首页    期刊浏览 2025年08月19日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Dynamics of private industrial space demand in Singapore
  • 作者:Sing, Tien F
  • 期刊名称:The Journal of Real Estate Research
  • 印刷版ISSN:0896-5803
  • 出版年度:2003
  • 卷号:Jul-Sep 2003
  • 出版社:American Real Estate Society

Dynamics of private industrial space demand in Singapore

Sing, Tien F

Abstract This study empirically examines the dynamics of the private industrial market in Singapore using a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM), which is derived based on the theoretical framework of an extended accelerator investment model. The GDP in manufacturing sector (LMGDP) and the composite leading indicator (LCLI) were two unrestricted long-run forcing variables included in the VECM for the industrial space demand. In the generalized forecast error variance decomposition analysis, one-standard deviation shocks to the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) was found to account for an average 67.10% of the variances of the private industrial space demand (LPRD). It was also found that the most volatile impulse responses from the industrial demand variance were inflicted by one-standard error shocks on the ecm and the manufacturing GDP terms.

Introduction

In Singapore, industrial real estate demand or take up in both private and public markets has been predicted in an adaptive process by looking at the absorption rate in the previous periods. The supply of new industrial real estate stocks was adjusted in a piece-meal basis with the objective of meeting the demand projection, which would presumably not differ substantially from the previous year's take-up.1 Koh (1987) undertook a rigorous study of industrial real estate stock demand using a two-stage least squares model. He found significant relationships between the industrial space demand and economic variables like industrial output, gross domestic product, manufacturing employment and wage, interest rate and investment commitment. In Koh's model, the positive effects of industrial output on the industrial real estate demand were indirectly channeled via the employment equation. There were also other unpublished researches that used Shenkel's (1965) employment model (Lam, 1984) and multiple regression models (MRM) (Chan, 1976; and Mao, 1977)2 to determine the industrial real estate stock investment in Singapore.

There were no direct tests of the acceleration effect of the industrial output on the industrial real estate stock in Singapore. The earlier empirical studies that tested the flexible accelerator models were based primarily on the industrial real estate data in the United States and the United Kingdom (Nicholson and Tebbutt, 1979; Wheaton and Torto, 1990; Giussani and Tsolacos, 1994; and Tsolacos, 1995). They all found positive relationships between industrial real estate stock adjustments and manufacturing outputs. When the test of the acceleration effects is done on the industrial real estate market in Singapore, two factors need to be taken into consideration. First, Singapore has gone through different phases of industrialization than the U.S. and the U.K. (Zhu, 2000).3 For manufacturing firms that move up the technological ladder, more physical real estate stock would be substituted for investments in advanced productive capitals. As a result, the level of production output may increase at the expense of smaller real estate capitals. Second, the constraint of land resource in Singapore may create inelasticity in the supply of physical industrial real estate stocks. Firms may, therefore, be induced to invest and procure more physical real estate stocks than required during the weak output cycle. They could then optimize the excess real estate stocks when the output cycle rebounds.

The technology-related substitution and the land resource constraint factors may create negative acceleration effects on the industrial real estate stock adjustment process. This study thus attempts to test the dynamics of private industrial real estate stock demand in Singapore using an expanded flexible accelerator model. This article is organized as follows. First, the empirical literature on industrial real estate is reviewed, which helps sets the objectives of the study. Next, the salient features of the structure and the stock-flow process of the industrial market in Singapore is discussed. This is followed by a discussion of the theoretical accelerator model that incorporates other economic variables. Next, the empirical methodology and data are discussed. An industrial real estate demand function that comprises both the long run correction and short run fluctuations of the economic variables is formulated using a vector error correction model (VECM) with lag terms. Based on the proposed VECM structure, the post estimation analyses that include in-the-sample forecasting, impulse response and variance decomposition of the shocks to exogenous variables are discussed. The final section presents the conclusions.

Singapore's Private Industrial Real Estate Market

For a land and resource scarce country, Singapore has been transformed into one of the fastest growing economies in the world in the thirty-five years since independence. The main engine of growth has been the manufacturing sector, which accounted for 25.17% of the total gross domestic product (GDP) on average for the periods from 1985:1 to 1999:4. Currently, the land allocated for industrial use constitutes 12.2% of the total available land,4 of which approximately 76.2% (as in 1985) was made up of state lands.5 The state lands for industrial use are supplied to the market via two channels: inter-government agency alienation and the government's land sale program. Industrial lands are alienated to government agencies involved in industrial development, which include Jurong Town Corporation (JTC), Housing Development Board (HDB), Port Authority of Singapore (PSA) and Land Transport Authority (LTA). Private developers or manufacturing firms are also allocated industrial lands via the land sale by tender program administered by the Urban Redevelopment Authority (URA). Privately owned industrial lands are another source of industrial real estate supply. Private industrial lands are mainly held in 99-year, 999-year or freehold tenures, whereas the industrial lands coming through the state-channels are either via the land sale or alienation arrangement on shorter leasehold tenures of either 30- or 60-years.

In 1968, the government of Singapore set up JTC to spearhead the industrialization plan and to develop large scaled industrial real estate facilities in the post-independent period. JTC has satisfactorily fulfilled its role as the national industrial development authority and become the largest supplier of industrial facilities in the country. To date, it has developed and managed thirty-five industrial estates in Singapore, which accommodate more than 7,000 companies in Singapore.6 There are three types of industrial facilities developed and provided by JTC: ready-built detached and flatted factories and prepared industrial land. The ready-built industrial facilities can be procured through either rent or purchase schemes. For firms that require customized factory premises, they can lease a prepared industrial land from JTC on 30-year, 30+30-year or 60-year leases and develop on it a build-to-specification factory that meets the investment and building criteria stipulated by JTC (Sing, 2002). HDB is another major public industrial facilities supplier, which develops mainly multi-tenanted factories and workshops in housing estates to directly tap the source of labor supply. PSA and LTA are not directly involved in the supply of industrial real estate stocks. The former develops and manages warehouses, whereas the latter uses industrial land mainly for vehicle depots.

Based on the real estate statistics7 compiled by the URA, the private market share of industrial stock varied from 65.24% to 75.49% from 1988 to 1999. A substantial portion of the private sector supply, as captured in the statistics, was made up of customized industrial premises built on land leased from JTC. The average annual private sector supply and take-up for 1988-1999(8) were recorded at 823,060 square meters (sm) and 739,670 sm. Exhibit 1 shows the annual supply and take-up data of industrial real estate stocks between 1988 and 1999. There was an apparent upward trend in the supply and demand of industrial real estate after 1992, which was partly caused by the active and more systematic industrial land sale program implemented by the URA. The annual supply of industrial real estate stock increased almost four-fold from 413,000 sm in 1992 to 1,538,000 sm in 1997. The industrial real estate demand also indicated a strong upward trend since 1988 before hitting the peak in 1995 with an annual take-up of 1,193,000 sm. Thereafter, the demand slowed down and hit the slump in 1998 following the aftermath of Asia's currency crisis in 1997. Weak demand and excess supply as a result of the failure of private industrial developers to defer their industrial development projects jointly contributed to the glut of industrial space in 1997 and 1998.

Theoretical Framework: Accelerator Model

The accelerator model predicts a positive relationship between investment expenditure and the rate of adjustment of the fixed capital stock to the desired level, on the assumption that there are no substitution and vintage effects between the real estate and other fixed capital stocks. Based on the accelerator model, investment in real estate stock can be derived in an acceleration pattern by increases in industrial output. There are variations in the time structure and rate of adjustment of the accelerator model. Clark (1917) proposed a rigid version of the accelerator model, which assumes no time lag in the delivery of the shortfall in capital stock. Chenery (1952) and Koyck (1954) proposed a flexible version of the accelerator model, which allows partial adjustments of actual and desired capital from period to period.

The accelerator model has been extended with variations to empirically analyze the industrial real estate stock adjustment process (Giussani and Tsolacos, 1994; Tsolacos, 1995; Nicholson and Tebbutt, 1979; and Wheaton and Torto 1990). In the early studies, different empirical data were used to proxy the industrial real estate stock, which include the new order of non-residential construction (U.K.) (Nicholson and Tebbutt, 1979), the stock of completed industrial space in fifty-two major metropolitan areas in the U.S. (Wheaton and Torto, 1990), the value of new orders of private industrial buildings and works in the U.K. at both the national level (Giussani and Tsolacos, 1994) and regional level (Tsolacos, 1995). The results all pointed to a significant positive relationship of the industrial stocks and the lagged changes in output.

In the neo-classical production function that consists only of two factors of production: capital (K) and labor (L), the output can be represented by a Cobb-Douglas function as Q = AK^sup [alpha]^L^sup [lambda]^, where A measures the scale or productivity of firms with a specific technology, [alpha] and [lambda] denote the elasticity of scale, such that the constant return to scale is defined when [alpha] = 1 - [lambda]. In this model, K is invariably referred to the production capital (K^sub p^), which takes the form of plant and machinery investment. The physical real estate investment (K^sub r^) is either implicitly subsumed under K, or it can be made explicit as an arithmetic component of K (i.e., K = K^sub p^ + K^sub r^), on the assumption that the two capitals are perfectly substitutable. However, the perfect substitutability assumption will no longer be valid, if K^sub r^ is inelastic in the short-term and vintage effects exist between K^sub p^ and K^sub r^.9 The two-factor production function may have to be expanded to incorporate K^sub r^ and K^sub p^ as two independent variables in the output function, Q = [function of](K^sub p^, K^sub r^, L).

For empirical analysis purposes, however, K^sub r^ is regarded as the sole endogenous variable in the capital-output function by assuming that K^sub p^ and L are perfectly elastic in supply. The desired real estate stock, K*^sub r^, can then be represented as:

where p is the product price, c is the user cost of capital, [sigma] is the elasticity of substitution and [mu] is the coefficient of capital in the production function. The user cost of capital, given the zero-tax environment, could be simplified to the following equation:

where q is the purchase price of new capital, [delta] is the rate of capital depreciation, [iota] is the interest rate and dq is the gain resulted by the product price increases. In the empirical model, q can be included as both supply-side and demand-side variables. From the developer's perspective (supply-side), q is represented by the building material costs, whereas from the user's perspective (demand-side), it is more appropriately represented by the industrial real estate price.

As "time to build" is an inherent feature in the delivery and construction of real estate stock (Kling and McCue, 1991), time lags in the stock adjustment process are inevitable. The rigid form of Clark's (1917) investment model is, therefore, not realistic. A more flexible form of stock adjustment model allows backlogs of undelivered or uncompleted stocks from the earlier periods to be partially fulfilled by the current period investment (I^sub t^). [beta] is the coefficient that regulates the previous periods' gaps between desired and actual stock. The desired level of new investment (I^sub t^), which excludes the replacement capital ([delta]K), is defined as:

where the elasticity of substitution is unity, [sigma] = 1, and [lambda](L) in the equation denotes the power series of the coefficient of adjustment in the lag operator, L. The theoretical model in Equation (3) forms the basic framework for the empirical analysis.

The composite leading indicator (CLI) that reflects the business confidence and prospects is included in the empirical model as a variable that represents the rational expectation of decision makers as argued in the critique of Lucas (1976). On the supply-side, unfilled space and changes in available floor space were found to be empirically significant in affecting industrial space demand by Giussani and Tsolacos (1994) and Tsolacos (1995). Therefore, the new annual industrial space supply by both public sector (PBS) and private sector (PRS) are included as flow variables that regulate the supply-demand mismatches in the industrial real estate market.10

Based on the extended flexible accelerator model and the user cost of capital function defined above, the reduced form empirical model for the industrial real estate stock demand ([Delta]K^sub r^) is specified as:

Empirical Methodologies

Data Source

In the earlier empirical studies, new construction order (Nicholson and Tebbutt, 1979; Giussani and Tsolacos, 1994; and Tsolacos, 1995) and completed stocks (Wheaton and Torto, 1990) of industrial real estate have been used to proxy the industrial stock demand. The construction starts and accumulated inventory figures are flow variables that represent the upstream process of investment decision. These variables may, however, not reflect adequately the time lags in the stock delivery and vacancy when the stock adjustment process is "sticky," (Grenadier, 1995).

This study covers the demand for the private industrial space in Singapore for a twelve-year period from 1987:4 to 1999:3. The quarterly time-series data of the cumulative industrial real estate stocks compiled by the URA of Singapore11 provides a direct measure of the actual take-up of physical industrial real estate inventory stocks. The net change in the occupied stocks between two consecutive quarters is used as a direct proxy for the private industrial space demand.

The industrial property price index published by the URA, which is computed based on caveats lodged with the Singapore's Land Registry, is the proxy for the price variable. This index shows the relative price between the current per square meter price and that in the base year of 1990. Other economic variables are obtained from the national statistic database, TRENDS, administered by the Department of Statistics of the Trade and Industry Ministry. The dependent and independent variables identified in the empirical model are listed in Exhibit 2. With the exception of the current bank interest rates and the inflation rate variables, all other variables are transformed into their natural logarithm terms. Then, the first order difference terms of the variables are computed.

Vector Error Correction Model for Industrial Space Demand

Based on the flexible accelerator and neo-classical investment model discussed earlier, the following empirical demand model is conceptually derived to explain the causal-relationships between the demand for private industrial space and other economic variables,

The gross domestic manufacturing product (LMGDP) is the closer proxy for the firms' performance in the manufacturing sector. The Composite Leading Indicator (LCLI)12 in the model provides a forward-looking indication of the economic outlooks and investors' confidence of the country. The two variables: LMGDP and LCLI, were found to establish significant long-run cointegrating relationships with the private industrial space demand (LPRD), in the pair-wise cointegration tests conducted using the Engle and Granger (E-G) (1987) two-stage estimation procedure (Exhibit 3). The results thus suggest that the manufacturing GDP and the composite leading indicator be included in the empirical model as long-run variables. The rest of the variables would be considered as short-run variables in the empirical model.

Unlike the empirical models of Kling and McCue (1991), Giussani and Tsolacos (1994) and Tsolacos (1995), a rental variable is not included in the empirical model due to the short rental time-series data for the private industrial space.13 The rental effect is captured by the private industrial property price index (LIPPI). However, as LIPPI is I(2) stationary as shown in the unit root tests14 (Exhibit 3), its first-difference term (DLIPPI) is represented in the demand function.

Cost is an important consideration for profit maximizing firms when evaluating the feasibility of industrial real estate projects. Building Material Index (LBMI) is the supply side proxy for the construction costs of industrial space, whereas the user cost of capital is used as a demand-side variable that measures the feasibility of industrial real estate projects. Omitting the tax factor, the user cost of capital is empirically represented by the prime interest rate (IR) and the inflation (IF), which reflects the transitory gain component of the user cost of capital.

The availability of industrial real estate stocks was found to be a significant factor in affecting the choice of industrial space by firms (Giussani and Tsolacos, 1994; and Tsolacos, 1995). The private supply (PRS) and public supply (PBS) of industrial space15 are included in the empirical model to examine the effects of private and public inventory stocks on the industrial space demand.

The vector error correction model (VECM) for private industrial space demand empirically combines both the long run and short run variables in a single regression equation. The manufacturing GDP and the composite leading indicator are unrestricted independent variables identified to have long-run relationships with the industrial demand variable. All other variables are included as exogenous stationary variables,16 either as first (DX^sub i^) or second (D2X^sub i^) order differenced variables, where X^sub i^ denotes the variable, to capture the short-run effects in the demand function.

Formulation of Vector Error Correction Model (VECM)

The Johansen's Maximum Likelihood (ML) tests of a four-period lagged17 Vector Autoregressive (VAR) private industrial space demand model with an unrestricted intercept and no trend term showed that there was at most one significant cointegrating vector in the model (Exhibit 4). The normalized cointegrating vector, which would be included as the long-run error correction mechanism (ecm) in the VAR model, is given below:

The standard errors, given in the parentheses of Equation (6), show that the estimated coefficients for LMGDP and LCLI are significant at the 5% level.

The ecm identified in Johansen's ML process is incorporated into the empirical VAR model to adjust for short-term deviations in the system. The final model, which is known as vector error correction model (VECM), with 4-lag orders is formulated to explain the causal-relationships between the change in private industrial space demand and other economic variables. The estimation results of the VECM model that consists of two unrestricted long run variables: the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) and the composite leading indicator (LCLI), an error correction mechanism (ecm) and other short-run variables in their respective differenced stationary order were summarized in Exhibit 5.

The R^sup 2^ of the VECM model indicated that the unrestricted long run variables, the error correction term and the exogenous economic and real estate market variables jointly explain 86.40% of the variations in the change in industrial stock demand.

The diagnostic test showed that the model has a robust functional form. The VECM model was also cleared of serial correlation problems, which was the result of a correct selection of the lag-length and the inclusion of the ECM term in the model.

The coefficient of ecm has a correct sign and is statistically significant at 5% level. However, the small value of -0.0559 for the ecm coefficient suggests that it would take a long time for the system to return to its equilibrium once it has been shocked. Other variables that show significant explanatory relationships with respect to the changes in industrial space demand include the manufacturing GDP variables in their first, second and also third order lags [DLMGDP(-1), DLMGDP(-2), DLMGDP(-3)], the first and third order lagged composite leading variables [DLCLI(-1) and DLCLI(-3)], the private sector supply variable (DLPRS) and the building material price index variable (DLBMPI), both in level terms. By dropping the variables that are not statistically different from zero, the parsimonious form of the VECM for the industrial demand (DLPRD) can be specified as follows:

Manufacturing Output and Industrial Space Demand Relationship

For a 12-year sample period between 1987:4 and 1999:3, the empirical results of the VECM model using Singapore data showed a negative relationship between the industrial space demand and the lagged changes in manufacturing outputs.18

The results contradicted those found in the empirical studies in the U.K. (Nicholson and Tebbutt, 1979; Giussani and Tsolacos, 1994; and Tsolacos, 1994) and the U.S. (Wheaton and Torto, 1990).

There are three possible explanations hypothesized for the negative, but significant effects of the three lagged orders manufacturing GDP [DLMGDP(-1), DLMGDP(-2) and DLMGDP(-3)] on the demand for industrial space (DLPRD):

1. Given the constraint on resources, firms may increase their outputs by replacing existing physical real estate space with other factors of production assuming that these factors of production are substitutable. Firms may decide to use more high-technology equipment and/or employ more labor or increase the operational hours in order to lift the level of manufacturing output. By increasing investments in advanced production technology and adopting a more efficient operation process, firms can achieve a higher level of manufacturing outputs in a smaller physical production space, since real estate capital is inelastic in supply in the short-term.

2. Due to the inherent lumpiness and indivisibility of real estate, it would not be practical for manufacturing firms to acquire industrial space on a piecemeal basis to meet their needs from time to time. With a longer-term objective in mind, firms in Singapore tend to develop or purchase industrial real estate space in excess of that required for the scale of production at the time of investment. The excess space can be easily translated into productive use with minimal transitory disruption to the production process when the needs arise in the future. The consolidation and/or partial conversion of excess real estate space to improve productive capacity is not technically captured in the demand statistics, unless new planning submission is made to the URA in the process. This may be one of the reasons that explain why an increase in output can be met without a corresponding adjustment to industrial real estate stock.

3. Public industrial real estate space offers an alternative source of supply to firms, which may choose to switch their production facilities from private to public industrial real estate space. The spatial switching is possible when the cost incurred in the switch is less than the incremental revenue generated from an increased output. The crisscrosses of the occupancy rates between the private and industrial real estate stocks as observed over the sample periods (Exhibit 6) may be construed as evidence of the intra-market switching of industrial space demand. This partly explains the negative relationship between the manufacturing output growth rate and the change in the private industrial real estate demand.

Post-Estimation Tests: Model Efficiency and Shocks

In-the-Sample Forecasting Tests

Using a shorter model estimation period from 1987:4 to 1998:4, in-the-sample forecasting tests for the VECM demand function for the period from 1999:1 to 1999:3 were carried out. The results of the in-the-sample residuals and forecast errors were summarized in Exhibit 7.

The results showed that the model was efficient in forecasting the short-term fluctuation of the DLPRD with a small root mean sum of squares of 0.0084. Exhibit 8 shows that the forecast values of the VECM closely track the actual changes in private industrial demand (LPRD) except for 1999:1, which could be due to the aftermath 'shocks' of the 1997 Asian currency crisis.

Variance Decomposition & Impulse Response

In the VAR model for industrial real estate construction that contains independent shocks like manufacturing employment, price, interest rates, real money stocks and real output, Kling and McCue (1991) found that employment shocks accounted for the majority of the variation in the industrial real estate construction. Employment, output and nominal interest rate shocks also inflicted significant positive responses in the industrial construction. In this study, dynamic responses of the industrial space demand to the shocks emanating from its own and other determinants were tested using the variance decomposition and impulse response analyses.

The generalized forecast error variance decomposition arising from one-standard error (S.E.) shock to the variables in the cointegrating relation was estimated. Exhibit 9 shows the decomposition of variances for the private industrial space demand (LPRD), the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) and the composite leading indicator (LCLI) over fifty estimation periods. The private industrial demand factor (LPRD) accounted for the majority of its own variance for the first seven periods. The self-inflicted industrial demand (LPRD) variability effects were shifted to and dominated by those inflicted by the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP). The average variance decompositions for selected sub-periods were computed in Exhibit 10. It was shown that one-standard deviation shock to the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) accounted for an average 67.10% of the variances of the private industrial demand (LPRD) followed by the self-inflicted shocks (LPRD) (28.79%) and theshocks on the composite leading indicator (LCLI) (15.18%). However, in the shorter terms of less than 15-periods, the own shocks from the industrial space demand (LPRD) appeared to be the most important determinant of the variation in industrial real estate demand.

The generalized impulse responses to one-standard error (S.E.) shocks in the industrial space demand VECM equation were plotted in Exhibit 11. The impulse responses to the shocks of the industrial space demand (LPRD) and the composite leading indicator (LCLI) were flat over the fifty estimation periods, though the responses inflicted by the composite leading indicator (LCLI) shocks fluctuated for the first sixteen periods, but within a narrow band of -0.06% and 0.29%. The strongest positive impulse response of 0.99% was inflicted by the shocks on the error correction mechanism (ecm) term at period 3, whereas the strongest negative ecm-inflicted impulse response of -1.04% was recorded at period t = 0. The shocks by the ecm and the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) created the most volatile responses for the change in the industrial space demand (LPRD), whereas the own shocks on the demand variable (?LPRD) inflicted the most consistent positive responses ranging between 0.41% and 0.47%.

It was also observed that opposite responses inflicted by the shocks on the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) and the error correction mechanism (ecm) terms occurred consistently in four-period intervals. This may imply that the negative responses inflicted by the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) shocks were corrected instantly in the model by the positive responses inflicted by the ecm shocks.

Conclusion

Based on the theoretical framework of an extended accelerator investment model, this study empirically formulated a VECM to explain the dynamic relationships between the private industrial space demand and other determinants. Compared to the earlier empirical studies that used U.S. and U.K. market data, the study that used data of Singapore-a small industrialized country that has undergone different phases of industrialization phases-offered significantly different insights into the predictability of the industrial space demand. Different institution and market structures between the U.S., the U.K. and Singapore also shed new light on how firms respond or react to economic and market shocks when making investment decisions on industrial real estate.

The GDP in the manufacturing sector (LMGDP) and the composite leading indicator (LCLI) were two variables that established cointegration relationships with the industrial real estate demand (LPRD) in the Engle-Granger cointegration tests. They were included as unrestricted long-run forcing variables together with a pre-determined error correction mechanism (ecm) in the VECM for the industrial space demand. The results of the VECM estimation showed negative relationships between the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) of different lag orders and the private industrial demand (DLPRD). The empirical evidence contradicted the empirical findings in the U.S. and the U.K., which did not explicitly address the issues of substitution and vintage effects of the real estate stocks.

Three possible reasons are hypothesized for the negative manufacturing outputs and industrial space demand relationship observed in this study. First, firms may substitute space for other factors of production when the demand for their output increases. Second, firms may take up more space than required for the existing scale of production and the excess space can be converted to meet the production needs of the short-term surge in the outputs. A possible switch of demand from the private to the public industrial market during a period of strong output growth may be the third contributory factor.

The rest of the selected economic variables, namely public industrial space supply, private industrial space supply, interest rates, industrial property price index, building materials price index and inflation rate, were found to have no cointegration relationship with the private industrial space demand. However, in the short-run, the private industrial space supply and the building materials price index were found to have significant effects on the private industrial space demand.

The results of the in-the-sample forecasting test showed that the VECM is efficient in predicting the demand for private industrial space. The generalized forecast error variance decomposition showed that one-standard deviation shocks to the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) accounted for an average 67.10% of the variances of LPRD followed by the private industrial demand self-inflicted shocks (LPRD) (28.79%) and the shocks on the composite leading indicator (LCLI) (15.18%). However, in shorter terms of less than fifteen periods, the own shocks on the private industrial demand (LPRD) appeared to be the most important determinant of the variation in industrial real estate demand. It was also found that the most volatile impulse responses of the industrial demand (LPRD) were inflicted by the shocks on the error correction mechanism (ecm) and the manufacturing GDP (LMGDP) variables.

The author wishes to thank P. T. Foo for her research assistance, and S. K. Lum and J. M. Zhu for their comments and discussion on the study.

End notes

1 The projection of industrial space demand based on the adaptive model was reliable in an expansionary phase of the economy in the early and mid 1990s, where sufficient demand is derived to absorb new industrial space supply. This adaptive projection, however, produced disastrous results in the declining phase of the economic growth at the end of 1997, during which mismatch of supply and demand projection led to a glut of industrial space.

2 The use of non-stationary time-series economic variables in the MRM is one of the critical constraints that cause spurious results in the MRM when it is applied to model the industrial space demand.

3 Singapore, as a newly industrialized country, has undergone different phases of industrial transformation from labor intensive, low value-added manufacturing in the 1960s and 1970s, to the high-technology, high value-added industrialization in the 1980s and 1990s and now the research-intensive and knowledge-based industries that concentrate in life-sciences, micro-electronic and wafer fabrication industries.

4 The statistic was obtained from the final consultant report of the Concept Plan Review Focus Group on Land Allocation (2001). The review group was convened by the Urban Redevelopment Authority (URA), the national planning authority, to look into the issues of land use allocation and optimization in the future.

5 A large proportion of state lands have been amassed over time by the government via the Land Acquisition Act (1966) (Zhu, 2000).

6 Source: "The JTC Story-Conquering Challenges," at the JTC corporate webpage at: http://www.jtc.gov.sg/.

7 The classification of public and private sector industrial property in the URA statistics was based on the details of the planning submission received from the applicants.

8 The statistics for 1999:4 were not available at the time of the analysis, and therefore, the figures computed for 1999 did not include the last quarter supply and demand figures.

9 Given the short-term inelasticity of Kr, coupled with the constraint on capital resources, i.e. K is not infinitely available, optimal choice of resources becomes critical in firms' decision-making process. Firms may substitute Kr for additional investments in advanced production technology, Kp. Firms thus achieve the output maximization objective at the expense of a smaller or even a negative change in fixed capital investment, Kr.

10 Exhibit 1 shows that there were consistent mismatches between the supply and demand in the private industrial real estate space. The situation was particularly evident after the government's liberalization of industrial land sale program in 1992, which partly led to the glut of industrial space in 1997.

11 The statistics on the existing stock of factory space are obtained through mail questionnaire surveys. Owners or managing agents of the completed industrial buildings are the respondents of these quarterly surveys.

12 The CLI indicator is constructed by the Economic Development Board based on the commitments and projections made on the new orders, money supply, stocks of finished goods, stock prices, company formation, wholesale prices for manufactured goods, real unit labor cost, business forecast for wholesale trade and the Central Provident Fund (CPF). The CPF is a form of compulsory saving of workers, which helps to take care of their home mortgage financing and healthcare and also provide financial security in their retirement.

13 The rental index for private industrial space in Singapore as compiled by the Inland Revenue Authority of Singapore is relatively short, and started only in 1990.

14 The DF and ADF statistics are not included in here, but they can be made available upon request.

15 In Singapore, the private and public sector share of the industrial space supply at 1999: 3 was estimated at 75% and 25% of the total industrial real estate stocks respectively.

16 The Dickey-Fuller (DF) test and Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit roots tests of up-to four lags showed that the building material price index (LBMPI) is stationary in level, ((0), and that the industrial property price index (LIPPI) is stationary in the second differencing order, ((2). All other variables are first-order differenced stationary, ((1), at a 5% significance level.

17 The 4-lag orders of the VAR model were selected based on the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and the Shwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC). The results of the lag-order selection criteria are not included, but will be made available upon request.

18 To reaffirm the negative sign of the coefficients, a cointegration regression involving only LMGDP and LPRD and their respective 3-lag terms is estimated. The results support the negative relationship between MGDP and PRD (see the Appendix).

References

Chan, C. W., A Study of the Supply and Demand of Industrial Land in Singapore, Unpublished B.Sc. dissertation, School of Building and Estate Management, National University of Singapore, 1976.

Chenery, H. B. Overcapacity and the Acceleration Principle, Econometrica, 1952, 20:1, 1-28.

Clark, J. M. Business Acceleration and the Law of Demand: A Technical Factor in Economic Cycles, Journal of Political Economy, 1917, 25:1, 217-35.

Engle, R. F and C. W. J. Granger, Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing, Econometrica, 1987, 55:2, 251-76.

Giussani, B. and S. Tsolacos, Investment in Industrial Buildings: Modelling the Determinants of New Orders, Journal of Property Research, 1994, 11, 1-16.

Grenadier, S. R. The Persistence of Real Estate Cycles, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1995, 10, 95-119.

Kling, J. L. and T. E. McCue, Stylized Facts About Industrial Property Construction, Journal of Real Estate Research, 1991, 6:3, 293-304.

Koh, A. A. M., An Econometric Model for Forecasting Industrial Space Demand in Singapore, Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Georgia, 1987.

Koyck, L. M., Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1954.

Lam, S. Q., Supply and Demand of Industrial Space, Unpublished B.Sc. dissertation, School of Building and Estate Management, National University of Singapore, 1984.

Lucas, R. E., Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique, Journal of Monetary Economics, 1976, 1, 19-64.

Mao, K. H., A Study of the Supply and Demand of Public Industrial Premises, Unpublished B.Sc. dissertation, School of Building and Estate Management, National University of Singapore, 1977.

Nicholson, R. J. and S. G. Tebbutt, Modelling of New Orders for Private Industrial Building, Journal of Industrial Economics, 1979, 28:2, 147-60.

Shenkel, W. M., Industrial Zoning Regulations and the Demand for Industrial Space, The Appraisal Journal, 1965, 55-64.

Sing, T. F., Renewal Options in Industrial Leases of Jurong Town Corporation, Journal of Property Investment & Finance, 2002, 22:3, 222-41.

Tsolacos, S., Industrial Property Development in the U.K.: A Regional Analysis of New Orders, Journal of Property Research, 1995, 12, 95-125.

Wheaton, W. C. and R. G. Torto, An Investment Model of the Demand and Supply for Industrial Real Estate, Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 1990, 18:4, 530-47.

Zhu, J. M., The Impact of Industrial Land Use Policy on Industrial Change, Land Use Policy, 2000, 17, 21-8.

Tien F. Sing, National University of Singapore, Singapore 117566 or rststf@nus.edu.sg.

Copyright American Real Estate Society Jul-Sep 2003
Provided by ProQuest Information and Learning Company. All rights Reserved

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有