首页    期刊浏览 2025年06月06日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:It doesn't always pay to take the money and run
  • 作者:Alan B. Krueger N.Y. Times News Service
  • 期刊名称:Journal Record, The (Oklahoma City)
  • 印刷版ISSN:0737-5468
  • 出版年度:2001
  • 卷号:Jun 4, 2001
  • 出版社:Journal Record Publishing Co.

It doesn't always pay to take the money and run

Alan B. Krueger N.Y. Times News Service

Suppose your employer hands you a pink slip and offers you a choice: an annual payment of $8,000 a year for 30 years or a lump sum of $50,000 today. Which would you choose?

This is not just a hypothetical exercise. When it downsized in the early 1990s, the Defense Department offered many military personnel a similar choice. The military also provided pamphlets and counseling to explain how to make the choice wisely. To the surprise of most economists, the affected employees rarely followed the military's sound advice.

The decision should depend, of course, on how much one values money received today versus tomorrow. A bird in the hand is worth more today than tomorrow, but how much more? The difference between the value an individual places on a dollar received today as opposed to a year from now is called the discount rate.

Standard economic theory says that if capital markets work perfectly, people will borrow or lend until their discount rate equals the market rate for borrowing or lending. Someone with a low discount rate will save money and accumulate interest; someone with a high discount rate will borrow and accumulate debt. This should continue to the point where their personal discount rates equal the market rate.

Thus, with some justification, the military's pamphlet provided calculations of the current value of the annuity payment using a 7 percent discount rate, the interest rate on money market funds at the time. If the annuity's current value exceeds the value of the lump sum, the annual payment is a better deal.

Capital markets are not perfect, so different people have different discount rates. Someone who is unable to borrow, perhaps because of a bad credit rating, is likely to have a higher discount rate and therefore take the money and run.

Mounting evidence indicates that most people put excessive weight on a bird in the hand.

That $8,000 annual payment is worth more than $106,000 if future income is discounted at 7 percent a year -- more than double the value of the lump sum. If the discount rate is 10 percent, as high as the interest rate on 30-year fixed-rate mortgages has been the last decade, the promised $8,000 payment is still worth $83,000. The annual payment is a better deal for anyone who can borrow from a bank.

Yet when the military offered essentially this package, three- quarters of enlisted personnel selected the lump sum, according to an article by John Warner of Clemson University and Saul Pleeter of the Defense Department in the latest issue of The American Economic Review. The authors also examined a number of other separation packages. The break-even discount rate -- or rate that makes the lump sum and annuity payment equivalent -- varied from 17 percent to 20 percent, depending on years of service and salary. Over all, 92 percent of enlisted personnel and 51 percent of officers chose the lump sum.

Because the government could borrow at 7 percent at the time, Warner and Pleeter calculate that the Treasury saved $1.7 billion by offering the lump sum option.

Using a sample of 65,000 departing members of the armed forces, they estimated that the average personal discount rate, taking taxes into account, exceeded 25 percent. Discount rates were higher for the less educated, the young, minorities and those with dependents, and lower for officers.

Other studies have found that people have high discount rates outside the military as well.

What makes the Warner-Pleeter study unique is that they looked at a situation in which large sums were offered to people who made actual, not hypothetical, choices. Moreover, subjects were given advice that should have discouraged them from taking the lump sum.

Why are personal discount rates so high? An idea gaining currency among economists known as hyperbolic discounting is that individuals use a larger discount for shorter time periods. That is, a sum that will be received in 19 years is valued the same as a sum that will be received in 20 years, while money that will be received next year is highly discounted compared with money received today.

The Warner-Pleeter study, however, found little evidence for such telescopic behavior.

At a given break-even discount rate, the length of time over which benefits are paid is unrelated to the likelihood of choosing the lump sum.

For whatever reason, people act as if they have very high discount rates. Recognition of this fact helps to explain a number of other phenomena.

For example, it is not surprising that the public supports policies that could produce a budget deficit, like a tax cut.

High discount rates also help explain the tepid support for public investments, like child care or inner-city education; people are too impatient to wait for the returns when given the opportunity for an immediate tax cut.

2001Copyright
Provided by ProQuest Information and Learning Company. All rights Reserved.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有