THE WORLD ECONOMY.
Naisbitt, Barry ; Hantzsche, Arno ; Lennard, Jason 等
THE WORLD ECONOMY.
Last year saw global economic growth of 3.8 per cent, the strongest
since 2011. In addition, our analysis in the last issue (see Lennard,
2018) showed that this growth had been broad-based, with a very high
degree of synchronisation across countries. While it is plausible to
expect these two features of the global economy--relatively robust
growth and synchronisation --to continue in the short term, there are a
number of uncertainties about the outlook, reflected in the fan chart
for global GDP growth shown in figure 1, which is drawn to reflect
normal business cycle risks and does not include the downside risks
associated with any possible escalation of protectionist trade policies.
For some advanced economies, GDP growth in the first quarter of the
year was weaker than expected, partly related to the adverse weather in
the quarter. In addition, the data so far indicate slow export growth as
a factor. An immediate issue is whether the first quarter was a
'soft patch' or whether it marked something deeper. Initial
readings from the second quarter, including PMI surveys which have shown
some strengthening in the Euro Area, UK and US and continuing labour
market trends that have indicated a tightening rather than a weakening
market, suggest the temporary 'soft patch' narrative is
plausible. The indicators suggest that growth in the second quarter will
be stronger than in the first, especially in the US supported by the
pro-cyclical fiscal boost.
As a consequence, our overall forecast judgement is little changed
from May. The global economy looks set to continue growing this year at
a pace slightly below 4 per cent, with a broadly synchronised pattern of
growth. We continue to expect that further growth in the advanced
economies will lead to more evident pressures on capacity and skills and
that these will be reflected in (probably limited) upward pressure on
inflation and policy moves towards less accommodative monetary policy.
Robust growth in the advanced economies is helping the emerging market
economies, especially the commodity producers, and emerging economies as
a whole are continuing to expand more rapidly than the advanced
economies. But as the forecast horizon extends, a combination of slowing
domestic demand growth (partly from demographics: see Aksoy et al, 2017)
and slightly higher interest rates in the advanced economies are
expected to feed into slower growth in some emerging market economies.
In turn, this will contribute to slower overall global growth.
An important factor in the global forecast is the expectation that
the pace of growth in China will gradually slow, as the economy makes
its transition and investment spending growth plays a less prominent
part in determining overall annual growth. The scale of China's
contribution to global growth is such that a slowing is also reflected
in slightly slower global growth. Reflecting anticipated trends in
demographics, productivity and structural factors, our medium-term
forecast continues to expect global growth to run at around 3.5 per cent
a year.
Two features of the outlook are particularly noteworthy. First, the
possible escalation of protectionist trade policies are providing an
increased downside risk to the outlook. The announcements by President
Trump on 1 March of tariff increases, initially on steel and aluminium
imports from a range of countries and effective from 1 June on products
from a small number of focused sectors, are unlikely to have a
significant negative effect on the global outlook. On 22 March further
tariffs on a wider range of Chinese goods prompted retaliation. To date,
the scale of the trade under consideration has been limited, with
affected total Chinese trade of $50 billion, of which $34 billion was
effective from 6 July. The initial actions are included in the baseline
forecast. However, the President announced on 11 July a possible wider
extension on Chinese trade of up to $200 billion and $500 billion has
also been mentioned, which would mark a major change in both the size
and breadth of tariff action. Box A provides a simulation of our NiGEM
model that considers the effects of various tariff changes (see also
Hantzsche and Liadze, 2018; Liadze and Hacche, 2017). The possibility of
further impositions and retaliations is a risk for the prospects for
both world trade and global economic growth. The change in direction of
US trade policy is a significant one and has added uncertainty to the
trading environment.
Secondly, stronger growth and falling unemployment rates have led
to increasing concerns about reduced spare capacity, signs of skills
shortages in recruiting and some anticipation of pressure building on
wage and price inflation. So far, generally inflation figures have
failed to register this build-up in capacity utilisation but there are
some signs of rising annual inflation in Germany, France and the US. As
we raised in the February Review, (1) oil prices are now about 60 per
cent higher than their low in June 2017. The issue of whether continued
growth and tighter labour markets will lead to faster wage growth and
eventually higher inflationary pressure and further monetary policy
tightening remains a key risk to the profile of growth and inflation in
the forecast. The US has led the way in terms of reducing the extent of
monetary accommodation, and our expectation remains that this process
will spread. Our forecasts include gradual increases in policy rates in
the UK and Euro Area over the medium term which are broadly in line with
recent market expectations. The forecast does not assume dramatic
changes in policy interest rates--rather a general gradual upward path
of interest rates.
Recent developments and the baseline forecast
Recent economic developments
The developing data for the first quarter of 2018 have been
dominated by indications of slower growth in the advanced economies,
particularly in Japan, the Euro Area and the UK (figure 2). While part
of this can be explained by one-off factors such as the adverse weather,
a potential concern is that it could possibly be an early sign of a
broader picture of slower growth. After world trade growth outpaced GDP
growth in 2017, export growth surveys have generally pointed to slower
growth in early 2018, possibly related to uncertainty following the
protectionist rhetoric and tariff actions from the US. These possibly
temporary factors in the first quarter have to be balanced against more
positive survey readings for growth in the second quarter, especially in
the US, and the apparent absence of 'one-off' negative factors
in the quarter.
With the US expansion now the second longest on record, one feature
of commentaries has been some understandable interest in whether a
recession might be in prospect. The term spread (see Lenoel, 2018) has
moved little over the past three months and the expansion phase looks
set to continue. But, although the expansion has been long, it has not
been strong (figure 3). US GDP is only 21 per cent above the trough in
mid-2009. By contrast, the slightly shorter expansion after 1982 saw a
38 per cent rise in GDP, suggesting that the longevity of the expansion
should not be taken as an indicator of its likely duration.
While growth in the Euro Area generally surprised on the upside in
2017, with growth of 2.6 per cent in 2017 showing a rebound from
2016's dip in growth (1.8 per cent), the overall pace of growth (at
0.7 per cent quarter-on-quarter in each quarter in 2017) masked a
divergence between countries within the Euro Area.
Spain grew strongly (by 3.1 per cent) and continued that strong
performance in the first quarter of 2018, while several other countries
saw weaker growth in the first quarter, particularly in exports. As a
result of stronger growth, unemployment has fallen but still remains
high by pre-recession standards. Inflation within the Euro Area has so
far remained subdued, enabling the ECB to continue its accommodative
monetary policy. However, the ECB announced at its June meeting that
continued quantitative easing would end in December 2018 and that policy
interest rates were expected to remain at present levels at least
through the summer of 2019.
Japan saw an unexpected fall in GDP in the first quarter, largely
due to a reversal of the building of inventories, and growth is expected
to resume. Among emerging economies, India and China continue to show
growth well ahead of the global average and Turkey and Vietnam performed
strongly in 2017 with output expanding by 7.4 and 6.7 per cent
respectively, although in Turkey it was accompanied by rapid inflation.
Argentina and Venezuela have continued to deal with economic problems
and both have seen very rapid inflation. While continued low inflation
elsewhere is notable (figure 4), the general pick-up in demand has
benefitted commodity producers and oil prices, in particular, having
risen strongly over the past two years.
Our revised baseline forecast
Taking the recent news as a whole, forward-looking developments
have not been sufficient to lead us to make any major changes to our
view for the global outlook. Global growth is expected to run at 3.9 per
cent this year and 3.8 per cent in 2019, after 3.8 per cent last year.
Into the medium term, the pace of growth is forecast to settle at about
3 1/2 per cent, reflecting a continued narrowing of output gaps in the
recovery from the Great Recession, demographic effects (especially in
the major industrial economies) and a gradual deceleration in growth in
China. There are clearly risks around the forecast and these are
illustrated by the fan chart for global economic growth (figure 1).
Our expectation remains for inflation to continue to be higher than
in 2014-16 but to be broadly in line with policy targets. The reductions
in unemployment rates and some reports of skilled labour shortages,
together with the slow pace of investment since the crisis, could mean
that capacity pressures are building and these would likely lead to
higher inflation. Our policy rate expectations are for a gradual
tightening internationally, reflecting a response to potential pressures
from a narrowing of output gaps.
Monetary policy
Within the advanced economies, the US Federal Reserve raised policy
rates three times in 2017 and has already acted twice so far this year
(in March and June). At least one further increase this year is implied
in the Federal Reserve's latest 'dot plot' chart and
further increases are anticipated in 2019 as policy rates continue to be
'normalised'. However, the profile of policy rates remains
dependent on the economic outlook and is not pre-set. The fiscal boost
this year will feed through and one policy concern will be whether this
contributes to capacity problems and creates pressures for inflation to
rise above its target, something that it has failed to do consistently
so far.
In contrast, the ECB is still continuing its policy of quantitative
easing, with policy rates held at the lower bound, although the monthly
scale of purchases has been scaled back and is due to end in December
2018. Given currency linkages, the pressure from US policy rate rises is
likely to be transmitted to some emerging market economies, perhaps with
some concerns about non-financial companies' debt intensifying
(Naisbitt, 2018). With economies at different phases of the cycle, the
pattern of potential policy and market rate movements is diverse.
Financial and foreign exchange markets
Bond yields in the US rose in May, with 10-year yields up to over 3
per cent, touching their highest level since mid2011, and 5-year rates
at 2.90 per cent, regaining their high of June 2009. Since mid-May both
yields have eased back, with 5-year at around 2.75 per cent and 10-year
at around 2.85 per cent, at mid-July. In terms of longer-term
'guidance', the Federal Reserve's implied expectation for
longer-term rates from the 'Dot Plot' chart stood at 2.75 per
cent in December 2017. This has now risen to 3 per cent and market
implied rates are at similar levels.
Movements in 10-year government bond yields in the Euro Area have
shown a more steady path so far this year, with rates holding below 1.50
per cent since July 2015. This reflects the policy actions of the ECB,
which has held the rate on the deposit facility at -0.4 per cent and
continued with its quantitative easing policy. The latter is set to
reduce further after September, but guidance has been that policy rates
are expected to be held at least through much of 2019, providing
continued support for low longer-term rates.
Although US short-term interest rates have risen as the US economy
has performed relatively strongly, the US dollar depreciated against the
euro through 2017 by almost 20 per cent, with a low point reached in
early February 2018. After holding at around 1.23 [euro], from late
April the US dollar has appreciated by around 6 per cent against the
euro. This pattern also broadly holds in trade-weighted exchange-rate
terms. This marks a contrast with the euro, which has depreciated since
late April by around 2 per cent. For the Japanese Yen effective exchange
rate, after appreciating by around 3 per cent during January and
February, the second quarter was a period of stability.
With equity markets continuing their multi-year rise in 2017 (the
S&P index rose by 19 per cent through the year, the Nikkei by 19 per
cent and the FTSE 100 by 7 per cent), equity prices rose to record
levels. This resulted in some warnings in press and market commentaries
about the possible over-valuation of stocks. It appeared that some of
the market risks had started to materialise in February when strong US
labour market news prompted worries of sharper interest rate rises. The
S&P index fell by 8.5 per cent in just over a week and this fall
reverberated in other markets. However, markets calmed and the S&P
rose by 6 per cent over the following month. Announcements of US tariffs
on steel and automobiles and then on trade with China on 22 March led to
further market jitters late in the first quarter. In the second quarter
markets saw more of a consolidation, with the S&P 500 up 3 per cent,
the Nikkei up 4 per cent and the FTSE 100 up 8 per cent.
The Vix index, (2) an indicator of financial market volatility or
uncertainty (sometimes referred to as the 'fear index' for
equity markets), traded at a lower level (by about 3 points) in the
second half of 2017 than a year earlier. But the first quarter of this
year saw much more volatility, including a spike on 5 February following
strong data. After falling back (to 14) in early March, it peaked again
(at 25) on 23 March. Since then volatility has gradually reduced,
reaching a low of 12 in early June and it has remained close to that
level to mid-July despite the escalating trade and tariff rhetoric.
Commodity markets
So far in 2018 oil prices have continued their sustained increase
since early 2016. The Brent oil price has increased to around $75 per
barrel and gives an upward revision to our assumptions. The sustained
rise is being reflected in higher consumer prices for petrol and energy.
For other commodities, The Economist all-items commodity price
index (in dollar terms) fell by about 5 per cent in the second quarter
after a 1 per cent rise in the first quarter, with food prices falling
by about 7 per cent after an earlier 6 per cent rise. Metals were up in
the second quarter by just under 1 per cent after a fall of 6 per cent
in the preceding quarter.
Risks to the global forecast
Our near-term global growth projections are for continued
relatively robust growth but, with the focus on tariffs and speculation
about a 'trade war', the downside risks have increased over
the past three months and upside risks have receded. Our view is that
the near-term risks around the central forecast are broadly balanced.
However, the uncertainties around the possibility of a worse outcome
into the medium term have increased with the more strident protectionist
talk on tariffs and trade. Whether the recent strident talk will be
matched by further actions is yet to be seen.
On the positive side, the synchronised nature of relatively strong
activity could well have further to run, with domestic demand growth in
economies being boosted by investment spending growth which is
responding to stronger global demand. If inflation remains subdued, this
transmission mechanism could provide a boost to global growth. Monetary
policy has remained accommodative across most economies since the Great
Recession and, if low inflation continues, this could continue and
support a faster pace of growth.
While the output of economies has expanded, the pace of that
expansion has been relatively slow. From a longer-term viewpoint, a key
feature of the expansion has been the disappointing rate of productivity
growth. This, as discussed in the February Review (Kazalova and
Naisbitt, 2018), has been a generalised feature in the advanced
economies, with productivity growth disappointing relative to previous
experience. The exact causes of this shortfall are not agreed (Riley et
al, 2018) but it is possible that a strong and synchronised expansion
could lead to a stronger path for productivity growth. Stronger
investment spending, in particular, could add to future capacity and
result in stronger productivity growth, so supporting higher future real
earnings growth. If productivity growth does strengthen, the upswing
could continue more strongly than anticipated.
In addition, the fiscal measures in the US could add more momentum
than expected, both in the US economy and through import demand
channels, leading to a stronger outlook in the near term. There may also
be scope for other economies to increase fiscal support, as discussed in
Box B.
Downside risks to the global outlook come from several possible
sources. The gradual tightening of US monetary policy since 2015 has
been accompanied by the unemployment rate falling to an 18-year low of
3.8 per cent in May. Despite some worries about increased capacity usage
leading to inflationary pressures, to date US inflation has been
persistently below its target. But low inflation might not persist and
the Federal Reserve could face tough decisions to raise interest rates
more rapidly and substantially. At a time when equity markets appear to
be richly valued relative to what might be regarded as fundamentals (see
figure 5 for one such possible indicator), such a change in policy
stance could lead to a fall in equity prices and so in household wealth,
which would have direct and indirect (via reduced consumer confidence)
negative effects on consumer spending, in turn reducing import demand.
The synchronised nature of the recent global expansion may, of
itself, present a risk to sustained growth. Greater synchronisation may
reflect greater connectivity of economies and so imply that a shock that
is unique to one economy may be more readily transmitted to other
economies. The imposition of tariffs and the direct effects of higher
import costs could be supplemented by lower export growth due to
retaliation and, so, reduced risk sharing across economies. In addition,
uncertainty over future trade policy has increased this year with
President Trump's pronouncements on tariffs. It is difficult to
know how far the most recent announcements with regard to trade with
China will become reality or what other possible trade actions President
Trump may initiate, but heightened protectionist rhetoric turning into
action and retaliation adds a substantial downside risk to the outlook
for global trade growth (see Hantzsche and Liadze, 2018). With continued
robust growth in China remaining a key contributing factor to global
economic growth, any internal economic downside risks in China (perhaps
due to the rapid credit growth that has already led to concerns being
expressed) could be added to by downside external trade shocks.
Finally, the potential downside risk to global economic prospects
from the build-up of debt--in both public and private sectors--is the
subject of the Commentary in this issue (see also Naisbitt, 2018). As in
the 2000s, higher debt can create a potential vulnerability even if the
precise trigger that could realise that risk is not evident. After a
long period of ultra-low interest rates perhaps the key risk is that
borrowers may have grown too accustomed to low debt service costs and
that even gradual and limited increases in interest rates may lead to a
need for larger than anticipated changes in spending and saving patterns
with adverse consequences for continued economic growth.
Box A. Trade wars--any winners?
On 6 July President Trump's administration imposed new tariffs on
goods worth $34bn of annual imports from China. China retaliated
with a package matching the magnitude of that of the US. At the
time of writing, further tariffs covering $ 16bn worth of imports
are expected to follow by both countries in the coming weeks. As
the tit-for-tat trade battle escalates, both the US and China have
threatened to levy tariffs up to the full range of imports (worth
about $500 billion per year in the case of US imports from China).
We use NIESR's Global Econometric Model (NiGEM) to run stylised
scenarios to investigate the impact of these increases in tariffs
on US and Chinese imports, continuing earlier work (Liadze and
Hacche, 2017; Hantzsche and Liadze, 2018), which shows that tariff
imposition not only harms the economies that the tariffs are aimed
at, but also the country that imposes them, as well as spilling
over to other economies who might be innocent bystanders in the
trade dispute. (1) We consider only the direct effects of tariffs
and do not take account here of the negative impact that
uncertainly is expected to have on business investment, which may
exacerbate the fall in output The Bank of England governor's
analysis of tariffs, also using NiGEM, does take account of this
effect (2)
In the simulations initially 25 per cent duties are assumed to be
applied to $50bn worth of imports from both the US and China. This
is followed by the introduction of a 10 per cent levy first on
$200bn worth of US imports from China, then expanded further to
cover the remaining $250bn worth of imports. Within NiGEM higher
tariffs work by raising import prices in the tariff imposing
country which leads ultimately to lower demand and output through a
number of channels including lower consumption, lower investment
and lower exports to countries that are disadvantaged by higher
tariffs. Shocks are applied exogenously for 3 years after which
they are allowed to return back to their initial levels.
The simulation results (see figure A1) suggest that the loss of
output from the first round of tariffs by both the US and China
would be modest, reducing GDP by less than 0.2 per cent relative to
what it would otherwise have been. However, the adverse impact on
GDP in both countries is significantly higher if duties are imposed
on a larger range of imports from China into the US. Even though
the shocks are of a bilateral nature, given the share of the US and
China in global output and trade (about 32 and 40 per cent
respectively), there is a material negative spillover effect on
other economies.
In all simulations, higher tariffs lead to an increase in domestic
inflationary pressures via an increase in import prices (see figure
A2). A tit-for-tat trade dispute leads to an increase in domestic
prices of a comparable magnitude in both China and the US, but the
impact on inflation in the US becomes more pronounced after the US
levy tariffs on a wider range of imports from China.
NOTES
(1) An expanded version of NiGEM v2.17b is used, enabling tariffs
to be imposed between die US and all countries. Monetary policy
reacts to deviations from nominal GDP and inflation targets;
financial markets are forward looking and respond to expected
changes in interest rates, so that if expectations of future
interest rates are raised, following tariff imposition, then bond
and equity prices will fall and the exchange value of the domestic
currency will increase immediately, bringing some effects forward.
(2) 'From protectionism to prosperity', speech by Mark Carney,
Governor of the Bank of England, 5 July 2018.
REFERENCES
Hantzsche, A. and Liadze, I. (2018), 'Box D, The World Economy',
National Institute Economic Review, 244, F46-47.
Liadze, I. and Hacche, G. (2017), 'The macroeconomic implications
of increasing tariffs on US imports', NiGEM Observations, No 12.
This box was prepared by Iana Liadze.
Box B. Intra-Euro Area spillovers--simulating the effects of fiscal
stimulus
What would European policymakers do if there was a severe slowdown
in the global economy now? Monetary policy ammunition is largely
exhausted and many countries appear to have little space to
implement expansionary fiscal measures. In this Box, we address the
heterogeneity of fiscal positions in the Euro Area, with a view to
examining the effectiveness of fiscal expansions undertaken
individually and collectively in stimulating aggregate demand in
the monetary union.
Fiscal policies implemented by a country in isolation have an
effect on other countries through trade linkages and resource
flows. These spillover effects are particularly important in the
Euro Area, given the comprehensiveness of its special agreements,
integration among member states and its common currency.
Nonetheless, there are large differences across Euro Area countries
in the amount of room that individual countries have available to
carry out fiscal expansions. Figure B1 shows the size of public
debt and the budget balances in Euro Area countries, and highlights
the degree of dispersion amongst them.
The medium-term budgetary objectives (MTOs) defined by the European
Commission in the Stability and Growth Pact are set to ensure sound
fiscal policies. According to those criteria, we assume here that a
country has 'fiscal space' (i.e. the space to expand fiscal policy)
if the levels of government debt-to-GDP and budget balance are
broadly in line with those commitments. Considering the five major
Euro Area economies, only Germany and the Netherlands appear to
have fiscal space to increase public spending. However, amongst the
constrained countries, Italy and France have recently legislated
for or are calling for fiscal measures. In this Box, we assess the
benefits that come with a more collective approach with regard to
fiscal policy.
The analysis uses the National Institute's Global Econometric Model
(NiGEM) to examine the effect of a co-ordinated Euro Area fiscal
expansion and an expansion conducted by member states in isolation.
The different scenarios simulate an expansion to government
spending of the same magnitude (1 per cent of GDP) and duration
(for two years), before they gradually revert to baseline. Monetary
policy and exchange rates are kept exogenous for the duration of
the shock.
Table B1 below shows the effect of fiscal expansions on first year
output and contrasts the effects of the fiscal stimulus when done
in isolation and when it is co-ordinated across the Euro Area as a
whole. (1) The diagonal elements report the effects of the fiscal
expansion in the country originating the fiscal expansion, while
the off-diagonal elements show the spillover effect onto the other
countries. At the bottom of the table, the line 'Isolated' reports
once again the fiscal multiplier in the country originating the
stimulus, and the line 'Co-ordinated' shows the fiscal multipliers
from the co-ordinated Euro Area expansion on the individual
countries and Euro Area as a whole. (2) Finally, the trade spillovers
are reported.
The domestic first-year fiscal multipliers are country-specific and
are larger for countries where the number of liquidity-constrained
consumers is higher, such that a rise in output determines a
greater response of consumption. That is the case for Spain, where
the isolated expansion yields a significantly higher increase in
output relative to the same isolated expansion conducted elsewhere.
In contrast, the same isolated expansion in Germany has a smaller
fiscal multiplier as the estimated marginal propensity to consume
out of current income is lower. However, a German expansion would
yield the most beneficial effects to Euro Area growth relative to a
fiscal shock adopted in the other member countries separately
(around 0.2 percent points higher).
Comparing the size of domestic fiscal multipliers with the
off-diagonal values, spillovers on other Euro Area states arising
from the fiscal stimulus adopted only in one country are relatively
small compared to their domestic effects. However, when all
countries adopt them simultaneously, the trade spillovers account
for around 30 per cent of the rise in output one year after the
stimulus.
The magnitude of trade spillovers reflects the structure of Euro
Area trade linkages and the degree of countries' openness, which
determines their sensitivity to foreign demand shocks. The
spillover effects of a co-ordinated Euro Area shock are bigger for
countries that are more sensitive to a shock to Euro Area demand
for their exports. For example, the co-ordinated fiscal multiplier
in the Netherlands is more than double that of the isolated
scenario (1.1 percentage points higher GDP when coordinated
compared to 0.5 percentage points when done in isolation).
What if the expansion was limited to countries with fiscal space?
We have also simulated the effect of a co-ordinated expansion of
only the countries that have space to expand fiscal policy--as
defined before--and assessed the impact on the constrained
countries that are not shocked. Figure B2 shows that the spillover
effects generate benefits to those countries from the fiscal
stimulus co-ordinated across the 'stimulators'.
The fiscal multiplier generated by the co-ordinated expansion
conducted by the five countries with fiscal space is around 0.1
percentage points higher than if the expansion were implemented in
Germany alone. Compared to table BI, the impact of a fully
co-ordinated Euro Area expansion is significantly greater than an
expansion limited to the five countries with fiscal space.
These results show that, if there were to be a fiscal expansion by
Euro Area countries, the dispersion in Euro Area members' fiscal
positions calls for a more collective approach. Many factors would
contribute to the size of the final effect of a fiscal expansion.
These results, however, provide a basis for ranking the
effectiveness of various policies either co-ordinated across
countries or undertaken in isolation. If a fiscal boost is
implemented simultaneously, the fiscal multipliers are larger for
all countries in the monetary union, with the trade spillover
channel accounting for some 30 per cent of the average rise in
output.
NOTES
(1) The analysis excludes Cyprus, Luxembourg and Malta as they are
not modelled separately in NiGEM; also Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania,
Slovakia and Slovenia are not included as, although in NiGEM, there
is not an explicit model for the government sector.
(2) Pain, N., Rusticelli, E., Salins, V. and Turner, D. (2018), in
'A model-based analysis of the effects of increased public
investment' (National Intitute Economic Review, May), used NiGEM to
estimate the size of fiscal multipliers across the G7 from an
expansion to government consumption relative to government
investment.
This box was prepared by Marta Lopresto.
Prospects for individual economies
United States
After another relatively soft performance in the first quarter of
the year, economic activity appears to have picked up significantly in
the second quarter of 2018, underpinned by stronger consumption. The
labour market has continued to strengthen with total non-farm payroll
employment expanding by 213,000 in June, almost identical to the 6-month
average. The unemployment rate has increased marginally to 4 per cent
due to a rise in the labour force participation rate (see figure 6).
Labour markets are expected to continue to tighten, and the
participation rate to increase somewhat as the economy expands. Fiscal
policy is set to become expansionary over the course of this year and
the next, with a projected reduction in tax revenue coupled with an
increase in government spending leading to a widening of the government
budget deficit and hence an increase in the debt position. As the fiscal
stimulus takes more effect, we expect economic growth to strengthen
through this year to about 3 per cent, marginally stronger than our
forecast three months ago. The assessment of risks around the baseline
forecast in the US economy is shown in the GDP growth rate fan chart
(figure 7).
After remaining below the Federal Reserve's target for the
most of the time since 2012, inflation based on the consumer expenditure
deflator is back to 2 per cent. Business surveys and the producer price
index are indicating rising input costs that can be a result of
tightening supply chains. However, the main driver of the rise in
consumer price inflation so far has been health care costs, which are
not trade related. The fiscal boost, coupled with the introduction of
tariffs on imported goods, is expected to generate upward pressure on
prices and, as a result, we expect inflation to overshoot the target
slightly during the course of the next two years.
With the economy growing steadily, the Federal Reserve has
continued its gradual monetary policy normalisation and increased the
federal funds rate by 50 basis points in two rounds since the beginning
of this year. With the economy operating already at about its capacity
and a sizeable fiscal easing taking place, further increases in interest
rates are expected.
Recent escalation of trade related disputes creates uncertainty and
adds downside risks to the economic outlook. So far, the US tariffs have
been aimed at intermediate products and the impact on output is expected
to be modest. Based on our simulation (see Box A in this chapter) 25 per
cent tariffs on $50 billion worth of imports between the US and China is
expected to reduce GDP (relative to the baseline case) in the US by
about 0.05 per cent and increase inflation by about 0.1 percentage point
in the first year. However, if the threat to impose more substantial
tariffs on a much wider range of imported goods materialises, then the
negative impact on the economy and the pass through to domestic
inflation are expected to be much larger.
Canada
Despite finding itself in the direct firing line of US trade
policy, the Canadian economy has so far remained resilient and has
expanded at a pace very close to potential. However, the shift in the
composition of GDP growth away from domestic consumption to exports and
investment in the current trade environment may make it more vulnerable
in the near term. GDP rose by only 0.3 per cent in the first quarter of
2018, mainly due to a slowdown in household spending, non-energy exports
and housing investment, continuing the slower pace seen in the second
half of 2017. Tighter mortgage rules and a slower pick-up of wage growth
than under similar circumstances in the past look to be restraining
consumption growth. On the other hand, the business outlook remains
positive. As an energy producer, higher oil prices support export growth
and business investment continues to profit from favourable financial
conditions. Overall, we expect Canadian GDP to grow by 2.4 per cent in
2018, softening to around 2.2 per cent in 2019.
The stronger reliance on export-led growth makes the economic
outlook more uncertain in the face of NAFTA renegotiations and the
imposition of tariffs by the US administration and the counter-measures
announced by the Canadian government. At the time this Review went to
press, US tariffs in place on Canadian exports of newsprint, softwood
lumber, steel and aluminium products affected 4.1 per cent of total
Canadian exports. An escalation to include, for instance, the automobile
sector would have substantially larger consequences for exporters and
firms linked through supply chains as well as for business investment;
while tariffs imposed by the Canadian government on US imports would put
pressure on consumer prices (see also Box A).
Headline consumer price inflation in June stood near the middle of
the Bank of Canada's target range at 2.5 per cent per annum, and so
did the Bank's preferred measures of core inflation at close to 2.0
per cent (these include a trimmed inflation measure similar to the one
examined for the UK in Box D of the UK Economy chapter). Abstracting
from possible inflationary pressures arising from trade barriers, the
inflation outlook is mixed. On one hand, indicators suggest that
capacity constraints are increasingly binding--in the most recent
Business Outlook Survey 57 per cent of firms reported facing
difficulties meeting unanticipated increases in demand (up from 47 per
cent in 2017) and 34 per cent of firms reported labour shortages (up
from 25 per cent in 2017). On the other hand, signals about wage growth
are mixed. Researchers at the Bank of Canada have constructed a measure
that reflects a common wage growth component across a number of data
sources (Brouillette et al., 2018). As illustrated in figure 8, common
wage growth has flatlined since the start of last year. At the same
time, employment growth eased at the beginning of 2018 and unemployment
rose slightly above its 40-year low to 6 per cent in June. Against this
backdrop, the central bank continued its gradual path of raising
interest rates by setting its main policy rate to 1.5 per cent in July,
25 basis points higher than after its last hike in January this year. We
forecast inflation to hover around 2 per cent in 2018 and 2019 as a
whole.
Euro Area
In the Euro Area, growth in the first quarter of 2018 at 0.4 per
cent was weaker than at any time in 2017 (at 0.7 per cent in each
quarter). The lower reading raised the issue of whether the weakness was
specific to that quarter (a temporary 'soft patch' due to
factors such as the adverse weather) or a reflection of the above-par
rate of growth in 2017 returning to trend. The 2.6 per cent growth in
2017 was the strongest since 2007.
Within the first quarter figures, Spain maintained its strong 0.7
per cent quarterly growth, while growth in France slipped from 0.7 per
cent to 0.2 per cent and in Germany it dropped from 0.6 per cent to 0.3
per cent. Within the first quarter, Euro Area consumer spending growth
actually strengthened, from 0.2 per cent to 0.5 per cent. In contrast,
fixed investment spending growth dropped from a very strong 1.3 per cent
in the first quarter of 2017 to 0.5 per cent. The external sector also
contributed to the weaker performance, with strong quarterly export
growth in the second half of 2017 (1.5 per cent in Q3 and 2.2 per cent
in Q4) not being repeated in the first quarter of 2018 (see figure 9)
when exports fell by 0.4 per cent and Germany, France and Italy all saw
falls in exports. Our expectation is that this is likely to have been a
temporary fall and that export growth will contribute to a strengthening
of growth in the rest of the year. That said, overall growth is expected
to slow from last year's very strong performance, to 2.2 per cent
in 2018, and 2.0 per cent next year. Into the medium term, the Euro Area
is anticipated to show average annual growth of just under 1.5 per cent
a year, reflecting broader demographic trends.
Consumer price inflation was 2.0 per cent in the twelve months to
June, up sharply from 1.3 per cent in April, with the increase in the
month widespread across the member countries. Increases in the prices of
energy, services and food, alcohol and tobacco, were the main
contributors to the sharp jump in annual inflation. Our expectation is
that inflation will continue to remain "close to but below its 2
per cent" target over the forecast horizon.
If domestic price pressures, particularly from faster average
earnings growth, build, then there could be a limited over-shoot of the
2 per cent target. Nevertheless, the European Central Bank (ECB) has
indicated that it sees no immediate need to raise policy interest rates,
perhaps implicitly viewing a sizeable output gap as preventing
significant upward pressure on inflation, especially with the
unemployment rate still currently above 8 per cent, and higher than its
level before the financial crisis. Accordingly, while quantitative
easing is expected to end this year (as announced by the ECB), the
interest rate outlook is assumed to be for very gradual rate rises into
the medium term.
Germany
Most recent indicators suggest that the German economy has left
behind the soft patch it appeared to hit at the beginning of the year.
We expect output growth to continue to be solid in 2018, albeit not as
strong as in 2017. GDP expanded by only 0.3 per cent in the first
quarter as a consequence of a global slowdown in trade and a severe
influenza outbreak. Since then, orders data have picked up in May, as
did industrial production.
As a result, we have revised our projections of GDP growth for 2018
to 2.1 per cent, and for 2019 to 2.0 per cent. Domestic demand is
expected to make a substantial positive contribution to growth, as is
demand from Euro Area trading partners. Fiscal policy will buffer the
expected deceleration of growth, in particular in 2019 when most of the
expansionary measures that were agreed by the German government in July
will come into force. Given higher than expected revenue, the budgetary
position remains favourable and would provide room for additional
spending (see also Box B) should the government wish to use it.
Additional spending could be used to upgrade the country's
transport and broadband infrastructure in order to raise the
economy's productive potential. We expect the government budget to
remain in surplus over the whole of the forecast horizon.
The unemployment rate remains at a three-decade low of 3.4 per cent
and shortages of labour are increasingly reported as constraining the
rate of economic growth from moving above potential. Solid wage
settlements in some sectors, like construction, the metal industries and
the public sector, suggest that the reduction in slack may finally be
translating into stronger wage pressure in areas that face particular
recruitment difficulties. Low rates of overall unemployment, however,
conceal the fact that the share of non-permanent employment contracts
reached a 20-year high of 8.3 per cent last year (IAB, 2018). This may
explain why in the economy as a whole wages and inflation have struggled
to move up further. Real wages were 1.1 per cent higher in 2018Q1 than a
year previously, which is below the post-crisis average and more recent
data on negotiated wages does not suggest this trend has yet reversed.
Without a sustained rise in the pace of earnings increases, we expect
consumer prices to rise by about 2.0 per cent in 2018 and 2019.
The main risk to the German economy is a slowdown in international
trade as a result of new tariff and non-tariff barriers (see also Box
A). Figure 12 illustrates that the volume of exports to the United
Kingdom has been falling since the Brexit referendum. Similarly, the
growth in exports to the United States has slowed down over the past
twelve months, despite favourable exchange-rate movements, possibly
reflecting some fear about protectionist measures. German exporters have
instead relied more on demand from the Euro Area and China. Political
uncertainty in the currency union and an economic reversal in China
would therefore have important implications for the German economy.
Against this, the recent trade agreement between the EU and Japan should
be positive for German exporters.
France
The French economy expanded in 2017 at a rate much faster than
potential: 2.3 per cent versus a potential estimated at around 1 1/4 per
cent. (3) In the first quarter of 2018, GDP growth slowed to 0.2 per
cent after expanding by about 0.7 per cent in each of the previous four
quarters, driven by a slowdown in consumption, investment and net trade.
Household consumption growth was lacklustre at 0.1 per cent in the
quarter as real personal income was hit by a combination of higher
consumer price inflation, which rose from 1.2 per cent in the previous
quarter to 1.5 per cent in the first quarter, and an increase in
generalised social contribution (CSG), a tax on income and wealth used
to finance social security. Fixed investment growth declined sharply
from 0.9 per cent in the fourth quarter of 2017 to 0.2 per cent in the
first quarter of 2018. In addition to the slowdown in domestic demand,
exports fell in the first quarter by 0.3 per cent as the euro
appreciated against the US dollar, which made French exports less
competitive. Although industrial production declined by 0.8 per cent in
the three months to May 2018, service sector output rose by 0.5 per cent
in the three months to April 2018 (after a rise of 1.7 per cent in the
previous three months).
The inflation rate reached 2.3 per cent in May and June, the
highest since August 2012 (figure 13). Domestic factors--the economy
growing above potential and closing its output gap--and external
factors--a spike in energy prices--contributed to higher inflation.
Higher inflation is likely to further dampen households' purchasing
power unless earnings growth picks up.
The unemployment rate, which reached a peak of 10.5 per cent in
2015, has been declining steadily but appears to have stalled at
slightly above 9 per cent since the fourth quarter of 2017, as a result
of slightly fewer new jobs being created and an increase in labour force
participation. We expect the downward trend to resume in the second half
of 2018 as there is still evidence of slack in the labour market.
Following a temporary dip in the first quarter, we forecast quarterly
French GDP growth to stabilise at around 0.4 per cent in each of the
following three quarters and annual inflation to stabilise at just under
2 per cent.
Italy
Our annual projections for the short term are for continued
economic expansion, although at a rate slightly weaker than we
anticipated in May. We expect GDP to grow by 1.3 per cent this year and
1.2 per cent next. Since the turn of the year, growth has been slightly
softer than expected, with the slowdown driven by the domestic political
uncertainty and a deceleration in global trade.
Consumption was the main driver of growth in the first quarter and
we expect it to continue to be strong in the second quarter on the back
of lower unemployment in the months to May and positive consumer
confidence surveys. On the output side, the projections for the second
quarter are for weak industrial production, partially compensated by
stronger service sector output, in line with the outlook conveyed by
activity surveys.
The headline inflation rate softened slightly during the first
quarter of this year, but then rose to 1.4 per cent in June largely due
to higher energy prices. We expect headline inflation to stabilise at
just above 1 per cent this year and next. The unemployment rate could
fall to just below 11 per cent in the second quarter of this year and we
expect it to moderate below that in the rest of this year and the next.
The main risks to these projections are driven by the continued
domestic political uncertainty and also the external trading
environment. The process of coalition negotiations at the end of May
added significant turbulence to financial markets and government bond
yields which, although they have now stabilised somewhat, are still some
100 basis points above the levels in early May. Importantly, the new
government has called into question the EU fiscal rules and that adds
risk to our fiscal projections in the medium term (although we have not
incorporated any new budget proposals to our forecasts as they will not
be formally presented until autumn).
Spain
The positive economic outlook in Spain continues to hold. Annual
economic growth was 3 per cent in the first quarter of 2018, marking the
twelfth consecutive quarter at which it has been 3 per cent or above.
Unemployment has continued to fall steadily, from 16.1 per cent in March
to 15.8 per cent in June. Prices increased by 2.3 per cent in the year
to May, with inflation rising from 1.1 per cent in April, in part
reflecting higher energy prices. Given the apparent degree of spare
capacity remaining in the Spanish economy, the spike in inflation is
likely to be due to the recent surge in oil prices.
There have been a number of important developments in the Spanish
economy over the past quarter. Firstly, the government approved the 2018
Stability Programme in April. The main budgetary measures include income
tax cuts for low income households and a 1 per cent increase in public
sector wages. Secondly, the People's Party, which had held a
majority since 2011, was replaced in government by the Spanish Socialist
Workers' Party on 1 June following a vote on the corruption
scandal. While this political crisis led to a sharp spike in economic
policy uncertainty, the overall positive economic trends have continued.
Looking ahead, we forecast that economic growth will be around 2.8
per cent in 2018 and 2.5 per cent in 2019. Unemployment should continue
to fall, reaching 15.5 per cent this year and around 14.5 per cent next.
Inflation is likely to peak this year as the energy price increase works
through and edge back thereafter, reflecting the transitory effect of
the increase in oil prices. With a robust outlook as our central
forecast, the risks to our forecast are tilted to the downside.
Domestically, the situation in Catalonia remains uncertain, while
externally the key risks are a rise in protectionism and the effects of
a gradual normalisation of monetary policies.
Japan
Japanese economic activity contracted by 0.2 per cent in the first
quarter of 2018, down from an upwardly revised 0.3 per cent growth in
the previous quarter. This is the first quarterly contraction since 2015
and was largely due to firms running down inventories, following a
build-up of inventories in previous quarters. Housing investment also
continued to decline following a contraction of bank lending for
apartment construction as increasing numbers of new-builds lie vacant.
Domestic demand was flat in the first quarter of this year. Since
inventories are unlikely to continue to be run down and household
consumption is likely to be supported in the near-term by rising wages,
this fall in GDP looks to be temporary and we expect growth to return in
the second quarter and for Japan to show growth of 1.0 per cent this
year and next.
Consumer price inflation rose slightly to 0.7 per cent year-on-year
in May, up from 0.6 per cent in April.
While this reading was above consensus estimates of 0.3 per cent,
it remains well below the rates of inflation seen in the first quarter
of this year and the central bank's 2 per cent target. We expect
inflation to edge up to 1.4 per cent in 2019, in part reflecting
stronger wage growth, which for March showed the largest annual increase
in earnings since 2003, with nominal earnings increasing by 2.1 per cent
year-on-year. While this figure was boosted by large increases in bonus
payments, base pay rose by 1.3 per cent, the strongest increase since
1997. Although labour shortages are becoming increasingly acute, there
has been little sign of pass-through to wages until now. To ease the
problem of labour shortages, Japan is set to loosen immigration rules,
allowing up to 500,000 guest workers into the country.
The Japanese government has pushed back its target date for
achieving a primary budget balance to 2025, citing slow growth in tax
revenues, a delay in raising the consumption tax and plans to increase
spending on education as factors that meant the initial 2020 goal would
be difficult to meet. From our forecast projections this target will
prove to be tough to meet.
China
Output grew by 6.7 per cent year-on-year in the second quarter of
2018, just 0.1 percentage point lower than in the preceding three
quarters. Since the first quarter of this year, high frequency
indicators have been pointing to a somewhat softer pace of economic
activity, largely as a reaction to financial deleveraging. The rate of
growth of retail sales, investment and industrial output weakened in May
and June. Looking forward, we maintain our view of a very gradual
reduction in the rate of GDP growth and expect annual output growth to
be about 6.6 per cent and 6.3 per cent this year and next respectively.
As the political drive to reduce financial risks continues, the
pace of increase of corporate debt has slowed. After reaching a high of
over 165 per cent of GDP in 2016, the ratio has edged down recently to
around 160 per cent as policy changes have had an effect. Stricter
financial rules seems to have affected liquidity as well, with the
12-month growth in M2 money supply for the past four months under 9 per
cent and spreads between AA-rated corporate and government bond yields
have risen since late 2016.
The introduction of a series of tariffs by the US on imports from
China complicates implementation of domestic reforms. Tariffs imposed up
to now are expected to have a modest impact on GDP growth and inflation.
Based on our simulation results presented in Box A, the imposition of 25
per cent tariffs on $50 billion worth of imports from China to the US
and vice versa is expected to reduce (the level of) GDP in China by
about 0.02 per cent and add about 0.2 percentage points to inflation in
the first year.
However, the negative impact on the economy is expected to be
significantly larger if a threat by the US President to apply tariffs on
half or even the full range of imported goods from China materialises.
News of the tariffs announcement led to a fall in Chinese domestic stock
markets. Equity prices in China have declined by about 18 per cent since
the start of this year, reaching lows last seen two years ago. The
People's Bank of China reacted to the uncertainty by cutting
banks' cash reserve ratio, which is a signal for banks to expand
their balance sheets and hence liquidity in the system. However, as the
statement accompanying the announcement stressed --the
"prudent" monetary policy stance is expected to continue,
which is an indication that the authorities are not planning a large
stimulus. The escalation of the trade dispute creates uncertainty,
increases volatility and creates a downside risk to economic activity.
Nevertheless, output growth in China is largely domestically driven (see
figure 19) and the government still has enough ammunition to soften the
negative effect from the trade dispute with the US.
Russia
Following a landslide election victory on 18 March 2018 with 77 per
cent of the vote, President Putin has set about his agenda. After the
inauguration for another 6-year term on 7 May he signed a 'May
decree' setting out the national development targets for the next
term to 2024. The measures aim to raise Russia's potential growth
rate, with the overriding objective of joining the group of the
world's five largest economies by the end of the term (currently
Russia is the world's 12th largest economy as measured at market
exchange rates). The implementation of the 'May decree'
requires an additional 8 trillion rubles (about US$130 billion) over six
years, which amounts to about half of total federal expenditure set out
in Russia's 2018 budget. The plan is viewed as ambitious, with
Prime Minister Medvedev admitting that the timeframe is "rather
tight".
On 14 June 2018, the start of the World Cup held in Russia, the
government outlined a package of budget measures to fund the 'May
decree'. This contained three main components of note. First, value
added tax (VAT) will rise from 18 per cent to 20 per cent from 2019.
Second, the retirement age will increase from one of the lowest in the
developed world--at 60 for men and 55 for women--to 65 and 60 for men
and women respectively. Third, a tax reform of the oil industry will
abolish export duties for crude and oil products and raise a production
levy. International sanctions remain a key factor hindering recovery: in
addition to the EU's further extension of its economic sanctions
until 31 January 2019, there remains controversy over the alleged cyber
interference in the 2016 US elections, and in June several companies and
individuals had sanctions imposed for allegedly aiding Russia's
main intelligence agency.
Annual consumer price inflation slowed a little to 2.3 per cent in
June from 2.4 per cent in March. The decline in inflation into June was
a result of seasonal lower food inflation. Having peaked at 16.9 per
cent in the year to March 2015, inflation has now fallen below the
Central Bank's target of 4 per cent, and has been around the 2.02.5
per cent range for the eight months to June 2018. The VAT increase due
to be implemented in January 2019 should lead to an uptick in inflation
into 2019. The current harvest has been estimated to be some 20-25 per
cent lower than usual and will be another factor driving higher prices
in the next 12-18 months. We expect inflation to pick up towards 2.7 per
cent in 2018 and 4.0 per cent in 2019, reflecting the pass-through of
exchange rate depreciation and commodity price rises to domestic prices.
The VAT increase adds a further upside risk to inflation.
Following six rounds of reductions in interest rates which took
them from 10 to 7.75 per cent in 2017, the central bank lowered its
benchmark interest rate in mid-February to 7.50 per cent and in
late-March to 7.25 per cent, where it has been held since. At the 15
June 2018 meeting the Governor cited the forthcoming VAT increase as the
main reason for postponing more monetary easing.
We have revised our GDP forecast down slightly to 1.8 per cent from
1.9 per cent in 2018 and to 1.9 per cent from 2.3 per cent in 2019. The
current year revision reflects the existing weakness in 2018 data, the
weak harvest and tightening US sanctions, whilst the 2019 revisions
reflect the balance of the new fiscal package.
India
The rate of growth of the Indian economy continued to increase in
the first quarter of 2018, with the economy expanding by 7.7 per cent
year-on-year, up from 7.0 per cent in the previous quarter. Some of this
continued rapid expansion can be attributed to a continued bounce back
following disruption due to demonetisation in November 2016 and the
implementation of radical tax reforms in July 2017. However, a large
contribution to growth has come from increases in government spending in
the run-up to next year's general election, while private
investment has been broadly flat. India's economy had benefitted
from the low oil price, but with oil at around $75 per barrel, this
stimulus to growth has been removed. Thus, unless private sector
investment surprises on the upside, we expect growth to slow next year,
averaging 7.8 per cent this year and 7.5 per cent in 2019.
The annual inflation rate increased for the third consecutive month
in June, reaching 5.0 per cent. India's increasingly protectionist
stance is likely to push up consumer prices further, as well as hurting
domestic producers as the prices of imported goods rises. Increases in
tariffs on a range of goods imported from the US will come into effect
on 4 August, in retaliation for President Trump's decision to
increase duties on steel and aluminium imports from India.
Increasing inflationary pressure and concerns around rising oil
prices and uncertainty in financial markets prompted the Reserve Bank of
India to raise policy interest rates on 6 June for the first time since
2014, with the benchmark repo rate rising by 25 basis points to 6.25 per
cent. We expect inflation to average 5.2 per cent this year before
easing slightly to 4.9 per cent in 2019.
Brazil
Driven by stronger investment growth than anticipated, we have
revised up our projections for GDP growth in Brazil for this year and
next, with growth forecast at 2 per cent and 2.7 per cent respectively.
The weakening of inflation from a peak of almost 9 per cent in 2015 to
just above 3 per cent last year gave space for monetary policy to lower
the policy rate to 6.5 per cent in March which is likely to support
investment. Also, the recent reform plan from the government has
improved confidence and restored stability in financial markets.
Inflation is assumed to settle at a rate within the 2018 Central
Bank's target of 3-6 per cent this year and the next, which will
continue to provide space for an accommodative monetary policy stance,
and further support investment and consumption. The regional, as well as
global, upturn in demand has driven a sustained increase in demand for
Brazilian exports. This has aided the net trade position, although we
expect the recent strength in exports to soften gradually going forward.
Some risks to these forecasts come from continued political
uncertainty. The 2015-16 recession took its toll on traditional politics
which had leaned to the left, and this may jeopardise the recent reform
effort. According to the latest polls, the elections due in October 2018
could see an overhaul of the current left-wing government by a
right-wing party. In addition, the adverse fiscal position represents a
risk to our forecasts, as the primary balance required to stabilise the
public debt ratio in the medium term is estimated to be around 2 per
cent, while it currently stands at a negative 1.6 per cent of GDR
NOTES
(1) 'Oil and the macroeconomy' (2018), National Institute
Economic Review, February.
(2) The Vix index is seen as a barometer of investor sentiment and
market volatility and is a measure of market expectations of uncertain
volatility implied by S&P 500 index option prices.
(3) European Commission estimate: 1.3 per cent, French Treasury
estimate: 1.25 per cent.
REFERENCES
Aksoy, Y., Basso, H.S. and Smith, R.P. (2017), 'Medium-run
implications of changing demographic structures for the
macro-economy', National Institute Economic Review, August.
Brouillette, D., Lachaine, J. and Vincent, B. (2018), 'Wages:
measurement and key drivers', Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Note
2018-2.
Hantzsche, A. and Liadze, I. (2018), The war on trade: beggar thy
neighbour--beggar thyself?', National Institute Economic Review,
May.
IAB (Institut fur Arbeitsmarkt-und Berufsforschung) (2018), IAB
Kurzbericht, 16/2018.
Kazalova, Y. and Naisbitt, B. (2018), 'Disappointing
productivity growth: an international dimension', National
Institute Economic Review, February.
Lennard, J. (2018), 'The great synchronisation', National
Institute Economic Review, May.
Lenoel, C. (2018), 'Predicting recessions in the United States
with the yield curve', National Institute Economic Review, May.
Liadze, I. and Hacche, G. (2017), 'The macroeconomic
implications of increasing tariffs on US imports', NiGEM
Observations, No. 12. Naisbitt, B. (2018), 'The re-emergence of
concerns about debt', National Institute Economic Review, May.
Riley, R., Rincon-Aznar, A. and Samek, L. (2018), 'Below the
aggregate: a sectoral account of the UK productivity puzzle', ESCoE
Discussion Paper 2018-06, May.
Appendix A: Summary of key forecast assumptions by Iana Liadze and
Barry Naisbitt
The forecasts for the world economy and the UK economy reported in
this Review are produced using the National Institute's global
econometric model, NiGEM. NiGEM has been in use at NIESR for forecasting
and policy analysis since 1987, and is also used by a group of more than
40 model subscribers, mainly in the policy community. Further details,
including articles by model users, are provided in the May 2018 edition
of the Review. Most countries in the OECD are modelled separately, (1)
and there are also separate models for Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria,
China, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Lithuania, Romania, Russia,
Singapore, South Africa, Taiwan and Vietnam. The rest of the world is
modelled through regional blocks so that the model is global in scope.
All models contain the determinants of domestic demand, export and
import volumes, prices, current accounts and net assets. Output is
determined in the long run by factor inputs and technical progress
interacting through production functions, but is also affected by demand
in the short to medium term. Economies are linked through trade,
competitiveness and financial markets and are fully simultaneous.
Further details on NiGEM are available on http://nimodel.mesr.ac.uk/.
The key interest rate and exchange rate assumptions underlying our
current forecast are shown in tables A1-A2. Our short-term interest rate
assumptions are generally based oncurrent financial market expectations,
as implied by the rates of return on treasury bills and government bonds
of different maturities. Long-term interest rate assumptions are
consistent with forward estimates from short-term interest rates,
allowing for a country-specific term premium. Where term premia do
exist, we assume they gradually diminish over time, such that long-term
interest rates in the long run are simply the forward convolution of
short-term interest rates.
Short-term interest rates in the US, UK and Canada are expected to
rise in 2018, but remain unchanged in the Euro Area and Japan. Interest
rates in the US are broadly consistent with the path signalled by the
most recent Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) minutes. As discussed
in the UK chapter in this Review, we expect the UK economic growth to
stabilise at a rate that is close to its potential. Our central forecast
assumes a soft Brexit scenario and is conditioned on Bank Rate rising 25
basis points in August this year and February 2019. Bank Rate is
expected to reach 1.5 per cent in 2020, this being the point at which
the MPC is assumed to stop reinvesting the proceeds from maturing gilts
it currently holds, allowing the Bank of England's balance sheet to
shrink 'naturally'. (2)
Figure A1 illustrates the recent movement in, and our projections
for, 10-year government bond yields in the US, Euro Area, the UK and
Japan. The levels of 10-year sovereign bond yields in the second quarter
of 2018 have increased slightly since the first quarter in the US by
about 20 basis points, but remained largely unchanged in the Euro Area,
the UK and Japan. Expectations currently for bond yields for the end of
2018 are slightly lower, by about 30 basis points, for the UK compared
to expectations formed just three months ago, but are largely unchanged
for the US, the Euro Area and Japan. The forecast implies gradual
increases for 10-year bond yields but, given the risks around the
forecast, more volatile paths could emerge.
Sovereign risks in the Euro Area were a major macroeconomic issue
for the global economy and financial markets over several years after
the financial crisis. Figure A2 depicts the spread between 10-year
government bond yields of Spain, Italy, Portugal, Ireland and Greece
over Germany's. After remaining relatively flat or somewhat
decreasing over the course of last year, spreads increased in May and
have remained elevated since. Italy experienced the largest increase in
spreads. In our current forecast, we have assumed that spreads over
German bond yields narrow slightly in all Euro Area countries.
Figure A3 shows the spreads of corporate bond yields over
government bond yields in the US, UK and Euro Area. This acts as a proxy
for the margin between private sector and 'risk-free'
borrowing costs. Since the beginning of February corporate bond spreads
in the US, UK and Euro Area have been on an upward trend, with private
sector borrowing costs rising more than the observed increase in
risk-free rates. Our forecast assumption for corporate spreads is that
they gradually converge towards their long-term average level.
Nominal exchange rates against the US dollar are generally assumed
to remain constant at the rate prevailing on 12 July 2018 until the end
of March 2019. After that, they follow a backward looking
uncovered-interest parity condition, based on interest rate
differentials relative to the US. Figure A4 plots the recent history as
well as our short-term forecast of the effective exchange rate indices
for Canada, the Euro Area, Japan, UK, and the US. Between the first and
the second quarters of 2018, in trade-weighted terms, the US dollar
appreciated slightly, by about 2 per cent, which leaves it at just about
4 per cent below the recent peak reached at the beginning of 2017. After
having strengthened over the past year, the euro weakened marginally in
effective terms in the second quarter of this year relative to the
previous quarter. Among the emerging market currencies in our model, the
largest movement in trade-weighted terms between the second and the
first quarters of 2018 has been the depreciation of the Argentinian peso
by about 13 per cent, followed by the Turkish lira, which lost about 11
per cent of its value, and the Brazilian real, which depreciated by
about 8 per cent.
Our oil price assumptions for the short term generally follow those
of the US Energy Information
Administration (EIA), published in July 2018, and updated with
daily spot price data available up to 12 July 2018. The EIA uses
information from forward markets as well as an evaluation of supply
conditions. As illustrated in figure A5, oil prices, in US dollar terms,
have continued to increase since their recent trough in 2016, and gained
about 12 per cent between the second and the first quarters of 2018.
Expectations of oil prices by the end of 2019 are somewhat higher,
compared to the expectation three months ago, which leaves oil prices
about $35 per barrel lower than their nominal level in mid--2014.
Our equity price assumptions for the US reflect the expected return
on capital. Other equity markets are assumed to move in line with the US
market, but are adjusted for different exchange rate movements and
shifts in country-specific equity risk premia. Since the beginning of
this year stock market performance has been mixed, without major falls
or gains in equity prices in the largest developed economies. Figure A6
illustrates the key short-term equity price assumptions underlying our
current forecast.
NOTES
(1) With the exception of Iceland and Israel.
(2) Interest rate assumptions are based on information available
for the period to 12 July 2018.
Table A1. Interest rates
Per cent per annum
Central bank intervention rates
US Canada Japan Euro Area UK
2014 0.25 1.00 0.10 0.16 0.50
2015 0.26 0.65 0.10 0.05 0.50
2016 0.51 0.50 -0.08 0.01 0.40
2017 1.10 0.70 -0.10 0.00 0.29
2018 1.91 1.35 -0.10 0.00 0.60
2019 2.69 1.94 -0.10 0.06 1.08
2020-24 3.55 3.29 0.26 1.31 2.31
2016 Q1 0.50 0.50 0.00 0.04 0.50
2016 Q2 0.50 0.50 -0.10 0.00 0.50
2016 Q3 0.50 0.50 -0.10 0.00 0.34
2016 Q4 0.55 0.50 -0.10 0.00 0.25
2017 Q1 0.80 0.50 -0.10 0.00 0.25
2017 Q2 1.05 0.50 -0.10 0.00 0.25
2017 Q3 1.25 0.79 -0.10 0.00 0.25
2017 Q4 1.30 1.00 -0.10 0.00 0.41
2018 Q1 1.53 1.20 -0.10 0.00 0.50
2018 Q2 1.80 1.25 -0.10 0.00 0.50
2018 Q3 2.08 1.43 -0.10 0.00 0.66
2018 Q4 2.24 1.50 -0.10 0.00 0.75
2019 Q1 2.42 1.75 -0.10 0.00 0.92
2019 Q2 2.60 1.88 -0.11 0.00 1.00
2019 Q3 2.78 2.01 -0.10 0.00 1.16
2019 Q4 2.96 2.13 -0.08 0.25 1.25
10-year government bond yields
US Canada Japan Euro Area UK
2014 2.5 2.2 0.6 1.9 2.5
2015 2.1 1.5 0.4 1.0 1.8
2016 1.8 1.3 0.0 0.7 1.3
2017 2.3 1.8 0.1 1.0 1.2
2018 2.9 2.2 0.1 1.1 1.4
2019 3.2 2.8 0.3 1.6 2.0
2020-24 3.9 3.8 1.1 3.0 3.4
2016 Q1 1.9 1.2 0.1 0.8 1.5
2016 Q2 1.7 1.3 -0.1 0.7 1.4
2016 Q3 1.6 1.1 -0.1 0.4 0.8
2016 Q4 2.1 1.5 0.0 0.8 1.3
2017 Q1 2.4 1.7 0.1 1.1 1.3
2017 Q2 2.3 1.5 0.0 1.0 1.0
2017 Q3 2.2 1.9 0.0 1.0 1.2
2017 Q4 2.4 2.0 0.0 0.9 1.3
2018 Q1 2.8 2.2 0.1 1.0 1.5
2018 Q2 2.9 2.3 0.0 1.0 1.4
2018 Q3 2.8 2.2 0.0 1.0 1.3
2018 Q4 3.0 2.3 0.1 1.2 1.5
2019 Q1 3.1 2.5 0.2 1.4 1.8
2019 Q2 3.2 2.7 0.3 1.5 2.0
2019 Q3 3.3 2.8 0.3 1.7 2.1
2019 Q4 3.4 3.0 0.4 1.8 2.3
Table A2. Nominal exchange rates
Percentage change in effective rate
US Canada Japan Euro
Area
2014 3.8 -5.7 -5.5 3.1
2015 13.2 -11.2 -6.3 -6.0
2016 5.2 0.3 15.2 4.8
2017 0.6 2.0 -2.4 3.0
2018 -0.8 -1.5 0.9 4.7
2019 1.2 -0.4 0.7 0.8
2016 Q1 1.6 4.2 6.5 2.5
2016 Q2 -1.7 2.1 5.7 1.1
2016 Q3 1.1 -1.2 5.9 0.3
2016 Q4 3.6 -0.6 -4.1 0.0
2017 Q1 1.1 -0.1 -2.9 -0.6
2017 Q2 -2.4 0.0 1.0 1.1
2017 Q3 -3.4 7.3 -1.5 4.3
2017 Q4 1.3 -3.7 -1.7 0.6
2018 Q1 -1.9 -2.1 2.5 2.0
2018 Q2 2.0 1.0 0.5 -0.4
2018 Q3 2.1 -1.5 -0.3 0.3
2018 Q4 0.0 -0.1 -0.1 0.0
2019 Q1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
2019 Q2 -0.2 0.1 0.5 0.5
2019 Q3 -0.2 0.1 0.5 0.5
2019 Q4 -0.2 0.1 0.6 0.5
Percentage change in effective rate
Germany France Italy UK
2014 1.6 1.5 2.5 7.4
2015 -3.7 -3.8 -3.1 5.6
2016 2.4 2.5 2.9 -9.9
2017 1.3 2.0 2.0 -5.2
2018 2.5 2.6 3.1 2.4
2019 0.5 0.3 0.5 -0.4
2016 Q1 1.3 1.2 1.5 -5.6
2016 Q2 0.5 0.8 0.7 -1.6
2016 Q3 0.0 0.4 0.0 -7.9
2016 Q4 -0.1 0.1 0.2 -2.6
2017 Q1 -0.4 -0.2 -0.2 0.8
2017 Q2 0.6 0.7 0.7 1.1
2017 Q3 2.3 2.3 2.6 -1.6
2017 Q4 0.3 0.4 0.5 1.7
2018 Q1 0.9 1.2 1.4 2.0
2018 Q2 -0.1 -0.4 -0.2 0.1
2018 Q3 0.3 0.0 0.2 -1.0
2018 Q4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
2019 Q1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
2019 Q2 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.1
2019 Q3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.1
2019 Q4 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.0
Bilateral rate per US $
Canadian Yen Euro Sterling
$
2014 1.112 105.8 0.754 0.607
2015 1.299 121.1 0.902 0.654
2016 1.314 108.8 0.904 0.741
2017 1.294 112.2 0.887 0.776
2018 1.306 110.3 0.842 0.742
2019 1.317 110.9 0.849 0.753
2016 Q1 1.323 115.2 0.908 0.699
2016 Q2 1.289 107.9 0.886 0.697
2016 Q3 1.310 102.4 0.896 0.762
2016 Q4 1.333 109.5 0.927 0.805
2017 Q1 1.339 113.6 0.939 0.807
2017 Q2 1.330 111.1 0.909 0.781
2017 Q3 1.229 111.0 0.852 0.764
2017 Q4 1.277 112.9 0.849 0.753
2018 Q1 1.294 108.3 0.814 0.718
2018 Q2 1.291 109.2 0.840 0.736
2018 Q3 1.320 111.9 0.856 0.757
2018 Q4 1.321 112.0 0.857 0.757
2019 Q1 1.321 112.0 0.857 0.757
2019 Q2 1.318 111.3 0.851 0.755
2019 Q3 1.316 110.6 0.846 0.752
2019 Q4 1.314 109.8 0.840 0.749
Appendix B: Forecast detail
Table B1. Real GDP growth and inflation
Real GDP growth (per cent)
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020-24
Argentina 2.7 -1.8 2.9 2.0 2.3 2.2
Australia 2.5 2.6 2.2 3.1 2.8 2.7
Austria (a) 1.1 1.5 3.2 2.4 1.7 1.5
Belgium (a) 1.4 1.4 1.7 1.7 1.9 1.0
Bulgaria (a) 3.6 3.9 3.7 4.0 3.3 1.8
Brazil -3.5 -3.5 1.0 2.0 2.7 2.1
Chile 2.3 1.2 1.6 3.1 2.6 2.7
China 6.9 6.7 6.9 6.6 6.3 5.8
Canada 1.0 1.4 3.0 2.4 2.2 1.8
Czech Rep. 5.4 2.4 4.5 3.2 2.8 1.3
Denmark (a) 1.6 2.0 2.3 1.7 1.8 1.1
Estonia (a) 1.7 2.2 4.7 3.7 3.9 2.2
Finland (a) 0.1 2.3 2.7 2.7 2.3 1.1
France (a) 1.0 1.1 2.3 1.9 1.8 1.5
Germany (a) 1.5 1.9 2.5 2.1 2.0 1.2
Greece (a) -0.3 -0.3 1.3 2.0 1.9 1.1
Hong Kong 2.4 2.2 3.8 3.7 2.4 2.4
Hungary (a) 3.3 2.1 4.2 3.8 3.1 1.3
India 7.6 7.9 6.2 7.8 7.5 7.2
Indonesia 4.9 5.0 5.1 5.2 5.7 4.9
Ireland (a) 25.0 4.9 7.2 6.4 3.0 2.7
Italy (a) 0.8 1.0 1.6 1.3 1.2 1.1
Japan 1.4 1.0 1.7 1.0 1.0 0.9
Lithuania (a) 2.0 2.3 3.9 3.4 3.2 1.0
Latvia (a) 2.8 1.5 5.0 3.3 2.4 1.5
Mexico 3.3 2.6 2.3 2.1 2.5 2.5
Netherlands (a) 2.0 2.1 3.0 2.9 2.7 1.2
New Zealand 4.2 4.1 3.0 2.6 3.2 2.5
Norway 1.8 1.0 2.0 2.4 2.1 1.5
Poland 3.8 3.0 4.7 4.7 3.6 2.4
Portugal (a) 1.8 1.6 2.7 2.2 2.3 1.9
Romania (a) 4.0 4.8 6.8 3.7 2.7 2.2
Russia -2.5 -0.2 1.5 1.8 1.9 2.6
Singapore 2.2 2.4 3.6 3.2 2.8 3.8
South Africa 1.3 0.6 1.2 1.4 1.7 2.4
S. Korea 2.8 2.9 3.1 3.0 3.1 3.1
Slovakia (a) 3.9 3.3 3.4 3.7 3.9 1.5
Slovenia (a) 2.0 3.2 5.4 4.1 3.9 2.1
Spain (a) 3.4 3.3 3.1 2.8 2.5 1.5
Sweden (a) 4.3 3.0 2.5 2.7 2.6 1.7
Switzerland 1.2 1.4 1.1 2.0 1.5 1.8
Taiwan 0.8 1.4 2.9 2.5 2.8 2.6
Turkey 5.9 3.2 7.4 4.6 3.7 4.0
UK (a) 2.3 1.8 1.7 1.4 1.7 1.8
US 2.9 1.5 2.3 2.9 2.7 2.2
Vietnam 6.6 6.1 6.7 7.0 7.4 5.7
Euro Area (a) 2.0 1.8 2.6 2.2 2.0 1.3
EU--28 (a) 2.2 1.9 2.6 2.2 2.1 1.5
OECD 2.5 1.8 2.6 2.5 2.3 1.9
World 3.5 3.2 3.8 3.9 3.8 3.6
Annual inflation (a) (per cent)
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020-24
Argentina 26.5 41.4 26.3 27.1 19.3 12.3
Australia 1.5 0.9 1.2 2.3 2.2 2.7
Austria (a) 0.8 1.0 2.2 2.3 1.5 1.7
Belgium (a) 0.6 1.8 2.2 2.1 1.6 1.9
Bulgaria (a) -1.1 -1.3 1.2 2.5 1.8 1.9
Brazil 9.0 8.7 3.4 3.8 5.1 5.4
Chile 4.3 3.8 2.2 2.7 2.9 2.6
China 1.4 2.0 1.6 1.9 2.2 2.7
Canada 1.1 0.9 1.1 2.0 2.1 2.0
Czech Rep. 0.3 0.7 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.4
Denmark (a) 0.2 0.0 1.1 1.1 1.9 1.6
Estonia (a) 0.1 0.8 3.7 3.6 2.7 2.2
Finland (a) -0.2 0.4 0.8 1.4 2.0 1.8
France (a) 0.1 0.3 1.2 2.0 1.4 1.7
Germany (a) 0.1 0.4 1.7 2.0 1.9 1.8
Greece (a) -1.1 0.0 1.1 0.5 1.4 2.3
Hong Kong 1.3 1.5 2.4 3.7 2.3 3.3
Hungary (a) 0.1 0.4 2.4 3.1 3.8 3.9
India 4.9 5.0 3.3 5.2 4.9 4.7
Indonesia 6.4 3.5 3.8 4.0 4.3 3.5
Ireland (a) 0.0 -0.2 0.2 0.7 1.4 1.9
Italy (a) 0.1 -0.1 1.3 1.3 1.3 1.4
Japan 0.4 -0.5 0.2 0.8 1.4 1.2
Lithuania (a) -0.7 0.7 3.7 3.2 1.9 1.3
Latvia (a) 0.2 0.1 2.9 3.0 2.3 1.7
Mexico 2.7 2.8 6.0 4.9 3.6 3.5
Netherlands (a) 0.2 0.1 1.3 1.7 2.1 1.9
New Zealand 0.7 0.7 1.5 1.5 2.4 2.3
Norway 2.5 3.4 1.5 2.3 2.0 1.9
Poland -0.7 -0.2 1.6 1.6 2.2 2.2
Portugal (a) 0.5 0.6 1.6 1.6 2.1 1.6
Romania (a) -0.4 -1.1 1.1 4.8 2.2 2.4
Russia 15.5 7.1 3.6 2.7 4.0 4.0
Singapore -0.5 -0.5 0.6 0.5 1.5 2.9
South Africa 4.0 6.2 4.6 5.1 5.0 3.8
S. Korea 0.7 1.0 1.9 1.9 2.4 2.2
Slovakia (a) -0.3 -0.5 1.4 2.7 1.8 1.4
Slovenia (a) -0.8 -0.2 1.6 2.5 1.7 1.7
Spain (a) -0.6 -0.3 2.0 1.9 1.5 1.9
Sweden (a) 0.7 1.1 1.9 1.7 1.8 2.0
Switzerland -0.6 -0.2 0.2 0.7 1.3 1.2
Taiwan -0.7 0.8 0.0 1.5 1.0 2.1
Turkey 7.7 7.8 11.1 12.7 10.2 6.9
UK (a) 0.1 0.7 2.7 2.3 1.9 2.0
US 0.3 1.2 1.7 2.3 2.3 2.1
Vietnam 0.6 2.7 3.5 3.2 3.9 3.7
Euro Area (a) 0.0 0.2 1.5 1.8 1.6 1.8
EU-28 (a) 0.0 0.3 1.7 1.0 1.4 1.9
OECD 0.8 1.1 2.1 2.6 2.5 2.3
World 3.8 4.0 4.2 4.5 4.5 3.7
Note: (a) Harmonised consumer price inflation in the EU
economies and inflation measured by the consumer
expenditure deflator in the rest of the world.
Table B2. Fiscal balance and government debt
Fiscal balance (per cent of GDP) (a)
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2024
Australia -1.5 -2.1 -1.7 -1.6 -1.0 -1.2
Australia -1.1 -1.5 -0.5 -0.5 -0.5 -1.1
Austria -1.0 -1.6 -0.7 -0.3 -0.1 -1.1
Belgium -2.5 -2.5 -1.0 -1.0 0.0 -2.1
Bulgaria -1.6 0.2 0.9 1.0 0.7 -0.6
Canada -0.1 -1.1 -1.1 -1.6 -1.5 -1.6
Czech Rep. -0.6 0.7 1.6 1.4 1.4 -0.8
Denmark -1.5 -0.4 1.0 -0.2 0.3 -0.9
Estonia 0.1 -0.3 -0.3 -0.4 -0.6 -1.3
Finland -2.8 -1.8 -0.6 -0.2 0.3 -1.5
France -3.6 -3.4 -2.6 -2.1 -2.1 -2.8
Germany 0.8 1.0 1.3 1.6 1.2 -0.9
Greece -5.7 0.6 0.8 0.3 0.9 0.3
Hungary -1.9 -1.7 -2.0 -2.2 -2.0 -2.4
Ireland -1.9 -0.5 -0.3 0.2 0.0 -0.9
Italy -2.6 -2.5 -2.3 -2.1 -2.0 -2.6
Japan -3.6 -3.4 -3.5 -3.2 -3.1 -3.9
Lithuania -0.2 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.3 -1.0
Latvia -1.4 0.1 -0.5 -0.3 -0.4 -0.8
Netherlands -2.0 0.4 1.1 2.1 1.8 -1.4
Poland -2.6 -2.3 -1.7 -1.3 -0.7 -2.0
Portugal -4.4 -2.0 -3.0 -1.6 -1.1 -1.8
Romania -0.8 -3.0 -2.9 -3.5 -3.3 -2.0
Slovakia -2.7 -2.2 -1.0 -0.1 0.3 0.1
Slovenia -2.9 -1.9 0.0 0.4 0.1 -1.5
Spain -5.3 -4.5 -3.1 -2.3 -2.0 -2.4
Sweden 0.2 1.2 1.3 1.9 1.8 -0.5
UK -4.2 -2.9 -1.8 -1.9 -1.7 -1.7
US -4.3 -5.0 -3.6 -5.3 -5.1 -4.0
Government debt (per cent of GDP, end year) (b)
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2024
Australia 43.9 44.9 45.5 45.2 44.1 38.2
Australia 40.3 40.9 42.6 43.0 42.6 37.4
Austria 84.6 83.5 78.2 73.2 69.4 61.3
Belgium 106.1 106.0 103.4 99.0 95.5 86.6
Bulgaria -- -- -- -- -- --
Canada 97.3 95.7 92.3 89.8 87.4 79.6
Czech Rep. 38.7 35.6 33.3 31.8 29.1 24.7
Denmark 39.9 37.9 36.4 35.1 34.2 32.2
Estonia -- -- -- -- -- --
Finland 63.5 63.0 61.4 59.6 57.2 53.7
France 95.6 96.7 96.7 96.5 95.4 91.8
Germany 71.0 68.2 64.1 59.1 54.2 42.5
Greece 177.1 181.1 179.2 174.5 168.1 134.9
Hungary 76.5 75.2 73.1 68.9 66.8 62.4
Ireland 77.1 72.9 68.1 61.6 58.8 49.9
Italy 131.6 132.0 131.7 129.4 127.4 121.4
Japan 216.4 221.8 222.2 224.4 222.0 212.6
Lithuania -- -- -- -- -- --
Latvia -- -- -- -- -- --
Netherlands 64.6 61.8 56.7 51.7 47.8 43.3
Poland 52.2 53.5 51.4 46.6 43.9 42.1
Portugal 128.8 129.9 125.7 122.6 119.2 107.9
Romania -- -- -- -- -- --
Slovakia -- -- -- -- -- --
Slovenia -- -- -- -- -- --
Spain 99.4 99.0 98.3 96.2 93.7 85.1
Sweden 44.2 42.2 40.6 37.3 33.8 26.5
UK 87.3 87.3 87.0 85.5 84.2 77.8
US 104.1 105.4 103.4 103.5 103.7 103.8
Notes: (a) General government financial balance; Maastricht
definition for EU countries, (b) Maastricht definition for
EU countries.
Table B3. Unemployment and current account balance
Standardised unemployment rate
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020-24
Australia 6.1 5.7 5.6 5.5 5.1 5.2
Austria 5.7 6.0 5.5 4.7 4.5 4.5
Belgium 8.5 7.8 7.1 6.0 6.2 5.7
Bulgaria 9.1 7.6 6.2 5.0 5.2 5.9
Canada 6.9 7.0 6.3 6.0 6.2 6.1
China -- -- -- -- -- --
Czech Rep. 5.1 3.9 2.9 2.5 2.8 3.3
Denmark 6.2 6.2 5.7 5.1 5.1 5.3
Estonia 6.2 6.8 5.8 5.2 5.2 6.4
Finland 9.3 8.9 8.6 7.9 7.9 7.8
France 10.4 10.1 9.4 9.1 8.7 8.3
Germany 4.7 4.1 3.8 3.4 3.2 3.7
Greece 25.0 23.5 21.5 20.4 19.7 16.6
Hungary 6.8 5.1 4.2 4.0 4.1 3.7
Ireland 9.9 8.4 6.7 5.5 5.2 5.1
Italy 11.9 11.7 11.3 10.9 10.7 10.5
Japan 3.4 3.1 2.8 2.3 2.7 3.2
Lithuania 9.1 7.9 7.1 6.8 7.3 7.6
Latvia 9.9 9.6 8.7 7.3 6.8 6.6
Netherlands 6.9 6.0 4.8 4.0 3.6 3.8
Poland 7.5 6.2 4.9 4.0 4.0 3.8
Portugal 12.6 11.2 9.0 7.7 7.5 6.4
Romania 6.8 5.9 4.9 4.7 4.9 4.9
Slovakia 11.5 9.7 8.1 7.2 7.6 8.1
Slovenia 9.0 8.0 6.6 5.3 5.8 6.3
Spain 22.1 19.6 17.2 15.5 14.3 14.0
Sweden 7.4 6.9 6.7 6.4 6.3 6.6
UK 5.4 4.9 4.4 4.2 4.2 4.7
US 5.3 4.9 4.3 3.8 3.7 4.6
Current account balance (per cent of GDP)
2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020-24
Australia -4.7 -3.1 -2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -1.6
Austria 1.9 2.1 1.9 3.0 3.0 2.1
Belgium -0.2 0.1 -0.2 0.8 -0.4 0.5
Bulgaria 0.0 2.3 4.6 3.3 4.5 1.9
Canada -3.6 -3.2 -2.9 -2.7 -1.9 -0.4
China 2.8 1.8 1.3 0.6 0.5 1.1
Czech Rep. 0.2 1.5 0.9 -1.3 -2.1 -0.8
Denmark 8.8 7.3 7.9 7.9 6.9 8.6
Estonia 1.9 1.9 3.2 1.8 0.6 -1.1
Finland -0.9 -0.4 0.7 -0.2 -0.5 0.6
France -0.4 -0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 -0.2
Germany 9.0 8.5 8.1 8.5 8.2 7.3
Greece -0.2 -1.0 -0.7 0.3 0.7 1.3
Hungary 3.5 6.1 3.1 4.5 4.8 2.3
Ireland 10.9 3.4 12.4 7.3 7.5 11.5
Italy 1.5 2.6 2.8 2.3 2.6 4.3
Japan 3.1 3.8 4.0 3.4 3.4 4.6
Lithuania -2.8 -1.1 0.8 0.5 -1.9 -3.5
Latvia -0.5 1.4 -0.8 0.6 0.4 -1.0
Netherlands 6.3 8.0 10.5 10.0 9.0 8.4
Poland -0.6 -0.3 0.3 0.9 2.3 -0.4
Portugal 0.3 0.6 0.7 -0.3 -1.1 -1.1
Romania -1.2 -2.1 -3.4 -4.0 -3.0 -2.4
Slovakia -1.7 -1.5 -2.1 -2.8 -1.8 -0.8
Slovenia 4.4 5.3 6.4 6.2 3.1 0.5
Spain 1.1 1.9 1.9 0.7 1.1 2.5
Sweden 4.5 4.2 3.3 3.9 5.3 6.6
UK -4.9 -5.2 -3.9 -3.3 -3.5 -3.4
US -2.3 -2.3 -2.3 -2.8 -3.2 -3.6
Table B4. United States
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 2.6 2.9 1.5 2.3
Consumption 2.9 3.6 2.7 2.8
Investment : housing 3.5 10.2 5.5 1.8
: business 6.9 2.3 -0.6 4.7
Government : consumption -0.5 1.3 1.0 0.1
: investment -1.4 1.6 -0.2 0.1
Stockbuilding (a) -0.1 0.2 -0.4 -0.1
Total domestic demand 2.7 3.5 1.6 2.4
Export volumes 4.3 0.4 -0.3 3.4
Import volumes 4.5 5.0 1.3 4.0
Average earnings 2.6 2.8 1.1 1.6
Private consumption deflator 1.5 0.3 1.2 1.7
RPDI 3.6 4.1 1.4 1.1
Unemployment, % 6.2 5.3 4.9 4.3
General Govt, balance as % of GDP -4.9 -4.3 -5.0 -3.6
General Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 103.0 104.1 105.4 103.4
Current account as % of GDP -2.1 -2.3 -2.3 -2.3
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 2.9 2.7 2.2
Consumption 2.5 2.7 2.0
Investment : housing 2.9 5.6 3.3
: business 7.3 5.3 2.8
Government : consumption 1.2 1.5 1.6
: investment 1.3 1.3 1.7
Stockbuilding (a) 0.0 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 2.9 2.9 2.1
Export volumes 5.5 4.3 3.6
Import volumes 5.2 5.4 2.6
Average earnings 2.6 3.3 3.2
Private consumption deflator 2.3 2.3 2.1
RPDI 2.1 2.8 1.7
Unemployment, % 3.8 3.7 4.6
General Govt, balance as % of GDP -5.3 -5.1 -4.4
General Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 103.5 103.7 104.2
Current account as % of GDP -2.8 -3.2 -3.6
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP. (b) End-of-year basis.
Table B5. Canada
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 2.9 1.0 1.4 3.0
Consumption 2.6 2.2 2.3 3.4
Investment : housing 2.2 3.8 3.3 2.9
: business 4.5 -11.0 -9.2 2.9
Government : consumption 0.5 1.6 2.2 2.3
: investment -3.4 0.3 5.1 3.8
Stockbuilding (a) -0.4 -0.2 -0.2 0.7
Total domestic demand 1.8 0.3 1.0 3.8
Export volumes 5.9 3.5 1.0 1.1
Import volumes 2.3 0.7 -1.0 3.6
Average earnings 3.3 1.7 1.1 2.6
Private consumption deflator 1.9 1.1 0.9 1.1
RPDI 1.3 3.4 1.5 3.6
Unemployment, % 6.9 6.9 7.0 6.3
General Govt, balance as % of GDP 0.2 -0.1 -1.1 -1.1
General Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 91.0 97.3 95.7 92.3
Current account as % of GDP -2.4 -3.6 -3.2 -2.9
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 2.4 2.2 1.8
Consumption 2.3 2.0 1.5
Investment : housing 1.6 2.3 2.2
: business 7.2 1.9 0.7
Government : consumption 2.7 2.0 1.8
: investment 5.6 2.7 2.0
Stockbuilding (a) 0.1 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 2.9 2.0 1.5
Export volumes 3.0 4.9 3.5
Import volumes 4.9 4.1 2.5
Average earnings 3.8 3.2 3.5
Private consumption deflator 2.0 2.1 2.0
RPDI 3.0 1.7 1.5
Unemployment, % 6.0 6.2 6.1
General Govt, balance as % of GDP -1.6 -1.5 -1.6
General Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 89.8 87.4 82.3
Current account as % of GDP -2.7 -1.9 -0.4
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP. (b) End-of-year basis.
Table B6. Japan
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 0.3 1.4 1.0 1.7
Consumption -0.9 0.0 0.1 1.0
Investment : housing -4.0 -1.2 5.6 2.7
: business 5.2 3.4 0.6 2.9
Government : consumption 0.5 1.5 1.3 0.4
: investment 0.6 -1.3 0.1 1.2
Stockbuilding (a) 0.1 0.3 -0.2 -0.1
Total domestic demand 0.3 1.0 0.4 1.2
Export volumes 9.3 2.9 1.7 6.7
Import volumes 8.2 0.7 -1.6 3.5
Average earnings 0.9 0.9 1.7 0.9
Private consumption deflator 2.0 0.4 -0.5 0.2
RPDI -1.7 1.3 1.7 1.0
Unemployment, % 3.6 3.4 3.1 2.8
Govt, balance as % of GDP -5.4 -3.6 -3.4 -3.5
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 216.8 216.4 221.8 222.2
Current account as % of GDP 0.8 3.1 3.8 4.0
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 1.0 1.0 0.9
Consumption 0.6 0.7 1.1
Investment : housing -2.4 2.4 2.7
: business 2.4 1.6 1.1
Government : consumption 0.3 0.1 0.2
: investment 0.2 1.2 0.4
Stockbuilding (a) 0.1 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 0.8 0.8 1.0
Export volumes 4.4 3.4 3.5
Import volumes 3.4 2.3 3.7
Average earnings 2.2 2.1 1.7
Private consumption deflator 0.8 1.4 1.2
RPDI 1.2 0.3 1.5
Unemployment, % 2.3 2.7 3.2
Govt, balance as % of GDP -3.2 -3.1 -3.3
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 224.4 222.0 215.5
Current account as % of GDP 3.4 3.4 4.6
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP. (b) End-of-year basis.
Table B7. Euro Area
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 1.4 2.0 1.8 2.6
Consumption 0.9 1.8 1.9 1.7
Private investment 2.3 3.0 3.6 5.0
Government : consumption 0.7 1.3 1.8 1.2
: investment -0.8 3.2 1.2 1.2
Stockbuilding (a) 0.3 0.0 -0.2 0.0
Total domestic demand 1.3 1.9 2.0 2.1
Export volumes 4.6 6.2 3.3 5.5
Import volumes 4.9 6.5 4.6 4.5
Average earnings 1.4 1.6 1.4 1.4
Harmonised consumer prices 0.4 0.0 0.2 1.5
RPDI 0.9 1.4 1.9 1.2
Unemployment, % 11.6 10.9 10.0 9.1
Govt, balance as % of GDP -2.5 -2.0 -1.5 -0.9
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 92.6 90.7 89.7 87.3
Current account as % of GDP 2.4 3.2 3.6 3.5
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 2.2 2.0 1.3
Consumption 1.6 1.5 1.1
Private investment 4.4 3.7 1.7
Government : consumption 1.3 1.8 1.4
: investment 1.7 2.4 1.5
Stockbuilding (a) 0.2 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 2.3 2.0 1.3
Export volumes 2.2 2.9 2.8
Import volumes 2.1 3.1 2.8
Average earnings 2.1 2.4 2.9
Harmonised consumer prices 1.8 1.6 1.8
RPDI 1.6 2.0 1.5
Unemployment, % 8.4 8.0 7.9
Govt, balance as % of GDP -0.4 -0.5 -1.3
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 83.8 80.5 74.7
Current account as % of GDP 3.7 3.5 3.6
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.
Table B8. Germany
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 1.9 1.5 1.9 2.5
Consumption 1.0 1.6 1.9 2.0
Investment : housing 3.1 -1.2 3.8 3.6
: business 4.8 1.4 2.5 4.0
Government : consumption 1.5 2.9 3.7 1.5
: investment -1.2 4.5 2.6 4.6
Stockbuilding (a) -0.3 -0.3 -0.1 0.1
Total domestic demand 1.3 1.5 2.4 2.4
Export volumes 4.5 4.7 2.4 5.3
Import volumes 3.5 5.2 3.8 5.6
Average earnings 2.5 3.0 2.9 2.3
Harmonised consumer prices 0.8 0.1 0.4 1.7
RPDI 1.5 1.9 2.2 2.0
Unemployment, % 5.0 4.7 4.1 3.8
Govt, balance as % of GDP 0.5 0.8 1.0 1.3
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 74.7 71.0 68.2 64.1
Current account as % of GDP 7.5 9.0 8.5 8.1
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 2.1 2.0 1.2
Consumption 1.6 2.4 0.8
Investment : housing 2.8 2.1 1.9
: business 4.0 3.9 1.6
Government : consumption 1.8 2.9 1.0
: investment 4.8 3.9 1.2
Stockbuilding (a) -0.1 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 2.0 2.7 1.1
Export volumes 2.5 3.3 2.8
Import volumes 2.5 5.2 2.7
Average earnings 3.2 3.4 3.2
Harmonised consumer prices 2.0 1.9 1.8
RPDI 1.8 2.1 1.2
Unemployment, % 3.4 3.2 3.7
Govt, balance as % of GDP 1.6 1.2 -0.1
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 59.1 54.2 46.1
Current account as % of GDP 8.5 8.2 7.3
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.
Table B9. France
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 1.0 1.0 1.1 2.3
Consumption 0.8 1.4 2.0 1.1
Investment : housing -3.0 -1.5 2.8 5.6
: business 3.0 3.4 3.4 5.2
Government : consumption 1.3 1.0 1.4 1.4
: investment -5.4 -4.7 0.1 1.6
Stockholding (a) 0.7 0.3 -0.1 0.4
Total domestic demand 1.5 1.5 1.8 2.4
Export volumes 3.4 4.4 1.5 4.7
Import volumes 4.9 5.7 3.1 4.1
Average earnings 1.8 0.9 1.4 1.2
Harmonised consumer prices 0.6 0.1 0.3 1.2
RPDI 1.2 0.9 1.8 1.4
Unemployment, % 10.3 10.4 10.1 9.4
Govt, balance as % of GDP -3.9 -3.6 -3.4 -2.6
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 94.7 95.6 96.7 96.7
Current account as % of GDP -1.0 -0.4 -0.8 -0.6
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 1.9 1.8 1.5
Consumption 1.0 0.8 0.6
Investment : housing 3.3 4.8 6.2
: business 3.4 3.6 1.9
Government : consumption 1.3 1.3 1.7
: investment 2.7 3.5 2.0
Stockholding (a) -0.2 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 1.3 1.6 1.4
Export volumes 4.4 3.9 2.9
Import volumes 2.6 3.3 2.7
Average earnings 1.1 1.3 2.9
Harmonised consumer prices 2.0 1.4 1.7
RPDI 1.1 1.3 1.4
Unemployment, % 9.1 8.7 8.3
Govt, balance as % of GDP -2.1 -2.1 -2.5
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 96.5 95.4 92.3
Current account as % of GDP -0.4 -0.2 -0.2
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.
Table B10. Italy
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 0.2 0.8 1.0 1.6
Consumption 0.2 1.9 1.4 1.4
Investment : housing -6.8 -1.7 2.9 2.2
: business 0.6 4.0 4.3 5.7
Government : consumption -0.7 -0.6 0.6 0.1
: investment -5.4 -1.2 -1.0 -2.5
Stockbuilding (a) 0.7 0.0 -0.3 -0.2
Total domestic demand 0.3 1.4 1.3 1.3
Export volumes 2.4 4.2 2.6 6.0
Import volumes 3.0 6.6 3.8 5.7
Average earnings 0.4 0.9 0.1 0.3
Harmonised consumer prices 0.2 0.1 -0.1 1.3
RPDI 0.5 1.2 1.3 0.6
Unemployment, % 12.6 1 1.9 11.7 11.3
Govt, balance as % of GDP -3.0 -2.6 -2.5 -2.3
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 131.7 131.6 132.0 131.7
Current account as % of GDP 1.9 1.5 2.6 2.8
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 1.3 1.2 1.1
Consumption 1.1 0.6 0.5
Investment : housing 2.3 1.2 0.8
: business 3.7 3.6 0.6
Government : consumption 0.6 1.2 0.9
: investment 2.8 2.8 1.0
Stockbuilding (a) 0.4 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 1.8 1.2 0.6
Export volumes -0.2 2.0 3.0
Import volumes 1.3 1.8 1.5
Average earnings 1.7 1.7 1.7
Harmonised consumer prices 1.3 1.3 1.4
RPDI 2.1 1.6 0.5
Unemployment, % 10.9 10.7 10.5
Govt, balance as % of GDP -2.1 -2.0 -2.4
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 129.4 127.4 123.1
Current account as % of GDP 2.3 2.6 4.3
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.
Table B11. Spain
Percentage change
2014 2015 2016 2017
GDP 1.4 3.4 3.3 3.1
Consumption 1.5 3.0 3.0 2.4
Investment : housing 11.3 -1.0 4.4 8.3
: business -2.5 7.7 3.2 3.8
Government : consumption -0.3 2.1 0.8 1.6
: investment 8.8 16.5 2.2 2.5
Stockbuilding (a) 0.2 0.4 0.0 0.1
Total domestic demand 2.0 4.0 2.6 2.9
Export volumes 4.3 4.2 4.8 5.0
Import volumes 6.6 5.9 2.7 4.7
Average earnings 0.0 1.9 -0.1 1.3
Harmonised consumer prices -0.2 -0.6 -0.3 2.0
RPDI 1.2 2.3 1.9 0.0
Unemployment, % 24.5 22.1 19.6 17.2
Govt, balance as % of GDP -6.0 -5.3 -4.5 -3.1
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 100.4 99.4 99.0 98.3
Current account as % of GDP 1.0 1.1 1.9 1.9
Average
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP 2.8 2.5 1.5
Consumption 2.4 1.8 1.7
Investment : housing 7.8 4.0 3.2
: business 4.1 2.5 -0.4
Government : consumption 1.9 1.9 1.9
: investment -0.3 1.0 1.8
Stockbuilding (a) 0.0 0.0 0.0
Total domestic demand 2.7 2.1 1.6
Export volumes 3.1 3.2 2.1
Import volumes 2.7 1.9 2.7
Average earnings 2.1 2.0 3.4
Harmonised consumer prices 1.9 1.5 1.9
RPDI 1.4 2.7 2.0
Unemployment, % 15.5 14.3 14.0
Govt, balance as % of GDP -2.3 -2.0 -2.3
Govt, debt as % of GDP (b) 96.2 93.7 87.2
Current account as % of GDP 0.7 1.1 2.5
Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.
Barry Naisbitt with Arno Hantzsche, Jason Lennard, Cyrille Lenoel,
Iana Liadze, Marta Lopresto, Rebecca Piggott and Craig Thamotheram *
* All questions and comments related to the forecast and its
underlying assumptions should be addressed to Iana Liadze
(i.liadze@niesr.ac.uk). We would like to thank Jagjit Chadha, Amit Kara
and Garry Young for helpful comments and Yanitsa Kazalova for compiling
the database underlying the forecast The forecast was completed on 25
July, 2018. Exchange rate, interest rate and equity price assumptions
are based on information available to 12 July 2018. Unless otherwise
specified, the source of all data reported in tables and figures is the
NiGEM database and NIESR forecast baseline.
Caption: Figure 1. World annual GDP growth fan chart (per cent per
annum)
Caption: Figure 2. World GDP growth and its components
Caption: Figure 3. US GDP in expansions
Caption: Figure 4. Consumer price inflation
Caption: Figure 5. Shiller cyclically adjusted price-earnings ratio
for the S&P 500
Caption: Figure A1. Impact on the level of GDP (in the third year)
Caption: Figure A2. Impact on inflation (in the third year)
Caption: Figure B1. 2017 public debt and budget balance in Euro
Area countries (per cent of GDP)
Caption: Figure B2. First-year fiscal multipliers and spillovers
from a 1 per cent of GDP temporary fiscal expansion
Caption: Figure 6. US: Unemployment and labour force participation
rates
Caption: Figure 7. US: Annual GDP growth fan chart (per cent per
annum)
Caption: Figure 8. Canada: Labour market developments
Caption: Figure 9. Euro Area: Export growth
Caption: Figure 10. Euro Area: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 11. Germany: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 12. Germany: Growth in exports to main trading
partners
Caption: Figure 13. France: Harmonised consumer price inflation
Caption: Figure 14. France: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 15. Italy: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 16. Spain: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 17. Japan: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 18. China: Credit growth to non-financial
corporations
Caption: Figure 19. China: Contributions to GDP growth
Caption: Figure 20. Russia: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 21. India: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure 22. Brazil: GDP growth and inflation
Caption: Figure A1. 10-year government bond yields
Caption: Figure A2. Spreads over 10-year German government bond
yields
Caption: Figure A3. Corporate bond spreads. Spread between BAA
corporate and 10-year government bond yields
Caption: Figure A4. Effective exchange rates
Caption: Figure A5. Oil prices
Caption: Figure A6. Share prices
Caption: Figure B1. World GDP is estimated to have expanded by 3.8
per cent (year-on-year) in the first quarter of 2018
Caption: Figure B2. NIESR estimates that world trade grew by 4.9
per cent (year-on-year) in 2018Q1
Caption: Figure B3. China is not expected to become the
world's biggest importer of goods and services before 2023
Caption: Figure B4. Since 2014, on a PPP basis, China has remained
the world's largest economy
Table 1. Forecast summary
Percentage change
Real GDP (a)
World OECD China EU-28 Euro USA
2008-13 3.3 0.8 9.1 0.0 -0.2 0.8
2014 3.6 2.2 7.3 1.8 1.4 2.6
2015 3.5 2.5 6.9 2.2 2.0 2.9
2016 3.2 1.8 6.7 1.9 1.8 1.5
2017 3.8 2.6 6.9 2.6 2.6 2.3
2018 3.9 2.5 6.6 2.2 2.2 2.9
2019 3.8 2.3 6.3 2.1 2.0 2.7
2020-24 3.6 1.9 5.8 1.5 1.3 2.2
Real GDP (a)
Japan Germany France Italy UK Canada
2008-13 0.2 0.7 0.4 -1.5 0.4 1.4
2014 0.3 1.9 1.0 0.2 2.9 2.9
2015 1.4 1.5 1.0 0.8 2.3 1.0
2016 1.0 1.9 1.1 1.0 1.8 1.4
2017 1.7 2.5 2.3 1.6 1.7 3.0
2018 1.0 2.1 1.9 1.3 1.4 2.4
2019 1.0 2.0 1.8 1.2 1.7 2.2
2020-24 0.9 1.2 1.5 1.1 1.8 1.8
Private consumption deflator
World
trade (b) OECD Euro USA Japan
Area
2008-13 3.2 1.8 1.5 1.7 -0.7
2014 3.9 1.6 0.5 1.5 2.0
2015 2.8 0.8 0.3 0.3 0.4
2016 2.6 1.1 0.3 1.2 -0.5
2017 5.0 2.1 1.5 1.7 0.2
2018 4.1 2.6 1.6 2.3 0.8
2019 4.2 2.5 1.6 2.3 1.4
2020-24 4.0 2.3 1.7 2.1 1.2
Private consumption deflator
Germany France Italy UK Canada
2008-13 1.3 1.0 1.9 2.5 1.3
2014 0.9 0.1 0.3 1.9 1.9
2015 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.5 1.1
2016 0.6 -0.2 0.1 1.4 0.9
2017 1.7 1.3 1.2 2.1 1.1
2018 1.9 1.6 1.2 2.5 2.0
2019 1.9 1.4 1.3 1.9 2.1
2020-24 1.8 1.7 1.4 2.0 2.0
Interest rates (c) Oil
($ per
USA Japan Euro barrel)
Area (d)
2008-13 0.6 0.2 1.5 95.5
2014 0.3 0.1 0.2 99.6
2015 0.3 0.1 0.1 52.8
2016 0.5 -0.1 0.0 43.4
2017 1.1 -0.1 0.0 53.5
2018 1.9 -0.1 0.0 72.1
2019 2.7 -0.1 0.1 74.7
2020-24 3.5 0.3 1.3 78.7
Notes: Forecast produced using the NiGEM model,
(a) GDP growth at market prices. Regional aggregates
are based on PPP shares, 2011 reference year. (b) Trade
in goods and services, (c) Central bank intervention rate,
period average, (d) Average of Dubai and Brent spot prices.
Table B1. First-year fiscal multipliers from a
1 per cent of GDP temporary fiscal expansion
(percentage deviations of GDP from baseline)
Effects on:
Fiscal Germany France Italy Spain
expansion by:
Germany 0.42 0.07 0.05 0.04
France 0.05 0.53 0.03 0.04
Italy 0.04 0.04 0.49 0.03
Spain 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.76
Netherlands 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01
Others 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.03
Isolated 0.42 0.53 0.49 0.76
Co-ordinated 0.59 0.71 0.61 0.91
Trade spillovers 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2
Effects on:
Fiscal Netherlands Others Euro Area
expansion by:
Germany 0.25 0.09 0.19
France 0.12 0.03 0.15
Italy 0.09 0.03 0.11
Spain 0.04 0.02 0.11
Netherlands 0.50 0.01 0.05
Others 0.10 0.44 0.11
Isolated 0.50 0.44
Co-ordinated 1.09 0.63 0.72
Trade spillovers 0.5 0.3
Sources: NiGEM database and simulations
Notes: trade spillovers are computed as the differential
between the fiscal multiplier generated by the co-ordinated
expansion relative to the isolated one, as a share of the
co-ordinated.
COPYRIGHT 2018 National Institute of Economic and Social Research
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.