, to indicate which side of the target range is most likely to be breached. Inspection of the forecasts for output growth for 2018Q4 in table BI suggests that, compared with our forecasts made one quarter ago, lower output growth is more likely. The most likely range for the forecast remains for economic growth between I per cent and 2 per cent in 2018Q4, but the probability of growth less than 2 per cent has increased from 58 per cent in April to 71 per cent in July. Looking out further to 2019Q4, the change in the probability forecast from April to July is less pronounced, with higher growth between 2 and 3 per cent now marginally less likely. As table Bl shows, the difference between the forecasts made in April and July, for 2019q4, is small--with a small upward revision to the risk of 'low' growth (growth less than I per cent)--the probability of this event has risen from 20 to 25 per cent. For inflation, our probabilistic forecasts for 2018Q4 have changed between April and July, such that the probability of inflation being outside the 1-3 per cent range, thereby triggering an explanatory letter from the Governor of the Bank of England, has decreased from 41 to 28 per cent. This change is largely attributable to the probability of inflation exceeding 3 per cent falling from 35 per cent to 24 per cent. An inflation rate between 2 and 3 per cent remains the most likely outcome in the year ending 2018Q4, with a 44 per cent probability (up by 6 percentage points from the previous estimate of 38 per cent). But the WBSFS predicts that inflationary pressures for 2019Q4 remain approximately as we forecast in April, with a probability of around 27 per cent of inflation falling in the 1-2 per cent range and 32 per cent in the 2-3 per cent range. In comparison with our previous forecasts, the probability of inflation rising above 3 per cent in 2019Q4 remains essentially the same, having fallen from 30 per cent to 29 per cent. NOTE WBSFS forecasts for UK output growth and inflation have been released every quarter since November 2014. Details of the releases are available at https://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/subjects/emf/forecasting/ and a description of the models in the system and of the indicators employed is available at https://wvvw2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/wbs/subjects/emf/forecasting/summary of_wbs_forecastng_system.pdf. REFERENCES Bates, J.M. and Granger, C.W. (1969), The combination of forecasts', Operational Research Quarterly, 20, pp. 451-68. Geweke, J. and Amisano, G. (2012), 'Predictions with misspecified models', American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 102, pp. 482-6. Rossi, B. (2013), 'Advances in forecasting under model instability' in Elliott, G. and Timmermann, A. (eds), Handbook of Economic Forecasting, Volume 2B, Elsevier Publications, pp. 1203-324. Wallis, K.F. (201 I), 'Combining forecasts--forty years later', Applied Financial Economics, 21, pp. 33-41. This Box was prepared by Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell. Box C. Monetary trends giving cautionary signal This box provides a different perspective on UK economic prospects based on an assessment of recent developments in the monetary aggregates. UK monetary growth rates have fallen significantly since 2016 and are below post-crisis averages, suggesting weak prospects for economic activity and domestically-generated inflation. The discussion below focuses on 'non-financial' broad (M4) and narrow (Ml) monetary aggregates, comprising money holdings of households and private non-financial businesses. The Bank of England's M4ex broad aggregate additionally includes money held by non-bank financial corporations, excluding intermediaries, but such holdings are volatile and appear unrelated to future spending on goods and services. Figure C1 compares annual rates of change of nominal GDP and the non-financial money measures. Swings in monetary momentum have generally preceded swings in nominal GDP momentum over the period shown, although the lead time has been variable. Non-financial MI has given clearer directional signals than non-financial M4. The annual growth rates of the aggregates were well above their post-crisis averages in mid-2016, suggesting that economic expansion would continue in 2016-17 despite the negative shock of the EU referendum result. The growth rates, however, peaked in September 2016, more than halving over the subsequent 18 months before recovering slightly in April/May 2018. This downswing was reflected in a slowdown in nominal GDP, annual growth of which peaked in the fourth quarter of 2016 and fell steadily through the first quarter of 2018. The monetary slowdown occurred despite the August 2016 rate cut, a further round of quantitative easing between August 2016 and March 2017 and additional monetary base expansion until February 2018 resulting from Bank of England lending to banks under the term funding scheme. This suggests that the slowdown was demand-driven: the referendum shock may have weakened economic confidence and spending intentions, leading to a reduction in desired money holdings. According to the credit counterparts analysis of non-financial M4, the fall in annual growth between September 2016 and May 2018 was attributable (in an accounting sense) to a combination of slowdowns in bank lending to the public sector and to households/ non-financial firms and a drag from other sterling counterparts (i.e. net overseas deposits and non-deposit funding). Figure C2 compares, over a longer period, the two-quarter rate of change of constant-price GDP and the six-month change in non-financial MI deflated by consumer prices. The fall in real non-financial M I momentum since 2016 ranks as the fourth largest since the mid-1980s. The three larger declines in 1986-88, 1989-90 and 2007-8, and a smaller reduction in 2010-11, were followed by a significant loss of economic momentum. A sectoral split is available between the household sector and private non-financial corporations. Six-month growth of real household MI is currently below that of real corporate MI but the latter has also slowed significantly since 2016, suggesting weak prospects for both consumer spending and business investment. The current pace of broad money growth may be inconsistent with achievement of the 2 per cent inflation target over the medium term. The velocity of non-financial M4--i.e. the ratio of nominal GDP to the aggregate--has fallen at an average rate of 0.7 per cent per annum since end-2009, compared with a reduction of 3.0 per cent per annum over the prior decade. Assuming a continued decline of 0.7 per cent per annum, current annual growth of non-financial M4 of 3.3 per cent in May, if sustained, would result in a 2.6 per cent per annum rate of increase of nominal GDP. This would imply an inflation undershoot unless potential economic expansion is below I per cent per annum. Monetary Policy Committee member Michael Saunders has suggested that broad money trends have been affected by a portfolio shift by households into mutual funds, sales of which rose strongly in 2017 after weakness in 2016. This shift cannot fully explain the slowdown in non-financial M4: annual growth of an expanded liquidity measure including mutual funds, National Savings instruments and foreign currency deposits has also fallen, reaching a six-year low in April/May. Mutual funds and other longer-term savings products, moreover, are not money: a portfolio shift into such funds may indicate a reduced likelihood of near-term spending. This box was prepared by Simon Ward of NS Partners and Janus Henderson Investors
Box D. The price of everything The consumer price index is a fundamental economic statistic for households, firms and policymakers. This number summarises the prices of hundreds of thousands of goods and services across the country. Yet the behaviour of individual prices is erratic, some rise and fall by an order of magnitude from one month to the next, others rarely change. These idiosyncrasies are central to understanding aggregate price dynamics (Gagnon, 2009; Nakamura et al., forthcoming). What is the rate of inflation when the most volatile prices are excluded? This box answers this question by constructing a measure of trimmed mean inflation, which excludes a fraction of the highest and lowest price changes each month, calculating the arithmetic mean across the remaining observations. (1) We find that current trimmed mean inflation is a powerful predictor of future consumer price index inflation. Although trimmed mean inflation has fallen in recent months, it remains in line with the Bank of England's target. We begin by collecting micro data on the prices of the individual items that underlie the all items consumer price index (CPI) for the United Kingdom. This data set contains the prices of up to 135,000 goods and services each month, which adds up to approximately 30 million price quotes since the 1990s. (2) This data will also allow us to monitor the variance, skewness, kurtosis and frequency of price changes at a regional and national resolution. In order to calculate the trimmed mean, the first step is to calculate month-on-month inflation rates for items i = 1,2 ..., N at time t: [DELTA][p.sub.i,t] = [[p.sub.i,t]/[p.sub.i,t-1]] - 1. The second step is to calculate the j = 0,1, ..., 50 per cent trimmed mean for each month, [[PI].sup.m.sub.j,t]. The final step is to calculate the jth per cent annualised trimmed mean for each month: [[product].sup.y.sub.j,t] = ((I + [[product].sup.m.sub.j,t]) x (1 + [[product].sup.m.sub.j,t-1]) x ... x (1 + [[product].sup.y.sub.j,t-11]) - 1). It is possible to discard anything from 0 per cent of the most extreme price changes, which is simply the mean of the full distribution, to 50 per cent, which is equivalent to the median. (3) In order to select the optimal trimming percentage, we run a simple horserace, where we assess how well the jth per cent trimmed mean forecasts future CPI inflation. In this race, we also include CPI inflation and CPI excluding energy, food, alcoholic beverages and tobacco inflation (CPI-ex) as benchmarks. Specifically, we calculate the root mean square error (RMSE) from the following equation: [[pi].sub.t+12] = [alpha] + [beta][x.sub.t] + [e.sub.t] (1) which regresses year ahead CPI inflation, [[pi].sub.t+12], on a constant, [alpha], and a measure of inflation (either the jth trimmed mean, CPI or CPI-ex), [x.sub.t]. The results are shown in figure Dl. The results indicate that the 5 per cent trimmed mean is optimal. In addition, the 5 per cent trimmed mean yields better forecasts of future inflation than the CPI and CPI-ex not only at the 12-month horizon but also at the 24-and 36-month horizons. Figure D2 plots the 5 per cent trimmed mean, CPI and CPI-ex inflation rates. The three measures are highly correlated, with a correlation coefficient of 0.90 between trimmed mean and CPI inflation and 0.74 between trimmed mean and CPI-ex inflation. The level of CPI-trim inflation is lower on average but more volatile than CPI inflation. These differences are due to how the largest price changes are treated and to how the prices are weighted, as trimmed mean inflation is an unweighted average of a truncated distribution, while CPI inflation is a weighted average of the full distribution. An important result is how trimmed mean inflation has recently fallen. After the depreciation of sterling in 2016, both trimmed mean inflation and CPI inflation rose sharply following a spell of disinflation. Since October 2017, however, trimmed mean inflation has fallen by 1.5 percentage points, suggesting that the pass-through effects are fading. Based on the latest outturn of trimmed mean inflation, equation (I) suggests that CPI inflation will be 2.2 per cent in a year's time. NOTES (1) See Dolmas (2005) and Bryan and Cecchetti (1994) for overviews of trimmed mean inflation measures. Trimmed mean inflation is based on the arithmetic mean, while the CPI typically uses the geometric mean. (2) Quotes are linked by the item ID, shop code, shop type and region to form a panel. Items that could not be uniquely linked between months were excluded, as were items where the price is zero. (3) Asymmetric trimmed means can also be calculated, where a different percentage is trimmed from each tail. While we only focus on integers, there are still 2450 possible combinations. For computational reasons, we focus on the 50 possible integers for symmetric trimmed means. REFERENCES Bryan, M.F. and Cecchetti, S.G. (1994), 'Measuring core inflation', in Mankiw, N.G. (ed.), Monetary Policy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Dolmas, J. (2005), Trimmed mean PCE inflation', Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Research Department Working Paper, No. 0506. Gagnon, E. (2009), 'Price setting during low and high inflation: evidence from Mexico', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 3, pp. 1221-63. Nakamura, E., Steinsson, J., Sun, P. and Villar, D. (forthcoming), 'The elusive costs of inflation: price dispersion during the U.S. great inflation', Quarterly Journal of Economics. This box was prepared by Jason Lennard.
Box E. The Brexit assumptions underpinning our forecasts In this box we outline the Brexit-related assumptions embedded in our central forecast. The UK government published its preferred blueprint for a future relationship between the UK and EU in a White Paper on 12 July. We discuss the White Paper proposals in Box B. Suffice to say that the White Paper has done little to lift the fog of uncertainty about the future relationship and as a result our central forecast continues to assume a soft Brexit. We define 'soft' Brexit as: the UK and the EU maintain a very high level of access to each other's market for both goods and services, fully functioning financial markets, free movement of labour, a budgetary contribution that is broadly unchanged and a 21-month transition period after the UK exits the EU in March 2019 during which the country remains bound by regulations of the single market and customs union. Our central forecast continues to assume a soft Brexit. The specific assumptions in our central forecast are as follows: * UK trade: As before, we assume the UK maintains a close but not frictionless trading relationship with the EU. This also reflects the Prime Minister's expectation that "people need to face up to some hard facts" and "life is going to be different". That less comprehensive relationship is reflected by negative residuals to the export volume equation. * Productivity: The smaller degree of competition due to lower trade volumes, less investment and a potential reduction in skilled migration could drive productivity lower in the long run. Effects on labour productivity are likely to materialise only with a long lag and may be ambiguous in the short run if employment reduces as a result of Brexit We have not explicitly introduced a Brexit-related productivity shock into our forecast, which therefore constitutes a key downside risk to our forecast. * Fiscal contributions: Regarding the UK's financial contributions to the EU budget, a payments schedule is yet to be decided. The British government has already announced that it would seek associate membership in EU agencies, which would require financial contributions to be made, in addition to payments towards the 'divorce bill'. We have assumed that the UK continues to make contributions beyond 2020 as if it were a member of the EU. The risk of a more pessimistic scenario remains high. In our February 2018 Review we reported estimates for a case in which negotiations fail and the UK moves to a WTO-style trading relationship on exit. (1) Our results show that this would cause a mild recession within one year and real GDP per head would be some 2,000 [pounds sterling] lower relative to our 'soft' Brexit case after a decade. In the May 2018 Review, Erken et at. (2018) provided a more pessimistic view: their headline result for a 'hard' Brexit is that cumulative GDP growth could be 18 percentage points lower by 2030 compared to a scenario in which the UK remains in the EU. (2) In this Review (Box B) we provide an analysis of a scenario that is broadly in line with the proposals outlined in the July White Paper. NOTES (1) See also Hantzsche, A. and Kara, A. (2018), 'Deal, or no deal? The 2,000 [pounds sterling] question', NIESR blog, 16 February 2018. (2) Erken, H., Hayat, R., Prins, C., Heijmerikx, M. and de Vreede I. (2018), 'Measuring the permanent costs of Brexit', National Institute Economic Review, 244, pp. 46-55. This box was prepared by Arno Hantzsche and Amit Kara.
Table A1. Exchange rates and interest rates UK exchange rates FTSE Effective Dollar Euro All-share 2011 = 100 index 2012 104.1 1.6 1.2 2617.7 2013 102.6 1.6 1.2 3006.2 2014 110.2 1.7 1.2 3136.6 2015 116.3 1.5 1.4 3150.1 2016 104.8 1.4 1.2 3102.0 2017 99.3 1.3 1.1 3542.4 2018 101.7 1.4 1.1 3640.6 2019 101.3 1.3 1.1 3661.5 2020 101.5 1.4 1.1 3678.5 2021 101.6 1.4 1.1 3749.4 2022 101.7 1.4 1.1 3852.9 2017 Q1 98.9 1.2 1.2 3467.5 2017 Q2 100.0 1.3 1.2 3549.2 2017 Q3 98.3 1.3 1.1 3548.3 2017 Q4 100.1 1.3 1.1 3604.5 2018 Q1 102.1 1.4 1.1 3552.5 2018 Q2 102.2 1.4 1.1 3643.8 2018 Q3 101.2 1.3 1.1 3673.0 2018 Q4 101.2 1.3 1.1 3693.3 2019 Q1 101.2 1.3 1.1 3683.5 2019 Q2 101.2 1.3 1.1 3666.4 2019 Q3 101.3 1.3 1.1 3647.2 2019 Q4 101.3 1.3 1.1 3649.1 Percentage changes 2012/2011 4.2 -1.1 7.0 1.2 2013/2012 -1.5 -1.3 -4.5 14.8 2014/2013 7.4 5.3 5.4 4.3 2015/2014 5.6 -7.2 11.1 0.4 2016/2015 -9.9 -11.4 -11.2 -1.5 2017/2016 -5.2 -4.9 -6.7 14.2 2018/2017 2.4 4.6 -0.7 2.8 2019/2018 -0.4 -1.5 -0.6 0.6 2020/2019 0.2 1.6 -1.0 0.5 2021/2020 0.2 1.6 -1.0 1.9 2022/2021 0.1 1.4 -1.0 2.8 2017Q4/2016Q4 2.0 6.9 -2.1 9.2 2018Q4/2017Q4 1.1 -0.5 0.3 2.5 2019Q4/2018Q4 0.2 1.2 -0.8 -1.2 Interest rates 3-month 10-year World (a) Bank rates gilts Rate (b) 2012 0.8 1.8 1.2 0.5 2013 0.5 2.4 0.9 0.5 2014 0.5 2.5 0.9 0.5 2015 0.6 1.8 0.9 0.5 2016 0.5 1.3 0.9 0.3 2017 0.4 1.2 1.2 0.4 2018 0.7 1.4 1.8 0.8 2019 1.3 2.0 2.2 1.3 2020 1.7 2.6 2.5 1.7 2021 2.1 3.1 2.6 2.1 2022 2.5 3.5 2.8 2.5 2017 Q1 0.4 1.3 1.0 0.3 2017 Q2 0.3 1.0 1.1 0.3 2017 Q3 0.3 1.2 1.2 0.3 2017 Q4 0.5 1.3 1.3 0.4 2018 Q1 0.6 1.5 1.4 0.5 2018 Q2 0.7 1.4 1.6 0.5 2018 Q3 0.7 1.3 2.0 0.7 2018 Q4 0.9 1.5 2.1 0.8 2019 Q1 1.1 1.8 2.1 0.9 2019 Q2 1.2 2.0 2.2 1.0 2019 Q3 1.3 2.1 2.2 1.2 2019 Q4 1.4 2.3 2.4 1.3 Percentage changes 2012/2011 2013/2012 2014/2013 2015/2014 2016/2015 2017/2016 2018/2017 2019/2018 2020/2019 2021/2020 2022/2021 2017Q4/2016Q4 2018Q4/2017Q4 2019Q4/2018Q4 Notes: We assume that bilateral exchange rates for the second quarter of this year are the average of information available to 12 July 2018. We then assume that bilateral rates remain constant for the following two quarters before moving in line with the path implied by the backward-looking uncovered interest rate parity condition based on interest rate differentials relative to the US. (a) Weighted average of central bank intervention rates in OECD economies, (b) End of period. Table A2. Price indices 2016=100 Unit Imports Exports World labour deflator deflator oil price costs ($) (a) 2012 96.2 104.8 99.0 112.5 2013 98.0 105.6 101.2 109.1 2014 97.3 101.8 98.7 99.6 2015 98.1 95.4 94.2 52.8 2016 100.0 100.0 100.0 43.4 2017 102.4 105.9 106.4 53.5 2018 105.0 109.0 106.1 72.1 2019 106.8 11l.1 105.9 74.7 2020 108.7 112.8 106.1 75.6 2021 110.6 115.0 107.0 77.1 2022 112.8 117.6 108.3 78.7 Annual Growth Rates 2012/2011 1.0 -0.9 -0.9 1.8 2013/2012 1.9 0.7 2.2 -3.0 2014/2013 -0.7 -3.6 -2.4 -8.7 2015/2014 0.8 -6.3 -4.6 -47.0 2016/2015 1.9 4.8 6.1 -17.7 2017/2016 2.4 5.9 6.4 23.3 2018/2017 2.5 2.9 -0.3 34.7 2019/2018 1.8 1.9 -0.2 3.5 2020/2019 1.8 1.5 0.2 1.3 2021/2020 1.8 2.0 0.8 2.0 2022/2021 1.9 2.2 1.2 2.0 GDP Consump- deflator Retail Consumer tion (market price prices deflator prices) index index 2012 94.0 94.2 92.3 95.5 2013 96.2 95.9 95.1 97.9 2014 98.1 97.6 97.3 99.3 2015 98.6 98.0 98.3 99.4 2016 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 2017 102.1 101.9 103.6 102.7 2018 104.6 103.5 107.1 105.0 2019 106.6 105.3 111.2 107.0 2020 108.7 107.4 115.1 109.1 2021 110.9 109.5 119.2 111.3 2022 113.1 111.6 123.3 113.5 Annual Growth Rates 2012/2011 2.1 1.6 3.2 2.9 2013/2012 2.3 1.9 3.0 2.6 2014/2013 1.9 1.7 2.4 1.4 2015/2014 0.5 0.4 1.0 0.1 2016/2015 1.4 2.1 1.7 0.7 2017/2016 2.1 1.9 3.6 2.7 2018/2017 2.5 1.6 3.4 2.3 2019/2018 1.9 1.7 3.8 1.9 2020/2019 2.0 2.0 3.5 2.0 2021/2020 2.0 2.0 3.6 2.0 2022/2021 2.0 2.0 3.4 2.0 Notes: (a) Per barrel, average of Dubai and Brent spot prices. Table A3. Gross domestic product and components of expenditure billion [pounds sterling], 2016 prices Final consumption Gross capital expenditure formation Households General Gross Changes in & NPISH (a) govt. fixed in- inventories (b) vestment 2012 1176.0 353.0 282.8 -0.3 2013 1197.7 352.4 292.4 7.9 2014 1222.1 360.1 313.5 14.4 2015 1253.4 365.2 324.0 10.8 2016 1292.6 368.0 331.4 8.4 2017 1316.0 367.5 342.8 -0.3 2018 1333.0 372.0 345.0 -2.2 2019 1354.4 377.5 354.2 -2.2 2020 1370.5 386.1 366.1 -2.2 2021 1387.2 396.6 374.8 -2.2 2022 1404.8 407.9 381.4 -2.2 Percentage changes 2012/2011 1.5 1.2 2.1 2013/2012 1.8 -0.2 3.4 2014/2013 2.0 2.2 7.2 2015/2014 2.6 1.4 3.4 2016/2015 3.1 0.8 2.3 2017/2016 1.8 -0.1 3.4 2018/2017 1.3 1.2 0.6 2019/2018 1.6 1.5 2.6 2020/2019 1.2 2.3 3.4 2021/2020 1.2 2.7 2.4 2022/2021 1.3 2.9 1.8 Decomposition of growth in GDP 2012 1.0 0.2 0.3 0.2 2013 1.2 0.0 0.5 0.5 2014 1.3 0.4 1.1 0.4 2015 1.7 0.3 0.6 -0.2 2016 2.0 0.1 0.4 -0.1 2017 1.2 0.0 0.6 -0.4 2018 0.8 0.2 0.1 -0.1 2019 1.1 0.3 0.4 0.0 2020 0.8 0.4 0.6 0.0 2021 0.8 0.5 0.4 0.0 2022 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.0 Domestic Total Total demand exports final (c) expenditure 2012 1793.7 508.3 2302.1 2013 1839.4 516.0 2355.3 2014 1902.0 527.8 2429.5 2015 1953.2 551.2 2504.2 2016 2000.4 557.0 2557.4 2017 2026.0 586.9 2613.0 2018 2047.8 600.4 2648.1 2019 2083.8 617.8 2701.6 2020 2120.5 638.1 2758.6 2021 2156.3 658.2 2814.6 2022 2191.9 677.6 2869.5 Percentage changes 2012/2011 1.9 1.4 1.8 2013/2012 2.5 1.5 2.3 2014/2013 3.4 2.3 3.1 2015/2014 2.7 4.4 3.1 2016/2015 2.4 1.0 2.1 2017/2016 1.3 5.4 2.2 2018/2017 1.1 2.3 1.3 2019/2018 1.8 2.9 2.0 2020/2019 1.8 3.3 2.1 2021/2020 1.7 3.1 2.0 2022/2021 1.6 2.9 2.0 Decomposition of growth in GDP 2012 1.9 0.4 2.3 2013 2.5 0.4 3.0 2014 3.4 0.9 4.0 2015 2.7 1.1 3.9 2016 2.4 0.4 2.8 2017 1.3 1.4 2.8 2018 1.1 0.7 1.8 2019 1.8 0.9 2.6 2020 1.8 1.0 2.8 2021 1.7 1.0 2.7 2022 1.7 0.9 2.6 Total Net GDP imports (c) trade at market prices (d) 2012 503.9 4.5 1799.5 2013 519.8 -3.7 1836.4 2014 539.5 -11.7 1890.5 2015 569.1 -17.9 1934.9 2016 587.8 -30.9 1969.5 2017 606.9 -20.0 2002.1 2018 612.9 -12.6 2030.1 2019 631.0 -13.2 2065.5 2020 652.2 -14.1 2101.3 2021 672.0 -13.8 2137.4 2022 689.2 -11.6 2/75.2 Percentage changes 2012/2011 3.0 1.4 2013/2012 3.2 2.0 2014/2013 3.8 2.9 2015/2014 5.5 2.3 2016/2015 3.3 1.8 2017/2016 3.2 1.7 2018/2017 1.0 1.4 2019/2018 2.9 1.7 2020/2019 3.4 1.7 2021/2020 3.0 1.7 2022/2021 2.5 1.8 Decomposition of growth in GDP 2012 -0.8 -0.4 1.4 2013 -0.8 -0.5 2.0 2014 -1.3 -0.4 2.9 2015 -1.5 -0.3 2.3 2016 -1.1 -0.7 1.8 2017 -0.8 0.6 1.7 2018 -0.3 0.4 1.4 2019 -0.9 0.0 1.7 2020 -1.0 0.0 1.7 2021 -0.9 0.0 1.7 2022 -0.8 0.1 1.8 Notes: (a) Non-profit institutions serving households, (b) Including acquisitions less disposals of valuables and quarterly alignment adjustment (c) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (d) Components may not add up to total GDP growth due to rounding and the statistical discrepancy included in GDP. Table A4. External sector Exports of Imports of Net goods (a) goods (a) trade in goods (a) billion [pounds sterling], 2016 prices (b) 2012 279.3 373.2 -93.9 2013 277.0 384.6 -107.6 2014 284.1 398.3 -114.3 2015 303.0 415.9 -112.9 2016 299.1 431.7 -132.7 2017 319.2 449.3 -130.2 2018 331.9 452.6 -120.7 2019 346.4 470.4 -124.1 2020 360.3 489.5 -129.2 2021 373.1 506.7 -133.6 2022 384.8 521.0 -136.2 Percentage changes 2012/2011 -0.7 2.5 2013/2012 -0.8 3.0 2014/2013 2.6 3.6 2015/2014 6.7 4.4 2016/2015 -1.3 3.8 2017/2016 6.7 4.1 2018/2017 4.0 0.7 2019/2018 4.4 3.9 2020/2019 4.0 4.1 2021/2020 3.5 3.5 2022/2021 3.1 2.8 Exports Imports Net of of trade in services services services billion [pounds sterling], 2016 prices (b) 2012 228.4 130.2 98.2 2013 239.8 134.8 104.9 2014 244.3 140.9 103.5 2015 248.2 153.3 94.8 2016 257.9 156.1 101.8 2017 267.8 157.6 110.2 2018 268.4 160.3 108.1 2019 271.4 160.5 110.8 2020 277.8 162.7 115.1 2021 285.2 165.4 119.8 2022 292.9 168.2 124.7 Percentage changes 2012/2011 4.6 4.3 2013/2012 4.9 3.5 2014/2013 1.9 4.5 2015/2014 1.6 8.9 2016/2015 3.9 1.8 2017/2016 3.8 0.9 2018/2017 0.3 1.8 2019/2018 1.1 0.1 2020/2019 2.4 1.4 2021/2020 2.7 1.6 2022/2021 2.7 1.7 Export World Terms of Current price trade (d) trade (d) balance competitive ness (c) 2016=100 % of GDP 2012 98.8 85.2 94.5 -3.8 2013 99.0 87.7 95.9 -5.1 2014 102.7 91.6 97.0 -4.9 2015 103.0 96.7 98.8 -4.9 2016 100.0 100.0 100.0 -5.2 2017 97.3 103.3 100.5 -3.9 2018 95.8 106.4 97.4 -3.3 2019 92.6 111.1 95.4 -3.5 2020 90.4 116.6 94.1 -3.8 2021 88.6 121.1 93.0 -3.6 2022 87.4 125.2 92.1 -3.4 Percentage changes 2012/2011 0.6 1.3 0.0 2013/2012 0.2 2.9 1.5 2014/2013 3.8 4.5 1.2 2015/2014 0.3 5.6 1.8 2016/2015 -2.9 3.4 1.2 2017/2016 -2.7 3.3 0.5 2018/2017 -1.6 3.0 -3.1 2019/2018 -3.3 4.4 -2.0 2020/2019 -2.4 5.0 -1.3 2021/2020 -1.9 3.8 -1.2 2022/2021 -1.4 3.4 -1.0 Notes: (a) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (b) Balance of payments basis, (c) A rise denotes a loss in UK competitiveness, (d) Weighted by import shares in UK export markets, (e) Ratio of average value of exports to imports. Table A5. Household sector Average (a) Compen- Total Gross earnings sation of personal disposable employees income income 2016=100 billion [pounds sterling], current prices 2012 93.3 847.2 1480.9 1163.5 2013 95.9 880.7 1532.7 1206.0 2014 96.3 900.0 1577.7 1242.8 2015 97.3 928.5 1665.4 1314.0 2016 100.0 963.4 1701.4 1332.5 2017 102.9 1002.9 1741.8 1352.5 2018 105.5 1042.4 1805.6 1398.3 2019 108.9 1079.3 1868.5 1445.8 2020 112.5 1117.3 1940.8 1500.4 2021 116.2 1156.8 2019.4 1559.5 2022 120.0 1200.0 2103.0 1623.0 Percentage changes 2012/2011 2.1 2.5 3.9 5.0 2013/2012 2.7 3.9 3.5 3.7 2014/2013 0.4 2.2 2.9 3.0 2015/2014 1.0 3.2 5.6 5.7 2016/2015 2.8 3.8 2.2 1.4 2017/2016 2.9 4.1 2.4 1.5 2018/2017 2.6 3.9 3.7 3.4 2019/2018 3.1 3.5 3.5 3.4 2020/2019 3.3 3.5 3.9 3.8 2021/2020 3.3 3.5 4.0 3.9 2022/2021 3.3 3.7 4.1 4.1 Real Final Saving disposable consumption ratio (c) income (b) expenditure billion [pounds per cent sterling], 2016 prices 2012 1237.2 1176.0 87.6 2013 1253.5 1197.7 89.9 2014 1267.1 1222.1 97.1 2015 1333.1 1253.4 102.9 2016 1332.6 1292.6 110.1 2017 1324.7 1316.0 115.1 2018 1336.2 1333.0 119.6 2019 1356.3 1354.4 123.0 2020 1380.3 1370.5 124.4 2021 1406.4 1387.2 125.0 2022 1434.6 1404.8 125.1 Percentage changes 2012/2011 2.8 1.5 2013/2012 1.3 1.8 2014/2013 1.1 2.0 2015/2014 5.2 2.6 2016/2015 0.0 3.1 2017/2016 -0.6 1.8 2018/2017 0.9 1.3 2019/2018 1.5 1.6 2020/2019 1.8 1.2 2021/2020 1.9 1.2 2022/2021 2.0 1.3 House Net prices (d) worth to income ratio (e) 2012 6.2 6.3 2013 6.3 6.2 2014 6.5 6.7 2015 6.8 6.8 2016 7.2 7.4 2017 7.4 7.5 2018 7.5 7.5 2019 7.5 7.4 2020 7.3 7.3 2021 7.2 7.2 2022 7.1 7.0 Percentage changes 2012/2011 0.7 2013/2012 1.1 2014/2013 4.0 2015/2014 3.7 2016/2015 7.0 2017/2016 2.7 2018/2017 0.7 2019/2018 -0.2 2020/2019 -1.7 2021/2020 -1.7 2022/2021 -1.8 Notes: (a) Average earnings equals total labour compensation divided by the number of employees, (b) Deflated by consumers' expenditure deflator, (c) Includes adjustment for change in net equity of households in pension funds, (d) Office for National Statistics, mix-adjusted, (e) Net worth is defined as housing wealth plus net financial assets. Table A6. Fixed investment and capital billion [pounds sterling], 2016 prices Gross fixed investment Business Private General Total investment housing (a) government 2012 166.9 58.1 57.9 282.8 2013 171.7 65.2 55.7 292.4 2014 180.6 71.7 61.1 313.5 2015 187.4 76.0 60.6 324.0 2016 187.0 83.2 61.2 331.4 2017 190.1 90.5 62.3 342.8 2018 192.1 95.5 57.5 345.0 2019 196.3 98.6 59.3 354.2 2020 200.9 102.2 63.0 366.1 2021 205.3 105.9 63.6 374.8 2022 207.5 109.8 64.2 381.4 Percentage changes 2012/2011 7.2 -1.5 -7.7 2.1 2013/2012 2.9 12.2 -3.8 3.4 2014/2013 5.2 10.0 9.7 7.2 2015/2014 3.7 6.0 -0.8 3.4 2016/2015 -0.2 9.4 1.0 2.3 2017/2016 1.6 8.8 1.7 3.4 2018/2017 1.1 5.5 -7.7 0.6 2019/2018 2.2 3.3 3.2 2.6 2020/2019 2.4 3.6 6.2 3.4 2021/2020 2.2 3.7 1.0 2.4 2022/2021 1.1 3.6 0.8 1.8 User Corporate Capital stock cost profit of share of Private Public (b) capital (%) GDP (%) 2012 13.0 24.6 3267.3 1020.8 2013 11.9 24.6 3217.2 1027.6 2014 11.9 25.6 3256.7 1070.8 2015 10.7 24.9 3292.5 1086.1 2016 10.5 25.0 3346.1 1098.7 2017 11.1 24.8 3407.8 1128.7 2018 11.2 24.4 3472.3 1158.4 2019 11.6 24.8 3539.8 1188.6 2020 11.8 25.4 3611.0 1221.7 2021 12.0 25.8 3685.6 1256.5 2022 12.2 26.0 3761.3 1292.7 Percentage changes 2012/2011 -2.9 -1.4 0.7 0.4 2013/2012 -8.1 0.0 -1.5 0.7 2014/2013 -0.2 3.8 1.2 4.2 2015/2014 -9.7 -2.8 1.1 1.4 2016/2015 -2.1 0.6 1.6 1.2 2017/2016 5.5 -0.7 1.8 2.7 2018/2017 1.3 -1.9 1.9 2.6 2019/2018 3.4 1.9 1.9 2.6 2020/2019 1.2 2.1 2.0 2.8 2021/2020 2.2 1.6 2.1 2.8 2022/2021 1.4 1.2 2.1 2.9 Notes: (a) Includes private sector transfer costs of non-produced assets, (b) Including public sector non-financial corporations. Table A7. Productivity and the labour market Employment ILO Employees Total (a) unemploy- Labour ment force (b) 2012 25213 29697 2572 32269 2013 25515 30045 2474 32519 2014 25962 30755 2026 32781 2015 26505 31284 1781 33064 2016 26760 31727 1633 33360 2017 27068 32057 1480 33537 2018 27433 32348 1406 33754 2019 27539 32472 1422 33894 2020 27594 32537 1524 34061 2021 27659 32614 1614 34228 2022 27782 32759 1635 34394 Percentage changes 2012/2011 0.4 1.1 -0.8 0.9 2013/2012 1.2 1.2 -3.8 0.8 2014/2013 1.7 2.4 -18.1 0.8 2015/2014 2.1 1.7 -12.1 0.9 2016/2015 1.0 1.4 -8.3 0.9 2017/2016 1.2 1.0 -9.4 0.5 2018/2017 1.4 0.9 -5.0 0.6 2019/2018 0.4 0.4 1.2 0.4 2020/2019 0.2 0.2 7.2 0.5 2021/2020 0.2 0.2 5.9 0.5 2022/2021 0.4 0.4 1.3 0.5 Productivity Population (2015=100) ILO of working unemployment age (c) Per hour Manufacturing rate 2012 40507 98.3 100.3 8.0 2013 40552 97.9 100.0 7.6 2014 40683 98.5 100.8 6.2 2015 40873 99.5 100.0 5.4 2016 41031 100.0 100.0 4.9 2017 41156 100.7 101.5 4.4 2018 41272 101.6 105.0 4.2 2019 41396 103.0 113.0 4.2 2020 41517 104.5 119.3 4.5 2021 41638 106.1 124.7 4.7 2022 41760 107.5 129.4 4.8 Percentage changes 2012/2011 -0.1 -0.7 -2.1 2013/2012 0.1 -0.4 -0.4 2014/2013 0.3 0.6 0.9 2015/2014 0.5 1.0 -0.9 2016/2015 0.4 0.5 0.0 2017/2016 0.3 0.7 1.5 2018/2017 0.3 0.9 3.4 2019/2018 0.3 1.3 7.7 2020/2019 0.3 1.5 5.5 2021/2020 0.3 1.5 4.5 2022/2021 0.3 1.3 3.8 Notes: (a) Includes self-employed, government-supported trainees and unpaid family members, (b) Employment plus ILO unemployment (c) Population projections are based on annual rates of growth from 2014-based population projections by the ONS. Table A8. Public sector financial balance and borrowing requirement billion [pounds sterling], fiscal years 2014-15 2015-16 Current Taxes on income 386.0 401.4 receipts: Taxes on expenditure 233.1 243.2 Other current receipts 40.9 39.7 Total 660.0 684.3 (as a % of GDP) 35.6 35.8 Current Goods and services 357.6 362.6 expenditure: Net social benefits paid 229.9 232.8 Debt interest 37.4 38.0 Other current expenditure 49.9 49.2 Total 674.8 682.6 (as a % of GDP) 36.4 35.7 Depreciation 39.0 40.1 Surplus on public sector -53.9 -38.4 current budget (a) -2.9 -2.0 (as a % of GDP) Gross investment 75.6 74.2 Net investment 36.6 34.1 (as a % of GDP) 2.0 1.8 Total managed expenditure 750.4 756.8 (as a % of GDP) 40.5 39.6 Public sector net borrowing 90.5 72.5 (as a % of GDP) 4.9 3.8 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b) 83.2 82.5 GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100) 97.6 98.4 Money GDP 1855.0 1912.5 Financial balance under -5.3 -4.2 Maastricht (% of GDP) (c) Gross debt under Maastricht 86.5 87.3 (% of GDP) (c) 2016-17 2017-18 Current Taxes on income 434.2 452.1 receipts: Taxes on expenditure 252.2 258.5 Other current receipts 39.9 39.4 Total 726.3 750.0 (as a % of GDP) 36.5 36.5 Current Goods and services 369.4 374.5 expenditure: Net social benefits paid 233.7 236.9 Debt interest 40.2 44.5 Other current expenditure 49.6 51.9 Total 692.7 707.8 (as a % of GDP) 34.8 34.4 Depreciation 40.8 41.0 Surplus on public sector -7.2 1.2 current budget (a) -0.4 0.1 (as a % of GDP) Gross investment 79.3 81.7 Net investment 38.5 40.7 (as a % of GDP) 1.9 2.0 Total managed expenditure 772.0 789.5 (as a % of GDP) 38.8 38.4 Public sector net borrowing 45.7 39.5 (as a % of GDP) 2.3 1.9 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b) 86.0 85.6 GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100) 100.6 102.3 Money GDP 1989.2 2056.2 Financial balance under -2.9 -1.8 Maastricht (% of GDP) (c) Gross debt under Maastricht 87.3 87.0 (% of GDP) (c) 2018-19 2019-20 Current Taxes on income 472.7 489.9 receipts: Taxes on expenditure 272.0 283.4 Other current receipts 32.8 32.3 Total 777.5 805.6 (as a % of GDP) 36.9 36.9 Current Goods and services 386.4 400.9 expenditure: Net social benefits paid 235.8 240.0 Debt interest 42.9 45.1 Other current expenditure 60.6 62.6 Total 725.8 748.6 (as a % of GDP) 34.4 34.3 Depreciation 40.9 42.2 Surplus on public sector 10.8 14.7 current budget (a) 0.5 0.7 (as a % of GDP) Gross investment 89.3 93.4 Net investment 48.4 51.2 (as a % of GDP) 2.3 2.3 Total managed expenditure 815.1 842.0 (as a % of GDP) 38.7 38.5 Public sector net borrowing 37.6 36.5 (as a % of GDP) 1.8 1.7 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b) 85.0 83.6 GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100) 103.9 105.8 Money GDP 2108.6 2185.6 Financial balance under -1.9 -1.7 Maastricht (% of GDP) (c) Gross debt under Maastricht 85.5 84.2 (% of GDP) (c) 2020-21 2021-22 Current Taxes on income 509.1 531.8 receipts: Taxes on expenditure 293.6 304.4 Other current receipts 33.5 34.7 Total 836.2 870.9 (as a % of GDP) 36.9 37.0 Current Goods and services 418.8 439.1 expenditure: Net social benefits paid 248.7 258.3 Debt interest 47.3 50.0 Other current expenditure 64.7 66.8 Total 779.5 814.2 (as a % of GDP) 34.4 34.6 Depreciation 43.5 44.9 Surplus on public sector 13.2 11.8 current budget (a) 0.6 0.5 (as a % of GDP) Gross investment 98.9 101.4 Net investment 55.4 56.5 (as a % of GDP) 2.4 2.4 Total managed expenditure 878.4 915.5 (as a % of GDP) 38.7 38.9 Public sector net borrowing 42.2 44.7 (as a % of GDP) 1.9 1.9 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) (b) 80.9 78.6 GDP deflator at market prices (2016=100) 107.9 110.0 Money GDP 2267.0 2351.0 Financial balance under -1.8 -1.9 Maastricht (% of GDP) (c) Gross debt under Maastricht 82.8 81.6 (% of GDP) (c) Notes: These data are constructed from non-seasonally adjusted Public Sector Finance data and all fiscal aggregates exclude public sector banks, (a) Public sector current budget surplus is total current receipts less total current expenditure and depreciation, (b) Data for QI. Seasonal adjustment applied in NiGEM results in differences in between the figures here and official unadjusted PSF data, (c) Calendar year. Table A9. Saving and investment As a percentage of GDP Households Companies Saving Investment Saving Investment 2012 6.6 3.3 9.8 9.9 2013 6.1 3.7 7.7 10.3 2014 6.1 3.8 8.6 10.8 2015 6.8 3.9 6.7 10.7 2016 4.8 4.1 7.3 10.7 2017 3.0 4.3 9.4 10.5 2018 2.8 4.4 9.6 10.0 2019 2.8 4.5 9.3 10.0 2020 3.2 4.6 8.9 10.1 2021 3.7 4.7 8.9 10.1 2022 4.1 4.9 8.7 10.1 General government Whole economy Saving Investment Saving Investment 2012 -4.3 2.6 12.1 15.8 2013 -2.4 2.5 11.4 16.5 2014 -2.3 2.6 12.3 17.3 2015 -1.1 2.6 12.3 17.2 2016 0.0 2.5 12.0 17.3 2017 1.1 2.5 13.5 17.4 2018 1.0 2.4 13.5 16.8 2019 1.3 2.4 13.4 16.9 2020 1.3 2.5 13.4 17.2 2021 1.2 2.5 13.8 17.4 2022 1.2 2.5 14.0 17.4 Finance from abroad (a) Net Total Net factor national income saving 2012 3.8 1.0 -0.2 2013 5.1 2.0 -0.9 2014 4.9 2.0 0.1 2015 4.9 2.2 0.1 2016 5.2 2.4 -0.2 2017 3.9 1.5 1.3 2018 3.3 0.7 1.2 2019 3.5 0.3 1.1 2020 3.8 0.1 1.1 2021 3.6 -0.4 1.4 2022 3.4 -0.9 1.7 Notes: Saving and investment data are gross of depreciation unless otherwise stated, (a) Negative sign indicates a surplus for the UK. Table A10. Medium and long-term projections All figures percentage change unless otherwise stated 2014 2015 2016 GDP (market prices) 2.9 2.3 1.8 Average earnings 0.4 1.0 2.8 GDP deflator (market prices) 1.7 0.4 2.1 Consumer Prices Index 1.4 0.1 0.7 Per capita GDP 2.2 1.5 1.0 Whole economy productivity (a) 0.6 1.0 0.5 Labour input (b) 2.8 1.5 1.4 ILO Unemployment rate (%) 6.2 5.4 4.9 Current account (% of GDP) -4.9 -4.9 -5.2 Total managed expenditure (% of GDP) 40.5 39.8 39.0 Public sector net borrowing (% of GDP) 5.2 4.0 2.8 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 81.9 83.5 83.3 Effective exchange rate (2011 = 100) 110.2 116.3 104.8 Bank Rate (%) 0.5 0.5 0.4 3 month interest rates (%) 0.5 0.6 0.5 10 year interest rates (%) 2.5 1.8 1.3 2017 2018 2019 GDP (market prices) 1.7 1.4 1.7 Average earnings 2.9 2.6 3.1 GDP deflator (market prices) 1.9 1.6 1.7 Consumer Prices Index 2.7 2.3 1.9 Per capita GDP 1.0 0.8 1.1 Whole economy productivity (a) 0.7 0.9 1.3 Labour input (b) 1.2 0.5 0.4 ILO Unemployment rate (%) 4.4 4.2 4.2 Current account (% of GDP) -3.9 -3.3 -3.5 Total managed expenditure (% of GDP) 38.5 38.4 38.3 Public sector net borrowing (% of GDP) 1.8 1.8 1.6 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 86.1 85.8 84.9 Effective exchange rate (2011 = 100) 99.3 101.7 101.3 Bank Rate (%) 0.3 0.6 1.1 3 month interest rates (%) 0.4 0.7 1.3 10 year interest rates (%) 1.2 1.4 2.0 2020 2021 2022 2023-27 GDP (market prices) 1.7 1.7 1.8 1.8 Average earnings 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.3 GDP deflator (market prices) 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.1 Consumer Prices Index 2.0 2.0 2.0 2.0 Per capita GDP 1.1 1.2 1.2 1.3 Whole economy productivity (a) 1.5 1.5 1.3 1.4 Labour input (b) 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.4 ILO Unemployment rate (%) 4.5 4.7 4.8 4.9 Current account (% of GDP) -3.8 -3.6 -3.4 -3.2 Total managed expenditure (% of GDP) 38.5 38.7 38.9 39.0 Public sector net borrowing (% of GDP) 1.8 1.9 1.9 1.7 Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 83.3 80.5 78.6 76.0 Effective exchange rate (2011 = 100) 101.5 101.6 101.7 101.5 Bank Rate (%) 1.5 1.9 2.3 3.4 3 month interest rates (%) 1.7 2.1 2.5 3.6 10 year interest rates (%) 2.6 3.1 3.5 4.0 Notes: (a) Per hour, (b) Total hours worked.
Table 1. Summary of the forecast Percentage change unless otherwise stated 2014 2015 2016 GDP 2.9 2.3 1.8 Per capita GDP 2.2 1.5 1.0 CPI Inflation 1.4 0.1 0.7 RPI Inflation 2.4 1.0 1.7 RPDI 1.1 5.2 0.0 Unemployment, % 6.2 5.4 4.9 Bank Rate, % 0.5 0.5 0.4 Long Rate, % 2.5 1.8 1.3 Effective exchange rate 7.4 5.6 -9.9 Current account as % of GDP -4.9 -4.9 -5.2 Net borrowing as % of GDP (a) 4.9 3.8 2.3 Net debt as % of GDP (a) 83.7 83.3 86.2 2017 2018 2019 GDP 1.7 1.4 1.7 Per capita GDP 1.0 0.8 1.1 CPI Inflation 2.7 2.3 1.9 RPI Inflation 3.6 3.4 3.8 RPDI -0.6 0.9 1.5 Unemployment, % 4.4 4.2 4.2 Bank Rate, % 0.3 0.6 1.1 Long Rate, % 1.2 1.4 2.0 Effective exchange rate -5.2 2.4 -0.4 Current account as % of GDP -3.9 -3.3 -3.5 Net borrowing as % of GDP (a) 1.9 1.8 1.7 Net debt as % of GDP (a) 86.2 85.2 84.3 2020 2021 2022 GDP 1.7 1.7 1.8 Per capita GDP 1.1 1.2 1.2 CPI Inflation 2.0 2.0 2.0 RPI Inflation 3.5 3.6 3.4 RPDI 1.8 1.9 2.0 Unemployment, % 4.5 4.7 4.8 Bank Rate, % 1.5 1.9 2.3 Long Rate, % 2.6 3.1 3.5 Effective exchange rate 0.2 0.2 0.1 Current account as % of GDP -3.8 -3.6 -3.4 Net borrowing as % of GDP (a) 1.9 1.9 1.9 Net debt as % of GDP (a) 81.7 78.5 78.8 Notes: RPDI is real personal disposable income. PSNB is public sector net borrowing. PSND is public sector net debt, (a) Fiscal year, excludes the impact of financial sector interventions, but includes the flows from the Asset Purchase Facility of the Bank of England. Annual averages unless stated otherwise. Table B1. Probability event forecasts for 2018Q4 and 2019Q4 annualised % real GDP growth and CPI inflation (extracted from theWBSFS forecast histograms) Real GDP growth (%, p.a.) Year Prob(growth<0%) Prob(growth<1%) Prob(growth<2%) Updated Forecasts (July 2018) 2018Q4 6% 31% 71% 2019Q4 9% 25% 53% Previous Forecasts (April 2018) 2018Q4 7% 26% 58% 2019Q4 8% 20% 49% CPI inflation (%, p.a.) Year Prob(letter) Prob(CPI<1%) Prob(CPI>3%) Updated Forecasts (July 2018) 2018Q4 28% 4% 24% 2019Q4 41% 12% 29% Previous Forecasts (April 2018) 2018Q4 41% 6% 35% 2019Q4 43% 13% 30%