Jobs for the Heartland: Place-Based Policies in 21st-century America.
Austin, Benjamin ; Glaeser, Edward ; Summers, Lawrence 等
Jobs for the Heartland: Place-Based Policies in 21st-century America.
Do America's profound spatial economic disparities require
spatially targeted policies? Traditionally, economists have been
skeptical about these policies because of a conviction that relief is
best targeted toward poor people rather than poor places, because
incomes in poor areas were converging toward incomes in rich areas
anyway, and because of fears that favoring one location would impoverish
another. In this paper, we argue for reconsidering place-based policies,
because (i) convergence has stalled or reversed in recent decades; (ii)
social problems are increasingly linked to a lack of jobs rather than a
lack of income, and subsidizing job creation may be easier at the place
level than at the person level; and (iii) a modest body of evidence
suggests that increasing the demand for labor has a materially greater
impact on nonemployment in depressed areas. Place-based policies can
take the form of more generous employment subsidies in depressed areas,
which provide implicit insurance against place-based shocks but distort
migration decisions, or equivalently generous policies that tilt
existing programs to encourage employment in areas with more
joblessness.
America's regions have long displayed enormous economic
disparities, but for most of the 20th century, poorer states were
catching up rapidly (Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1991) and high local
unemployment rates did not persist (Blanchard and Katz 1992). Migration
flowed to high-income regions, and capital was attracted by low wages in
poorer areas. Both flows helped incomes to converge.
In recent decades, regional income convergence has slowed or even
reversed (Berry and Glaeser 2005; Moretti 2011), and place-based
non-employment has become durable. Over the past 40 years, migration has
stopped flowing to high-income regions and has declined more generally
(Ganong and Shoag 2017). Economic divisions across space loom as the
backdrop to our political divisions (Autor and others 2017).
In section I of this paper, we document the hardening of
America's geographic divisions, and the rise of nonemployment among
men age 25-54, who are the focus of this paper. Many measures of
well-being suggest that not working is a far worse outcome than
low-income employment, which motivates our focus on employment rather
than income. (1) Regional disparities in joblessness are large. In 2016,
the nonemployment rate for men age 25-54 was over 35 percent in Flint,
Michigan, and was 5 percent in Alexandria, Virginia.
We divide the United States into three regions based on year of
statehood: the prosperous coasts, the western heartland, and the eastern
heartland. The coasts have high incomes, but the western heartland also
benefits from natural resources and historically high levels of
education. America's social problems--including nonemployment,
disability, opioid-related deaths, and rising mortality--are
concentrated in America's eastern heartland, states from
Mississippi to Michigan, generally east of the Mississippi River and not
on the Atlantic Coast. The income and employment gaps between the three
regions are not converging, but instead seem to be hardening into
semipermanent examples of economic hysteresis.
The European Union has long embraced place-based policies that
target distressed areas, but U.S. national policy has typically adopted
geographic uniformity. Place-based policies are popular with place-based
politicians, but economists often emphasize that a national perspective
pushes toward helping poor people, not helping poor places. In section
II, we analyze the economic rationales for place-based policies.
An abundant body of literature documents agglomeration economies
and human capital externalities (Duranton and Puga 2004; Combes,
Duranton, and Gobillon 2008; Moretti 2011). Although such externalities
suggest market failure, they do not imply any particular spatial policy.
Both New York and Appalachia might benefit from more economic activity
and more skilled residents, but we do not know if it is optimal to shift
skills and density from New York to Appalachia or vice versa.
A second justification for place-based policies is to insure
residents against place-based economic shocks, just as the federal
government already provides some insurance against place-based natural
disasters. In 1969, Detroit residents had higher incomes than Boston
residents, but today Boston residents are 40 percent wealthier. (2) But
smoothing income differences across states would only modestly reduce
income inequality. Controlling for states explains only 1.1 percent of
the variation in income levels; even the smaller Public Use Microdata
Areas (PUMAs) can explain only 6.6 percent of the variation in income.
Smoothing income differences across smaller geographic areas would
distort migration, raise housing costs in low-income areas, and
potentially even concentrate poverty.
The most compelling case for place-based policies is that
one-size-fits-all interventions are woefully inappropriate for regional
economies as diverse as Appalachia and Silicon Valley. Subsidizing
employment, either at the individual or firm level, makes little sense
in an economy as robust as that of the San Francisco Bay Area, where the
restricted housing supply limits future population growth. If
nonemployment is much more sensitive to subsidies in West Virginia, then
larger proemployment subsidies in that state seem likely to reduce
suffering more.
Place-based policies need not mean large-scale transfers to
distressed areas, but instead the tailoring of policies to particular
locales. For example, a bevy of current social welfare
policies--including the Housing Choice Voucher Program (Section 8), the
Supplemental Nutritional Assistance Program, and disability
insurance--currently implicitly tax earnings. The implicit taxes on
housing vouchers and food stamps could be reduced for low-income workers
from 30 percent to 20 percent in areas where employment is particularly
responsive to the returns to working.
Indeed, even the most die-hard opponent of place-based
redistribution should see the logic of tailoring federal policies to
local labor market conditions. Standard social policy rules, like the
Baily--Chetty formula for unemployment insurance (Baily 1978; Chetty
2006), depend on parameters that differ across space. If nonemployment
is particularly harmful in one location and particularly sensitive to
public policies, then that die-hard opponent could still support a
place-based, revenue-neutral twist that reallocates funds from benefits
that discourage working to benefits that encourage employment in that
area, without encouraging migration or raising housing prices.
We use a modified Baily--Chetty formula to analyze benefits for the
not working and for marginal workers. The formula depends on two
parameters: the ratio of the externalities associated with nonemployment
to the wages of low-income workers, and the heterogeneous response of
employment rates to policy interventions. In section III, we look for
heterogeneous responses by testing whether exogenous shocks reduce
nonemployment more in high nonemployment states.
We first use industrial-composition Bartik shocks. These shocks do
reduce not-working rates more in states where the average not-working
rate is higher. China trade shocks--as identified by David Autor, David
Dorn, and Gordon Hanson (2013)--also have an impact on not-working rates
more in commuting zones with historically higher levels of
non-employment. Military spending shocks, used by Emi Nakamura and Jon
Steinsson (2014), also have a larger impact on not-working rates in
states where the average not-working rate is higher, but the difference
is statistically insignificant. Our results are far from definitive, but
they do support the perfectly unsurprising view that you can reduce
nonemployment more in places where nonemployment is currently high. We
hope that future research will do more to examine spatial heterogeneity
in labor supply elasticities, and the regional heterogeneity of labor
markets more broadly.
Section IV follows Robert Gordon (1973) and focuses on the
externalities of nonemployment, which include fiscal costs to the state,
costs borne by friends and family, and possibly also spillovers that
encourage more nonemployment (Topa 2001). We calibrate these costs to
range from 0.21 to 0.36 times the typical wages earned by low-income
workers, but recognize that these numbers are quite debatable. Using
these estimates, section V calibrates our model, which suggests that the
generosity of pro-employment programs relative to nonemployment benefits
should be higher in West Virginia than in Nebraska. The modified
Baily--Chetty formula also implies that subsidies should skew more
toward employment in regions of high employment elasticity when the
coefficient of relative risk aversion is low.
Section VI turns to a taxonomy of place-based policies, and
discusses their costs and benefits--including distorted mobility,
capitalization, and other deadweight losses. (3) Empowerment Zones
subsidize employment in high-poverty areas, and Matias Busso, Jesse
Gregory, and Patrick Kline (2013) find them to be effective. (4)
Attempts to use infrastructure to help depressed cities, such as the
Detroit People Mover, have had results that are far less encouraging.
But infrastructure, like that built by the Tennessee Valley Authority,
that actually delivers a scarce and enormously valuable resource, such
as electricity, can have large economic effects (Kline and Moretti
2013). Conversely, the Appalachian Regional Commission, which provides a
potpourri of placed-based support, including highways, seems to have
done little to change the region's fortunes.
We end with a discussion of plausible policies that account for
spatial heterogeneity in employment responses. We discuss strengthening
employment subsidies, either to the firm or to the worker, in states
with high non-employment. The employment effects of paying subsidies to
the firm, rather than the worker, will be stronger if workers'
wages face a lower minimum wage bound. We discuss tilting the incentives
that community colleges face to provide job counseling and
employment-appropriate vocational skills.
A wide body of literature suggests that education combats
joblessness at both the individual and regional levels, and investing in
education is a natural complement to subsidizing employment. Finally, we
mention policies that might have benign spatial effects even if they are
apparently neutral. A flat per-dollar employment subsidy would
presumably have a larger effect in low-cost states where prices are
lower.
I. The Geography of Jobless America
A belief in individual upward mobility reduces the desire for
income redistribution (Alesina, Miano, and Stantcheva, forthcoming).
Similarly, a belief in the upward mobility of regions limits the demand
for place-based policies. America has long tolerated dramatic economic
differences across space, partially because people regularly moved from
poor places to rich places and capital flowed freely from high-wage to
low-wage areas. In this section, we document five trends suggesting that
this mobility has fallen considerably and that America appears to be
evolving into durable islands of wealth and poverty. At the broadest
level, the nation can be divided into its wealthy, costly coasts; a
reasonably successful western heartland; and a painfully jobless eastern
heartland. These differences are driven mainly by historical differences
in human capital and the economic dislocation caused by
deindustrialization.
I.A. The Closing of the Metropolitan Frontier
The United States has long been a nation with enormous spatial
differences in income. In 1950, 18 states in the continental United
States had per capita earnings that were double the per capita earnings
of Mississippi. In 2016, Mississippi is still the nation's poorest
state, but there is no state with double its per capita income. Many of
Mississippi's poorest residents went north to the factories of
Chicago and Detroit (Smith and Welch 1989). Industry flowed south,
encouraged by probusiness policies, like right-to-work laws (Holmes
1998). America's western frontier may have closed at the end of the
19th century, but there was still a metropolitan frontier where workers
from depressed areas could find a more prosperous future.
Five facts collectively suggest that this geographic escape valve
has tightened: (i) declining geographic mobility, (ii) increasingly
inelastic housing supplies in high-income areas, (iii) declining income
convergence, (iv) increased sorting by skills across space, and (v)
persistent pockets of nonemployment. Together, these facts suggest that
even if income differences across space have declined, the remaining
economic differences may be a greater source of concern. Consequently,
it may be time to target pro-employment policies toward the most
distressed areas.
Figure 1 shows that between 1950 and 1992, intercounty mobility
never dropped below 6 percent. Since 2008, the share of U.S. residents
who moved across counties never exceeded 3.9 percent. The first steep
drop occurred between 1990 and 1995, and then another dip occurred after
2005. This decline in cross-county mobility is mirrored by the drop in
the within-county mobility rate, which fell from over 13 percent in the
1950s to 7 percent. Declining mobility appears among both renters and
owners; the change is not merely underwater borrowers held in place by
their mortgages.
The great wave of postwar mobility included the Great Migration of
African Americans north, the nationwide move to the Sunbelt, and massive
suburbanization. In these previous migrations, as had been true
throughout almost all of American history, housing was supplied
abundantly to meet migrants' demand. Suburbanization itself can be
seen as a massive shock to housing supply, generated by cars and
highways (Baum-Snow 2007), that enabled African Americans coming north
to occupy urban apartments (Boustan and Margo 2013). The growth of the
Sunbelt reflects a combination of economic resurgence, the taste for
warm weather, and few restrictions on the mass production of housing
(Glaeser and Tobio 2008).
Moreover, the African American migrants to the north had little to
lose by departing the Jim Crow South. As David Schleicher (2017)
emphasizes, poorer Americans today are held in place by public benefits,
such as housing vouchers, which can be difficult to carry across state
or even county lines. Ostensibly, such federal programs as Medicaid and
Temporary Assistance for Needy Families are administered at the state
level. A move across states requires a new application that may not be
approved.
Migration has both declined and become less directed toward
high-income areas (Ganong and Shoag 2017). The unskilled flooded into
high-income areas between 1940 and 1960, presumably bringing wages down,
but they did not do so between 1980 and 2010. Mai Dao, Davide Furceri,
and Prakash Loungani (2017) show that interstate migration due to labor
market shocks has declined since the 1990s. Mike Zabek (2018) shows that
stronger local ties to a region lead to lower migration rates in
response to labor market shocks.
Low-income workers still receive significant wage gains from
migrating to high-income areas, but the housing-related costs of moving
to these areas have grown. Housing costs within skilled cities have
risen particularly dramatically (Glaeser and Saiz 2004). Between 1978
and 2017, real housing prices in Detroit were relatively flat according
to the Federal Housing Finance Agency's repeat sales index, while
real housing prices increased in Boston by 200 percent and in San
Francisco by 300 percent. Many authors associate higher housing prices
with stringent land use regulations, especially in better-educated
communities (Gyourko, Saiz, and Summers 2008; Glaeser and Ward 2009).
(5)
Throughout most of U.S. history, economic productivity has been
accompanied by a near-elastic housing supply. The settlers who moved to
richer, western agricultural land in the 19th century built their own
inexpensive, balloon-frame homes. The farmers and immigrants who came to
Chicago in the 19th century readily piled into overcrowded tenements.
New York City built over 100,000 units annually in the early 1920s, when
the city experienced its post-World War I boom. Silicon Valley exploded
as an engine of American innovation, but it is practically synonymous
with stringent land use restrictions, including some areas with
60-acre-minimum lot sizes. Chang-Tai Hsieh and Enrico Moretti (2017)
estimate that these restrictions have led to a misallocation of labor
that has significantly reduced America's overall GDP.
An additional barrier to interstate migration has been the rise of
occupational licensing laws, which restrict the movement of workers
across state lines. Janna Johnson and Morris Kleiner (2017) find that
individuals in occupations with state-specific licensing requirements
have a 36 percent lower rate of interstate migration than comparable
workers in other occupations.
The skilled do still move toward higher-skill, higher-wage areas,
helping to ensure that skilled areas are become more skilled over time.
This is illustrated in figure 2, where we see that prime age male
migrants are significantly better educated than the nonmigrant
population in the PUMA that they left.
Christopher Berry and Edward Glaeser (2005) report a robust
correlation between the change across metropolitan areas in the
percentage of the population with a college degree and the initial share
of the population with a college degree in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s.
The increasing segregation of skilled labor matters because the skill
level of a locality is strongly correlated both with the levels of
earnings for nonskilled workers (Moretti 2004), and with longer-term
growth of incomes and population (Glaeser and Saiz 2004).
Increased geographic sorting by skill probably reflects a
combination of restrictions that stymie the construction of affordable
housing and workplace complementarities between educated employees. (6)
The innovations generated by highly skilled workers today appear
increasingly to demand the labor of skilled workers rather than
unskilled workers. Henry Ford's automated assembly lines depended
on tens of thousands of less-skilled workers, and hence his skills
strongly complemented less-skilled labor. Bill Gates's innovations
primarily employed highly skilled software programmers.
Declining in-migration to high-wage areas has been accompanied by a
decline in the convergence of incomes across states and metropolitan
areas. Robert Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1991) document the
striking convergence in per capita income levels across U.S. states
between 1880 and 1980. This convergence is the backdrop for the
shrinking gap between incomes in Mississippi and the rest of the United
States. Berry and Glaeser (2005) show that by the 1990s, changes in
metropolitan area incomes were no longer negatively correlated with
initial per capita incomes. Peter Ganong and Daniel Shoag (2017) find
that the relationship between state-level changes in per capita and
initial per capita income was much weaker from 1990 to 2010 than from
1940 to 1960.
Figure 3 shows the convergence of log median personal incomes
across 538 PUMAs between 1980 and 2010 for prime age men. The
coefficient is -0.16, which is far less than the -2.4 coefficient that
Ganong and Shoag (2017) report for states between 1940 and 1960. Even
that modest income convergence may be a spurious reflection of
measurement error in the 1980 variable. When we instrument for log
median income using the log of the 10th and 90th percentiles of income
in 1980 (the R- of the first-stage regression is .85), we estimate
[mathematical expression not reproducible]
Robust standard errors clustered by state are in parentheses. It
seems plausible that true income convergence has also disappeared at the
PUMA level.
I.B. The Rise of Joblessness among Men
The growth of geographic barriers within the United States has
coincided with the dramatic increase in not-working rates among prime
age men, which primarily reflects men leaving the labor force. The share
of prime age men who are not in the labor force has grown from under 4
percent during the 1950s to over 10 percent today. (7)
Throughout this paper, we focus on the total rate of not working
among prime age men, defined as men age 25-54, rather than unemployment
or labor force participation. We define the nonemployment rate (or
not-working rate) as the share of men who are not currently employed, or
1 minus the employment-to-population ratio for prime age men. We take
the view that the distinction between unemployment and labor force
nonparticipation is relatively arbitrary because almost all the not
working would presumably work if the price were right (Clark and Summers
1979). In many cases, those who are not currently looking for a job will
nevertheless return to employment in a short period of time.
When we examine prime age men entering the Current Population
Survey (CPS) from 2014 to 2016, whose monthly responses can be linked
for all eight months, we find that over half of men who left and
reentered employment during the 16-month CPS window recorded at least
one month that they were not in the labor force. (8) John Coglianese
(2017) refers to these men who leave and reenter the workforce as
"in-and-outs," and we believe it is important to distinguish
these men who are temporarily absent from the labor force from the
long-term not working. In addition, the expanding role of disability
insurance relative to unemployment insurance (Autor and Duggan 2003) may
mean that an increasing share of individuals who would once have
classified themselves as unemployed now list themselves as out of the
labor force.
Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence Katz (1992) show a practically
nonexistent relationship between the unemployment rate in 1975 and the
unemployment rate in 1985 across states. This nonrelationship supports
the idea that geographic differences in the not-working rate are a
temporary phenomenon that is rapidly undone through migration and
cyclical shocks. Figure 4 shows the relationship between the prime age
male not-working rate in 2010 and the prime age male not-working rate in
1980 across PUMAs. The correlation between the two rates is .80.
Moreover, the relationship shows diverging not-working rates because the
coefficient on the 1980 not-working rate is 1.10, which means that the
growth in the not-working rate is positively associated with the initial
not-working rate.
Figure 5 shows the time series of not-working men split into three
categories: unemployed (not employed and actively seeking work), not in
the labor force but wanting a job, and not in the labor force and not
wanting a job. (9) The share of prime age men who are not in the labor
force and do not want a job shows a steady upward trend. The share that
is unemployed undulates, severely peaking at 9 percent during the Great
Recession. The third category, not in the labor force but still wanting
a job, has held steady, at around 2 percent.
We prefer to focus on the distinction between the long-term and
short-term nonemployed, where being long-term nonemployed is more
associated with leaving the labor force and being short-term nonemployed
is more typically associated with unemployment. Figure 6 includes both
the total not-working rate and the share of men who have been without a
job for over a year, using data from the CPS's Annual Social and
Economic Supplement (ASEC).
I.C. The Misery of Joblessness
We focus on joblessness among prime age men, rather than income
inequality, because we see it as a far greater problem. There is
significant correlational evidence suggesting that misery haunts the
lives of the long-term not working. Figure 7 shows life satisfaction
rates by work status, using data from the Behavioral Risk Factor
Surveillance System.
In figure 7, we compare the not working with the employed with
annual household earnings of more than $50,000 per year, the employed
with annual household earnings of $35,000 to $50,000 per year, and the
employed with annual household earnings of less than $35,000 per year,
and show the share of the male population in each group that reports a
low level of life satisfaction. This number is quite low among those
earning more than $35,000 per year. Low life satisfaction rises for
those who are employed but earning less than $35,000 per year, but low
life satisfaction is much higher among those who are not employed.
Almost 20 percent of the not working in the eastern heartland report a
low level of life satisfaction.
Andrew Clark and Andrew Oswald (1994) report that unemployment has
a much more negative effect on happiness than low earnings. Andre Hajek
(2013) estimates the relationship between unemployment and unhappiness
with individual fixed effects and finds a significant negative effect,
especially if the unemployment is described as involuntary. Rainer
Winkelmann (2014) similarly finds that happiness drops significantly
after an individual becomes unemployed.
Happiness is not equivalent to utility. Parents of young children,
for example, are typically less happy, but they are presumably
compensated in other ways. (10) Yet it is hard to see what benefit is
offsetting unhappiness among the not working.
Nonemployment is also strongly correlated with mental health
problems. A large body of literature, surveyed by Stephen Piatt (1984),
connects suicide and unemployment. More recent studies include those by
Augustine Kposowa (2001) and by Tony Blakely, Sunny Collings, and June
Atkinson (2003). Over 30 percent of the not working report having more
than 10 days of poor mental health in the past month. Once again, the
gap between the not working and the poor-but-employed is much larger
than the gap between poor and rich employed workers.
Opioid use is another marker of pain associated with nonemployment,
as highlighted by Alan Krueger (2017). Like suicide, opioid use may be
another consequence of nonemployment. Because opioids can also lead to
addiction and death, they are an added cause of social pain.
I.D. The Geography of Joblessness
We now turn to the geography of joblessness in the United States.
We begin with two maps of the United States showing the geography of
prime age male nonemployment in 1980 and 2015. The 1980 data come from
the decennial census, and the 2015 data are based on three years of the
American Community Survey (2014-16)." We use consistent PUMAs.
Figure 8 shows that fewer than 10 percent of men were not employed
in 1980 in much of the western United States and in the northeastern
corridor. Coastal California and much of the Midwest and Southeast had
non-employment rates between 10 and 15 percent. Rates over 15 percent
were only seen in Appalachia and a few isolated parts of lower-density
America, including a PUMA in Arizona, upstate New York, and a few parts
of California.
Figure 9 shows that in 2015 the nonemployment rate has risen almost
everywhere, but people in the northeastern corridor and much of the
western United States still remain relatively more employed.
Nonemployment is high in the Far West--except for the areas around Los
Angeles, San Francisco, and Seattle--and in a great swath of Middle
America that runs from Louisiana up to Michigan. Appalachia remains a
place of tremendous economic dysfunction.
Women are more likely to work in northern areas, whether in the
East or the West, and are less likely to work in southern areas. (12) If
we regress the change in prime age male not-working rates on the change
in prime age female not-working rates at the PUMA level between 1980 and
2010, we find that the [R.sup.2] is only .094. These differences seem as
likely to be driven by cultural norms as by economic distress. The
shifts in male and female employment are not particularly correlated
with one another, meaning that the declining male employment rates
reflect economic distress that does not seem to be offset by increases
in female labor force participation.
Figure 10 looks at the long-term (more than 12 months) not-working
rate, and shows that there has also been strong divergence since 1980.
For every extra percentage point of men who were long-term not working
in 1980 (the first year we can calculate this number), the growth in
long-term not working increases by 0.84 percentage point between 1980
and 2014." Robert Hall (1972) documented that unemployment was
slightly higher in higher-wage cities, suggesting that workers were
being compensated for a greater risk of being unemployed; but today, the
relationship between non-employment and income is strongly negative.
These previous maps inspire our division of America into three
groups: the coastal states, the eastern heartland, and the western
heartland. The PUMA maps suggest that many states could likewise be
usefully divided. Inland California looks quite different from the San
Francisco Bay Area. Yet many data sources contain only state
identifiers, so we use state boundaries. We refer to states formed
before 1840 as the eastern heartland, and to those formed after 1840 as
the western heartland. (14)
The coastal states have seen their real economies grow by 342
percent from 1965 to 2016. The western heartland has grown by 475
percent over the same period. The eastern heartland has experienced the
most sluggish growth, at 187 percent. (15)
The parallel growth in GDP between the coasts and the western
heartland can be divided into growth in GDP per worker and growth in the
number of workers. Although per capita GDP growth has been faster on the
coasts, employment growth has been much faster in the western heartland.
The difference may reflect the far more elastic housing supply in the
western heartland, which welcomes workers in response to rising
productivity.
The trends in GDP are matched by the trends in the not-working
rate. Figure 11 shows the prime age male not-working rate since 1980.
Before the recession of the early 1980s, nonemployment was roughly
comparable on the coasts and in the eastern heartland. The western
heartland had the lowest levels of not working. Since 2000, this
ordering has been stable. The not-working rate has been highest in the
eastern heartland and lowest in the western heartland; the coasts are in
between.
Figure 12 shows mortality rates between the three regions for prime
age men. Between 1970 and the early 1980s, mortality fell smoothly for
all three regions and the ordering was stable. The western heartland was
the healthiest region of the country. During the early 1980s, male
mortality rose on the coasts, partially reflecting the scourge of AIDS.
Since the 1990s, the eastern heartland has been the outlier, with
relatively high, and even occasionally rising, levels of mortality for
prime age men. If we seek to understand the striking fact of rising
prime age male mortality, as noted by Anne Case and Angus Deaton (2015,
2017), we need to look at the eastern heartland.
Figure 13 shows county-level opioid prescriptions per capita across
the United States. These are particularly high in the low-employment
areas of the eastern heartland.
A final social problem is imprisonment, which effects a significant
share of the male population in many states. (16) Until the mid-1990s,
imprisonment rates were generally higher on the coasts than in the
western heartland. Between the mid-1990s and 2010, the western heartland
had the highest imprisonment rate. Now, both heartlands have
imprisonment rates that are dramatically higher than the imprisonment
rates on the coasts.
I.E. Why Does the Nonemployment Rate Vary across the United States?
Katharine Abraham and Melissa Kearney (2018) credit labor
demand-side factors (for example, competition with China and robots)
with one-third of the decline in the male employment rate since 1999.
Supply-side factors account for less than one-tenth of the change, but
much of the overall trend remains unexplained. At the national level,
since 1999 wages at the bottom of the distribution (the 10th percentile)
have been higher than they were in the 1970s, so it would seem that the
rising rate of nonemployment must at least partially reflect shifting
labor supply. (17) Although perhaps not all of those not working could
get a job paying $8.90 per hour in 1999, many surely could and chose not
to work for such low earnings. Mark Aguiar and others (2017) suggest
that the labor supply has shifted because of better entertainment
options, but the willingness to work at low wages may have also fallen
because of a more generous public and private safety net (for example,
working spouses) or changing preferences.
However, nonemployment is a lower-tail phenomenon that may be more
sensitive to the variance than to the mean of wage across space. If two
separate regional markets experience a mean-preserving wage spread, then
nonemployment in the low-wage market may rise dramatically while
non-employment in the high-wage area both starts and stays low. Even if
the aggregate pattern shows constant wages and rising nonemployment,
which is most compatible with a labor supply shift, regional patterns
may be more compatible with shifting labor demand.
Figure 14 shows a -.39 correlation between changes in log median
wages at the PUMA level and changes in the male nonemployment rate.
Moreover, many of the PUMAs with sharply rising nonemployment rates have
also experienced declining wages. Together, these facts suggest that
labor demand shocks are playing a significant role in explaining the
geography of joblessness.
What determines the spatial heterogeneity in labor demand?
Deindustrialization has been a particularly adverse shock for
less-skilled men, but that has been somewhat ameliorated in high-skilled
areas, like Seattle, by reinvention based on knowledge-intensive
industries. Consequently, the six regressions given in table 1 test
whether area-level education and industrial history can explain the
heterogeneity in joblessness. In regression 1, we find that 34 percent
of the variation in male nonemployment rates across PUMAs in 2010 can be
explained by two historical education variables: the share of the men
without a high school diploma, and the share of men with a college
degree in 1980. This effect combines both the direct impact of education
and any of the human capital externalities, as identified by James Rauch
(1993) and Moretti (2004).
In regression 2, we include the share of prime age male workers in
the PUMA in durable and nondurable manufacturing in 1980, and the
[R.sup.2] rises to .409. (18) A history in durable manufacturing, which
was particularly prevalent in the eastern heartland, predicts more
nonemployment today. (19) A history in nondurable manufacturing, which
was more prevalent in the western heartland and the Southeast, predicts
less nonemployment. Regression 3 shows the impact of adding two state
variables (January and July temperatures), which raise the [R.sup.2] to
.474. Higher January temperatures are associated with more
nonemployment, while higher July temperatures are associated with less
nonemployment (Boldin and Wright 2015).
The next three regressions in table 1 show the impact of the same
variables on median wages. Almost universally, the same variables that
are associated with higher median wages are also associated with lower
not-working rates. The one prominent exception is durable goods
manufacturing, which is associated with higher nonemployment rates and
higher wages. One interpretation of this fact is that durable
manufacturing industries developed the largest gap between wages paid to
incumbent workers and the reservation wages of not-working outsiders.
Can state policies explain the differences in nonemployment across
the United States? In the six regressions in table 2, we connect
joblessness with three different state-level policy measures: corruption
convictions, right-to-work laws (following Holmes 1998), and
occupational licensing laws (which may capture local opposition to
entrepreneurship). (20) We do not use instruments, and we are well aware
that few of our variables are truly exogenous. These regressions use
individual-level data, with standard errors clustered at the state
level.
Regression 1 shows the raw not-working rates between the three
regions, controlling for nothing else. In regression 2, we control for
individual education and historical area education, which wipes out the
not-working gap between the eastern heartland and the coasts, but makes
the gap between the western heartland and the coasts larger.
In regression 3, we also control for three state variables:
corruption convictions, right-to-work laws, and the share of the
population that has an occupational license. None of the variables has a
statistically significant effect, and they do little to explain the
differences between the western heartland and all other regions.
The final three regressions in table 2 repeat this analysis for
1980, 1990, and 2000. With historical perspective, the western
heartland's gap looks unusually large. In 2000, both the eastern
and western heartlands have lower not-working rates than the coasts,
when we control for these characteristics. In 1980 and 1990, the
regional differences look relatively small.
Individual and historical area education have persistent and strong
negative effects on not working. From 1980 to 2000, the not-working rate
was lower in right-to-work states. Corruption was positively associated
with the not-working rate in 1990 and 2000. Occupational licensing has
been positively associated with the not-working rate in every year.
The strong correlation between joblessness and education supports
the common view that improved schooling is one way to address
under-performing primary, secondary, and postsecondary schools in the
American heartland. Community colleges are particularly natural
institutions for delivering employment-related skills; and early
childhood programs have been found to be particularly effective. We now
discuss place-based, employment-oriented policies, which we see as a
complement to, not a substitute for, education reform. (21)
II. The Economic Rationales for Place-Based Policies
Standard locational externalities, including agglomeration
economies and human capital externalities, imply that a decentralized
spatial equilibrium may not be a Pareto optimum. But the large empirical
literatures on such spatial spillovers provide little guidance about
where these externalities are likely to be larger. Place-based policies
can also insure against place-based shocks. Places may be useful tags
for redistribution, which enable policymakers to rely less on
effort-distorting, income-based redistribution. The largest weakness of
equity and insurance justifications for place-based policies is that
relatively little income variation occurs across, rather than within,
states. Focusing on small geographies improves targeting, but also
increases the downsides of place-based redistribution: capitalization of
the benefits into housing costs and distorted migration.
The best case for place-based policies exists when spending in some
areas generates a much bigger behavioral response than in other areas.
If the supply of workers in the labor force is more elastic in some
areas than in others, devoting more federal resources to that area will
do more to reduce the not-working rate. When employment responses differ
across space, welfare gains can be achieved, even without extra
transfers to that area, by redirecting existing federal transfers. For
example, reallocating Medicaid spending to employment subsidies may be
welfare-improving in areas with a higher employment response to the
effective wage.
II A. The Efficiency Rationale for Place-Based Redistribution
The existence of agglomeration economies and congestion
externalities means that local areas may have too many or too few
people. To see this point, assume that there are only two regions in the
economy, and assume that region 1 is the wealthier region. (22) A
totally homogeneous national labor force ([N.sub.T]) is divided into the
population of the two locales ([N.sub.j] for j = 1, 2). Welfare in each
region is a function of the population size, denoted
[U.sub.j]([N.sub.j]).
A spatial equilibrium requires that utility levels are equalized
between the two regions, so [U.sub.1]([N.sub.1]) = [U.sub.1]([N.sub.2]).
A social welfare planner who chooses populations to maximize aggregate
welfare, [N.sub.1][U.sub.1]([N.sub.1]) + [N.sub.2][U.sub.2]([N.sub.2]),
would set [U.sub.1]([N.sub.1]) = [U.sub.2]([N.sub.2]) +
[N.sub.2][U'.sub.2]([N.sub.2]) -
[N.sub.1][U'.sub.1]([N.sub.1]). The extra terms
[N.sub.2][U'.sub.2]([N.sub.2]) -
[N.sub.1][U'.sub.1]([N.sub.1]) imply that the spatial equilibrium
may not be a social optimum. Yet the fact that the competitive
equilibrium is not socially optimal does not justify targeted regional
policies if we do not know the direction of the problem. When we discuss
the empirical research on agglomeration below, we will conclude that we
have little confidence in our estimates of heterogeneity in
agglomeration effects. Hence, agglomeration-based interventions seem as
likely to harm as to help.
II.B. The Insurance and Equity Rationale for Place-Based
Redistribution
The simplest equity-based justification for place-based policies is
that a concave social welfare function implies benefits from insuring
against local shocks, or even redistributing from high-income areas to
low-income areas. Redistribution based on local income differences is
less justifiable when higher income levels in some areas are offset by
higher housing prices. A more straightforward argument for place-based
redistribution is that it provides insurance against place-based shocks,
without distorting the labor supply or work effort. (23)
The strongest argument against place-based redistribution is that
the correlation between place and income is relatively weak in the
United States. In a regression analysis where income is regressed on
region dummies corresponding to our heartland definitions, these dummies
explain only 0.2 percent of the variation in income. When income is
regressed on state dummies, these indicator variables explain only 1.1
percent of the variation. When income is regressed on PUMA dummies,
these dummy variables explain 6.6 percent of the variation.
How big could the welfare gains be from spatial insurance across
states and regions? To consider this question quantitatively, we assume
that individuals just consume their income and that welfare is
[y.sup.1-[gamma]]/1-[gamma], and we focus on the case where [gamma] >
1. If income is log-normally distributed, then expected welfare is
equivalent to E(ln y) - 0.5([gamma] - 1)V(ln y). (24)
In our data, the mean of log income for men is 10.55. The mean
standard deviation of log income within states is 1.14, and that of
income across states is 0.12. Consequently, eliminating the variation in
income across states would have only a small impact on welfare.
Eliminating spatial income variation would represent a real welfare
gain, but it would also distort migration and capitalization. (25) The
tighter the geographic targeting, the larger the share of inequality
that can be eliminated. Tighter geographic targeting will also ramp up
the effects on migration and capitalization. Those distortions could be
reduced if payments were based on birthplace, not place of current
residence, but it is hard to imagine a birthplace-based national policy.
The economic case for place-based insurance is theoretically strong; but
in practice, the possible effect of such a policy seems limited and
likely to have pernicious side effects.
II.C. Differential Response Elasticities and Hot-Spots Policing
We now turn to the third, and we think the best, rationale for
spatial policy: market failures that can most plausibly be addressed at
the local level. Police departments that use hot spots target their
resources toward areas where there is more crime, presumably because the
impact of these resources on crime is higher in these areas. This
strategy seems to be effective on both targeted areas and neighboring
areas, suggesting that crime is not merely displaced to different areas
(Braga, Papachristos, and Hureau 2014). We now turn to a model for
place-based policies that captures the same economic logic--that
resources can more effectively reduce the not-working rate when targeted
toward areas with higher not-working rates.
We focus on public transfers to a population of less-skilled
workers, who are on the margin of working. We assume that the United
States is divided into P regions, and that marginal workers' wages
equal [w.sub.p] in region p. We assume that these workers never pay
taxes, and that the social planner chooses lump sum transfers,
conditional on working (denoted [e.sub.p]) and not working (denoted
[b.sub.p]). The monetized private benefit of not working in place p
equals [b.sub.p]. Wages and other benefits are independent of public
transfers, and here we ignore mobility and housing markets. (26)
Individual i's welfare is V(Earnings)--[I.sub.w][c.sub.i],
where [I.sub.w] is an indicator function that takes on a value of 1 if
the individual works; and [c.sub.i] is an idiosyncratic cost of working,
where the cumulative density function [F.sub.p]([[??].sub.i]) denotes
the share of the population in place p that has the value of [c.sub.i]
< [[??].sub.i], and [f.sub.p]([[??].sub.i]) is the associated
probability density function. Individuals will therefore work if and
only if V([w.sub.p] + [e.sub.p]) - V([d.sub.p] + [b.sub.p]) >
[c.sub.i], and we denote [c*.sup.p] = V([w.sub.p] + [e.sub.p]) -
V([d.sub.p] + [b.sub.p]). We first assume that the population level of
each area is fixed.
The social welfare planner maximizes expected welfare across the
population less the share of the population that is not working times a
constant k, which captures any nonfiscal externalities from
nonemployment. The government's cost of funds equals [theta], which
can be interpreted as the Lagrange multiplier on the government's
overall budget constraint. Within each area, [b.sub.p] and [e.sub.p] are
chosen to maximize
(1) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
For proposition 1, we assume that V(*) is sufficiently concave to
ensure that second-order conditions hold:
Proposition 1. If V"(*) is sufficiently large in absolute
value and [[Florin]'.sub.p]([c*.sub.p]) is sufficiently small, then
both benefit levels are decreasing in both [w.sub.p] and [d.sub.p]; an
increase in k causes [e.sub.p] to rise and [b.sub.p] to fall.
This proposition contains the core insurance motive for
redistributing across space. Areas with lower wages should optimally
receive both more benefits and a higher employment subsidy. The marginal
utility of consumption for the working poor is higher in low-wage areas,
and this raises the optimal employment subsidy. When the employment
subsidy increases, it reduces the fiscal externality associated with
nonemployment and consequently increases the optimal payment to those
who do not work.
The first-order condition can also create a variant of the
Baily-Chetty formula relating to the marginal utility of consumption for
the employed and the jobless (Baily 1978; Chetty 2006):
(2) [V' ([w.sub.p] + [e.sub.p])/V' ([d.sub.p] +
[b.sub.p]] = 1 - [[[epsilon].sup.p.sub.W] ([b.sub.p] + k -
[e.sub.p])/[w.sub.p][1 - [F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])]],
where [[epsilon].sup.p.sub.w] = [[F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])V'( is
the elasticity of the employment rate with respect to the wage, and
([b.sub.p] + k - [e.sub.p])/[w.sub.p] reflects the size of the fiscal
and nonfiscal externality associated with not working relative to the
wage.
Equation 2 emphasizes the optimal heterogeneity in social policy
across areas, not optimal redistribution across areas. The equation
implies that in areas where the elasticity of employment with respect to
the wage is higher, the employment subsidy should be higher relative to
the payment for the jobless.
This can be interpreted as implying that even if the current U.S.
benefits system for the not working were kept entirely in place, it
would be optimal to increase support for the marginally employed in
places where the employment response to wages is higher. Alternatively,
the equation can be interpreted to mean that it would be optimal to
shift benefits from the jobless to the marginally employed in states
where employment is more responsive to the fiscal returns to working.
If [[epsilon].sup.p.sub.w] = 0, then consumption is equalized
between the not working and the employed. If ([b.sub.p] + k -
[e.sub.p])/[w.sub.p] = 0.2, the not-working rate equals 0.2, and
[[epsilon].sup.p.sub.w] = 0.25, then 1 -
[[epsilon].sup.p.sub.w]([b.sub.p] + k - [e.sub.p])/[w.sub.p][1 -
[F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])] = 0.75. If utility follows a constant relative
risk aversion function of 0.5, then the optimal consumption of the not
working is 0.56 times that of the employed. A lower elasticity of labor
response of 0.1 will imply higher levels of redistribution to the not
working, so that the not working consume only 19 percent less than the
employed.
These calculations suggest that small differences across space may
generate large differences in the appropriate balance between employment
subsidies and nonemployment benefits. In areas where the sensitivity of
employment to wages is high, then subsidizing not working becomes
particularly costly, when there are large externalities associated with
non-employment. In areas that are close to full employment, subsidizing
the poor is less problematic. In the next two empirical subsections, we
discuss the evidence related to both the size of the externality and
differential employment responses by place.
II.C. Mobility across Space
The previous calculations ignored mobility, which would reduce the
appeal of redistribution across space but might not change equation 2.
We can solve the social insurance problem in two steps: First, minimize
expected social insurance payments in each location, holding expected
utility fixed; and second, choose the combination of the levels of
expected utility and expenditures across space to maximize aggregate
social welfare, internalizing migration and capitalization effects. The
procedure can be separated as long as only expected utility affects
migrations, which will be true if we assume that migration decisions are
made before an individual's value of ci is revealed.
Minimizing the costs of transfers and externalities
[F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])[e.sub.p] + [1 - [F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])] ([b.sub.p]
+ k), subject to a fixed utility constraint [mathematical expression not
reproducible], is dual to the welfare maximization problem and also
yields equation 2. (27) Incorporating migration does have an effect on
the overall level of welfare in each area; but it does not change the
relationship between the marginal utility of consumption while working
and not working. These results would, however, change if individuals
observed their value of [c.sub.i] before migrating.
To formally model migration, we assume two locations and that
people are endowed with a preference for the second location of
[[epsilon].sub.i], which is distributed according to a cumulative
density function G(*) with probability density function g(*). We ignore
housing and spatial externalities and denote total spending in region p
as [S.sub.p] and expected utility in each region as
[U.sub.p]([S.sub.p]). The spatial equilibrium then defines a marginal
migrant with a preference for location 2 of [epsilon]*, which is defined
so that [U.sub.1]([S.sub.1]) = [U.sub.2]([S.sub.2]) + [epsilon]*, and
the share of the population in location 1 equals G([epsilon]*).
If the social planner's cost of funds is again [theta], the
overall maximization problem can be written as
(3) G([epsilon]*)[ [U.sub.1] ([S.sub.1]) - [theta][S.sub.1]] + [1 -
G([epsilon]*)][[U.sub.2]([S.sub.2]) -[theta][S.sub.2]] +
[[integral].sub.[epsilon][greater than or equal to][epsilon]*].
[epsilon]dG([epsilon])
This leads to two first-order conditions that can be combined to
generate
(4) [[U'.sub.1]([S.sub.1])/[U'.sub.2]([S.sub.2])] = 1 -
[[[epsilon].sup.S.sub.N1]([S.sub.2] - [S.sub.1])/[S.sub.1][1 -
G([epsilon]*)],
where [[epsilon].sup.s.sub.N1] reflects the elasticity of mobility
into area 1 with respect to area 1 subsidies, or
[[epsilon].sup.s.sub.N1] = [U'.sub.1]([S.sub.1])
[S.sub.1]g([epsilon]*)/G([epsilon]*). Equation 2 then describes the
structure of payments within an area, whereas equation 4 describes the
structure of payments across an area.
If [[epsilon].sup.s.sub.N1] = 0 and there is no mobility response,
then optimal policies equalize the marginal utility of spending across
areas. If mobility is perfectly elastic, so that
[[epsilon].sup.s.sub.N1] goes to infinity, then spending must be
equalized across areas. For intermediate levels of mobility, there will
be more spending on the area with a higher marginal utility of spending:
[S.sub.2] > [S.sub.1] if and only if [U'.sub.2]([S.sub.2]) >
[U'.sub.1]([S.sub.1]). This equation somewhat supports our previous
discussion suggesting that redistribution across space is more likely to
enhance welfare when migration is more limited.
But the larger point of this subsection is that concerns about
capitalization and migration influence the expected welfare for
residents of a specific area, but not the optimal ratio of marginal
utility levels for the employed and the not working. If the elasticity
of the not-working rate with respect to wages is higher in one place,
then that place should do more to make work pay.
A final justification for targeting related to "hot
spots" is that the macro-economic costs of supporting not working
might be lower if we target West Virginia more than San Francisco.
Phillips curve-type reasoning suggests that reductions in unemployment
might increase pressure for wage-led inflation. This threat seems larger
if San Francisco's not-working rate is being pushed from 5 percent
to 2 percent than if West Virginia's not-working rate is being
pushed from 13 percent to 10 percent.
II.D. The Downsides of Spatial Policy: Capitalization, Mobility,
and Cost
As the previous discussion emphasized, two of the major downsides
of place-based strategies are capitalization and distorted locational
choice. If a place-based policy makes an area more attractive to a
group, then that group will move into the area or bid up prices, or
both, depending on the elasticity of the housing supply. The policy will
have more of an impact on prices when the supply of space is inelastic.
The policy will distort location more when the supply of space is
elastic; but even when space is inelastic, there still can be a
distortionary effect on the composition of the population.
A third major downside of spatial policy is cost, which in turn is
a function of the targeting of the policy. In all three discussions, we
assumed that subsidies and taxes are not well targeted within the
region. A general employment subsidy has these features, as would
policies that increase general labor demand in the poor region through
the use of tax credits or direct government spending. Yet it is possible
to imagine policies that are more directly targeted toward marginal
workers. Those policies would reduce the taxes needed to encourage
employment and would also dampen capitalization and migration effects,
because they have an impact on a smaller share of the population.
The three motives for place-based strategies have different
implications for the costs of capitalization and distorted mobility. If
the point of spatial targeting is to achieve agglomeration-related
benefits, then distorted locational choice is not a problem but a
desired outcome. The point of the policy is to induce economic activity
to relocate. Capitalization might be a slight negative, in that the
property owners will reap many of the benefits, but that would not
particularly undo the efficiency gains from relocation.
If the purpose of spatial targeting is to redistribute toward
poorer residents, then relocation is not intrinsically desirable. Yet if
we cannot determine the sign of the impact of relocating people and
firms on aggregate efficiency, then we also cannot be sure whether
inadvertent relocation generates welfare losses or benefits. A prominent
exception to this claim is that there may be considerable downsides from
concentrating poverty and nonemployment, particularly because this may
cause welfare losses to the poor that undo any benefits that come from
targeting resources toward a particular area.
Capitalization, by contrast, will tend to work against the
redistributive benefits of targeting resources toward poorer areas. If
the primary beneficiaries of these benefits are property owners, then
the policy may be progressive across places but regressive within
places. Once again, targeting can reduce the capitalization-related
downsides of any policy.
If the goal is targeting resources against a demonstrable social
problem, like nonemployment, then efficiency, not equity, is again the
main objective. In this case, the redistribution to owners due to
capitalization is not particularly problematic; nor are distorted
locational choices. Even more broadly, the policy can be a place-based
benefit shift, which fights non-employment without inducing
in-migration. We now discuss the two parameters that are needed to use
equation 2, our modified Baily-Chetty formula.
III. Do Employment Elasticities Differ across Place?
The theoretical case for the spatial targeting of employment
subsidies depends on whether such policies have a greater marginal
impact on employment in some areas. Employment subsidies could have a
larger impact in distressed areas, but the opposite is also possible.
Areas with high not-working rates might have social problems that lead
even fewer people to be on the margin of working. Areas with high
not-working rates might have extremely inelastic labor demand, so that
few new jobs will be created because of a subsidy. The case for
infrastructure, relative to subsidies, is stronger when private labor
demand is inelastic. It is an empirical question as to whether
interventions in high-poverty areas are more likely to increase the
level of employment. (28)
We have three ways of testing for differential employment
elasticities. First, and most obviously, we can look at the impact of
labor demand shocks on the not-working rate and test for heterogeneity
across space. Second, we can review the surprisingly limited body of
literature on heterogeneous spatial effects of social programs on the
not-working rate. And third, we can revisit the evidence presented by
Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) linking government spending to GDP growth
and test for heterogeneous treatment effects on the not-working rate.
III.A. The Heterogeneous Impact of Labor Demand Shocks
We first look at the impact of labor demand shocks on the
not-working rate. We use a Bartik demand shock (following Bartik 1991),
interacting initial industry shares with changes in national employment
in the industry outside the PUMA or state, or
[mathematical expression not reproducible],
where [mathematical expression not reproducible] is employment in
industry i, location s, and initial time [t.sub.0]; [mathematical
expression not reproducible] is total employment in location s at
initial time [t.sub.0]; and [emp.sup.US not s.sub.i,t] is the employment
in industry i at time t in the United States outside location s. Thus,
this shock represents the percentage growth in employment in the
location that would have been predicted if the location's
industries saw their employment grow at the national average rate.
We look at Bartik shocks at both the PUMA and state levels. We
begin with state-level estimates over the 1977-2016 period. Regressions
1 and 2 in table 3 show the negative impact of the Bartik shock over the
entire period, as expected, and that this impact is larger in states
with higher initial not-working rates. Regressions 3 and 4 show that
this interaction term is robust to the addition of year fixed effects.
It does seem as if demand shocks are more strongly associated with
changes in the not-working rate in places with higher average
not-working rates.
Regressions 5 and 6 show results for housing prices. The
state-level housing price index is a repeat sales index prepared by the
Federal Housing Finance Agency. Regression 5 finds that positive Bartik
shocks are associated with more housing price growth, suggesting that
economic success is associated with higher housing costs; but the
coefficient is not statistically significant. Regression 6 shows a
strong positive correlation between the not-working rate and the Bartik
shock. The Bartik shock has a statistically significant impact on
not-working rates in states with high historical not-working rates
relative to other states, but this interaction is not statistically
significant for housing prices.
Regressions 7 and 8 show results at the substate level using
consistent PUMAs and annual changes since 2005, because of limited data
availability before that period. Regression 7 shows that the Bartik
shock has a strong negative impact on the not-working rate over this
period. And regression 8 shows that this effect is far more strongly
concentrated in places that had high levels of not-working rates in
2005. A change of 10 percentage points in the not-working rate increases
the impact of the Bartik shock by almost 50 percent relative to a zero
benchmark for the not-working rate.
Finally, we examine the impact of trade shocks on prime age male
non-employment, using shocks identified by Autor, Dorn, and Hanson
(2013). They use the change in Chinese import exposure per worker in a
region as their main measure of local labor market exposure to import
competition. To address potential endogeneity issues, they instrument
growth in U.S. imports with growth in Chinese imports in eight other
developed economies. In table 4, we follow their approach and regress
the share of not-working men or long-term not-working men on the change
in Chinese imports per worker.
In regression 1, we examine the effect of a shock in Chinese
imports on prime age male not-working rates. As expected, increases in
Chinese import exposure are associated with an increase in the level of
prime age male non-employment, and the coefficients are statistically
significant. Regression 2 examines the heterogeneity of responsiveness
based on initial not-working rates in 1990. We find that commuting zones
with the highest levels of initial not-working rates, defined as being
in the top 10 percent, experience a higher level of nonemployment in
response to changes in Chinese import exposure. Regressions 3 and 4
report the same results for long-term not-working rates, and we find a
similar pattern, albeit with smaller absolute increases. (29)
These results may be relatively unsurprising. A shock to local
labor demand has more impact on the not-working rate in places where
non-employment is high than in places that are already near full
employment. Yet this heterogeneity is crucial in justifying spatially
heterogeneous policies that encourage employment more in some areas than
in others.
III.B. Heterogeneous Responses to Past Social Programs
There has been surprisingly limited research testing whether
national changes in policy have heterogeneous treatment effects across
space. For example, a large body of literature (Meyer and Rosenbaum
2001; Eissa and Liebman 1996) has examined the impact of the Earned
Income Tax Credit (EITC) on employment. But we have found that none of
these studies ask whether the impact of the credit was higher in places
that had initially higher levels of nonemployment. David Neumark and
William Wascher (2011) find interactions between the EITC and state
minimum wages, but the imperfect relationship between the minimum wage
and nonemployment makes these results hard to interpret.
There is abundant evidence suggesting that targeted social programs
can have a large impact on the not-working rate. For example, Cynthia
Miller and others (2017) test an EITC-like product, called Paycheck
Plus, that is targeted toward people without children. The treatment
effect of this product on employment outcomes, especially on filing
taxes, is higher for people who initially earned less than $10,000 per
year. We hope that future research will test more regularly for whether
social interventions have more impact in some states than in others.
III.C. Spatial Heterogeneity as Identified by Nakamura and
Steinsson
In this subsection, we use the shocks to federal spending that are
identified by Nakamura and Steinsson (2014). (30) We focus on
state-level, prime age male not-working rates as our outcome of
interest, and we test for interactions between these shocks and average
not-working rates within states. Nakamura and Steinsson's approach
is to regress the percentage change in the employment rate within the
state on the change in military spending over the same period. They
instrument for the change in military spending by interacting the change
in national military spending with a state dummy.
Our specification is to follow Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) and
thus to regress
(5) [mathematical expression not reproducible]
where not working, refers to the not-working rate in the state,
spending, refers to per capita military procurement spending, output,
refers to per capita output, and [[delta].sub.t] and [[gamma].sub.t],
are time and year fixed effects. We instrument for the spending variable
using the percentage growth in national military spending interacted
with a state dummy. This specification follows the structure of Nakamura
and Steinsson's employment rate regressions.
We do this for one-, two-, and three-year changes. Our primary
focus is on the interaction between military spending and the average
not-working rate in the state. We implement this by generating an
interaction between the spending variable and an indicator variable that
takes on a value of 1 if the state is among the 25 percent of states
with the highest not-working rate during the entire period. This is a
conceptually different experiment from Nakamura and Steinsson's
(2014) interaction between military spending and whether the state has a
high not-working rate relative to its historic norm.
We show the results for the one-year change in the not-working rate
in regressions 1 and 2 in table 5. Regression 1 confirms that the basic
result holds for the not-working rate: An increase in military spending
equal to 1 percent of output is associated with a 6.2 percent decrease
in the not-working rate, although the coefficient is not statistically
significant. Regression 2 shows that the coefficient on military
spending is significantly larger in areas with high not-working rates
and is statistically significantly different from areas with low
not-working rates.
In regressions 3 and 4, we look at the two-year change in the
not-working rate, which is Nakamura and Steinsson's (2014)
preferred specification. The overall effect on the not-working rate is
significant at the 10 percent level. An increase in military spending
equal to 1 percent of output is associated with a 6.4 percent decrease
in the not-working rate. The interaction with high not-working rates is
small and insignificant.
In regressions 5 and 6, we look at the three-year change in the
not-working rate. In this case, an increase in military spending equal
to 1 percent of output is associated with a 9.6 percent decrease in the
not-working rate and is statistically significant at the 5 percent
level. The interaction is negative and economically meaningful in size,
but it is so imprecise that we can draw little confidence from this
result. Overall, these results, especially for the one-year change,
suggest that military spending might be more effective in areas with
high not-working rates, but they are no more than suggestive.
IV. The Externalities of Not Working
If joblessness generates no externalities, then there is no reason
for the government to promote employment in our model. There may still
be a redistributive or insurance motive for spatial policy, but there
would be little reason to focus particularly on joblessness. In this
section, we discuss the three types of externalities associated with
nonemployment: pure fiscal losses from reduced taxes and increased
social spending; social spillovers borne by family and friends; and
not-working spillovers, where one individual who is not working
increases the chance that others will not work. We do not consider
externalities that could work through congestion of the
employment-matching process, basically because we consider congestion to
be a short-run phenomenon, while we are primarily interested in the
long-run costs of concentrated nonemployment.
IV.A. Fiscal Externalities: Taxes and Spending
The most obvious externality associated with nonemployment is the
cost borne by other taxpayers due to a reduction in tax revenue and an
increase in public expenditures. We first focus on the income of
not-working prime age men, to understand the amount of public resources
they are receiving.
Table 6 shows income sources for four groups: all employed prime
age men; low-income employed prime age men, who are defined as having
annual family earnings below $40,000; prime age men who have not been
working for less than 12 months; and prime age men who have not been
working for more than 12 months. The data are averaged over the 2010-16
period and are based on the ASEC.
The missing earnings of the not working are supplemented mainly by
disability payments and by the other residents of their own home. The
added public expenditure going to the short-term not working relative to
low-income workers is $2,300; the average added expenditure going to the
long-term not working is $6,300. Averaged over the entire not-working
population, the increase is $4,900, which is 26 percent of low-income
individual wages in this sample.
In table 7, we break out the earnings of the long-term not working
by region. The results are quite similar. The family incomes in the
heartland areas are lower than in the coastal states. Disability
payments are higher in the eastern heartland than in the other regions.
Nowhere are family transfers a large share of total earnings.
Because disability is such an important part of public support for
not-working men, we now focus on the geography and time series of
disability in the United States. Figure 15 shows disability rates across
the United States. We see the familiar pattern of suffering in the
eastern heartland, but higher rates of being on disability certainly do
not seem to generate higher earnings for the not working.
Should disability be seen as a transfer to the not working that
would stop if employment increased, or a social insurance program that
compensates the unlucky who receive negative health shocks and could not
work in any case? Many of the not working report regular health
problems. Figure 16 shows that approximately 30 percent of the not
working in all three regions report 10 or more days of physical health
problems over the past month.
Autor and Mark Duggan (2003) depict disability insurance as a
substitute for unemployment insurance that may be better seen as a
social cost of nonemployment, rather than an independent insurance
program. Andreas Kostol and Magne Mogstad (2014) show that when disabled
people in Norway are able to keep more of their earnings, they work and
earn more. Nicole Maestas, Kathleen Mullen, and Alexander Strand (2013)
examine borderline applicants for Social Security Disability Insurance,
and find that employment would have been 28 percentage points higher
among successful applicants if they had not received benefits. Eric
French and Jae Song (2014) find a similar decrease in employment among
applicants who successfully appeal their applications compared with
those who are unsuccessful. These papers suggest that at least part of
the disability cost should be seen as a fiscal externality generated by
nonemployment.
In table 8, we turn to expenditures, using data from the Consumer
Expenditure Survey. We split the population into employed, employed
living alone, low-income employed (again, earning less than $40,000 a
year), and the long-term not working living alone.
The not working, unsurprisingly, pay far fewer taxes than employed
men generally, who pay over $15,000 annually, or employed men living
alone, who pay almost $10,000. However, if the comparison is with
low-income men living alone, the gulf in taxes is much smaller. The
not-working men living alone contribute $566 in taxes, as opposed to
$1,326 in taxes for the low-income employed living alone.
If the relevant margin is between nonemployment and average
earnings, then the tax-related fiscal externality is over $9,000. If the
relevant margin is between nonemployment and low-income wage labor, then
the tax-related fiscal externality is much smaller, closer to $800.
Perhaps the most surprising fact is that the expenditures of the
not working are much higher than their income level, and are not that
much lower than the expenditures of the low-income employed, who spend
$28,100 annually; the not working who live alone spend $20,700. The
plausible explanations for this group's gap between expenditures
and earnings include running down savings, borrowing, unreported family
transfers, and perhaps even illicit earnings. Typically, the members of
this group have neither significant assets nor great credit, which makes
it hard to believe that past savings and borrowing can explain the gap.
They also report low levels of family transfers.
The small gap in spending between the low-income employed and the
not working suggests that the Keynesian externalities associated with
moving the not working into low-wage jobs are small. The largest
spending increase associated with employment is transportation, which
may reflect the costs of getting to and from work. Annually, the
employed also spend $300 more on alcohol, $1,600 more on housing, and
$1,300 more on food. The greater food expenditure may reflect some
eating out on the job.
Do these data suggest a large fiscal externality from
nonemployment? Benefits fall by $4,900 and taxes fall by $800 when we
compare the not working with low-wage workers. If half the disability
payments would have been paid in any case, then the benefit gap drops to
$3,200, making the total fiscal externality $4,000, which is 21 percent
of the earnings of the low-income individuals.
IV.B. Social Externalities Borne by Families and Friends
We now turn to the costs of nonemployment that are borne by family
and friends. A large share of the long-term not working do not live
alone, but many of these men are not married. Figure 17 shows the time
series of the share of men who have never been married, for the
employed, the short-term not working, and the long-term not working. The
three lines show parallel upward trends, with the not working always
being less likely to have been married than the employed. By 2015, half
of the long-run not working have never been married, and over 40 percent
of the short-term not working have never been married. Less than 30
percent of the employed have never been married.
The share of the employed who are separated or divorced has risen
over time. The share of the not working who are separated or divorced
has remained steady, at over 15 percent, as shown in figure 18.
Consequently, less than 35 percent of the long-term not working have
current spouses, and the majority of their cohabitants are not their
current spouses.
In many cases, the not working are actually living with their
parents. Figure 19 shows the trend in cohabitating with parents by
employment status. This number has always been high for the long-run not
working, but it has risen in recent years to over 30 percent.
Does not working also impose externalities on family and friends
who subsidize the not working? If nuclear families are unitary
decisionmakers, then they are presumably making joint decisions about
work and leisure. If men make independent decisions about work, and then
spouses bargain ex post about the share of rents, spouses will
presumably lose their share of the forgone earnings.
Some of these externalities will be offset if the not-working
spouse participates more in household production, but time use surveys
suggest that this is not the case. Table 9 shows the time use by
employed and not-working men by region.
Working men spent about 530 minutes (8 hours 50 minutes) per day on
personal care, over 90 percent of which was typically sleep. They worked
an average of between 382 and 401 minutes per day, which roughly
corresponds to a 6.5 hour workday, averaged over the course of the week.
Notably, the men in the western heartland do seem to put in longer
hours. They offset this time by spending slightly less time on leisure
activities. Watching television remains the dominant use of leisure time
and takes up slightly over 2 hours per day for working men.
Not-working men work about 6 hours less per day. This extra time is
spent primarily on leisure activities. The not working in the eastern
heartland spend over 5 hours daily watching television. There is also an
uptick in computer use, including gaming, as noted by Aguiar and others
(2017) and Krueger (2017).
The not-working men on the coasts and in the western heartland
increase their time spent on household production tasks by 41 and 46
minutes, respectively. The modal categories for male household
activities are food preparation and lawn work. Consequently, even for
this group, less than one-sixth of the time freed up by not working goes
to activities that benefit the household rather than private
consumption. By contrast, not-working men in the eastern heartland spend
only 31 more minutes on household activities than working men and 9 more
minutes caring for others.
The view that spouses are not benefiting from their partners'
non-employment is further supported by the correlation between not
working and divorce rates. It is not merely that the not working are
more likely to be divorced. Losing one's job is associated with a
higher risk of becoming divorced (Killewald 2016). Although this fact
has many interpretations, one view is that a male's nonemployment
is a negative shock to his spouse.
We take the stand that bargaining is efficient between spouses, but
not between parents and children. Consequently, for the roughly one
quarter of not-working people who live with their parents, nonhousing
expenditures represent an externality from nonemployment. The long-term
not working who live alone have total nonhousing expenditures of
$11,500. Consequently, not working generates an average family
externality of $2,900, which is 15 percent of low-wage income. This
figure is a crude attempt to capture intrafamily losses
("internalities") and the more general spillovers from not
working that we discuss next, collectively bringing the total
externality to $6,900, which is 36 percent of low-wage earnings.
IV.C. Nonemployment Spillovers
The suffering of not working will be magnified if not working
spills over across individuals. This spillover could occur because an
individual's not working leads to less demand for local products,
which reduces local labor demand. Nonemployment could also spill over if
it reduces the stigma of not working (Lindbeck, Nyberg, and Weibull
1999), if it creates a culture of not working, or if the not working
enjoy being with each other. (31)
Giorgio Topa (2001) presents the now-standard model of this
phenomenon. He estimates this model using tract-level data from Chicago,
using a structural model. The sorting of the unemployed within the city
provides evidence supporting the view that the unemployment of one
person is a complement to the unemployment of his or her neighbor.
Timothy Conley and Topa (2002) extend this analysis.
Clark (2003) provides evidence for the social norm hypothesis. He
finds evidence that the self-reported life satisfaction of the
unemployed is much higher if there is more unemployment in the
individual's reference group. He also finds that individuals whose
unhappiness drops more at the point of unemployment are more likely to
find future employment. These findings seem to suggest that a norm of
not working translates into still more long-term nonemployment. A final
piece of evidence supporting the non-employment spillover hypothesis is
that aggregate employment relationships with variables like tax rates
are often much stronger than individual employment relationships
(Alesina, Glaeser, and Sacerdote 2005), which suggests the existence of
a social multiplier.
V. Calibrating the Level of Place-Based Interventions
We now use the modified Baily-Chetty formula discussed in section
II, and attempt to obtain quantitative estimates of the optimal degree
of place-based heterogeneity. We consider two thought experiments.
First, we assume that existing benefits continue in place, and we
estimate the optimal allocations of new employment subsidy across space.
The relevant first-order condition for such an employment subsidy bonus
is that V'([w.sub.p] + [e.sub.p])/[1 -
[[epsilon].sup.p.sub.W]([b.sub.p] + k - [e.sub.p])/[w.sub.p]] must be
constant over space. Second, we assume that funds are removed from
current benefits received by the not working and are allocated to
marginal workers. In this case, the relevant first-order condition is
V'([w.sub.p] + [e.sub.p])/V'([d.sub.p] + [b.sub.p]) = 1 -
[[epsilon].sup.p.sub.W]([b.sub.p] + k - [e.sub.p])/[w.sub.p][1 -
[F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])]. Our model does not incorporate wage effects of
subsidies, or migration and capitalization, which could be significant
by-products of the first thought experiment but not the second one.
Consequently, these calculations are illustrative at best.
In both cases, we depend on place-specific estimates of the
extensive margin elasticity of labor supply. Our purpose here is to
emphasize the heterogeneity across the United States, not to advance the
considerable literature on labor supply. (32) We use a simple empirical
approach, regressing the log employment rate at the PUMA level on the
log wages for the 25th percentile of employed men. We instrument for
wages using Bartik shocks, as described above. The use of Bartik shocks
as an instrument for labor demand is discussed in detail by Paul
Goldsmith-Pinkham, Isaac Sorkin, and Henry Swift (2018). They show that
using Bartik shocks as instruments is numerically equivalent to using
industry shares as instruments. Therefore, identification is dependent
on the exogeneity of initial industry shares.
Table 10 summarizes the results. The coefficient on log wages is
small and insignificant, but the interaction of wages and the 1980
not-working rate is large and significant. The measured elasticity
varies over space, with greater responsiveness in areas with high
not-working rates. Wyoming had the lowest not-working rate in 1980, at
6.5 percent, and the implied elasticity is 0.05. West Virginia had the
highest not-working rate in 1980, at 16.5 percent, and the implied
elasticity is 0.26. We hope that this simple approach will be superseded
in future work that will bring more sophisticated estimation techniques
to assess the heterogeneity of labor supply elasticities across space.
We assume a constant relative risk aversion utility function, with
a coefficient of relative risk aversion of [gamma]. Steffen Andersen and
others (2008) estimate that this coefficient is 0.741 in laboratory
experiments with relatively low stakes. Alma Cohen and Liran Einav
(2007) estimate a median coefficient of relative risk aversion of 0.37
from deductible choices in automobile insurance. Robert Barsky and
others (1997) find evidence for higher values using larger gambles. Some
macroeconomic estimates associated with explaining the equity premium
puzzle are higher still. We report values assuming coefficients of 0.5,
1.0, and 2.0.
We start with the employment subsidy formula
[mathematical expression not reproducible]
and we implement it by one region, indexed A, and with a benchmark
region, indexed 0, where [[epsilon].sup.0.sub.w] = 0, and [e.sub.0] = 0.
Essentially, we are asking how much larger a region's employment
subsidy should be than a place where there is no employment response to
wages and consequently no employment subsidy. We assume that the
marginal worker's wage is everywhere fixed at [w.sub.0] and
independent of the employment subsidy, perhaps because the wage is
determined by the federal minimum wage. We also assume that ([b.sub.A] +
k)/[w.sub.A] = 0.363. With those assumptions, V'([w.sub.0] +
[e.sub.A])/V'([w.sub.0]) = 1-0.363[[epsilon].sup.A.sub.w] +
[e.sub.A]/[w.sub.0][[epsilon].sup.A.sub.w]. (33)
Given our estimates of differential employment elasticity, we can
then consider the optimal subsidy. For example, states such as Wyoming
that have low not-working rates have an estimated elasticity close to 0,
suggesting a minimal optimal employment subsidy. Areas such as West
Virginia with high not-working rates, with an estimated elasticity of
0.26, have an optimal subsidy equal to 14 percent of wages if the
coefficient of relative risk aversion is 0.5, an optimal subsidy of 8
percent of wages if the coefficient is 1, and an optimal subsidy of less
than 5 percent of wages if the coefficient is 2. High coefficients mean
strong concavity, which reduces the benefits of the employment subsidy.
The previous thought experiment was a bonus that just allocated
employment dollars to states with high not-working rates. Our
alternative thought experiment is a twist that reallocates x * [w.sub.p]
dollars from not-working benefits and adds [ 1 -
[F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p])]/[F.sub.p]([c*.sub.p]) * x * [w.sub.p] to the
employment subsidy. We assume that [e.sub.p] = 0 without this subsidy.
We assume that [d.sub.p] + [b.sub.p] = 0.6[w.sub.p], which is in line
with tables 6 and 8. In this case, the modified Baily--Chetty condition
in equation 2 implies
[mathematical expression not reproducible]
Figure 20 illustrates the optimal benefits twist as a function of
[[epsilon].sup.p.sub.w] for the three different cases of constant
relative risk aversion utility.
Again, we can match the theoretical predictions against different
states. In states with low elasticities, we find that the optimal size
of the benefits twist is negative, so the optimal change to the benefit
scheme would be to increase benefits for the not working by increasing
taxes. (34) Indeed, if the coefficient of relative risk aversion is 2,
then the model almost always pushes toward more transfers for the not
working because of such strong concavity. When the coefficient of risk
aversion is 0.5, again the model suggests a positive benefits twist,
with a reallocation of 10 percent or more in states like West Virginia,
depending on the elasticity.
Finally, we can calculate the predicted optimal ratio of
consumption when working or not working in different states, based on
their employment and not-working shares. Our ratio of the fiscal and
other externalities of not working to the wage is 0.363, from the
previous section. The not-working rate is somewhat more complicated,
given that this is the share of the low-skill, at-risk workers who are
not working, not the not-working share of the entire population. We use
our previous definition of low-income men as those who are employed and
have a total annual family income of less than $40,000. Using this
definition, we find that the not-working rate for at-risk workers varies
from 39.5 percent in Wyoming to 61.3 percent in West Virginia, using the
2014-16 pooled responses from the ASEC.
Table 11 summarizes our results. Our model predicts that the ratio
of consumption of not-working to employed men should indeed be lower in
areas with high not-working rates. Although these values are only
tentative, they illustrate the importance of considering spatially
heterogeneous policy responses to nonemployment.
We view these results as thought experiments, not serious policy
proposals. These calculations suggest that if utility functions are not
too concave, then significantly stronger subsidies for employment would
be optimal for states like West Virginia. This conclusion would be
tempered if wages fell with subsidies, or if the subsidies distorted
migration. If migration were a paramount concern, then our model
suggests that there could even be welfare gains in areas with high
not-working rates from replacing benefits for the not working with
benefits subsidizing marginal workers. In areas with low not-working
rates, more benefits for the not working would be welfare-enhancing,
especially when risk aversion is high.
VI. Place-Based Policies: Efficacy, Capitalization, and Mobility
We now turn to a brief taxonomy of place-based policies in the
United States and elsewhere. Our goal is to link these policies with the
three objectives discussed above, and to discuss the evidence on their
downsides, including capitalization, distorted location choice, and
overall cost. We do not focus on the spatial heterogeneity that occurs
because of differences in local government actions, but rather on ways
in which national governments and the European Union generate policies
with spatially heterogeneous effects. A central theme of this section is
that spatial policies have the largest impact when they are targeted
toward the needs and problems of particular regions.
VIA. A Taxonomy
Spatial policies can be explicit, openly targeting one area or
another, or implicit, aiding particular areas disproportionately, but
without an acknowledgment of the geographic tilt. Spatial policies can
take the form of direct public investment, tax benefits or subsidies to
businesses, tax benefits or grants to individuals, and regulatory
relief. Table 12 provides a brief summary of the eight categories in our
taxonomy, with a few examples of each form.
VI.B. Direct Public Investment
A prime example of direct public investment is the Tennessee Valley
Authority (TVA), which was a New Deal innovation meant to deliver
electricity and improve conditions in one of the poorest parts of the
country. The TVA began not with a desire for a spatial big push but with
the recognition that electricity could have high returns and could be
produced by the region's abundant hydropower. Kline and Moretti
(2013) provide evidence showing that the TVA increased agricultural
employment in the region while subsidies were in place and increased
manufacturing employment even after the subsidies ended. They interpret
their findings as suggesting that the TVA generated durable
agglomeration economies. An alternative interpretation is that the TVA
was successful because it delivered electricity, which had a
particularly high return in the Tennessee Valley.
Kline and Moretti (2013) also provide evidence relevant for both
capitalization and mobility. None of their specifications show a
positive impact of the TVA on population growth in the region,
suggesting that there were minimal distortions of location choice, which
perhaps reflect the fact that the TVA was supposed to pay for itself
eventually. In some, but not all, of their specifications, there is a
positive impact on median home value. Yet these positive effects do not
withstand the inclusion of other controls.
The second particularly well-known spatial program in the United
States was the Appalachian Regional Commission, which became a federal
agency in 1965. The commission's formation was motivated by local
poverty, not any obvious economic opportunity, and its geographic scope
runs through 13 states and includes all of West Virginia. The commission
provides grants in many areas, but its signature project is the
Appalachian Development Highway System, which provides highway access
throughout the region. Economic conditions in the affected counties did
seem to improve during the 1970s, but there is little evidence of any
more durable economic transformation (Glaeser and Gottlieb 2008). The
program's scale was modest, relative to the size of the region,
which makes ex post evaluation difficult. Nonetheless, the
commission's limited success surely reflects its failure to find a
high-return regional intervention.
The European Union's cohesion policy is a much larger example
of spatially targeted public investment. The policy's explicit goal
is to reduce income disparities within the EU region, partially to
reduce the political tensions that can come with heterogeneity. The
policy differentiates at the subnational level--thus, for instance,
though Warsaw is considered more developed, the rest of Poland is
considered less developed. Michele Boldrin and Fabio Canova (2001) and
Sandy Dall'Erba and Julie Le Gallo (2007) both conclude that this
policy is ineffective. Aadne Cappelen and others (2003) find modest
positive effects, which are larger in the more developed EU countries.
Again, the policies seem to have a limited effect because they focus on
spreading money around rather than on interventions that have high
returns in particular places.
Within the United States and elsewhere, spatially motivated
infrastructure investment has been much less important to spatial
development than nonspatially motivated infrastructure investment. The
federal Interstate Highway System, for example, was not intended to help
suburbanize America or to strengthen particular communities relative to
others. Yet Nathaniel Baum-Snow (2007) finds that each new highway that
was built in a metropolitan area with federal support after World War II
reduced the central city's population by 18 percent. Gilles
Duranton and Matthew Turner (2012) find significant effects of highway
construction on the economic development of connected metropolitan
areas. The large mobility effects of the highway system reflect the fact
that the system delivered mobility that was valued by millions of
Americans. (35)
Although David Aschauer (1989), Alicia Munnell (1992), and others
have found positive effects of infrastructure on local economic
activity, Andrew Garin (2016) finds almost no impact of transportation
spending under the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on employment.
One interpretation of the difference is that earlier studies focused on
a period when infrastructure brought high value to drivers and
consequently also moved activity across space. Edward Gramlich (1994),
in particular, is associated with the view that the returns to
infrastructure have declined over time. The modest impact of recent
subways on urban structure (Baum-Snow and Kahn 2005) is compatible with
the view that investments that are poorly targeted toward local demand
also have little spatial impact.
Supporters of spatial targeting for direct government spending
sometimes argue that in some cases, spatial effects can be generated at
a moderate cost. For example, if the government is going to spend a
fixed amount on the military, then locating an installation in
Mississippi rather than New York may be largely irrelevant to any
military objectives. Nakamura and Steinsson (2014) find significant
effects of military spending on the local economy. Giulia Faggio and
Henry Overman (2014), however, use quasi-exogenous shifts in the size of
local government to estimate the spillovers from increases in public
employment. They find that 1 extra job in the public sector generates
0.5 extra service sector job and crowds out 0.4 tradable sector job.
(16) One explanation for the difference may be that nonmilitary
employment crowds out local jobs, but military employment is
sufficiently different so that it does not.
Land grant colleges may have been the federal government's
most successful foray into place-making." These educational
institutions, subsidized with federal land, are strongly associated with
high incomes (Moretti 2004) and population growth during recent decades
(Glaeser and Saiz 2004). Once again, these interventions seem to have
been spatially effective because they have supported an activity that
was thought to have high returns regardless of any spatial dimension.
Most direct public investment is probably most compatible with the
agglomeration-related justifications for spatial intervention. Indeed,
one interpretation of the TVA's results is that this investment
generated a "big push" that took advantage of convex
agglomeration economics. We are far from confident about
economists' current ability to identify such opportunities. The
general existence of agglomeration economies may support the case for
national proinvestment policies, such as reducing taxes on capital
gains, but unless we understand the spatial heterogeneity of
agglomeration effects, the existence of agglomerations does not justify
spatially heterogeneous polices.
Most of the best agglomeration studies (Combes and others 2012)
support the existence of agglomeration economies, but they give us
little confidence about heterogeneity of local spillovers across space.
The million-dollar plant identification strategy of Michael Greenstone,
Richard Hornbeck, and Moretti (2010) provides little hope of identifying
heterogeneous agglomeration effects because great swaths of America,
especially the high-income coastal regions, were generally not
recipients of these plants. Consequently, it is impossible to know
whether a relocation of capital and labor from Los Angeles to Kentucky
will lead to benefits in Kentucky that are large enough to offset the
losses in Los Angeles.
VI.C. Local Employment Subsidies
The case for spatial targeting is that supporting employment may
have a particularly high return in particular places. There is a serious
body of literature that documents the effects of national employment
subsidies. Jonathan Gruber (1997) finds that the elimination of the
payroll tax in Chile was mostly passed along in the form of higher wages
and did little for employment. James Heckman and Carmen Pages (2004)
find that between 0 and 60 percent of a firm's social security
contributions in Latin America are passed along to workers in the form
of lower wages. The EITC literature has typically found that most of the
benefit of the credit accrues to workers (Rothstein 2010). The track
record of local employment subsidies is more mixed, perhaps because they
have not been targeted toward places where they would be most effective.
The literature on local employment subsidies is large and varied.
Skepticism about direct government spending led the U.K. government of
Margaret Thatcher toward a different approach: enterprise zones. Peter
Hall (1982) is generally credited with the idea of reducing taxes and
regulation in troubled urban areas. Despite his solid credentials as a
social democrat, he had been impressed with the success of Hong Kong and
Singapore, and he hypothesized that a similar light-handed touch could
engender economic regeneration in Britain's troubled inner cities.
The Thatcher government embraced Hall's vision, and the United
Kingdom began its program of providing tax benefits for firms operating
in particular urban locations. Stuart Butler (1980) embraced the
adoption of this approach in the United States. Although the federal
government would not begin its program of "empowerment zones"
until 1993, a plethora of states experimented with enterprise zones
during the 1980s. The hallmark of such zones is that firms derive some
tax benefit from operating within a disadvantaged area.
Though enterprise and empowerment zones are typically targeted at
small, depressed urban areas, other countries have offered tax
incentives for businesses that locate in larger regions. Since 1987,
Italy has offered corporate tax exemptions for firms operating in the
poorer Mezzogiorno region, which includes southern Italy and Sicily.
These incentives are larger for firms that fall within the
government's favored industrial initiatives. France has been
offering grants to firms that spread industry away from Paris since the
1960s. The Netherlands also offers targeted spatial incentives for
businesses.
Barry Rubin and Craig Richards (1992) provided an early assessment
of the effects of these zones in the United Kingdom and across U.S.
states, and concluded that the U.K. experience was relatively
unsuccessful. They estimate a cost per job of about [pounds
sterling]50,000, which annualizes to be about $14,000 per job-year,
which would be almost $30,000 per job-year today. Leslie Papke (1994)
relied on these figures in her assessment of the difficulties facing
enterprise zones in the United States. Margaret Wilder and Rubin (1996)
summarize a large number of early studies, and find wildly divergent
effects. In some cases, the cost per job was as low as $1,000.
In the past 20 years, the literature on state enterprise zones has
grown, but results seem to be quite sensitive to the time period and
approach. Daniele Bondonio and John Engberg (2000) and Robert Greenbaum
and Engberg (2004) find little effect on employment or industrial
expansion using a standard difference-in-differences approach. Suzanne
O'Keefe (2004) compares enterprise zones in California with those
in other areas that are matched using propensity score techniques. She
finds a short-run 3 percent increase in employment associated with
enterprise zone status, but less of a long-run effect.
Neumark and Jed Kolko (2010) use particularly fine-grained
geography and find no impact of the California program. John Ham and
others (2011) also use fine-grained geographies, and work hard to
distinguish different programs. They find a negative impact on the
unemployment rate, but do not find a positive impact on employment.
Thus, if enterprise zones reduce unemployment but do not increase
employment, then they must operate by reducing the amount of job
seeking, which is a surprising finding.
The most impressive piece of recent research on zones is by Busso,
Gregory, and Kline (2013), who come to a relatively positive conclusion
about the impact of federal empowerment zones. They compare labor market
outcomes in the first round of empowerment with a treatment group that
consists of areas that also competed for zone status. They have access
to confidential census micro data and find positive effects on
employment, earnings, and housing prices. They do not see significantly
rising rents in empowerment zones.
Busso, Gregory, and Kline's (2013) estimates have been used to
produce a cost of only $18,000 per job, although it is unclear how many
years of employment this means. Nonetheless, this figure is quite low
relative to other estimates, which are often closer to $100,000. One
interpretation of Busso, Gregory, and Kline's (2013) results is
that the national empowerment zones subsidized employment in places
where there was an abundance of potential employers and marginal
workers. By contrast, the U.K. enterprise zones and state enterprise
zones may have been more scattered.
Busso, Gregory, and Kline (2013) also find significant
capitalization in housing values, but little in rents. Andrew Hanson
(2009) and Douglas Krupka and Douglas Noonan (2009) find broadly similar
results, again using a synthetic control group based on areas that
applied for but did not receive empowerment zone status. Research on the
capitalization of other social interventions into property values has
been more limited. (38)
Gordon Betcherman, Meltem Daysal, and Pages (2010) provide a
particularly relevant analysis of spatially targeted employment
subsidies in Turkey. They find that the employment subsidies did
substantially increase jobs, but that the cost was considerable. But
they also conclude that the programs were poorly targeted, and as much
as 78 percent of the benefits were paid for jobs that would have existed
even without the program. They call these costs deadweight losses, but
we think that they are better interpreted as a transfer to firms'
owners.
VI.D. Individual Tax Credits or Grants
Location-specific tax benefits for individuals are less common
spatial policies. The United States does, of course, have significant
spatial heterogeneity in state and local tax rates, but these
differences are presumably also tied to differences in spending and
services. Norway's grants of tax benefits to the residents of its
colder, darker, northern climes are an example, but notably these
benefits merely subsidize location, not employment or other behaviors.
Intellectually, there would seem to be no reason why places could
not be targeted by individual tax benefits as much as firm-specific tax
credits, yet there are good reasons why these are less common. The
primary beneficiaries of standard tax credits would tend to be richer,
rather than poorer, residents, and this makes them poorly targeted for
spatially targeted redistribution. Inducing business location in a
particular area may achieve agglomeration-related benefits. Inducing
people to locate in an area, without associated jobs, would have fewer
agglomeration benefits and could potentially make local nonemployment
problems worse. The political backlash against place-based individual
tax subsidies might be significant.
National tax policy can have important spatial dimensions. Joseph
Gyourko and Todd Sinai (2003), for example, show that the benefits of
the home mortgage interest deduction accrue to some places more than
others. (39) The 2017 tax law's changes to the deductibility of
state and local taxes represents a major spatial policy, essentially
benefiting low-tax areas at the expense of high-tax areas.
There are large bodies of literature on both the capitalization and
migration effects of differences in state taxes. Wallace Oates (1969)
famously reported significant capitalization of tax differences into
property values, but the subsequent literature has been far less clear.
Jon Bakija and Joel Slemrod (2004) find that the elderly rich move to
avoid high estate taxes, but few more general results have been
established on tax-based migration.
Federal benefits, such as unemployment insurance and disability
insurance, can also be spatially targeted. (40) Before the 1996 welfare
reform, there were significant differences across states in the
generosity of the Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC)
program. Although the program was nationwide, states could choose their
benefit levels, and they paid for part of the benefit.
There is little literature on the capitalization of AFDC
differences, but there is a healthy literature on whether these payments
induced migration of the poor. Rebecca Blank (1988) found that
single-parent families were more likely to leave areas with less
generous AFDC payments. George Borjas (1999) argued that the
disproportionate flow of immigrants into California reflected its
particularly high levels of AFDC payments.
Though it may be harder to imagine a program that increases nominal
payments in some states, programs with constant nominal benefits are the
norm, and these benefits have greater value in low-price states. Because
government tax dollars go further when local prices are lower, price
heterogeneity also gives an added push to spending more in places where
costs are lower (Kaplow 1996; Glaeser and Saiz 2004). A ramped-up
version of the EITC that provided a uniform hourly work subsidy would
have a more disproportionate real impact in lower-income parts of the
country.
VI.E. Regulatory Heterogeneity
The original enterprise zone model also envisioned significant
regulatory relief. In practice, these zones were more likely to feature
tax relief rather than regulatory relief. In the United States, this
reflects the fact that the national government has little power to
override local regulations. Globally, there are many prominent examples
of zones that offer a special set of rules to businesses. The special
economic zones of China, for example, were a powerful example of how
business formation can be abetted with freedom from China's robust
business controls.
Within the United States, the Devens Enterprise Commission provides
a small, local example of a zone with light regulation. When the
military base Fort Devens shut down, the Massachusetts state government
attempted to encourage business formation in the area with one-stop
permitting. The commission claims to have been successful in encouraging
new business formation, but there is no academic research documenting
its success.
Firms also experience different levels of regulation when they
operate in areas that are deemed to be environmentally sensitive.
Builders face different regulations when they operate in historic
preservation districts. In these cases, historic differences across
geography have regulatory consequences that also have an impact on the
level of economic activity.
There are also historical accidents that lead to significant
regulatory differences. The Channel Islands off the coast of the United
Kingdom are not actually part of the United Kingdom or the European
Union. Consequently, they operate under a different set of financial
regulations, which have made them a hot spot for a variety of financial
service firms.
Limiting the supply of new housing restricts migration to
particular areas and boosts prices in those areas (Glaeser and Gyourko
2018). We have less evidence on whether other forms of regulation have
such effects. Consequently, one of the best justifications for districts
with different types of regulations is that they enable experimentation
with new types of regulations. For example, entrepreneurship districts
that relaxed regulations on new businesses would allow one to study the
impact of such interventions.
VII. Place-Based Policies for America
Our theoretical section suggests that public support should shift
toward encouraging employment, rather than supporting the not working,
in areas where employment responses to earnings are particularly high.
Our empirical findings suggest that employment elasticities in some
states, like West Virginia, may be much higher than in other states,
like Wyoming. Our conclusion is that a policy mix that encourages more
employment in high nonemployment states, such as West Virginia, may
yield greater benefits than uniform national policies that treat all
states equally.
We begin with the two most plausible examples of such place-based
actions: targeted location of public activities, and infrastructure
investment. We then turn to employment subsidies, which are a natural
tool for fighting nonemployment but are harder to target spatially.
Finally, we end with education interventions, and prodding community
colleges to focus more on employability in regions with high not-working
rates.
VILA. The Location of Public Activity and Infrastructure Investment
Although there are approximately 22 million public sector workers
within the United States, only 2.8 million of them are actually in the
federal government. This relatively small employment share necessarily
limits the magnitude of any relocation of federal activities. Moreover,
51 percent of civilian, nonpostal workers are either in the military or
in veterans' affairs, and consequently, any serious relocation
policy would need to focus on the military. (41)
There is mixed evidence on the employment effects of public
activity, but the location of military bases does seem to have a
positive impact on the local economy (Nakamura and Steinsson 2014). The
harder question, which we cannot answer, is What are the costs of the
geographic targeting of military spending? Shuttering and reopening the
same base somewhere else seems prohibitively expensive. The best
opportunities for geographic targeting occur at the points of base
openings and closings. In principle, new bases can be sited and old
bases can be kept open in areas with more elastic employment responses
to labor demand.
The most reasonable proposal might be to ask the military to
incorporate the effects on local employment into its calculations. If
the military actually used a cost-benefit analysis in making location
decisions, it would be straightforward to multiply employment effects
with estimates of the externalities from employment and incorporate this
total location-specific benefit into calculations.
After the military, the Department of Veterans Affairs (VA) is the
second-largest federal employer. The VA has fewer spatially lumped
assets, but it does maintain hospitals and large offices. Again, the
department could be encouraged to internalize local employment effects
when it opens and shuts facilities, but this would be fundamentally
limited by the need to match medical facilities with the location of
military retirees. The VA's nonmedical employment is more spatially
fungible, but represents a modest share of its total employment.
Although the location decisions of the federal government could
internalize local employment effects, we are doubtful that such policies
could ever be significant in practice. The military will surely oppose
any push to have it internalize nonmilitary objectives. The VA will
similarly move only with difficulty.
Federally funded infrastructure projects are perhaps the most
popular tool for encouraging local economic development. Yet these
projects also have a very mixed record of encouraging local employment
(Garin 2016), and there is an inherent tension between targeting
infrastructure toward growing successful areas that need more
infrastructure and supporting distressed areas with a highly elastic
labor supply. America's most glaring infrastructure deficits are
visible in large, busy, urban areas where airports, like New York's
John F. Kennedy International Airport, are undermaintained and where
public transportation and highways are highly congested.
If users are willing to pay for both a project's operating and
capital costs, then it is unlikely to be a white elephant. If modest
federal investment can spur self-financing infrastructure projects in
distressed areas, then there seems to be little downside risk. But is
there a large number of such potential projects?
The Tennessee Valley Authority was close to being such a project.
The original financing for the TVA came from the federal government, but
that early investment has been repaid. The TVA also benefited from using
eminent domain to move thousands of farmers to gain access to waterways,
but many of those farmers benefited from subsequent electricity access.
The TVA succeeded because it offered a transformative
technology--electricity--for which there was abundant demand.
The Trump administration's infrastructure plan combines a
modest amount of federal seed money meant to spur the building of
infrastructure that is financed by user fees. The proposal contains
tools for scoring prospective proposals, but the details of the scoring
algorithm have not yet been made public. The natural means of
incorporating concerns about not working into that structure is to
provide extra points in the algorithm based on the number of people who
can be reasonably projected to find employment as a result of the
project after it is completed. Ideally, the social values of these
transitions should be denominated in dollars to make them comparable
with other criteria used in the scoring algorithm.
If federal investment comes with no expectations for user fee
financing, then there is more scope for spatially targeting areas with
high not-working rates, and more risk of white elephants. At this point,
most legislatively mandated projects do not come with a cost-benefit
analysis. If such analyses were to become the norm, then it would be
natural to include the social benefits of employment among overall
benefits. Even without a cost-benefit analysis, the current Highway
Trust Fund apportionment rules could incorporate nonemployment effects.
Such alterations to the code would, however, require one to be certain
that highway funds spent in areas with high not-working rates do more to
reduce not-working rates than highway funds spent in other areas.
In a reformed system with better checks on waste and real
cost-benefit analyses, infrastructure could provide a tool for regional
support; but without such reforms, the downsides remain significant.
VII.B. Employment Subsidies, Welfare Benefits, and Federal Taxes
The norm in U.S. politics is that national policies need to be
uniform, even when local heterogeneity argues strongly against such
uniformity. Housing subsidies, such as the Low Income Housing Tax
Credit, treat Detroit, Houston, and San Francisco essentially
identically, despite their wildly different housing costs and supply
conditions. We have tried to make the case that labor supply
elasticities are heterogeneous, and consequently one-size-fits-all
employment policies will generate less added employment than spatially
differentiated policies. Stronger employment subsidies are likely to
reduce joblessness more in eastern Tennessee than in San Francisco.
The current Earned Income Tax Credit is based on annual earnings.
It phases in at low incomes, where it essentially offers a proportionate
increase in earnings; it reaches a maximum value, and for individuals at
this earnings threshold it essentially offers a flat nominal subsidy for
working; and it phases out at higher incomes, essentially acting as a
deterrent on working more.
The EITC can be over $6,000 for individuals with three or more
children and earnings of about $16,000. For individuals who do not have
children in their households, it represents an extremely modest work
subsidy. However, the overwhelming preponderance of not-working men do
not have a child in their homes.
For the EITC to be more effective at spurring prime age male
employment, it would need to be more generous to single-person
households. One option would be to affect a straight wage subsidy,
perhaps administered through employers, which would obviously increase
the take-home pay per hour of work. One danger of this approach is that
it might engender fraud as workers and firms collude to declare that the
worker had labored for longer hours at lower wages. If fraud can be
effectively contained, an hourly employer-managed wage subsidy has
significant advantages in ease of administration and salience. Any
system would need to phase out to be fiscally prudent, which would
inevitably deter work. Edmund Phelps (1997) explores the potential
implementation of employment subsidies in detail, and proposes a system
of employment subsidies based on continuing tax credits for employers.
A flat cash wage subsidy would provide more push in areas with high
not-working rates because prices are lower. The current maximum EITC
payment, which is fixed in dollar terms, already achieves that end. The
phase-in period, which increases earnings proportionally, does not.
Consequently, the move to a dollar wage subsidy, instead of a percentage
increase, would partially strengthen geographic targeting. A more
aggressive approach would increase the size of the wage subsidy in
distressed areas, which our estimates suggest would increase employment
more per $ 1 spent.
Another approach is to reduce marginal taxes for everyone living in
areas with high not-working rates. This approach is embodied in the 2017
tax law, which lowered tax rates for many and increased the standard
deduction. But it also severely limited the deductibility of state and
local taxes. Effectively, this shift raised taxes in big government
states relative to small government states. If local government spending
on services like education has significant social value, then this
strategy has significant downsides. Yet given the negative correlation
between the size of local government and not-working rates, it may also
reduce the disincentive to work in areas where not working is more
endemic.
The actual tax code may be less important for deterring employment
than the rules surrounding public benefits, like the Supplemental
Nutritional Assistance Program, housing vouchers, and disability
insurance. These benefits effectively tax employment by decreasing or
disappearing entirely with higher earnings. The implicit taxes created
by these programs could be reduced in low-employment regions by enabling
people who work and earn low incomes to keep more of the benefits.
Current implicit tax rates of 30 percent could be reduced to 20 percent,
for example.
In this section, we focused on increasing spending in regions with
high not-working rates, and we recognize that this could distort
migration and lead to high real estate prices. As the theory section
made clear, this can be offset if other benefits are removed from the
region. We will not analyze appropriate areas to cut; but theoretically,
it is possible to reduce nonemployment in regions with high not-working
rates while keeping total spending in the region constant and not
distorting migration incentives, as long as other
nonemployment-enhancing spending is cut back.
Although our model suggests the value of more tailored employment
policies, we are notably not calling for local control. Localities often
have strong incentives to distort migration in order to attract the rich
and repel the poor. Purely local control over social welfare policy
could lead to a race to the bottom where states dismantled their safety
nets to get rid of their poorer residents.
VII.C. Place-Based Education Reform
The data strongly support the view that education is an extremely
powerful determinant of local success and failure. We consequently join
those who see investment in human capital as critical for long-run
growth, even if this investment takes a generation or more.
However, education also contains trade-offs between providing
skills that maximize future employability and other objectives. Liberal
arts education, naturally, has never accepted preprofessionalism, but
even in high schools and community colleges there are often diverse
objectives. Those trade-offs can be tilted toward employment in regions
with high not-working rates.
Currently, the federal government supports community colleges
through Pell Grants and other forms of support. This support could be
structured to provide incentives that induce those institutions to focus
more on job-generating skills. For example, community colleges could
receive bonus payments for admitting students from distressed regions,
who would then be employed for a number of years after graduation. At
the least, such a program could be tested for impact.
We do not anticipate that such incentives will do much in the
classroom. It is difficult to change teaching quality for courses such
as remedial writing and mathematics. The more likely impact of such an
incentive program is that college administrators would begin
experimenting with counseling and promoting more employable majors.
Bartik and George Erickcek's (2014) discussion of place-based
policies emphasizes the possibility of targeted training programs, which
might provide skills that are in high local demand. Though the track
record of adult training programs is mixed at best, we agree with Bartik
and Erickcek that there is value is experimenting with targeted
training. If there are fixed costs to supporting training in particular
locations, then it would make sense to have programs disproportionately
in areas with a greater need and a more elastic labor supply.
VIII. Final Thoughts
This paper has proposed three plausible justifications for
place-based policies: agglomeration economies, geographic targeting of
redistribution, and nonemployment reduction in hot spots. The
agglomeration case for spatial redistribution is weak, because we know
too little about the exact functional form of agglomeration economies.
The case for geographic targeting of redistribution is more plausible,
but income heterogeneity within areas is much larger than heterogeneity
across areas. Moreover, capitalization effects mean that property owners
are likely to reap many of the benefits of geographically targeted
policies.
The best case for geographic targeting of policies is that $1 spent
fighting nonemployment in an area with a high not-working rate will do
more to reduce nonemployment than $1 spent fighting nonemployment in an
area with a low not-working rate. The empirical evidence for
heterogeneous labor supply responses to demand shocks or public
interventions is limited, but is broadly supportive of the view that
reducing the not-working rate in some parts of the country is easier
than in other parts of the country.
This heterogeneity can either justify added spending in distressed,
more elastic areas, or a twist in spending that favors employment in
these areas. Though infrastructure remains an important investment for
the United States, targeting infrastructure spending toward distressed
areas risks producing projects with limited value for users. By
contrast, enhanced spending on employment subsidies in areas with
extreme joblessness, and perhaps in the United States as a whole, seems
like a more plausible means of reducing nonemployment. Subsidizing
employment seems likely to have a larger impact in the long run if it is
matched with investment in work-related human capital.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We are grateful to Harris Eppsteiner for
outstanding research assistance. For excellent comments, we are very
grateful to Gilles Duranton, Robert Hall, and James Stock; to the
participants in the Brookings Panel on Economic Activity; and to faculty
members of Johns Hopkins University.
References
Abraham, Katharine G., and Melissa S. Kearney. 2018.
"Explaining the Decline in the U.S. Employment-to-Population Ratio:
A Review of the Evidence." Working Paper no. 24333. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Ades, Alberto E, and Edward L. Glaeser. 1995. "Trade and
Circuses: Explaining Urban Giants." Quarterly Journal of Economics
110, no. 1: 195-227.
Aguiar, Mark, Mark Bils, Kerwin Kofi Charles, and Erik Hurst. 2017.
"Leisure Luxuries and the Labor Supply of Young Men." Working
Paper no. 23552. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Albouy, David. 2010. "Evaluating the Efficiency and Equity of
Federal Fiscal Equalization." Working Paper no. 16144. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Alesina, Alberto, Edward Glaeser, and Bruce Sacerdote. 2005.
"Work and Leisure in the United States and Europe: Why So
Different?" NBER Macroeconomics Annual 20: 1-64.
Alesina, Alberto, Armando Miano, and Stefanie Stantcheva.
Forthcoming.
"Immigration and Support for Redistribution." Working
paper, https://sch.olar.harvard.edu/stantcheva/publications/immigration-and-support-redistribution
Andersen, Steffen, Glenn W. Harrison, Morten I, Lau, and E.
Elisabet Rutstrom. 2008. "Eliciting Risk and Time
Preferences." Econometrica 76, no. 3: 583-618. Aschauer, David
Alan. 1989. "Is Public Expenditure Productive?" Journal of
Monetary Economics 23, no. 2: 177-200.
Autor. David H., David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson. 2013. "The
China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the
United States." American Economic Review 103, no. 6: 2121-68.
Autor, David, David Dorn, Gordon Hanson, and Kaveh Majlesi. 2017.
"A Note on the Effect of Rising Trade Exposure on the 2016
Presidential Elections." Working paper.
http://www.ddorn.net/papers/ADHM-President2016.pdf
Autor, David H" and Mark G. Duggan. 2003. "The Rise in
the Disability Rolls and the Decline in Unemployment." Quarterly
Journal of Economics 118, no. 1: 157-206.
Baily, Martin Neil. 1978. "Some Aspects of Optimal
Unemployment Insurance." Journal of Public Economics 10, no. 3:
379-02.
Bakija, Jon, and Joel Slemrod. 2004. "Do the Rich Flee from
High State Taxes? Evidence from Federal Estate Tax Returns."
Working Paper no. 10645. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1991. "Convergence
across States and Regions." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
no. 1: 107-82.
Barsky, Robert B., F. Thomas Juster, Miles S. Kimball, and Matthew
D. Shapiro. 1997. "Preference Parameters and Behavioral
Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement
Study." Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, no. 2: 537-79.
Bartik, Timothy J. 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic
Development Policies? Kalamazoo, Mich.: W. E. Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research.
--. 2015. "How Effects of Local Labor Demand Shocks Vary with
the Initial Local Unemployment Rate." Growth and Change 46, no. 4:
529-57.
Bartik, Timothy J., and George Erickcek. 2014. "Simulating the
Effects of the Tax Credit Program of the Michigan Economic Growth
Authority on Job Creation and Fiscal Benefits." Economic
Development Quarterly 28, no. 4: 314-27.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel. 2007. "Did Highways Cause
Suburbanization?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, no. 2:
775-805.
Baum-Snow, Nathaniel, and Matthew E. Kahn. 2005. "Effects of
Urban Rail Transit Expansions: Evidence from Sixteen Cities,
1970-2000." Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs 6: 147-206.
Berry, Christopher R., and Edward L. Glaeser. 2005. "The
Divergence of Human Capital Levels across Cities." Papers in
Regional Science 84, no. 3: 407-4.
Betcherman, Gordon, N. Meltem Daysal, and Carmen Pages. 2010.
"Do Employment Subsidies Work? Evidence from Regionally Targeted
Subsidies in Turkey." Labour Economics 17, no. 4: 710-22.
Blakely, Tony A., Sunny C. D. Collings, and June Atkinson. 2003.
"Unemployment and Suicide: Evidence for a Causal Association?"
Journal of Epidemiology & Community Health 57, no. 8: 594-600.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1992. "Regional
Evolutions." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1: 1-75.
Blank, Rebecca M. 1988. "The Effect of Welfare and Wage Levels
on the Location Decisions of Female-Headed Households." Journal of
Urban Economics 24, no. 2: 186-211.
Blundell, Richard, and Thomas MaCurdy. 1999. "Labor Supply: A
Review of Alternative Approaches." In Handbook of Labor Economics,
Vol. 3A, edited by Orley C. Ashenfelter and David Card. Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
Boldin, Michael, and Jonathan H. Wright. 2015.
"Weather-Adjusting Economic Data." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, Fall: 227-60.
Boldrin. Michele. and Fabio Canova. 2001. "Inequality and
Convergence in Europe's Regions: Reconsidering European Regional
Policies." Economic Policy 16, no. 32: 206-53.
Bondonio, Daniele, and John Engberg. 2000. "Enterprise Zones
and Local Employment: Evidence from the States' Programs."
Regional Science and Urban Economics 30, no. 5: 519-49.
Borjas, George J. 1999. "Immigration and Welfare
Magnets." Journal of Labor Economics 17, no. 4: 607-37.
Borjas, George J., and Lynette Hilton. 1996. "Immigration and
the Welfare State: Immigrant Participation in Means-Tested Entitlement
Programs." Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, no. 2: 575-604.
Boustan, Leah P., and Robert A. Margo. 2013. "A Silver Lining
to White Flight? White Suburbanization and African-American
Homeownership, 1940-1980." Journal of Urban Economics 78: 71-80.
Braga, Anthony A., Andrew V. Papachristos, and David M. Hureau.
2014. "The Effects of Hot Spots Policing on Crime: An Updated
Systematic Review and Meta-Analysis." Justice Quarterly 31, no. 4:
633-63.
Busso, Matias, Jesse Gregory, and Patrick Kline. 2013.
"Assessing the Incidence and Efficiency of a Prominent Place Based
Policy." American Economic Review 103, no. 2: 897-947.
Butler, Stuart M. 1980. Enterprise Zones: Pioneering in the Inner
City. Washington: Heritage Foundation.
Cappelen, Aadne, Fulvio Castellacci, Jan Fagerberg, and Bart
Verspagen. 2003. "The Impact of EU Regional Support on Growth and
Convergence in the European Union." Journal of Common Market
Studies 41, no. 4: 621-44.
Case, Anne, and Angus Deaton. 2015. "Rising Morbidity and
Mortality in Midlife among White Non-Hispanic Americans in the 21st
Century." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112, no.
49: 15078-83.
--. 2017. "Mortality and Morbidity in the 21st Century."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring: 397-43.
Chernobai, Ekaterina, Michael Reibel, and Michael Carney. 2011.
"Nonlinear Spatial and Temporal Effects of Highway Construction on
House Prices." Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 42, no.
3: 348-70.
Chetty, Raj. 2006. "A General Formula for the Optimal Level of
Social Insurance." Journal of Public Economics 90, nos. 10-11:
1879-901.
Chetty, Raj, Adam Guren, Day Manoli, and Andrea Weber. 2013.
"Does Indivisible Labor Explain the Difference between Micro and
Macro Elasticities? A Meta-Analysis of Extensive Margin
Elasticities." NBER Macroeconomics Annual 27: 1-56.
Chetty, Raj, and Nathaniel Hendren. Forthcoming. "The Impacts
of Neighborhoods on Intergenerational Mobility I: Childhood Exposure
Effects." Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Chodorow-Reich, Gabriel. 2017. "Geographic Cross-Sectional
Fiscal Multipliers: What Have We Learned?" Working Paper no. 23511.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Clark, Andrew E. 2003. "Unemployment as a Social Norm:
Psychological Evidence from Panel Data." Journal of Labor Economics
21, no. 2: 323-51.
Clark, Andrew E., and Andrew J. Oswald. 1994. "Unhappiness and
Unemployment." Economic Journal 104, no. 424: 648-59.
Clark, Kim B., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1979. "Labor Market
Dynamics and Unemployment: A Reconsideration." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, no. 1: 13-60.
Coglianese, John. 2017. "The Rise of In-and-Outs: Declining
Labor Force Participation of Prime Age Men." Job market paper,
Harvard University. https://scholar.harvard.edu/coglianese/publications/rise-of-in-and-outs
Cohen, Alma, and Liran Einav. 2007. "Estimating Risk
Preferences from Deductible Choice." American Economic Review 97,
no. 3: 745-88.
Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Gilles Duranton, and Laurent Gobillon.
2008. "Spatial Wage Disparities: Sorting Matters!" Journal of
Urban Economics 63, no. 2: 723-42.
Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Gilles Duranton, Laurent Gobillon, Diego
Puga, and Sebastien Roux. 2012. "The Productivity Advantages of
Large Cities: Distinguishing Agglomeration from Firm Selection."
Econometrica 80, no. 6: 2543-94.
Conley, Timothy G., and Giorgio Topa. 2002. "Socio-Economic
Distance and Spatial Patterns in Unemployment." Journal of Applied
Econometrics 17, no. 4: 303-27.
Council of Economic Advisers. 2016. "The Long-Term Decline in
Prime-Age Male Labor Force Participation." Washington: White House.
https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/page/files/20160620_primeage_male_lfp_cea.pdf
Dall'Erba, Sandy, and Julie Le Gallo. 2007. "The Impact
of EU Regional Support on Growth and Employment." Czech Journal of
Economics and Finance 57, nos. 7-8: 325-40.
Dao, Mai, Davide Furceri, and Prakash Loungani. 2017.
"Regional Labor Market Adjustment in the United States: Trend and
Cycle." Review of Economics and Statistics 99, no. 2: 243-57.
Dube, Arindrajit, Ethan Kaplan, and Ben Zipperer. 2015.
"Excess Capacity and Heterogeneity in the Fiscal Multiplier:
Evidence from the Obama Stimulus Package." Working paper,
http://econweb.umd.edu/~kaplan/stimulus_effects.pdf
Duranton, Gilles, and Diego Puga. 2004. "Micro-Foundations of
Urban Agglomeration Economies." In Handbook of Regional and Urban
Economics, Vol. 4, edited by J. Vernon Henderson and Jacques-Francois
Thisse. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Duranton, Gilles, and Matthew A. Turner. 2012. "Urban Growth
and Transportation." Review of Economic Studies 79, no. 4: 1407-40.
Eberstadt, Nicholas. 2016. Men without Work: America's
Invisible Crisis. West Conshohocken, Pa.: Templeton Press.
Eissa, Nada, and Jeffrey B. Liebman. 1996. "Labor Supply
Response to the Earned Income Tax Credit." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 111, no. 2: 605-37.
Faggio, Giulia, and Henry Overman. 2014. "The Effect of Public
Sector Employment on Local Labour Markets." Journal of Urban
Economics 79: 91-107.
French, Eric, and Jae Song. 2014. "The Effect of Disability
Insurance Receipt on Labor Supply." American Economic Journal:
Economic Policy 6, no. 2: 291-337.
Ganong, Peter, and Daniel Shoag. 2017. "Why Has Regional
Income Convergence in the U.S. Declined?" Journal of Urban
Economics 102: 76-90.
Garin, Andrew. 2016. "Putting America to Work, Where? The
Limits of Infrastructure Construction as a Locally Targeted Employment
Policy." Working Paper no. 2016-01. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University. Kennedy School of Government, Taubman Center for State and
Local Government.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joshua D. Gottlieb. 2008. "The
Economics of Place-Making Policies." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, Spring: 155-239.
Glaeser, Edward L., Joshua D. Gottlieb, and Oren Ziv. 2016.
"Unhappy Cities." Journal of Labor Economics 34, suppl. 2:
S129-S182.
Glaeser, Edward, and Joseph Gyourko. 2018. "The Economic
Implications of Housing Supply." Journal of Economic Perspectives
32, no. 1: 3-30.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Albert Saiz. 2004. "The Rise of the
Skilled City." Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs 5: 47-105.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Raven E. Saks. 2006. "Corruption in
America." Journal of Public Economics 90, nos. 6-7: 1053-72.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Krishna Tobio. 2008. "The Rise of the
Sunbelt." Southern Economic Journal 74, no. 3: 610-13.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Bryce A. Ward. 2009. "The Causes and
Consequences of Land Use Regulation: Evidence from Greater Boston."
Journal of Urban Economics 65, no. 3: 265-78.
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 2008. The Race between
Education and Technology. Belknap Press. Goldsmith-Pinkham. Paul. Isaac
Sorkin, and Henry Swift. 2018. "Bartik Instruments: What, When,
Why, and How." Working Paper no. 24408. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Gordon, Robert J. 1973. "The Welfare Cost of Higher
Unemployment." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1:
133-95.
Gramlich, Edward M. 1994. "Infrastructure Investment: A Review
Essay." Journal of Economic Literature 32, no. 3: 1176-96.
Greenbaum, Robert T., and John B. Engberg. 2004. "The Impact
of State Enterprise Zones on Urban Manufacturing Establishments."
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 23, no. 2: 315-39.
Greenstone, Michael, Richard Hornbeck, and Enrico Moretti. 2010.
"Identifying Agglomeration Spillovers: Evidence from Winners and
Losers of Large Plant Openings." Journal of Political Economy 118,
no. 3: 536-98.
Greenwood, Michael J., and Gary L. Hunt. 1984. "Migration and
Interregional Employment Redistribution in the United States."
American Economic Review 74, no. 5: 957-69.
Gruber, Jonathan. 1997. "The Incidence of Payroll Taxation:
Evidence from Chile." Journal of Labor Economics 15, suppl. 3:
S72-S101.
Gyourko, Joseph, Albert Saiz, and Anita Summers. 2008. "A New
Measure of the Local Regulatory Environment for Housing Markets: The
Wharton Residential Land Use Regulatory Index." Urban Studies 45,
no. 3: 693-729.
Gyourko, Joseph, and Todd Sinai. 2003. "The Spatial
Distribution of Housing-Related Ordinary Income Tax Benefits." Real
Estate Economics 31, no. 4: 527-75.
Hajek, Andre. 2013. "Life Satisfaction and Unemployment: The
Role of Voluntariness and Job Prospects." SOEP Paper on
Multidisciplinary Panel Data Research no. 601. Berlin: DIW Berlin.
Hall, Peter. 1982. "Enterprise Zones: A Justification."
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 6, no. 3: 416-21.
Hall, Robert E. 1972. "Turnover in the Labor Force."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 3: 709-56.
Ham, John C, Charles Swenson, Ayse Imrohoroglu, and Heonjae Song.
2011. "Government Programs Can Improve Local Labor Markets:
Evidence from State Enterprise Zones, Federal Empowerment Zones and
Federal Enterprise Community." Journal of Public Economics 95, nos.
7-8: 779-97.
Hanson, Andrew. 2009. "Local Employment, Poverty, and Property
Value Effects of Geographically Targeted Tax Incentives: An Instrumental
Variables Approach." Regional Science and Urban Economics 39, no.
6: 721-31.
Hausman, Naomi. 2017. "University Innovation and Local
Economic Growth." Discussion Paper no. 17.05. Jerusalem: Hebrew
University of Jerusalem, Maurice Falk Institute for Economic Research in
Israel.
Heckman, James J., and Carmen Pages. 2004.
"Introduction." In Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin
America and the Caribbean, edited by James J. Heckman and Carmen Pages.
University of Chicago Press.
Holmes, Thomas J. 1998. "The Effect of State Policies on the
Location of Manufacturing: Evidence from State Borders." Journal of
Political Economy 106, no. 4: 667-705.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Enrico Moretti. 2017. "Housing
Constraints and Spatial Misallocation." Working Paper no. 21154.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Johnson, Janna E., and Morris M. Kleiner. 2017. "Is
Occupational Licensing a Barrier to Interstate Migration?" Working
Paper no. 24107. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M. Murphy, and Robert H. Topel. 1991.
"Why Has the Natural Rate of Unemployment Increased over
Time?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 2: 75-142.
Kaplow, Louis. 1996. "The Optimal Supply of Public Goods and
the Distortionary Cost of Taxation." National Tax Journal 49, no.
4: 513-33.
Killewald, Alexandra. 2016. "Money, Work, and Marital
Stability: Assessing Change in the Gendered Determinants of
Divorce." American Sociological Review 81, no. 4: 696-719.
Kleiner, Morris M., and Evgeny Vorotnikov. 2017. "Analyzing
Occupational Licensing among the States." Journal of Regulatory
Economics 52, no. 2: 132-58.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. 2013. "Local Economic
Development, Agglomeration Economies, and the Big Push: 100 Years of
Evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 129, no. 1: 275-331.
Kostol, Andreas Ravndal, and Magne Mogstad. 2014. "How
Financial Incentives Induce Disability Insurance Recipients to Return to
Work." American Economic Review 104, no. 2: 624-55.
Kposowa, Augustine J. 2001. "Unemployment and Suicide: A
Cohort Analysis of Social Factors Predicting Suicide in the US National
Longitudinal Mortality Study." Psychological Medicine 31, no. 1:
127-38.
Krueger, Alan B. 2017. "Where Have All the Workers Gone? An
Inquiry into the Decline of the U.S. Labor Force Participation
Rate." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall: 1-59.
Krupka, Douglas J., and Douglas S. Noonan. 2009. "Empowerment
Zones, Neighborhood Change and Owner-Occupied Housing." Regional
Science and Urban Economics 39, no. 4: 386-96.
Lindbeck, Assar, Sten Nyberg, and Jorgen W. Weibull. 1999.
"Social Norms and Economic Incentives in the Welfare State."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, no. 1: 1-35.
Maestas, Nicole, Kathleen J. Mullen, and Alexander Strand. 2013.
"Does Disability Insurance Receipt Discourage Work? Using Examiner
Assignment to Estimate Causal Effects of SSDI Receipt." American
Economic Review 103, no. 5: 1797-829.
Meghir, Costas, and David Phillips. 2010. "Labour Supply and
Taxes." In Dimensions of Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review, edited by
James Mirrlees, Stuart Adam, Timothy Besley, Richard Blundell, Stephen
Bond, Robert Chote, Malcolm Gammie, Paul Johnson, Gareth Myles, and
James Poterba. Oxford University Press.
Meyer, Bruce D., and Dan T. Rosenbaum. 2001. "Welfare, the
Earned Income Tax Credit, and the Labor Supply of Single Mothers."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, no. 3: 1063-114.
Miller, Cynthia, Lawrence F. Katz, Gilda Azurdia, Adam Isen, and
Caroline Schultz. 2017. "Expanding the Earned Income Tax Credit for
Workers without Dependent Children: Interim Findings from the Paycheck
Plus Demonstration in New York City." New York: MDRC.
Moretti, Enrico. 2004. "Estimating the Social Return to Higher
Education: Evidence from Longitudinal and Repeated Cross-Sectional
Data." Journal of Econometrics 121, nos. 1-2: 175-212.
--. 2011. "Local Labor Markets." In Handbook of Labor
Economics, Vol. 4B, edited by Orley Ashenfelter and David Card.
Amsterdam: North-Holland. Munnell, Alicia H. 1992. "Policy Watch:
Infrastructure Investment and Economic Growth." Journal of Economic
Perspectives 6, no. 4: 189-98.
Nakamura, Emi, and Jon Steinsson. 2014. "Fiscal Stimulus in a
Monetary Union: Evidence from US Regions." American Economic Review
104, no. 3: 753-92.
Neumark, David, and Jed Kolko. 2010. "Do Enterprise Zones
Create Jobs? Evidence from California's Enterprise Zone
Program." Journal of Urban Economics 68, no. 1: 1-19.
Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 2011. "Does a Higher
Minimum Wage Enhance the Effectiveness of the Earned Income Tax
Credit?" ILR Review 64, no. 4: 712-16.
Oates, Wallace E. 1969. "The Effects of Property Taxes and
Local Public Spending on Property Values: An Empirical Study of Tax
Capitalization and the Tiebout Hypothesis." Journal of Political
Economy 77, no. 6: 957-71.
O'Keefe, Suzanne. 2004. "Job Creation in
California's Enterprise Zones: A Comparison Using a Propensity
Score Matching Model." Journal of Urban Economics 55, no. 1:
131-50.
Papke, Leslie E. 1994. "Tax Policy and Urban Development:
Evidence from the Indiana Enterprise Zone Program." Journal of
Public Economics 54, no. 1: 37-49.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1997. Rewarding Work: How to Restore
Participation and Self-Support to Free Enterprise. Harvard University
Press.
Platt, Stephen. 1984. "Unemployment and Suicidal Behaviour: A
Review of the Literature." Social Science & Medicine 19, no. 2:
93-115.
Rauch, James E. 1993. "Productivity Gains from Geographic
Concentration of Human Capital: Evidence from the Cities." Journal
of Urban Economics 34, no. 3: 380-400.
Rivera Drew, Julia A., Sarah Flood, and John Robert Warren. 2014.
"Making Full Use of the Longitudinal Design of the Current
Population Survey: Methods for Linking Records across 16 Months."
Journal of Economic and Social Measurement 39, no. 3: 121-44.
Rothstein, Jesse. 2010. "Is the EITC as Good as an NIT?
Conditional Cash Transfers and Tax Incidence." American Economic
Journal: Economic Policy 2, no. 1: 177-208.
Rubin, Barry M., and Craig M. Richards. 1992. "A Transatlantic
Comparison of Enterprise Zone Impacts: The British and American
Experience." Economic Development Quarterly 6, no. 4: 431-43.
Schleicher, David. 2017. "Stuck! The Law and Economics of
Residential Stagnation." Yale Law Journal 127, no. 1: 78-154.
Smith, James P., and Finis R. Welch. 1989. "Black Economic
Progress after Myrdal." Journal of Economic Literature 27, no. 2:
519-64.
Stull, William J., and Judith C. Stull. 1991. "Capitalization
of Local Income Taxes." Journal of Urban Economics 29, no. 2:
182-90.
Topa, Giorgio. 2001. "Social Interactions, Local Spillovers
and Unemployment." Review of Economic Studies 68, no. 2: 261-95.
Wilder, Margaret G., and Barry M. Rubin. 1996. "Rhetoric
versus Reality: A Review of Studies on State Enterprise Zone
Programs." Journal of the American Planning Association 62, no. 4:
473-91.
Winkelmann, Rainer. 2014. "Unemployment and Happiness."
World of Labor no. 94. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).
Yinger, John, Howard S. Bloom, Axel Borsch-Supan, and Helen F.
Ladd. 1988. Property Taxes and House Values: The Theory and Estimation
of intrajurisdictional Property Tax Capitalization. Boston: Academic
Press.
Zabek, Mike. 2018. "Local Ties in Spatial Equilibrium."
Job market paper. University of Michigan.
https://mikezabek.com/pdf/LocalTies.pdf
BENJAMIN AUSTIN
Harvard University
EDWARD GLAESER
Harvard University
LAWRENCE SUMMERS
Harvard University
Conflict of Interest Disclosure: The authors received financial
support for this work from the Smith Richardson Foundation. With the
exception of the aforementioned, they did not receive financial support
from any firm or person for this paper or from any firm or person with a
financial or political interest in this paper. With the exception of the
aforementioned, they are currently not officers, directors, or board
members of any organization with an interest in this paper. No outside
party had the right to review this paper before publication.
(1.) Eberstadt (2016) and the Council of Economic Advisers (2016)
both provide excellent overviews of the rise in nonemployment among
prime age males.
(2.) Place of birth has a strong impact on economic opportunity
(Chetty and Hendren. forthcoming). Almost 50 years ago, in 1969, the
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis also listed Stamford, Conn., as the
wealthiest metropolitan area and McAllen. Tex., as the poorest. In that
year, Stamford was almost three times as rich as McAllen. In 2016,
America's richest metropolitan areas (Stamford and Midland, Tex.)
were four times richer than the poorest (McAllen).
(3.) The impact of spatially heterogeneous policies on migration is
a long-standing question in antipoverty policy, and much of the best
work on this topic preceded welfare reform, when state differences in
payments for Aid to Families with Dependent Children could be quite
large (Borjas and Hilton 1996).
(4.) Busso. Gregory, and Kline (2013) also find that Empowerment
Zones do seem to get capitalized into housing prices, especially in
depressed areas, but evidence for capitalization into rents is weaker.
(5.) One plausible explanation for the relationship between
regulation and education is that higher-skilled people are also better
at organizing into groups that oppose new construction, such as the San
Francisco Bay Area's Save the Bay initiative, which was cofounded
by Catherine Kerr, the wife of Clark Kerr, the first chancellor of the
University of California, Berkeley.
(6.) Berry and Glaeser (2005) find that the correlation across
industries between the education levels of managers and the education
level of workers increased significantly between 1970 and 2000, which
supports the view that skilled workers increasingly complement each
other at work.
(7.) This is as shown in online appendix figure 1. Online appendix
figure 2 shows a steady rise in prime age female labor force
participation through the 1990s and then a leveling off. The online
appendixes for this and all other papers in this volume may be found at
the Brookings Papers web page, www.brookings.edu/bpea, under "Past
BPEA Editions."
(8.) The CPS consists of a 4-8-4 rotation structure, where
households are interviewed for four months, rotate out of the panel for
eight months, and are then interviewed for an additional four months. We
use the method developed by Rivera Drew. Flood, and Warren (2014) to
match respondents across months.
(9.) We note that some men who state they want a job may be unable
to start a job immediately. However, we believe it is instructive to
decompose not-working men into those who have a stated preference for
future employment and those who do not.
(10.) The residents of rust belt cities were less happy during the
1940s and 1970s, but they were presumably compensated by higher wages
(Glaeser, Gottlieb, and Ziv 2016).
(11.) There are slight population differences between decennial
census data, which were used to create the 1980 map, and American
Community Survey data, which were used to create the 2015 maps.
Moreover, the 2015 PUMAs are defined differently than the consistent
PUMAs used from 1980 to 2010. The maps look broadly similar using 2010
data and consistent 1980-2010 PUMAs.
(12.) Online appendix figure 5 shows a map of prime age female
not-working rates in 2015. Online appendix figure 4 shows that in 1980.
female nonemployment was more common everywhere and was particularly
high in Appalachia.
(13.) Online appendix figures 6 and 7 show the convergence of
nonemployment rates at the state level, which has gotten weaker over
time.
(14.) Online appendix figure 12 shows the division.
(15.) Online appendix figure 14 shows the cumulative growth by
region based on a three-year pooled moving average. Online appendix
figures 15 and 16 show the growth in per-worker GDP and employment.
(16.) Online appendix figures 28 and 29 show the increase in
incarceration rates.
(17.) Although real hourly wages for the 10th percentile of the
U.S. male income distribution were lower in the 1980s and 1990s than
they had been in 1979, by 1999 hourly real wages had recovered.
(18.) Online appendix figure 17 shows the share of manufacturing
across the United States.
(19.) As Goldin and Katz (2008) document, industrial areas saw less
reason to invest in education.
(20.) Heterogeneity in these variables across states is shown in
online appendix figures 30, 31, and 32.
(21.) Adult retraining for the displaced and nonemployed would also
seem to be highly desirable, but the literature on such problems is
decidedly mixed.
(22.) We include a somewhat richer model in the online appendix.
(23.) Albouy (2010) makes a related point by emphasizing how
standard progressive income taxation, without an explicit spatial
dimension, distorts spatial decisions. Income taxes induce people to
choose amenities and low housing costs rather than high incomes,
although the distortionary impact of the income tax is diminished by the
home mortgage interest deduction.
(24.) We can rewrite this as
[1/1 - [gamma]][e.sup.ln([y.sup.1 - [gamma]])] = [1/1 -
[gamma]][e.sup.-([gamma] - 1)ln(y),
and from this point, the standard constant absolute risk aversion
calculations follow to derive a linear mean-variance frontier.
(25.) Distorting migration can itself be part of the benefit for
residents of poorer areas, if out-migration reduces employment for the
remaining residents, as shown by Greenwood and Hunt (1984).
(26.) Some of these concerns are remedied in the online appendix.
(27.) We are implicitly assuming that k represents a national
rather than a local externality. Results are not significantly changed
if k is treated as a local cost borne by potential migrants.
(28.) Our discussion of this question builds on the work of Bartik
(2015), who finds some evidence that local demand shocks have a greater
impact in areas with higher initial unemployment rates. A large number
of previous studies have also examined the persistence of local labor
demand shocks, with varying conclusions.
(29.) These results are merely suggestive of the importance of
regional heterogeneity. The size and statistical significance of
heterogeneity is dependent on the exact form chosen. We have focused on
the interaction of shocks with the initial not-working rate, but other
state characteristics may also be important.
(30.) A number of other studies have examined the heterogeneous
impact of government expenditures at the local level. For example, see
Dube, Kaplan, and Zipperer (2015). A general review of local multipliers
is provided by Chodorow-Reich (2017).
(31.) The welfare effects of such spillovers would be ambiguous.
Not-working people benefit from having more not-working friends, even if
others pay the costs of a generally higher not-working rate.
(32.) For example, Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991) find that partial
elasticity varies depending on the income distribution of men, with an
average value of 0.13 and a high value of 0.35 for men in the 10th
percentile of income. Meghir and Phillips (2010) similarly find a higher
elasticity of 0.4 for low-income men in the United Kingdom. Broader
reviews include those by Blundell and MaCurdy (1999) and Chetty and
others (2013).
(33.) We make the simplifying assumption that the labor elasticity
in the region is constant as we change the employment subsidy. We
recognize that this is not entirely accurate, and a more complete
calibration would involve imputing the reservation wages for not-working
men in each region.
(34.) In a broader model, the funds could come from other sources
than just taxes on low-income earners.
(35.) A host of studies also find effects of highways on local
property values (Chernobai, Reibel, and Carney 2011). A working version
of the paper by Duranton and Turner (2012) found that more highway miles
were associated with slight decreases in the number of poor people and
the number of high school dropouts, suggesting that if anything the
sorting effects of infrastructure are slightly positive.
(36.) Ades and Glaeser (1995) argue that political forces explain
why the capital cities of dictatorships and unstable democracies are
about 40 percent larger than the capital cities of stable democracies.
There is little doubt that enough government spending of the right kind
can have an impact on a local economy.
(37.) A second unplanned federal place-making policy was the
Bayh-Dole Act of 1980. which allowed researchers to capitalize on ideas
developed with the support of federal grants. Hausman (2017) shows that
economic activity increased around universities after the act.
(38.) There is compelling evidence that quasi-random increases in
property taxes, caused by court-mandated property revaluation, is
capitalized into low property values (Yinger and others 1988). Stull and
Stull (1991) find evidence for capitalization of differences in local
income taxes in the Philadelphia area.
(39.) Albouy (2010) has argued that the spatial implications of the
deduction are helpful in undoing the spatial distortions created by the
income tax itself, which deters people from moving to high-income areas.
(40.) Bartik and Erickcek's (2014) discussion of targeted
training programs does not explicitly focus on spatial targeting, but
the possibility is clearly implicit in their discussion.
(41.) Spatial targeting could also be done with the much larger set
of federal government contractors. Yet imposing added geographic
restrictions on contractors would be cumbersome, and would make other
objectives, such as supporting minority-owned businesses, more
difficult. Moreover, geographic targeting would be quite susceptible to
gaming. We suspect that a requirement to use Kentucky-based software
providers would lead to relabeling rather than large-scale employment in
Kentucky.
Table 1. Geographic Predictors of Not Working and Income (a)
Not-working rate, 2010 (b)
(1) (2) (3)
College graduation -0.134 (***) -0.076 -0.068
rate, 1980 (d)
(0.050) (0.053) (0.044)
Share with less than 0.276 (***) 0.368 (***) 0.394 (***)
a high school
education, 1980 (e) (0.075) (0.081) (0.072)
Share of employment 0.085 (*) 0.091 (***)
in durable
manufacturing, 1980 (0.047) (0.034)
Share of employment -0.233 (***) -0.187 (**)
in nondurable
manufacturing, 1980 (0.075) (0.071)
Average January 0.002 (***)
temperature ([degrees]F)
(0.000)
Average July -0.005 (***)
temperature ([degrees]F)
(0.001)
[R.sup.2] 0.337 0.409 0.474
No. of observations 538 538 538
Median wage, 2010 (c)
(4) (5) (6)
College graduation 66,088 (***) 73,041 (***) 73,489 (***)
rate, 1980 (d)
(10,066) (7,838) (7,806)
Share with less than -15,005 (*) -13,478 -11,900
a high school
education, 1980 (e) (8,280) (8,209) (8,781)
Share of employment 14,779 (***) 14,510 (**)
in durable
manufacturing, 1980 (4,729) (5,626)
Share of employment 18,540 (*) 20,120 (*)
in nondurable
manufacturing, 1980 (10,956) (10,974)
Average January 68
temperature ([degrees]F)
(93)
Average July -200
temperature ([degrees]F)
(186)
[R.sup.2] 0.478 0.510 0.513
No. of observations 538 538 538
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, 1980 census, American Community Survey;
IPUMS; National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration; authors'
calculations.
(a.) Data for 1980 are from the 1980 census; data for 2010 are pooled
2009-11 data from the American Community Survey. The sample includes
civilian noninstitutionalized prime age men in 1980-2000 consistent
Public Use Microdata Areas in the continental United States (excluding
the District of Columbia). Regressions include a constant term. Robust
standard errors clustered by state are in parentheses. Statistical
significance is indicated at the (***) 1 percent, (**) 5 percent, and
(*) 10 percent levels.
(b.) The not-working rate is defined as the share of the population not
currently employed.
(c.) Median wage, expressed in 2016 dollars, is calculated using
reported annual wage income for respondents who usually work more than
35 hours per week and who worked at least 50 weeks in the past year,
excluding those reporting zero wages.
(d.) The college graduation rate is defined as the share of respondents
who report completion of four or more years of college.
(e.) The share with less than a high school education is defined as the
share of respondents who report completion of eleven or fewer years of
education in the 1980 sample.
Table 2. The Probability of Not Working for Prime Age Men, 1980-2010 (a)
(1) (2)
2010 2010
Eastern 0.021 (**) 0.008
heartland (b)
(0.009) (0.007)
Western -0.030 (***) -0.034 (***)
heartland (b)
(0.008) (0.007)
High school -0.094 (***)
education (c)
(0.019)
Some college -0.152 (***)
education (c)
(0.021)
College -0.229 (***)
education (c)
(0.021)
College -0.136 (***)
education
rate for
men in 1980 (0.018)
Corruption (d)
Right to work
Occupational
licensing
rate
No. of 1,664,011 1,664,011
observations
(3) (4)
2010 2000
Eastern 0.011 -0.019 (**)
heartland (b)
(0.008) (0.009)
Western -0.036 (***) -0.013
heartland (b)
(0.007) (0.009)
High school -0.094 (***) -0.159 (***)
education (c)
(0.019) (0.005)
Some college -0 152 (***) -0.206 (***)
education (c)
(0.021) (0.005)
College -0.229 (***) -0.255 (***)
education (c)
(0.021) (0.005)
College -0.142 (***) -0.075 (***)
education
rate for
men in 1980 (0.018) (0.026)
Corruption (d) -0.044 0.068 (**)
(0.027) (0.034)
Right to work -0.004 -0.017 (**)
(0.004) (0.007)
Occupational 0.104 0.176 (***)
licensing
rate
(0.062) (0.052)
No. of 1.664,011 2,858,392
observations
(5) (6)
1990 1980
Eastern 0.002 0.003
heartland (b)
(0.008) (0.007)
Western 0.007 -0.015 (**)
heartland (b)
(0.005) (0.006)
High school -0.128 (***) -0.099 (***)
education (c)
(0.007) (0.005)
Some college -0.158 (***) -0.109 (***)
education (c)
(0.007) (0.005)
College -0.194 (***) -0.147 (***)
education (c)
(0.007) (0.006)
College -0.092 (***) -0.117 (***)
education
rate for
men in 1980 (0.022) (0.021)
Corruption (d) 0.050 -0.004
(0.030) (0.027)
Right to work -0.023 (***) -0.019 (***)
(0.005) (0.004)
Occupational 0.132 (***) 0.102 (**)
licensing
rate
(0.046) (0.040)
No. of 2,473,956 2,013.485
observations
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau. 1980. 1990, and 2000 censuses, American
Community Survey; IPUMS; Glaeser and Saks (2006); Kleiner and
Vorotnikov (2017); authors' calculations.
(a.) Data for 1980, 1990, and 2000 are from the decennial censuses;
data for 2010 are pooled 2009-11 data from the American Community
Survey. The sample includes civilian non-institutionalized prime age
men in 1980-2000 consistent Public Use Microdata Areas in the
continental United States (excluding the District of Columbia).
Individual respondents are weighted using sampling weights. Regressions
include a constant term. Robust standard errors clustered by state are
in parentheses. Statistical significance is indicated at the (***) 1
percent, (**) 5 percent, and (*) 10 percent levels.
(b.) The omitted category is the coasts.
(c.) The omitted category is less than a high school education.
(d.) Corruption is measured using average annual corruption convictions
per 100.000 residents, following Glaeser and Saks (2006).
Table 3. State- and PUMA-Level Bartik Analysis (a)
Growth in state not-working rate (b)
(1) (2)
Bartik employment -0.665 (***) -0.447 (***)
growth (e)
(0.034) (0.104)
Historical
not-working
rate (f)
Bartic employment -2.013 (**)
growth
x historical (0.994)
not-working
rate (e,f)
State fixed effects Yes Yes
Time trend Yes Yes
Year fixed effects No No
No. of observations 1,872 1,872
Growth in state Growth in the house
not-working rate (b) price index (c)
(3) (4) (5) (6)
Bartik employment 0.198 0.440 (**) 0.295 -0.218
growth (e)
(0.149) (0.211) (0.450) (0.517)
Historical
not-working
rate (f)
Bartic employment -2.129 (**) 4.535
growth
x historical (1.060) (2.885)
not-working
rate (e,f)
State fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time trend No No No No
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
No. of observations 1,872 1,872 1,584 1,584
Growth in PUMA not-working rate (d)
(7) (8)
Bartik employment -0.859 (***) -0.523 (***)
growth (e)
(0.137) (0.136)
Historical -0.015 (***) 0.011 (*)
not-working
rate (f)
(0.004) (0.005)
Bartic employment -2.341 (***)
growth
x historical (0.384)
not-working
rate (e,f)
State fixed effects Yes Yes
Time trend No No
Year fixed effects Yes Yes
No. of observations 11,693 11,693
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, Annual Social
and Economic Supplement, American Community Survey; Federal Housing
Finance Agency; authors' calculations.
(a.) The not-working rate is defined as the share of the population not
currently employed. Robust standard errors clustered by state are in
parentheses. Statistical significance is indicated at the (***) I
percent, (**) 5 percent, and (*) 10 percent levels.
(b.) Data at the state level are from the 1978-2016 Annual Social and
Economic Supplements of the Current Population Survey. The sample
includes civilian noninstitutionalized prime age men in the continental
United States (excluding the District of Columbia).
(c.) The growth in the house price index is calculated by averaging the
quarterly all-transaction index from 1984 to 2016.
(d.) Data at the PUMA level are from the 2006-16 American Community
Surveys. The sample includes noninstitutionalized prime age men in
1980-2000 consistent PUMAs in the continental United States.
(e.) Bartik employment growth shocks are calculated based on predicted
growth in employment based on 1977 (state) or 2005 (PUMA) industry
shares and industry employment growth rates for all workers in the
continental United States.
(f.) Historical refers to 2005 for PUMAs.
Table 4. The Impact of Chinese Import Shocks on Not Working, 1990-2007
(a)
Change in
not-working rate
(1) (2)
Change in trade 0.831 (***)
exposure (0.172)
Change in trade 0.823 (***)
exposure, baseline (0.173)
zones, [[beta].sub.l]
Change in trade 0.597 (*)
exposure, high (0.318)
not-working rate
zones, [[beta].sub.h]
- [[beta].sup.c.sub.l]
Percentage of total -0.068 (**) -0.066 (**)
employment in (0.028) (0.028)
manufacturing, t - 1
Percentage of -0.031 -0.027
population that (0.030) (0.029)
is college educated,
t - 1
Percentage of -0.108 (***) -0.106 (***)
population that is (0.024) (0.024)
foreign born, t - 1
Percentage of total 0.191 (**) 0.199 (**)
employment that is (0.090) (0.092)
female, t - 1
Percentage of total 0.217 (**) 0.226 (**)
employment in (0.095) (0.094)
routine occupations,
t - 1
Average offshorability -1.142 (*) -1.204 (*)
index of occupations, (0.660) (0.661)
t - 1
Census region fixed Yes Yes
effects
Period fixed effects Yes Yes
No. of observations 1,444 1,444
Change in long-term not-working rate (b)
(3) (4)
Change in trade 0.372 (***)
exposure (0.093)
Change in trade 0.368 (***)
exposure, baseline (0.094)
zones, [[beta].sub.l]
Change in trade 0.339 (*)
exposure, high (0.191)
not-working rate
zones, [[beta].sub.h]
- [[beta].sup.c.sub.l]
Percentage of total -0.015 -0.013
employment in (0.014) (0.014)
manufacturing, t - 1
Percentage of -0.010 -0.007
population that (0.014) (0.014)
is college educated,
t - 1
Percentage of -0.051 (***) -0.050 (***)
population that is (0.011) (0.011)
foreign born, t - 1
Percentage of total 0.002 0.006
employment that is (0.030) (0.031)
female, t - 1
Percentage of total 0.044 0.049
employment in (0.050) (0.050)
routine occupations,
t - 1
Average offshorability -0.187 -0.222
index of occupations, (0.270) (0.270)
t - 1
Census region fixed Yes Yes
effects
Period fixed effects Yes Yes
No. of observations 1,444 1,444
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, 1990 and 2000 censuses, American Community
Survey; IPUMS; Autor. Dorn, and Hanson (2013); authors' calculations.
(a.) The not-working rate is defined as the share of the population not
currently employed. Data for 1990 and 2000 are from the decennial
censuses; data for 2007 are pooled 2006-08 data from the American
Community Survey. The sample includes noninstitutionalized prime age
men. Regressions are weighted as by Autor, Dorn. and Hanson (2013).
Robust standard errors clustered by state are in parentheses. The
change in trade exposure and controls at the commuting zone level are
for the entire working population. Statistical significance is
indicated at the (***) 1 percent, (**) 5 percent, and (*) 10 percent
levels.
(b.) Long term is defined as more than 12 months.
(c.) Zones with high not-working rates are in the top 10 percent of the
distribution of not-working rates for prime age men in 1990.
Table 5. The Impact of Government Spending Shocks on Not Working,
1980-2006 (a)
Percentage change in the not-working
rate for prime age men
1-year change 2-year change
(1) (2) (3)
Prime military -6.218 -6.370 (*)
contracts
(4.587) (3.578)
Prime military -5.725
contracts,
baseline states,
[[beta].sub.l]
(4.464)
Prime military -11.051 (**)
contracts,
high not-working
rate states, (4.900)
[[beta].sub.h]
- [[beta].sub.l.]
State fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
No. of observations 1,377 1,377 1,377
Percentage change in the not-working
rate for prime age men
2-year change 3-year change
(4) (5) (6)
Prime military -9.613 (**)
contracts
(4.153)
Prime military -6.214 (*) -9.491 (**)
contracts,
baseline states,
[[beta].sub.l]
(3.587) (4.168)
Prime military -1.553 -3.048
contracts,
high not-working
rate states, (5.551) (5.181)
[[beta].sub.h]
- [[beta].sub.l.sup.b]
State fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
No. of observations 1,377 1,377 1,377
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, Annual Social
and Economic Supplement; IPUMS; Nakamura and Steinsson (2014); authors'
calculations.
(a.) The not-working rate is defined as the share of the population not
currently employed. The change in prime military contract spending as a
share of output per capita is instrumented using national per capita
spending as a share of output, as described by Nakamura and Steinsson
(2014). The sample includes noninstitutionalized prime age men. Robust
standard errors clustered by state are in parentheses. Statistical
significance is indicated at the (**) 1 percent, (**) 5 percent, and
(*) 10 percent levels.
(b.) States with high not-working rates are in the top 25 percent of
the distribution of mean not-working rates for prime age men from 1980
to 2006.
Table 6. Income Sources for Prime Age Men, 2010-16 (a)
Employed Not working, less
than 12 months
Source Total Low Living Living with
income alone (c) others
(b)
Total family income 93,939 24,522 35,744 65,810
Total individual income 63,931 21,471 35,699 33,280
Wages 58,038 19,000 28,712 27,452
Investments or business 4,938 1,711 2,306 2,326
Retirement 205 23 506 376
Workers' compensation 36 25 151 150
Family transfers 33 43 378 65
Total government support 605 645 3,547 2,827
Unemployment 234 331 2,032 1,877
compensation
Disability insurance 99 135 793 376
Veterans' benefits 126 37 224 156
Other 146 142 497 418
Other sources 76 24 100 85
Percentage of 81.7 19.3 1.0 5.5
prime age men
Not working,more than 12 months
Source Living Living with
alone (c) others
Total family income 12,682 42,757
Total individual income 12,583 8,227
Wages 0 0
Investments or business 673 343
Retirement 746 950
Workers' compensation 327 305
Family transfers 539 146
Total government support 9,966 6,400
Unemployment 949 942
compensation
Disability insurance 7,532 4.471
Veterans' benefits 1,009 510
Other 476 476
Other sources 333 83
Percentage of 1.8 10.0
prime age men
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau. Current Population Survey. Annual Social
and Economic Supplement; IPUMS: authors' calculations.
(a.) The sample includes noninstitutionalized prime age men with
nonnegative incomes. The data are pooled over 2010-16. Except for the
final row, the units are real 2016 dollars.
(b.) Low income is defined as having annual family earnings below
$40,000.
(c.) Respondents are classified as living alone if there are no other
residents age 18 or over in the household.
Table 7. Income Sources for Long-Term Not-Working Prime Age Men,
2010-16 (a)
Source Coasts Eastern Western heartland
heartland
Total family income 40,318 34,859 36,897
Total individual income 8,665 9,283 8,964
Wages 0 0 0
Investments or business 400 275 541
Retirement 890 850 1,089
Workers' compensation 358 254 244
Family transfers 211 145 279
Total government support 6,652 7,688 6,711
Unemployment 1,072 756 862
compensation
Disability insurance 4,584 5,834 4,661
Veterans' benefits 499 638 751
Other 498 461 438
Other sources 154 69 100
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, Annual Social
and Economic Supplement; PUMS; authors' calculations.
(a.) The sample includes civilian noninstitutionalized prime age men
with nonnegative incomes in the continental United States (excluding
the District of Columbia). Long term is defined as more than 12 months.
The data are pooled over 2010-16. The units are real 2016 dollars
Table 8. Expenditures of Prime Age Men, 2016 (a)
Employed, Long-term
Employed, Employed, living alone, not working,
Income or total living low income living alone
expenditure alone (b) (b,c) (b,d)
Pretax household 98,575 55,898 22,190 12,870
income
Tax 15,397 9,449 1,326 566
Posttax household 83,170 46,444 20,861 12,301
income
Total 64,694 43,508 28,086 20,686
expenditures
Food 9,491 6,506 5,091 3,830
Housing 21,250 14,752 10,857 9,221
Apparel and 1,283 721 452 336
services
Transportation 10,297 6,935 4,664 2,918
Personal care 349 168 129 55
Health care 3,963 2,099 1,222 1,044
Entertainment 3,024 2,015 1,159 975
Alcohol 722 766 475 179
Tobacco products 325 345 398 459
Other expenditures 13,989 9,200 3,639 1,669
Sources: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Expenditure Survey;
authors' calculations.
(a.) The sample includes noninstitutionalized prime age men. The units
are dollars
(b.) Respondents are classified as living alone if there are no other
residents age 18 or over in the household.
(c.) Respondents are classified as low income if their household pretax
income is less than $40,000.
(d.) Long term is defined as more than 12 months.
Table 9. Time Use by Prime Age Men, 2003-16 (a)
Employed
Eastern Western
Activity Coasts heartland heartland Coasts
Personal care 530 529 529 598
Household activities 74 83 75 115
Food preparation 76 73 76 67
Caring for others 41 42 41 56
Working 392 382 401 33
Searching for work 1 1 1 21
Education 6 5 6 35
Leisure 257 262 248 450
Socializing 36 37 34 51
Watching TV 137 142 133 258
Computer use (b) 17 17 17 41
No. of observations 19,213 9,738 10,258 2,590
Not working
Eastern Western heartland
Activity heartland
Personal care 604 587
Household activities 114 122
Food preparation 62 62
Caring for others 51 53
Working 28 32
Searching for work 16 21
Education 22 38
Leisure 481 449
Socializing 57 56
Watching TV 303 269
Computer use (b) 34 37
No. of observations 1,480 1,068
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, American Time Use Survey; IPUMS; authors'
calculations.
(a.) The sample includes civilian noninstitutionalized prime age men in
the continental United States (excluding the District of Columbia). The
data are pooled over 2003-16. The weighted means include respondents
who report zero time spent on an activity. Except for the final row,
the units are minutes per day.
(b.) Computer use includes playing games (activity 120307) and computer
use for leisure, excluding games (activity 120.308).
Table 10. Estimating the Elasticity of the Labor Supply
(1) (2) (3)
OLS IV OLS
Log wage (b) -0.038 -0.093 -0.008
(0.027) (0.080) (0.021)
Not-working rate, -12.248 (***) -22.633 (***) -12.611 (***)
1980 (c)
(2.874) (4.144) (2.624)
Log wage x 1.102 (***) 2.126 (***) 1.152 (***)
not-working
rate, 1980 (b,c) (0.277) (0.404) (0.256)
College graduation 0.009 0.045 0.028
rate, 1980 (d) (0.032) (0.052) (0.029)
Share with less -0.097 (**) -0.029 -0.107 (**)
than a high school (0.042) (0.061) (0.049)
education, 1980 (e)
Period fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
State fixed effects No No Yes
Implied elasticity
Wyoming 0.03 0.05 0.07
West Virginia 0.14 0.26 0.18
First-stage F
statistic
Log wage 14.6
Interaction term 8.4
No. of observations 1,614 1,614 1,614
(4)
IV
Log wage (b) 0.022
(0.075)
Not-working rate, -28.768 (***)
1980 (c)
(6.019)
Log wage x 2.772 (***)
not-working
rate, 1980 (b,c) (0.599)
College graduation 0.112 (*)
rate, 1980 (d) (0.064)
Share with less 0.118
than a high school (0.126)
education, 1980 (e)
Period fixed effects Yes
State fixed effects Yes
Implied elasticity
Wyoming 0.20
West Virginia 0.48
First-stage F
statistic
Log wage 14.4
Interaction term 7.3
No. of observations 1,614
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau, 1980, 1990, and 2000 censuses. American
Community Survey; IPUMS; authors' calculations.
(a.) The dependent variable is the log employment-to-population ratio.
Data for 1980, 1990. and 2000 are from the decennial censuses; data for
2010 are pooled 2009-11 data from the American Community Survey. The
sample includes civilian noninstitutionalized prime age men in
1980-2000 consistent Public Use Microdata Areas in the continental
United States (excluding the District of Columbia). Robust standard
errors clustered by state are in parentheses. Statistical significance
is indicated at the (***) 1 percent, (**) 5 percent, and (*) 10 percent
levels.
(b.) Log wage, expressed in 2016 dollars, is the 25th percentile of
total annual wages for respondents who are currently employed. Changes
in log wages are instrumented using Bartik employment growth shocks,
which are calculated based on predicted growth in employment based on
1980 industry shares within Public Use Microdata Areas and industry
employment growth rates for all workers in the continental United
States.
(c.) The not-working rate is defined as the share of the population not
currently employed.
(d.) The college graduation rate is defined as the share of respondents
who report completion of four or more years of college.
(e.) The share with less than a high school education is defined as the
share of respondents who report completion of eleven or fewer years of
education in the 1980 sample.
Table 11. Estimates of the Optimal Consumption Ratio of Not-Working
Individuals to Employed Individuals
Estimate Wyoming Massachusetts West Virginia
At-risk not-working 39.5 48.6 61.3
rate (2014-16)
Elasticity of the 0.05 0.12 0.26
employment rate
Externality as a 36.3 36.3 36.3
percentage of wages
Ratio of consumption
[gamma]=0.5 0.919 0.831 0.718
[gamma]= 1.0 0.958 0.911 0.848
[gamma]=2.0 0.979 0.955 0.921
Sources: U.S. Census Bureau. Current Population Survey; 1PUMS: authors'
calculations.
Table 12. A Taxonomy of Place-Based Policies
Policy Explicitly spatial Implicitly spatial
Direct public Tennessee Valley Interstate Highway
Authority System
investment Appalachian Relocation of
Regional public offices
Commission
Tax benefits or grants New Markets Agricultural subsidies
Tax Credit
for businesses Program Oil depletion allowance
Cassa del
Mezzogiorno
Tax benefits or grants Northern Norway Flood insurance
tax benefits
for individuals Customized training Nominal tax credits
programs
State and local
tax deductibility
Regulatory relief Chinese special Channel Islands
economic financial haven
zones Heterogeneous
environmental
Devens Enterprise regulations
Commission
COPYRIGHT 2018 Brookings Institution
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.