THE LACK OF WAGE GROWTH AND THE FALLING NAIRU.
Bell, David N.F. ; Blanchflower, David G.
THE LACK OF WAGE GROWTH AND THE FALLING NAIRU.
In this note, we argue that a considerable part of the explanation
for the benign wage growth in the advanced world is the rise in
underemployment. In the years after 2008 the unemployment rate
understates labour market slack. Underemployment is more important than
unemployment in explaining the weakness of wage growth in the UK. The
Phillips curve in the UK has now to be rewritten into wage
underemployment space. Underemployment now enters wage equations while
the unemployment rate does not. There is every reason to believe that
the NAIRU has fallen sharply since the Great Recession. In our view the
NAIRU in the UK may well be nearer to 3 per cent, and even below it,
than around 5 per cent, which other commentators including the MPC and
the OBR believe.
Keywords: unemployment; underemployment; wage inflation; hours;
JEL Codes: J31, J42, J22, E31.
**********
There remains a puzzle around the world over why wage growth is so
benign given the low levels of unemployment. In the US, the unemployment
rate at the time of writing is 4.1 per cent and in the UK 4.3 per cent.
The wage growth of production and non-supervisory workers in the US,
which accounts for 82 per cent of private sector workers, has remained
flat at around 2.5 per cent for twenty-four months in a row as the
unemployment rate fell from 4.9 per cent to 3.8 per cent. In the UK wage
growth in April 2018 was 2.5 per cent.
There has also been little wage growth across the OECD. Table 1
reports real wage growth in the period 2000-8 and then from 2008 through
2016 using data from the OECD on annual earnings in local currencies at
2016 prices. Real wage growth across the OECD has been benign in the
years since 2008 and much less than in the period 2000-8. Over this
eight-year period only France, Germany, Iceland, Norway and Sweden saw
average growth rates of above 1 per cent. In the UK real wages grew not
at all and they fell in Greece, Italy and Portugal. The highest growth
rate was 11 per cent in Sweden, compared with the highest in the
previous period of 27 per cent in Norway.
The weakness of wage growth has continued to be a surprise to
policymakers. At the press conference following the rate increase
decision at the FOMC meeting on 13 June 2018, chair Jerome Powell said
"we bad anticipated and many people have anticipated that
wages--that in a world where we're hearing lots and lots about
labor shortages--everywhere we go now, we bear about labor shortages,
but where is the wage reaction? So, it's a bit of a puzzle. I
wouldn't say it's a mystery, but it's a bit of a puzzle.
And one of the things is, you will see pretty much people who want to
get jobs--not everybody--but people who want to get jobs, many of them
will be able to get jobs. You will see wages go up."
Hope springs eternal. The projections from the June meeting showed
that the FOMC members thought that the long-run value for unemployment,
its natural rate, is in the range 4.1 per cent to 4.7 per cent. (1) With
the unemployment rate at 3.8 per cent, there surely, according to the
FOMC, should have been roaring wage pressure, and fear of a wage
explosion is one of the main reasons the Fed is raising rates. The fact
that there is little sign of wage growth picking up is neither a puzzle
nor a mystery. To be clear, the FOMC are raising interest rates to
increase the unemployment rate, which they estimate is currently below
the NAIRU. Hence why, for them, the lack of wage growth is a puzzle and
a mystery.
It is our contention in this paper that a considerable part of the
explanation for the benign wage growth in the advanced world is the rise
in underemployment. This is also reported in table 1, here measured as
the proportion of those who say they are involuntarily part-time as a
percentage of total employment. This measure of underemployment picked
up for most countries after 2008 and then turned down. However, it is
notable that in Australia, Italy, New Zealand and the Netherlands the
rate rose steadily over the period. With the exception of Belgium,
Finland, Germany, Israel and Sweden, the 2016 rate is still above the
2007 rate. It is about the same in Japan. This contrasts with the
unemployment rate, which, as noted above, for example, for the US and UK
has returned to pre-recession levels. In 2016, underemployment rates on
this measure were especially high in Australia (8.9 per cent), France
(7.8 per cent), Spain (9.9 per cent) and Italy (11.9 per cent).
This lack of wage pressure has continued to generate consternation
among policymakers, who still expect nominal annual wage growth to
revert to pre-recession averages of 4 per cent or higher and real wage
growth nearer to 2 per cent. We begin by looking at wages and wage
growth in the UK and how wage growth weakness is related to the rise in
underemployment. We then move on to examine wage growth in 28 OECD
countries and also find that underemployment plays a significant role.
Underemployment now replaces unemployment as the main measure of labour
market slack in the UK. The Phillips curve in the UK has now to be
rewritten into wage underemployment space. We examine arguments that
suggest the natural rate of unemployment, the NAIRU, has fallen sharply.
We present evidence to show that the UK Phillips curve has flattened.
Lack of wage growth in the UK
Policymakers in the UK have been expecting wage growth to take off
for years. For example, in the opening statement at the February 2018
press conference for the Inflation Report Bank of England Governor
Carney argued,
"The firming of shorter-term measures of wage growth in recent
quarters, and a range of survey indicators that suggests pay growth will
rise further in response to the tightening labour market, give
increasing confidence that growth in wages and unit labour costs will
pick up to target-consistent rates."
In large part the MPC has had to reduce its estimates of the
natural rate of unemployment because it has continued to over-estimate
wage growth. Table 2 shows the MPC's forecast for wage growth in
the last seventeen inflation reports dating from February 2014 through
February 2018. Each of these forecasts over-estimated wage growth and
there has been little or no learning from previous errors. The forecasts
have been poor to say the least. Three-year ahead wage forecasts in
every case were around 4 per cent, but over time the forecasts were
reduced as the data showed that a 2 per cent pay norm existed. Pay
settlements have continued to suggest a pay norm over the past several
years of around 2 per cent. Even in February 2018, the MPC is
forecasting wage growth of 3 per cent in 2018, 314 per cent in 2019 and
3Vi per cent in 2020 which seems most unlikely. The outcomes reported in
the final row of the table are the averages for the year-on-year growth
rates by month of AWE Total Pay. It makes little sense to focus on
regular pay excluding bonuses as we are interested in how much workers
are paid rather than what the payments are called; many bonuses are paid
regularly.
Results from the Bank's Agents' annual pay survey are
consistent with an increase in pay growth. The survey recorded an
average pay settlement in the private sector of 2.6 per cent in 2017,
higher than companies had expected in the survey a year ago. In 2018,
the average private sector pay settlement was expected to be 1/2 per
cent higher, at 3.1 per cent. With the exception of construction,
average pay settlements were predicted to rise in all sectors in 2018.
Respondents to the survey had reported that the main factors pushing up
total labour cost growth per employee were the difficulty of recruiting
and retaining staff, employer pension contributions, higher consumer
price inflation and the National Living Wage.
Pay experts XPertHr also reported a rise in settlements at the
start of 2018. Median pay deals in the three months to the end of
January 2018 were 2.5 per cent, which marks an increase on the 2 per
cent median award recorded in every rolling quarter during 2017, and is
the highest figure seen since the three months to the end of March 2014
(when pay awards were also at a median rate of 2.5 per cent). Maybe it
will all change in 2018 and after seventeen failed attempts they will
have it right this time? We doubt it.
In a recent speech Sir John Cunliffe, Deputy Governor at the Bank
of England, took a somewhat more dovelike tone, arguing that there was
likely more labour market slack in the UK due to underemployment. (2)
"A straightforward explanation of why pay growth is subdued at
very low levels of unemployment is that we are under-measuring the
amount of spare capacity --or 'slack'--in the labour market.
Recent trends in the world of work have meant greater (voluntary and
involuntary) self-employment and part-time employment. Measures
incorporating under-employment as well as unemployment--i.e. how much
more people who are in work would like to work--may give a better
indication of the amount of spare capacity in the labour market. In such
a world, low pay is simply telling the policymaker that there is more
labour market slack than the unemployment indicators are registering,
that the output gap is larger than thought and that the economy can grow
at a faster rate without generating domestic inflation pressure."
That seems right.
It is our contention that the MPC's failure to forecast wage
growth appropriately and hence accurately to predict the natural rate of
unemployment is because its members have focused on unemployment and
have largely ignored underemployment. We described in Bell and
Blanchflower (2014) how the MPC argued in May 2014 that it was
appropriate to consider the rise in underemployment but would only take
account of half of this increase because "only around half of the
present gap between actual hours and the estimate of desired hours
represents labour market slack". This judgement was based on
calculations presented in a speech by Martin Weale (2014) which seemed
unusual given that underemployment historically had disappeared when
labour markets tightened. In fact, rather than being above the
unemployment rate, the underemployment rate was below the unemployment
rate for the years 2001-8 because workers wanted, in aggregate, to
reduce their hours, rather than increase them. Hence the Weale
adjustment looks in error. The subsequent path of wage growth indicated
that judgement laid to continuing overestimation of wage growth--the MPC
forecast for wage growth in 2016 was 3V2 per cent and for 2017 it was
314 per cent.
In the United States, underemployment is measured by estimating the
number of part-time workers who say they are part-time for economic
reasons (PTER). In Europe, the estimates of underemployment are based on
the number of part-time workers who want a fulltime job (PTWFT). Figure
1 reports these two measures for the UK and USA, expressed as a
proportion of total employment. In both countries they rose sharply,
peaking at 6.7 per cent in the US in March 2010 and at 4.8 per cent in
the UK between June and August 2013. both series declined more slowly
than the respective unemployment rates, which by the end of 2017 in both
countries had returned to their pre-recession levels. But not so for
both underemployment series, which remained well above their starting
levels. There were similar rises across other European countries. (3)
In previous papers, we have examined underemployment in the UK
using micro-data (Bell and Blanchflower, 2011, 2013, 2018; Blanchflower,
2015). The data used in this and the previous studies are the quarterly
ONS Labour Force Surveys (LFS). In this paper, we use LFS data for the
period April 2001 to December 2017. Individuals may be included for up
to five waves.
The simplest underemployment variable to construct using the LFS is
the 'part time-wants full-time' (PTWFT) category which is
included as one possible response for the variable ftptw. This response
is used to construct the UK time series in figure 1. We are also able to
construct an overhrs (undhrs) variable for those who say they want less
(more) hours at the going wage rate. Those who wish to increase
(decrease) their hours have undhrs (overhrs) set to zero. If individuals
express no preference to change their hours, all three variables are set
to zero.
Questions over hours preferences are asked of all workers, not just
of those who are PTWFT. This potentially matters because the data
suggest that less than a third of aggregate desired increases in hours
come from those who are PTWFT. In the US, only PTER is available from
the Current Population Survey so it is not possible to measure desired
increases or decreases in hours, and therefore impossible to assess the
contribution of PETR to aggregate desired hours increases.
Table 3 reports the distribution of workers available in the LFS
sample in the pre-recession period 2001-8 and post-recession 2009-17. It
identifies five different types of part-time work, one of which is
PTWFT, and full-time classified as under hours for those who wanted more
hours and over hours for those who wanted less, along with their share
of total employment. It reports the number of hours individuals would
like, conditional on saying they wanted to change their hours, which
includes all the PTWFT, who want, on average, to increase their working
week by ten hours in the first period and by eleven hours in the second.
A number of points stand out.
1) There is a rise over time in the proportion of workers who are
PTWFT.
2) There is a roughly equivalent fall in the proportion of
full-timers.
3) The number of under hours reported is positive in all six
categories and rises over time in all of them.
4) There is little or no change over time in the number of over
hours.
5) Overall, only 23 per cent of under hours in the first period and
31 per cent in the second is accounted for by PTWFT.
6) On average the PTWFT want to increase their hours by 10 hours
pre-recession and by 11 post-recession. There also are a lot more of
them post-recession.
Figure 2 presents quarterly time series evidence on the
Bell/Blanchflower underemployment index. It compares the unemployment
rate with the underemployment rate we construct. In the pre-recession
period the underemployment rate is below the unemployment rate and in
the years after 2008 it is above it. Why?
Figure 3 shows how that comes about. It plots aggregate under hours
and aggregate over hours. The under hours series is below the over hours
series before 2008, when the series cross. The over hours series starts
to rise from around 2014, whereas the under hours series seems to have
been rising from around 2004 and then declines in 2014. The two are
quite close by 2017Q4, with the unemployment rate and the
underemployment rate at 4.6 per cent and the underemployment rate at 4.9
per cent (seasonally adjusted).
A number of commentators suggested that this chart shows that the
underemployment slack has been used up, but figure 4 suggests that may
not be correct. In equilibrium, it may be that workers in aggregate want
to reduce their hours. For the entire period 2001Q2 to 2008Q2, the
number of desired hours was negative, because the numbers who wanted
more hours was less than the number wanting less. This suggests there
may be more labour market slack to be used up to get back to the
conditions prevailing between 2002 and 2004, when the monthly
unemployment rate averaged 5.1 per cent.
Wages
We now turn to examine wage determination using the LFS micro-level
data for the period 2001-17. This builds on earlier work estimating wage
equations for the UK in Blanchflower and Oswald (1994a, b) and
Blanchflower and Bryson (2010). Overall, in our LFS sample we have
hourly wage data on 856,366 employees across the pooled data file. We
drop around 10,000 cases in the regressions due to missing values. Wages
are only reported in waves 1 and 5. The self-employed do not report
earnings so therefore they cannot be included in the wage analysis.
Table 4 estimates a log hourly wage equation for employees for the
period 2001-17, and then for 20018, and finally for 2009-17. In our
previous work on underemployment we have not estimated a wage equation
with underemployment and over-employment terms. Table 4 includes both
the under hours and over hours variables which are negative and
positive, respectively, and (highly) significantly so. If the job offers
fewer hours than the employee desires, wage increases will be lower.
In contrast, wages are higher in jobs where hours are longer than
employees wish--a compensating wage differential. In addition,
coefficients on all five categories of part-time working are
significantly negative, where full-time is the excluded category.
Part-timers who want extra hours are paid less than part-timers who are
content with their hours. It seems that having workers in jobs where
they want more hours keeps wages down as they accept lower pay,
conditional on their characteristics.
In a recent paper, Hong et al. (2018) estimated relationships
seeking to explain wage changes in 29 advanced countries from 2000 to
2016. They augmented the unemployment rate in these relationships with
measures of underemployment, arguing that headline unemployment rates
are becoming less able to capture accurately labour market slack. They
found that "involuntary part-time employment appears to have
weakened wage growth even in economies where headline unemployment rates
are now at, or below, their averages in the years leading up to the
recession." In a wage change equation, the involuntary part-time
employment share enters negatively and significantly in most
specifications. Across all countries, on average, a 1 percentage point
increase in the involuntary part-time employment share is associated
with a 0.3 percentage point decline in nominal wage growth. It should be
said, though, that their equations look to be mis-specified as they do
not contain a lagged wage term.
The authors have very kindly shared their data with us. It
comprises an unbalanced panel of 688 observations on wages, involuntary
employment as a share of total employment and the unemployment rate on
28 countries. (4) Table 5 reports the results of estimating wage change
equations that also include a highly significant lagged wage term. Both
the unemployment rate and the involuntary share variables enter
significantly negative. Looking at column 4 of table 5 a 1 percentage
point increase in the involuntary part-time rate is associated with a
0.14 percentage point decline in nominal wage growth. This is over and
above the impact of the unemployment rate.
It is clear that the unemployment rate fails to explain fully the
level of slack prevailing in most OECD countries since the Great
Recession. But it does seem that underemployment cannot, on its own,
explain low levels of wage growth. A further possibility exists, namely
that there has been a structural shift in the UK economy such that the
natural rate of unemployment, or the NAIRU, has shifted downwards. The
data seem also to support this contention. Price inflation and wage
inflation both remain benign. And the UK seems to be a long way from
full employment.
The natural rate of unemployment or the NAIRU in the UK has fallen
In his 1968 address to the American Economic Association, Milton
Friedman (1968) famously argued that the natural rate of unemployment
can be expected to depend upon the degree of labour mobility in the
economy. (5) The functioning of the labour market will thus be shaped
not just by long-studied factors such as the generosity of unemployment
benefits and the strength of trade unions but also by the nature, and
inherent flexibility and dynamism, of the housing market.
Friedman also made clear that the natural rate of unemployment is
not unchanging: "I do not suggest that it is immutable or
unchangeable. On the contrary, many of the market characteristics that
determine its level are man-made and policy-made." Friedman goes on
to argue, for example, that the strength of union power and the size of
the minimum wage all make the natural rate higher; their declines in
recent years then make the natural rate lower. He further suggests that
improvements in labour exchanges, in availability of information about
job vacancies and labour supply, all of which have been enhanced by the
internet, tend to lower the natural rate. That, we contend, is what has
happened. The natural rate of unemployment in advanced countries has
fallen sharply since the Great Recession.
Friedman continues: "The natural rate of unemployment is such
that at a lower rate of unemployment indicates that there would be an
excess demand for labor that will push up wage rates. A higher level of
unemployment is an indication that there is an excess supply of labor
that will produce downward pressure on real wage rates" (p.8). Then
Chair of the US Federal Reserve, Janet Yellen, in a speech in September
2017 raised the possibility that indeed, the natural rate has fallen and
perhaps by a lot: (6) "some key assumptions underlying the baseline
outlook could be wrong in ways that imply that inflation will remain low
for longer than currently projected. For example, labor market
conditions may not be as tight as they appear to be, and thus they may
exert less upward pressure on inflation than anticipated."
And later:
"The unemployment rate consistent with long-run price
stability at any time is not known with certainty; we can only estimate
it. The median of the longer-run unemployment rate projections submitted
by FOMC participants last week is around 4Vi per cent. But the long-run
sustainable unemployment rate can drift over time because of demographic
changes and other factors, some of which can be difficult to
quantify--or even identify--in real time. For these and other reasons,
the statistical precision of such estimates is limited, and the actual
value of the sustainable rate could well be noticeably lower than
currently projected."
That makes sense. It is our contention that the natural rate of
unemployment in most advanced countries is well below 4 per cent and
perhaps even below 3 per cent. Employment rates and participation rates
can rise, and unemployment rates can fall and by a lot. (7)
Globalisation has weakened worker's bargaining power. Migrant flows
may have put downward pressure on wages and greased the wheels of the
labour market as their presence increased mobility. The decline in the
home ownership rate, which slows job creation and increases
unemployment, has helped mobility and lowered the natural rate
(Blanchflower and Oswald, 2013).
The Great Recession exposed underlying economic weaknesses and
displayed to the populace the possibility of catastrophic declines in
house prices and pension pots. The balance between capital and labour
shifted once again towards capital. Workers are frightened in a way that
they weren't pre-recession. They are afraid that firms will move
production facilities abroad or out-source: in addition, a public sector
pay freeze has helped moderate private sector pay increases. (8) Workers
are frightened and have less bargaining power than before. Hence the
natural rate has fallen and that is why there has been no spurt in wage
growth as the unemployment rate fell from 8 per cent to 6 per cent and
from 6 per cent to 4 per cent.
As William Beveridge noted in 1944, "full employment means
that unemployment is reduced to short intervals of standing by, with the
certainty that very soon will be wanted in one's old job again or
will be wanted in a new job that is within one's powers...it means
that the jobs are at fair wages, of such a kind, and so located that the
unemployed men can reasonably be expected to take them: it means, by
consequence, that the normal lag between losing one job and finding
another will be short" (p.18). We are a long way from that. We are
standing by.
Staiger, Stock and Watson (1997a) examined the precision of
estimates of the natural rate of unemployment. They note that the NAIRU
"is commonly taken to be the rate of unemployment at which
inflation remains constant. Unfortunately, the NAIRU is not directly
observable.... The task of measuring the NAIRU is further complicated by
the general recognition that, plausibly, the NAIRU has changed over the
post-war period, perhaps as a consequence of changes in labor
markets." They further note that "a wide range of values of
the NAIRU are consistent with the empirical evidence" and
crucially, that the trigger point--when wages and prices start to
rise--is poorly estimated. For example, they estimate a NAIRU for the US
of 6.2 per cent in 1990 with a 95 per cent confidence interval of 5.1
per cent to 7.7 per cent. In Staiger, Stock and Watson (1997b) they
argue that the tightest of the 95 per cent confidence intervals for 1994
in the US is 4.8 per cent to 6.6 per cent. They conclude that "it
is difficult to estimate the level of unemployment at which the curve
predicts is constant rate inflation."
It is our contention that the NAIRU has fallen sharply in the UK
post the Great Recession and is likely closer to 3 per cent--and maybe
well below it--than to 4 per cent or so as claimed by the MPC and
others.
In a recent speech MPC member Gertjan Vlieghe argues that a
credible Phillips curve still exists in the UK. We disagree. His main
evidence was, firstly, a plot of wage changes against the unemployment
rate using AWE data published by the Office of National Statistics
monthly for the period 2001-17. He focused on regular pay, excluding
bonuses, which makes little sense given that workers don't care
what their pay is called. No other wage series in the world separates
bonuses from total pay. Vlieghe showed that the data indicated a
negative relationship between unemployment and wage growth in the UK
since 2001.
Figure 5 plots the 3mth/3mth monthly AWE weekly wage growth total
pay series and the monthly unemployment rates.
The best fit line for these data is
Wage change = 7.1204 - 0.7181 x Unemployment rate (1)
It is clear that there are three distinct areas in the data marked
as circles, triangles, and squares. The first is top left plotted as
circles, between March 2001 and March 2008 which everywhere has wage
growth over 2 per cent to over 6 per cent. This is the pre-recession
zone. Then there is the recession zone marked as triangles in the bottom
right, from April 2009 to December 2014 along with a transition path
from unemployment rates of around 5.5 per cent to nearly 8.5 per cent.
The third area is plotted as squares, from January 2015 to March 2018
also with a transition path as the unemployment rate falls from over 7
per cent to 5 per cent and below.
We re-estimate Phillips curves on these three zones. For simplicity
we omit the recession months of April 2008--May 2009. In part that is
because of the three outlier months of February-April 2009, with
significant negative wage growth, which is driven by a single outlier
month of data for February 2009 of -5.8 per cent. AWE weekly wages drop
from 433 [pounds sterling] in January to 418 [pounds sterling] in
February and back to 435 [pounds sterling] in March.
It is clear that the plot in equation (1) doesn't seem to
apply to the first two periods as the Phillips curve slopes up. It
slopes down in the recovery period but is much shallower than in
equation (1) for the entire period.
a) Pre-recession zone--April 2001-March 2008
Wage change = 2.4479 + 0.3580 x Unemployment rate (2)
b) Post-recession zone--June 2009-December 2013 (9)
Wage change = -5.9831 + 0.9574 x Unemployment rate (3)
c) Recovery zone--January 2014-March 2018
Wage change = 5.2993 - 0.6168 x Unemployment rate (4)
If we plug in 4.2 per cent unemployment rate, prevailing in April
2018 into equation (1) it forecasts wage growth of 4.1 per cent against
the actual rate of 2.6 per cent. Equation (4) with the same unemployment
rate predicts wage growth of 2.7 per cent.
We also estimated a best fit line using AWE total pay averaged by
quarter against our quarterly underemployment rate. The best fit line is
Wage change = 5.9133 - 0.4751 x Underemployment rate (5)
Figure 6 then presents three plots Phillips curves using our
underemployment rates, against AWE total pay data averaged by quarter
for the pre-recession (2001Q2 to 2008Q1), immediate post-recession
(2009Q3 to 2013Q4) and later period (2014Q1 to 2017Q4). For simplicity,
again we omit the five recession quarters of 2008Q2-2009Q2. As with the
unemployment rate in the first period the best fit line slopes upwards.
The second period is essentially flat. Finally, there is a downward
sloping Phillips curve in underemployment space in the latter period. It
has the following equation.
Wage change = 3.0812 - 0.1340 x Underemployment rate (6)
At the most recent underemployment rate for 2017Q4 of 4.9 per cent,
wage growth is predicted by equation (6) to be 3.6 per cent, whereas in
the latter period it is 2.4 per cent. At an underemployment rate of 3.8
per cent, its historical low since 2001, wage growth is predicted to be
only 2.6 per cent. An obvious issue is whether wage growth would rise
rapidly once full-employment has been reached but there is nothing in
the data to suggest this is imminent. In April 2015 AWE 3mth/3mth total
pay wage growth was 2.4 per cent with an unemployment rate of 5.5 per
cent. Three years later, in April 2018 the unemployment rate was 4.2 per
cent and wage growth was 2.6 per cent.
A hypothesis of no structural break in the relationship between
underemployment or unemployment and wage inflation is rejected for each
year from 2006 onward using standard Wald tests. In addition, the
Elliott-Muller (2006) test for the absence of persistent time variation
in the underemployment coefficient is decisively rejected (test
statistic = -45.232, 1 per cent critical value = -11.05) with a similar
result being obtained for unemployment.
The second piece of evidence in Vlieghe's speech was an
econometric analysis estimating a wage growth --Phillips curve--equation
using 256 observations at the industry level from 1997 through 2017.
That is 21 years by 12 industries. He includes a lagged unemployment
rate and a lagged dependent variable and a set of sector dummies, but
does not include a full set of year effects, which is what would be
required to find credible results. In any case his finding suggests an
implausibly large impact of unemployment on pay --he finds that a
"one percentage point increase in the unemployment rate in a sector
lowers wage growth in that sector by half a per cent in the following
year. " So, given that the unemployment rate has fallen from 8.5
per cent to 4.3 per cent then wage growth should have risen by
approximately 2 percentage points. It has not, of course.
The UK unemployment rate hit 8.5 per cent in September-November
2011, when the AWE total pay annual 3mth/3mth growth rate was 1.9 per
cent. In October-December 2017 the unemployment rate was 4.3 per cent
while December 2017 wage growth was 2.5 per cent, so that goes in the
wrong direction. Note that the earnings of full-time workers from the
quarterly LFS averaged 4.0 per cent in the years from 1998 through
January-March 2008 and 1.9 per cent subsequently. (10) Wage growth in
the four quarters of 2011 averaged 1 per cent versus 1.9 per cent in the
four quarters of 2017.
The concern is that aggregating wages and unemployment by industry
sector may be a particular problem in the most recent years. First, new
entrants to the labour market, such as the young, don't have an
industry. Secondly, temporary workers, of which there are around 1.5
million, will likely switch industries frequently. Third, workers shift
between industries more than they do between regions. A computer
specialist works for three months for a retail store; then for three at
a bank; then for three in a university and then three at an electronics
company. A worker's present industry may not be their next or last.
The gig economy has meant people move industries more than they did in
the past. Fourth, the longer the spell of unemployment the less likely
it is that the unemployed individual will return to their prior
industry. Industry seems the wrong level of aggregation in a post Great
Recession world.
Vlieghe's analysis cannot rule out the possibility of a
structural break in the series. In private communications Jan admitted
as much.
"The point of the analysis was not about whether sectoral or
regional data is preferred. We tried both, we were agnostic ex ante. As
explained (in footnote 20), the results for regional data showed that
inclusion of year dummies rendered the regional unemployment rate
insignificant. After inspection of the data, we concluded that this is
because, aside from permanent level differences, there is not enough
cross-sectional variation across regions, everything moves too closely
with the aggregate. There is more cross-sectional variation across
sectors, so sectoral unemployment effects on wages are better
identified. Whether there is more or less substitutability across
regions or sectors is an empirical issue. Our results suggest there is
sufficiently low substitutability across sectors to identify a
significant effect of sectoral unemployment on sectoral wages, and the
effect does not appear to be weakening over time.
Our results are consistent with a downshift in the Phillips curve
(less wage pressure for given unemployment rate). The downshift could be
due a number of factors as we explain in the speech, and one of those
factors is indeed a reduction in the NAIRU, which we discuss
explicitly."
We explored this issue further using the same LFS micro-data for
the years 2001-17. We constructed unemployment, underemployment and
wages by twenty regions across 66 quarterly waves, using earnings
weights, and then constructed an equivalent annual wage change measure
from the LFS across four waves and then a four-wave lag. In total there
are 1260 observations. Using a broadly equivalent specification to
Vlieghe's, we were unable to find any significant unemployment
effects on wage growth, but we do find underemployment effects on both
weekly and hourly pay. The results are reported in table 6.
We first regress the log of hourly pay on a four-quarter lag and
the unemployment rate, along with full sets of wave and region dummies.
The wave dummies pick up the outlier months with negative growth
referred to earlier. We initially include the log of the unemployment
rate which is insignificant. We then add an underemployment measure, the
log of the number of additional hours the underemployed would like. This
enters significantly negative in the second column and remains
significant in the third column when the unemployment rate is dropped.
The results are the same in the final three columns that use weekly
wages. The Phillips curve in the UK has now to be rewritten into wage
underemployment space. (11)
We conclude the relationship between wage growth and labour market
slack is much flatter in the recent period than in previous periods. The
Phillips curve in the UK has now to be rewritten in wage and
underemployment space and is much flatter than in the past. The
implication is that the NAIRU is lower than it was in the past. That is
not to say that wage growth will not rise towards 4 per cent, but not
until there is much less slack in the UK labour market.
Productivity and employment
Figure 7 plots productivity growth rates per worker and employment
growth rates for the UK from 2001. (12) Employment growth picked up as
productivity slowed. Employment growth rates, according to the ONS, were
as follows--where we calculate the average monthly annual growth rates
of employment.
1970s 0.4%
1980s 0.6%
1990s 0.2%
2000-7 1.0%
2008-10 -0.1%
2011-17 1.3%
The Great Recession saw a fall in employment from 2008 through
2010. Then after that employment rose at an average record annual pace
of 1.3 per cent. Over the period January 2010 through January 2018, the
employment rate rose from 58.0 per cent to 60.9 per cent, while real
average weekly wages fell from a high of 522 [pounds sterling] in
February 2008 to 488 [pounds sterling] in January 2018, or by over 6 per
cent. In contrast, in the USA employment rates fell from 62.9 per cent
to 60.4 per cent while real weekly wages in the private sector rose from
$343.72 to $369.72 (in 1982-4 dollars).
As background we should also note that productivity growth has
declined steadily over time in the UK. According to the ONS productivity
rates were as follows.
1960s 2.88%
1970s 2.48%
1980s 2.07%
1990s 2.04%
2000s 1.01%
2010-17 0.73%
To put this in context, UK productivity is 17 per cent below the
average for the rest of the G7 in 2015. (13) By 2015, the UK produces in
five days what it takes the US, Germany and France to produce in four.
There is little or no sign of catch-up. It is hardly surprising that
wages have not risen--something structural has happened. Productivity
growth is a third of what it was from 1960-2000.
Higher productivity tends to lead to higher real wages and is
associated with higher consumption levels and better health. (14) It
seems that another contributory factor to slowing wage growth has been
the falling rate of productivity increase. The very low wage growth
rates in the last few periods have occurred when output per head was
growing at less than 1 per cent and employment growth was slowing. (15)
Low paid workers were hired. There was an industry-wide slowdown in
business investment during the crisis and subdued growth since, which
helps to explain the productivity slowdown.
Consistent with that is the recent work by Haltiwanger et al.
(2018) in the United States, who found strong evidence of a firm wage
ladder that was highly procyclical. During the Great Recession, this
firm wage ladder collapsed, with net worker reallocation to higher wage
firms falling to zero. They found that in the Great Recession, movement
out of the bottom rung of the wage ladder declined by 85 per cent, with
an associated 40 per cent decline in earnings growth. They find that
upward progress from the bottom rung of the job ladder declines by 40
per cent in contractions, relative to expansions.
Productivity is low when wage growth is low. A pay freeze in the
public sector that has existed in the UK since 2010 has not helped to
motivate staff. Workers on low pay are not motivated to work harder. In
addition, in contrast to the United States, the employment rate in the
UK has recovered to post-recession levels. (16) In both countries
private sector unionisation rates have collapsed so workers appear to
have less bargaining power than in the past. (17)
Blundell et al. (2014) have noted that the supply of workers in
this recession was higher than in previous recessions: the labour supply
curve has shifted to the right. However, despite the increase in supply
occurring among groups towards the lower end of the jobs market, they
found there is strong evidence against the composition or quality of
labour hypothesis as a potential explanation for the reduction in wages
and hence productivity that we observe. They found that there are more
individuals willing to work at any given wage and thus that there is
likely to be greater competition for jobs. As a consequence, Blundell et
al. argue, workers are likely to have lower reservation wages than in
the past and seem to attach more weight to staying in work (because
their expected time to find another job is longer than in the past) than
on securing higher wages and are thus willing to accept lower wages in
exchange for holding onto their job.
Stansbury and Summers (2018), for the US, find evidence of linkage
between productivity and compensation: over 1973-2016, 1 percentage
point higher productivity growth has been associated with 0.7 to 1
percentage points higher median and average compensation growth and with
0.4 to 0.7 percentage points higher production/ nonsupervisory
compensation growth. They further find the relationship between average
compensation and productivity in Canada, West Germany (pre-unification),
the UK and the USA to be strong and positive with the effects somewhat
weaker for France, Italy and Japan.
UK forecasters, including the Bank of England, have consistently
predicted that productivity growth would recover to a rate close to its
1970s-2000s average. The Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR)
continued to assume this recovery would occur, although reasons were
never given. Figure 8 is taken from the OBR's March 2017 Forecast
Evaluation Report and shows successive and essentially unchanging and
terrible OBR productivity forecasts and the actual data. The black line
on the chart shows the outcome over the period from 2009 through 2017
along with sixteen successive forecasts. Each forecast implausibly
slopes up sharply and they are basically parallel to each other. Each of
them forecasts an explosion of productivity growth which never happened
but there was zero learning and no change. The latest March 2017 report
showed a very slight shallowing. Each assumed the productivity puzzle
was solved when it wasn't. There was no learning.
Of interest is the timing of the collapse of productivity growth.
This follows almost exactly from the introduction of austerity in the
UK's Budget of June 2010. The changes took a little time to have an
impact so if we assume 2011Q2 as a reasonable starting point for the
effects of austerity, output per hour was 103.7, with 2009 = 100. By
2017Q2 it was 103.9.
In October 2017, in its Forecast Evaluation Report (FER) the OBR
produced a mea culpa admitting it had been wrong all along; the
productivity puzzle had not been solved and the UK economy was not set
to mean revert to pre-recession levels.
"One recurring theme in past FERs has been productivity
falling short of our forecasts.... Our rationale for basing successive
forecasts on an assumed pick-up in prospective productivity growth has
been that the post-crisis period of weakness was likely to reflect a
combination of temporary, albeit persistent, influences. And as those
factors waned, so it seemed likely that productivity growth would return
towards its long-run historical average." (p.6)
And later:
"While we continue to believe that there will be some recovery
from the very weak productivity performance of recent years, the
continued disappointing outturns, together with the likelihood that
heightened uncertainty will continue to weigh on investment, means that
we anticipate significantly reducing our assumption for potential
productivity growth over the next five years in our forthcoming November
2017 forecast," (p.7).
Flat productivity led to flat wage growth.
Conclusion
Wage growth continues to be close to 2.5 per cent despite low
unemployment rates in the UK and the US in particular. It seems that the
unemployment rate understates labour market slack. But perhaps more
importantly, something has changed in the years since the Great
Recession. The very low level of the unemployment of 4.3 per cent
prevailing in the UK at the time of writing may not indicate that the UK
is close to full-employment.
Our findings suggest that some of the reason for that is because
the unemployment rate understates labour market slack. Underemployment
is more important than unemployment in explaining the weakness of wage
growth in the UK. In the pre-recession years the underemployment rate
hit a low of 3.8 per cent in 2004Q1 and was associated with steadily
rising wage growth which hit 4.5 per cent in 2005Q3 (Appendix 1). There
is every reason to believe that now it could go even lower--perhaps even
below 3 per cent--before there is an equivalent up-tick in wage growth.
The Phillips curve in the UK has now to be rewritten into wage
underemployment space.
There is every reason to believe that the natural rate of
unemployment has fallen sharply since the Great Recession. That is why
there hasn't been a burst of wage growth as the unemployment rate
has fallen, from 8 per cent to 6 per cent to close to 4 per cent. In our
view the NAIRU in the UK may well be nearer to 3 per cent, and even
below it, than around 5 per cent which other commentators including the
MPC and the OBR believe.
In the years 2000-8 there was no relationship between high wage
growth of around 4 per cent and the relatively low unemployment rate.
Then the Great Recession came along and everything shifted down with
lower wage growth and higher unemployment. Once recovery happened there
was a transition to a new flatter equilibrium with low unemployment of
less than 5 per cent and low wage growth of around 2 per cent.
A big question is how low can unemployment go. William Beveridge
(1960) tells the story in the prologue to his book, written sixteen
years after the report was first published, that as a 'conservative
rather than unduly hopeful aim' of the amount of temporary idleness
that might be expected under full employment he had suggested in 1944 a
figure of 3 per cent of the labour force at any time. When Keynes saw
this number, he wrote to Beveridge to say that he saw no harm in aiming
at 3 per cent but that he would be surprised if it could go so low in
practice. During the twelve years from 1948 through 1959 Beveridge was
surprised to find the unemployment rate averaged 1.5 per cent with no
wage explosion. Here are the UK numbers: 194850=1.5 per cent; 1951 = 1.2
per cent; 1952 = 2.0 per cent; 1953 = 1.6 per cent; 1954 = 1.3 per cent;
1955=1.1 per cent; 1956 = 1.2 per cent; 1957 = 1.4 per cent; 1958=2.1
per cent and 1959 = 2.2 per cent. Unemployment may surprise on the
downside again.
Underemployment continues to push down on wage pressure even though
the unemployment rate is low. Over and above that we present evidence
that the UK Phillips curve has flattened and as a result the UK NAIRU
has shifted down. The combination of elevated underemployment and a
flattened Phillips curve means that wage growth is not going to take off
any time soon.
NOTES
(1) Economic projections of Federal Reserve Board members and
Federal Reserve Bank presidents under their individual assessments of
projected appropriate monetary policy, June 2018.
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtab120180613.pdf.
(2) Cunliffe, J. (2017), The Phillips curve: lower, flatter or in
hiding?', Speech given at the Oxford Economics Society, Bank of
England, 14 November.
(3) See 'Underemployment and potential additional labour force
statistics', Eurostat, May 2017.
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/
index.php/Underemployment_and_potentialadditionallabourforcestatistics.
(4) Australia 1999-2016; Austria 1995-2016; Belgium 1983-2016;
Canada 1976-2016; Czech Republic 1998-2016; Denmark 1983-2016; Estonia
2005-16; Finland 1985-2016; France 1993-2016; Germany 1992-2016; Greece
1996-2016; Iceland 2007-16; Ireland 1990-2016; Israel 1996-2016; Italy
1983-2016; Japan 2002-16; Lithuania 2005-16; Netherlands 1983-2016; New
Zealand 1986-2016; Norway 1989-2016; Portugal 1996-2016; Slovak Republic
1994-2016; Slovenia 2005-16; Spain 1987-2016; Sweden 1976-2016;
Switzerland 1991-2016; United Kingdom 1983-2016; United States
1998-2016.
(5) Friedman explained what the natural rate of unemployment is and
what determines it. "The 'natural rate of unemployment',
in other words, is the level that would be ground out by the Walrasian
system of general equilibrium equations, provided there is imbedded in
them the actual structural characteristics of the labor and commodity
markets, including market imperfections, stochastic variability in
demands and supplies, the cost of gathering information about job
vacancies and labor availabilities, the costs of mobility, and so
on."
(6) Janet L. Yellen, 'Inflation, uncertainty, and monetary
policy', speech at the Prospects for Growth: Reassessing the
Fundamentals, 59th Annual Meeting of the National Association for
Business Economics, Cleveland, Ohio, 26 September, 2017.
(7) There is an additional possibility that participation rates
rise and those who were previously OLF move to unemployment and start
looking for jobs which could imply the unemployment rate might rise
rather than fall.
(8) For work at NIESR on the importance of the interaction between
public and private sector pay, see Box B in Kara et al. (2017).
(9) If the regression is run from April 2008 through December 2013
the Phillips curve slopes down.
Wage change = 7.5023 - 0.7546 x Unemployment rate.
At 4.2% unemployment rate this equation predicts wage growth of
4.3%.
(10) Available as spreadsheet earn 05.x1s from the ONS.
(11) Recent work at NIESR by Lopresto and Kara (2017) confirms this
finding of a role for underemployment. They find that the involuntary
part-time rate enters significantly negative in a time-series wage
growth equation.
(12) The employment annual growth rates were simply taken from the
ONS labour market release a0lmar2018.xls, Table I. We used the data for
Jan-Mar for QI; Apr-Jun for Q2; Jul-Sep for Q3 and Oct-Dec for Q4.
Output per worker was obtained from the ONS series Output per workers:
Whole Economy SA: Index 2015=100, UK.
https://www.ons.gov.uk/employmentandlabourmarket/peopleinwork/labourproductivity/timeseries/a4ym/prdy.
(13) 'International comparisons of UK productivity (ICP),
final estimates, 2015', Statistical Bulletin, ONS, 5 April 2017.
(14) Silvana Tenreyro, 'The fall in productivity growth:
causes and implications', Peston Lecture, Queen Mary University of
London 15 January 2018.
(15) Rates were 2015Q3 0.4% 2015Q4 -0.1 %; 2016Q1 0.3%; 2016Q2
-0.5%; 2016Q3 0.4%; 2016Q4 0.9%; 2017Q1 0.8%; 2017Q2 0.8%; 2017Q3 0.9%.
(16) The 16+ employment rate in the US in January 2008 was 62.9%
versus 60.4% in January 2018. In contrast in the UK they were 60.4% and
60.9% respectively on these dates--source BLS and ONS.
(17) According to www.unionstats.gsu.edu private sector
unionisation rates in the US in 2017 were 6.5% down from 10.3% since
1995 versus, according to the ONS, 13.4% in the UK down from 21.4% in
1995. https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/616966/tradeunion-membership-statistical-bulletin-2016-rev.pdf.
REFERENCES
Bell, D.N.F. and D.G. Blanchflower (2011), 'Youth
underemployment in the UK in the Great Recession', National
Institute Economic Review, January, pp. RI-RII.
--(2013), 'Underemployment in the UK revisited', National
Institute Economic Review, 224, May, pp. F8-F22.
--(2014), 'Labour market slack in the UK', National
Institute Economic Review, 229 August, F4-F11.
--(2018), 'Underemployment and the lack of wage pressure in
the UK', National Institute Economic Review, 243, February, pp.
R53-R61.
Beveridge, W.H. (I960), Full Employment in a Free Society. A
Report, Routledge, NY first published in 1944.
Blanchflower, D.G. (2015), 'As good as it gets? The UK Labour
Market in recession and recovery', National Institute Economic
Review, 231, February, pp. F76-F80.
Blanchflower, D.G. and Bryson, A.J. (2010), 'The wage impact
of trade unions in the UK public and private sectors', Economic a,
77, 305, pp. 92-109, January.
Blanchflower, D.G. and Oswald, A.J. (1994a), The Wage Curve,
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
--(1994b), 'Estimating a British wage curve, 1973-1990',
Economic Journal, September, pp. 1025-43.
--(2013), 'Does high home-ownership impair the labor
market?' NBER Working Paper No. 19079, May.
Blundell, R., Crawford, C. and Jin, W. (2014), 'What can wages
and employment tell us about the UK's productivity puzzle?',
Economic Journal, 124, May, pp. 307-407.
Elliott, G. and Muller, U.K. (2006), 'Efficient tests for
general persistent time variation in regression coefficients',
Review of Economic Studies, 73(4), pp. 907-40.
Friedman, M. (1968), 'The role of monetary policy',
American Economic Review, LVIII, I, March, pp. 1-17.
Haltiwanger, J.C., Hyatt, H.R., Kahn, L.B. and McEntarfer, E.
(2018), 'Cyclical job ladders by firm size and firm wage',
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 10(2), pp. 52-85.
Hong, G.H., Koczan, Z., Lian, W. and Nabar, M. (2018), 'More
slack than meets the eye? Recent wage dynamics in advanced
economies,' IMF Working Paper /18/50, IMF Research Department.
Kara, A., Hantzsche, A., Leonard, J., Lenoel, C., Piggott, R.,
Thamotheram, C. and Young, G. (2017), 'Prospects for the UK
economy' National Institute Economic Review, October, pp. F10-F42.
Lopresto, M. and Kara, A. (2018), 'Weakness in wage growth;
what is driving it', 4 May, NIESR Blog,
https://www.niesr.ac.uk/blog/weakness-wage-growth-what-driving-it.
Staiger, D., Stock, J. and Watson, M. (1997a), 'How precise
are estimates of the natural rate of unemployment?', in Romer, C.D.
and Romer, D.H. (Eds), Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy,
University of Chicago Press.
--(1997b), 'The NAIRU, unemployment and monetary policy',
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1), Winter, pp. 33-49.
Stansbury, A.M. and Summers, L.H. (2018), 'Productivity and
pay: is the link broken?', NBER Working Paper 24165.
Weale, M. (2014), 'Slack and the labour market', speech
given at the Thames Valley Chamber of Commerce, 20 March.
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2014/speech716.pdf.
Appendix 1. UK unemployment and underemployment
rates, and growth in average weekly earnings
Year Quarter Unemploy- Underemploy- AWE total
ment rate ment rate pay growth
rate
2001 Q2 5.0 4.3 5.1
Q3 5.1 4.7 5.2
Q4 5.2 4.5 4.7
2002 Q1 5.2 4.5 4.9
Q2 5.2 4.4 4.2
Q3 5.3 4.9 3.5
Q4 5.1 4.2 3.0
2003 Q1 5.1 4.4 3.0
Q2 5.0 4.1 3.1
Q3 5.0 4.5 3.4
Q4 4.9 3.9 3.9
2004 Q1 4.8 4.0 3.4
Q2 4.8 3.8 3.6
Q3 4.7 4.2 3.8
Q4 4.7 3.9 3.9
2005 Q1 4.7 4.0 4.3
Q2 4.7 4.2 4.1
Q3 4.8 4.4 4.5
Q4 5.1 4.6 4.0
2006 Q1 5.2 4.9 4.0
Q2 5.5 5.1 4.0
Q3 5.5 5.5 3.5
Q4 5.5 5.3 4.1
2007 Q1 5.5 5.4 3.9
Q2 5.3 5.0 4.1
Q3 5.3 5.4 4.7
Q4 5.2 4.8 4.0
2008 Q1 5.2 5.0 4.2
Q2 5.3 5.2 3.9
Q3 5.8 6.4 3.3
Q4 6.3 6.7 3.3
2009 Q1 7.0 7.9 2.5
Q2 7.7 8.8 2.1
Q3 7.9 9.3 1.4
Q4 7.8 8.7 1.1
2010 Q1 8.0 9.1 1.8
Q2 7.9 8.7 1.3
Q3 7.8 9.4 2.2
Q4 7.9 9.1 2.2
2011 Q1 7.8 9.1 2.0
Q2 7.9 9.2 2.1
Q3 8.3 10.1 1.6
Q4 8.4 9.8 1.9
2012 Q1 8.2 9.8 1.5
Q2 8.0 9.6 1.8
Q3 7.9 9.6 1.8
Q4 7.8 9.8 1.3
2013 Q1 7.9 9.6 0.8
Q2 7.7 9.6 1.0
Q3 7.6 9.3 0.7
Q4 7.2 9.6 0.9
2014 Q1 6.8 9.3 1.1
Q2 6.3 9.4 0.5
Q3 6.0 8.5 1.2
Q4 5.7 8.0 1.8
2015 Q1 5.6 7.4 2.4
Q2 5.6 7.4 2.9
Q3 5.3 6.4 2.6
Q4 5.1 6.5 2.1
2016 Q1 5.1 6.3 2.4
Q2 4.9 6.2 2.3
Q3 4.9 5.5 2.4
Q4 4.8 5.5 2.6
2017 Q1 4.6 5.3 1.8
Q2 4.4 5.5 2.1
Q3 4.3 5.0 2.2
Q4 4.3 4.9 2.5
David N.F. Bell * and David G. Blanchflower **
* Stirling Management School, University of Stirling, IZA and CPC.
E-mail. d.n.f.bell@stir.ac.uk. ** Dartmouth College, Stirling Management
School, University of Stirling. IZA, Bloomberg and NBER. E-mail:
David.G.Blanchflower@dartmouth.edu. We thank Doug Staiger, Gertjan
Vlieghe, Malhar Nabar and Andy Levin for helpful comments and
suggestions.
Caption: Figure 1. Part-time for economic reasons (USA) and
part-time can't find full-time (UK) as % of employment
Caption: Figure 2. Unemployment and underemployment rates
Caption: Figure 3. Aggregate more and fewer desired hours
Caption: Figure 4. Difference between the underemployment and
unemployment rates
Caption: Figure 5. Monthly wage Phillips curve and unemployment,
March 2001-March 2018
Caption: Figure 6a. UK underemployment rate Phillips curve,
2001Q2-2008Q1
Caption: Figure 6b. UK underemployment rate Phillips curve,
2009Q3-2014Q2
Caption: Figure 6c. UK underemployment rate Phillips curve,
2014Q3-2017Q4
Caption: Figure 7. Productivity growth per worker and employment
growth rates %, 2001Q1 -2017Q4
Caption: Figure 8. Successive OBR productivity forecasts (output
per hour) for the UK, 2010-17
Table 1. Annual real wage growth % in 2016 constant
prices and involuntary part-time as a % of total
employment, 2007, 2012 and 2016
Involuntary
Real wage growth part-time rate
2000-8 2008-16 2007 2012 2016
Australia 12 5 6.7 7.6 8.9
Austria 8 1 2.7 2.5 3.6
Belgium 2 2 3.6 2.6 2.3
Canada 14 9 4.0 5.1 4.8
Denmark 14 9 3.1 4.3 3.7
Finland 14 3 2.9 3.2 0.9
France 9 10 5.3 5.3 7.8
Germany 2 10 5.3 3.9 3.1
Greece 18 -18 2.4 4.8 6.9
Ireland 21 8 2.0 0.2 7.2
Italy 4 -1 5.4 9.7 11.9
Japan -1 0 4.5 5.2 4.4
Netherlands 7 6 2.0 3.9 4.2
New Zealand 20 8 3.9 4.9 5.4
Portugal -2 -3 3.4 5.4 4.7
Spain 5 2 4.1 9.6 9.9
Sweden 17 11 7.7 8.1 5.9
Switzerland 8 5 1.8 2.5 2.9
United Kingdom 15 0 2.4 5.0 3.9
United States 8 7 0.8 1.8 1.3
Source: OECD and Hong et al. (2018).
Table 2. Seventeen successive MPC wage forecasts, for
2014-20 (%)
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2014 Q1 2 3/4 3 3/4 3 3/4
2014 Q2 2 1/2 3 1/2 3 3/4
2014 Q3 1 1/4 3.3 4
2014 Q4 1 1/4 3.3 3 3/4 3 3/4
2015 Q1 3 1/2 4 4
2015 Q2 2 1/2 4 4
2015 Q3 3 3 3/4 4/2
2015 Q4 2 1/2 3 3/4 4 4/4
2016 Q1 3 3/4 4/4
2016 Q2 3 3/4 4
2016 Q3 2 3/4 3 3/2
2016 Q4 2 1/2 2/4 3/4 3 3/4
2017 Q1 3 3/4 3 1/4
2017 Q2 2 3/2 3 3/4
2017 Q3 2 3 3 1/4
2017 Q4 2/4 3 3 1/4 3 1/4
2018 Q1 2/2 3 3 1/4 3 1/2
Outcome 1.1 2.6 2.4 1.9
Table 3. Distribution of under and over hours
2001-8
Under Over % of total
hours hours hours
worked
Part-time: student 2.8 0.2 4.0
Part-time: ill or disabled 2.7 0.5 0.6
Part-time: could not find full-time job 10.0 0.1 2.2
Part-time: did not want full-time job 1.4 0.5 18.3
Part-time: no reason given 5.1 0.4 0.1
Full-time 0.4 1.3 74.8
Per cent accounted for by PTWFT 23%
2009-17
Part-time: student 3.6 0.1 3.6
Part-time: ill or disabled 3.2 0.5 0.7
Part-time: could not find full-time job 11.0 0.1 4.1
Part-time: did not want full-time job 1.7 0.5 18.1
Part-time: no reason given 5.4 0.3 0.2
Full-time 0.6 1.3 73.3
Per cent accounted for by PTWFT 31%
Table 4. Hourly wage equations, 2001-17
2001-2017 2001-2008
Under hours -0.0058 (41.72) -0.0048 (23.91)
Over hours 0.0031 (23.58) 0.0031 (17.65)
PT student -0.1791 (57.56) -0.1792 (44.70)
PT disabled -0.2560 (40.38) -0.2488 (28.42)
PTWFT -0.1760 (53.29) -0.1714 (33.63)
PT DWFT -0.1239 (87.87) -0.1363 (71.88)
PT no reason -0.1141 (7.50) -0.1272 (6.19)
Age 0.0538 (201.70) 0.0566 (158.52)
Age squared -0.0006 (185.79) -0.0006 (148.08)
Male 0.1611 (146.68) 0.1596 (107.47)
NVQ 4 -0.2462 (133.98) -0.2437 (95.97)
NVQ 3 -0.3965 (257.32) -0.4055 (187.66)
Apprenticeship -0.5238 (209.04) -0.5443 (170.06)
NVQ 2 -0.5192 (341.58) -0.5292 (260.61)
Other qualifications -0.5979 (343.55) -0.6267 (260.66)
No qualifications -0.7210 (339.35) -0.7364 (274.64)
Years tenure 0.0185 (109.19) 0.0190 (82.39)
Tenure squared -0.0002 (44.94) -0.0003 (34.80)
Wave dummies 66 30
Region dummies 19 19
Constant 1.07731 1.0541
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.4250 0.4287
N 842,929 446,968
2009-2017
Under hours -0.0066 (33.94)
Over hours 0.0029 (14.79)
PT student -0.1740 (35.69)
PT disabled -0.2632 (28.70)
PTWFT -0.1757 (39.98)
PT DWFT -0.1094 (52.09)
PT no reason -0.1081 (4.80)
Age 0.0528 (131.12)
Age squared -0.0006 (119.27)
Male 0.1623 (99.79)
NVQ 4 -0.2544 (95.48)
NVQ 3 -0.3912 (177.54)
Apprenticeship -0.4955 (123.14)
NVQ 2 -0.5160 (222.37)
Other qualifications -0.5713 (225.79)
No qualifications -0.6930 (196.68)
Years tenure 0.0179 (71.42)
Tenure squared -0.0002 (29.07)
Wave dummies 35
Region dummies 19
Constant 1.3075
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.3768
N 395,961
Source: LFS 2001Q4-2017Q4.
Notes: excluded category; FT; no qualifications.
Table 5. Time series log wage and wage growth equations
in an unbalanced country panel, 1976-2016
Dependent variable Log [W.sub.t] Log [W.sub.t]
Log unemployment [rate.sub.t-1] -0.0336 (15.03) -0.0289 (9.66)
Log [Wage.sub.t-1] 0.9931 (1026.25) 0.9558 (368.52)
Log PTWFT% -0.0143 (7.54) -0.0114 (4.79)
Country dummies No Yes
Year dummies No No
Constant 0.1424 0.2598
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.9994 0.9998
N 686 686
Log [W.sub.t]-
Dependent variable Log [W.sub.t] Log [W.sub.t-1]
Log unemployment [rate.sub.t-1] -0.0239 (7.25) -0.0239 (7.25)
Log [Wage.sub.t-1] 0.9063 (119.96) -0.0937 (12.40)
Log PTWFT% -0.0144 (5.91) -0.0144 (5.91)
Country dummies Yes Yes
Year dummies Yes Yes
Constant 0.3312 0.3312
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.9998 0.6333
N 686 686
Source: Hong et al. (2018) and own calculations.
Table 6. Time series log wage equations
in a quarterly region panel, UK, 2002-17
Hourly pay
Log [Wage.sub.t-4] 0.0999 (3.43) 0.0991 (3.41)
Log unemployment [rate.sub.t-1] 0.0092 (0.72) 0.0140 (1.10)
Log # extra hours wanted -.0417 (3.02)
Constant 1.8898 1.8496
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.9201 0.9206
N 1260 1260
Hourly pay Weekly pay
Log [Wage.sub.t-4] 0.0990 (3.41) 0.0941 (3.19)
Log unemployment [rate.sub.t-1] 0.0089 (0.68)
Log # extra hours wanted -0.0398 (2.91)
Constant 1.8784 5.1576
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.9206 0.9195
N 1260 1260
Weekly pay
Log [Wage.sub.t-4] 0.0922 (3.14) 0.0918 (3.13)
Log unemployment [rate.sub.t-1] 0.0140 (1.08)
Log # extra hours wanted -0.0446 (3.18) -0.0428 (3.07)
Constant 5.1234 5.1544
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.9201 0.9201
N 1260 1260
Source: LFS.
Notes: all equations include a full set of region and wave dummies.
COPYRIGHT 2018 National Institute of Economic and Social Research
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.